External Conditions and Debt Sustainability in Latin America*

Contributor Notes

Author‘s E-Mail Address: gadler@imf.org; ssosa@imf.org

Highly favorable external conditions have helped Latin America strengthen its economic fundamentals over the last decade. But, has the region built enough buffers to guard itself from a weakening of the external environment? This paper addresses this question by developing a simple framework that integrates econometric estimates of the effect of global factors on key domestic variables that determine public and external debt dynamics, with the IMF‘s standard debt sustainability framework. Results suggest that, while some countries in the region are well placed to withstand moderate or even large shocks, many would benefit from having stronger buffers to be in a position to deploy countercyclical policies, especially under tail events. External sustainability, on the other hand, does not appear to be a source of concern for most countries.

Abstract

Highly favorable external conditions have helped Latin America strengthen its economic fundamentals over the last decade. But, has the region built enough buffers to guard itself from a weakening of the external environment? This paper addresses this question by developing a simple framework that integrates econometric estimates of the effect of global factors on key domestic variables that determine public and external debt dynamics, with the IMF‘s standard debt sustainability framework. Results suggest that, while some countries in the region are well placed to withstand moderate or even large shocks, many would benefit from having stronger buffers to be in a position to deploy countercyclical policies, especially under tail events. External sustainability, on the other hand, does not appear to be a source of concern for most countries.

I. Introduction

Over the last decade Latin America experienced an impressive strengthening of key macroeconomic fundamentals (Figures 1 and 2), especially during the period 2003-08, that ended with the global financial crisis triggered by the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers. The region not only displayed remarkable improvements in terms of stocks—reducing public and external debt levels, and accumulating public and foreign assets—and flows—improving primary fiscal and current account balances—but also notable changes towards less vulnerable debt structures—reducing the share denominated in foreign currency and extending maturity.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Latin America. Key Fiscal Indicators, 2002-12 1/

(simple average and 20th and 80th percentiles)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Sources: IMF International Financial Statistics, and country desks.1/ Latin America includes Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay and Venezuela.2/ Excludes Bolivia and Paraguay.
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Latin America. Key External Indicators, 2002-12 1/

(simple average and 20th and 80th percentiles)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Sources: IMF International Financial Statistics, and country desks.1/ Includes Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay and Venezuela.2/ Cumulative flow of gross international reserves since 2002.3/ At residual maturity.4/ Excludes Bolivia and Paraguay.

While, undoubtedly, prudent policies played an important role, these gains reflected to a significant extent the highly favorable external environment that the region benefited from during this period—interrupted only temporarily during the 2008-09 international financial crisis and characterized by strong external demand, an unprecedented boom in commodity prices, and very benign global financing conditions. However, with prospects of less favorable external conditions going forward, and even the possibility of a sharp deterioration associated with looming risks—e.g., an escalation of the euro area financial crisis—the regional policy debate is focusing on whether the region has taken full advantage of the ‘windfall’. In particular: Has the region built enough buffers to guard itself from external shocks?1,2

This paper sheds light on this question by studying the link between global variables—such as commodity prices, world growth, and financial market conditions—and a set of domestic variables (GDP growth, trade balance, real exchange rate, and sovereign spreads) that explain most—if not all—of the dynamics of public and external sustainability indicators. To this end, it develops a simple framework that integrates (i) econometric estimates of the effect of exogenous external variables on these key domestic variables with (ii) the IMF’s standard framework for debt-sustainability analysis (DSA). This integrated framework allows us to examine the evolution of public and external debt sustainability indicators (both in terms of stocks and flows) under alternative global scenarios; and consequently assess the adequacy of current levels of ‘buffers’ for eleven Latin American countries.3

The study entails a methodological contribution to the existing IMF framework for public and external DSA, as the latter is currently not equipped to assess how changes in external conditions affect debt dynamics, given its lack of linkages between global and domestic variables.4 Moreover, stress tests under the traditional DSA framework consider shocks to certain variables in isolation (output growth, interest rates, etc.), without taking into account the correlation among shocks and the joint dynamic response of some of these variables.

The paper relates to a growing literature seeking to improve debt-sustainability analysis. Most of these recent contributions (Celasun et al, 2006; Cherif and Hasanov, 2012; Favero and Giavazzi, 2007 and 2009; Kawakami and Romeu, 2011; and Tanner and Samake, 2008) have focused primarily on the joint stochastic properties of shocks, aiming at developing a probabilistic approach to DSA, including by incorporating explicit fiscal reaction functions to take into account the policy response to shocks and the feedback effects of fiscal policy on macroeconomic variables. Like our paper, they rely on a methodology that combines VAR models with debt feedback to assess the impact of a set of macroeconomic shocks on public debt dynamics. These studies, however, do not examine the impact of specific external shocks on debt dynamics—which are highly relevant for Latin America, especially for those economies that are highly financially integrated with international capital markets and/or rely heavily on commodity exports.5 In addition, most of these papers focus on a limited set of countries, and solely on public debt—without looking into external debt. Our paper contributes to the literature by filling this gap.

Our main results suggest that current fiscal positions in the region are, on average, adequate to deal with temporary and even moderate protracted external shocks, although fiscal space to face more severe protracted shocks could be limited. At the same time, there are important differences across countries especially with respect to their ability to deal with protracted shocks, with countries broadly falling into three groups: (i) a group (Argentina and Venezuela) that would face considerable fiscal sustainability issues under large shocks, and varying constraints even under moderate ones; (ii) a second group (Brazil, Ecuador, Mexico and Uruguay) that could manage moderate shocks but would benefit from building additional buffers to be in a position to deploy countercyclical policies under adverse scenarios, without reaching debt levels that could raise concerns about fiscal sustainability; and (iii) a third group (Bolivia, Chile, Paraguay, Peru and to a lesser extent Colombia) with a relatively solid position to withstand sizeable shocks—even responding with expansionary policies—without putting fiscal solvency at risk. Overall, these results suggest that many countries in the region would benefit from building further fiscal space while favorable conditions last, in order to be in a position to actively use fiscal policy should the external environment deteriorate markedly. In terms of the external position, our results indicate that, despite evidence of a recent widening in current account deficits, external sustainability does not appear to be a source of concern for Latin America in general.

The paper proceeds as follows: the next section presents key stylized facts about the factors behind the declining debt ratios in the region over the last decade. Section III describes the methodological approach used to examine how fiscal and external sustainability indicators would be affected under alternative (downside) scenarios. Section IV describes the scenarios under consideration and presents the main results, deriving an assessment of the adequacy of current buffers. Section V concludes with the key takeaways.

II. A Decade of Falling Public and External Debt, 2003-12

A. Fiscal sustainability

We first take a historical view at the drivers of public debt dynamics over the last decade, relying on the (accounting) decomposition offered by the IMF’s public DSA framework.6 For consistency across countries, we focus on general government gross debt, as reported by the World Economic Outlook. In most cases, this level of consolidation appropriately reflects the level of public indebtedness.7 In addition, while the focus on gross rather than net debt implies overlooking the recent accumulation of assets by the public sector in certain countries, this is unlikely to distort the results as the asset accumulation, when sizeable, has tended to coincide with low levels of gross debt, thus not changing the general conclusions of the sustainability assessment.

Pre-Lehman Period: 2003–08

Between 2003 and 2008, Latin America witnessed a steep improvement of its fiscal sustainability indicators, most notably bringing public debt-to-GDP ratios down, on average, by about 30 percentage points of GDP (Figure 3). The decline was primarily driven by a combination of the direct effect of rapid economic growth and sizeable primary surpluses. Negative real interest rates also appeared to have played a role in the downward debt dynamics in some countries.8 Interestingly, the marked real exchange rate appreciation observed during this period contributed only marginally to reduce debt levels.9

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Factors Driving Public Debt Dynamics, 2003-12 1/

(cumulative contributions since 2002, in percent of GDP, simple averages)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Sources: IMF International Financial Statistics, and authors' calculations.1/ Main factors driving public debt dynamics as identified in IMF's DSA framework.2/ Includes Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru, and Uruguay.3/ Includes Argentina, Bolivia, Ecuador, and Venezuela.

There are, however, visible differences across countries in the region, particularly regarding how they managed the rapidly raising revenues during this period. Indeed, the observed contribution of primary surpluses is not necessarily a reflection of fiscal discipline in all countries, as this was a period of economic bonanza characterized by strong growth and markedly higher commodity prices, and therefore a substantial increase in fiscal revenues.10

In the LA7 group (encompassing Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru, and Uruguay)11, a drop of 20 percentage points of GDP in public debt ratios reflected mainly the contributions of primary surpluses and rapid real GDP growth, with the former being the result of real public expenditures growing at a slower pace than booming revenues—and generally slower than potential GDP growth—(Figure 4). Chile, Colombia, Paraguay, and Peru displayed particularly restrained expenditure policies.12 A decomposition between commodity and non-commodity related revenues suggests that the extraordinary increase in revenues arose primarily from the commodity sector, as non-commodity revenues in these economies increased in line with real GDP at rates that, while higher than those observed in the previous decade, were broadly in line with long-term potential.13

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Components of Primary Balance Dynamics, 1995-2012 1/

(Index, 2003=100 unless otherwise stated, group averages in real terms)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Sources: IMF International Financial Statistics and authors' calculations.1/ Using GDP deflator for all series. Data on commodity-related revenues for Ecuador, Mexico and Venezuela (Chile) are available from 2000 (2005).2/ Expenditure base year equals percent of revenues in that year.3/ Based on projected growth for 2015-17.4/ Includes Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru, and Uruguay.5/ Includes Argentina, Bolivia, Ecuador, and Venezuela.

The rest of Latin America also experienced a remarkable fall in indebtedness during this period (averaging about 45 percentage points of GDP), although starting from much higher debt levels.14 In these cases, the decline was mostly driven by the direct effect of the economic boom on output (with GDP growth considerably above long-term potential, except in Bolivia) and by negative real interest rates.15 While primary balances also played an important role in reducing debt ratios, the extent of savings of the booming revenues (derived both from direct taxation on the commodity sector and from taxes on broad economic activity) was limited. Indeed, real public expenditure grew at a faster pace than potential GDP growth and even faster than observed output growth. As a result, and in contrast to the LA7 group, these countries spent a substantial fraction of the revenue boom.16

Post-Lehman Period: 2009–12

Public debt trends changed markedly in 2009, reflecting the effects of the global crisis. Since then, Latin America‘s debt ratios have remained broadly stable on average, at around 35 percent of GDP, mostly on account of no further contributions from primary balances. Again, there is a stark difference between LA7 and the rest of Latin America during this period.

After implementing significant fiscal stimulus during 2009-10, LA7 countries have been making efforts to consolidate their fiscal positions and recompose primary surpluses (most noticeably Chile and Peru), although the recent improvements in primary balances partly reflect the rebound in commodity-related revenues in some cases. The result has been a (modest) resumption of the declining trend in debt ratios in most countries of this group.

The rest of Latin America, in contrast, has shown a sustained deterioration in primary balances since 2009, turning primary surpluses into deficits and thus contributing to push debt ratios upwards.17 This deterioration has taken place despite the recovery of commodity-related revenues, as expenditure has continued to grow rapidly (significantly faster than potential GDP and even current GDP growth). In some of these economies, negative real interest rates on public debt have continued to play an important role supporting debt reduction (Argentina and Bolivia) or containing its increase (Venezuela).

B. External sustainability

Pre-Lehman Period: 2003–08

The dynamics of external debt during this period shares some of the trends observed for public debt. The region as a whole made significant progress in bringing down external debt-to-GDP ratios in this period, reducing them by more than 30 percentage points of GDP on average (Figure 5). Moreover, this sharp improvement was accompanied by a sizeable accumulation of foreign assets (reaching nearly 70 percent of GDP on a cumulative basis).18 However, once again, there are visible differences between the two groups of countries mentioned above.

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Factors Driving External Debt Dynamics, 2003-12 1/

(cumulative contributions since 2002, in percent of GDP, simple averages)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Sources: IMF International Financial Statistics, and authors' calculations.1/ Main factors driving public debt dynamics as identified in IMF's standard DSA framework.2/ Includes Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru, and Uruguay.3/ Includes Argentina, Bolivia, Ecuador, and Venezuela.

In the LA7 group, external debt declined by 25 percent of GDP, primarily on account of the significant real appreciation and external financing in the form of non-debt flows (especially FDI), combined with moderate current account surpluses.

The rest of Latin America (all of which are heavy commodity exporters) witnessed an even more remarkable drop in external indebtedness (reaching about 50 percentage points of GDP), although starting from much higher levels. This reduction was mainly explained by large current account surpluses—reflecting highly favorable terms of trade—as well as sizeable real exchange rate appreciation. Unlike for the LA7 group, the role of non-debt flows was quite limited. These economies accumulated large amounts of foreign assets (largely by the public sector in Bolivia and Ecuador, while mostly by the private sector in Argentina and Venezuela).

Post-Lehman Period: 2009–12

In 2009, however, the previous downward trend came to a halt—mainly reflecting a slowdown in real appreciation and a weakening of current account balances—leaving debt ratios at about 28-30 percent of GDP for both groups of countries.

In sum, despite the evident deterioration in debt trends after the Lehman event, the improvement in terms of both public and external debt sustainability over the last decade has been remarkable. At the same time, current debt levels are still, in some cases, relatively high and close to thresholds that are typically considered risky. In this context, and being many of these economies highly sensitive to external conditions, it is not obvious the extent to which countries across Latin America are well placed to withstand a significant deterioration in the external environment.

III. Methodological Approach

A. Public and External Debt Sustainability Analysis

This section describes the framework to examine how external conditions affect, through their impact on key domestic variables, the dynamics of public and external debt ratios.19 The framework entails mapping, by means or econometric estimates, how shocks to key global variables—commodity prices, world growth, and financial market conditions—affect a set of domestic variables—GDP growth, trade balance, real exchange rate, and sovereign spreads—that enter into the laws of motion of public and external debt.

A01ufig01

Illustration of Integrated Public and External Debt Sustainability Approach 1

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1 The diagram presents a simplified illustration of the integrated framework for public and external debt sustainability. Details and underlying assumptions are discussed in section III.

Once the econometric model is estimated and integrated with the DSA framework, one can undertake scenario analysis to evaluate the adequacy of the current fiscal or external position, by generating conditional forecasts of the endogenous domestic variables.

To start, we show how the law of motion of debt ratios can be expressed as a function of the small set of domestic variables mentioned above.

Public Debt

Consider the following equation that governs the path of public debt (in nominal, local currency, terms):

Dj,t=Ej,tDj,t1FC(1+rj,t1)+DJ,t1LC(1+ij,t1)PBj,t(1)

where Dj,t is country j’s nominal stock of public debt in period t; Dj,t1FC(Dj,t1LC) is the stock of foreign (domestic) currency-denominated debt; Ej,t is the nominal exchange rate vis-à-vis the U.S. dollar; rj,t-1 and ij,t-1 are the average interest rates on foreign and local currency debt respectively, and PBj,t is the nominal primary fiscal balance.

It is evident from the non-linearity of this equation that it is not possible to fully isolate the contribution of each of the main economic variables to the change in public debt. One can, however, write this equation in a way that approximates such contributions (as done in the IMF’s standard DSA).

Denote xtXt / GDPt as a nominal variable Xt expressed in percent of GDP; ij,te=αj,tij,t+(1αj,t)rj,t, as the effective average interest rate; πj,t as domestic inflation (GDP deflator); gj,t as real GDP growth and εj,t as the nominal depreciation of the domestic currency vis-à-vis the US dollar. Then, defining αj,t=Dj,tLC/Dj,t as the share of local-currency denominated debt, one can reduce equation (1) to a small number of terms:

Δdj,t=[ij,t1eπj,t(1+gj,t)]θj,t(gj,t)+[(1α)(1+rj,t)εj,t]θj,tpbj,t(2)

where θj,t={dj,t1(1+gj,t)(1+πj,t)}. The first term of equation (2) broadly captures the (accounting) contribution of the real interest rate; the second term captures the effect arising from real GDP growth; the third term captures the impact of exchange rate movements (through valuation effects on foreign currency-denominated debt); and the last term reflects the contribution of the primary balance.

Taking into account the share of debt falling due in the current period (γj,t-1) and subsequent periods (1-γj,t-1), we can model the dynamics of the average interest rate as a function of marginal interest rates:

ij,te=(1γj,t)ij,t1e+γj,t1{αij,t+(1α)rj,t}(3)

Assume the following pass-through structure from (global) risk-free interest rates (rt*) and sovereign spreads (Sj,t) into domestic interest rates (ij,t). That is, Δij,t=Δrt*+Δsj,t. Assume also that real and nominal exchange rate shocks map one-to-one: Δ In (reerj,t) = -εj,t.20

From equations (2) and (3), this set of (relatively innocuous) assumptions and from the fact that rj,t=rt*+Sj,t, one can show that dynamics of the public debt-to-GDP ratio is governed by the behavior of only four (endogenous) domestic variables:{s,g,reer,pb}.

Furthermore, one can model the primary balance in a simple fashion by decomposing it into commodity revenues, non-commodity revenues, and expenditures (all in percent of GDP):

pb=revc+revNCexp(4)

Subsequently, commodity revenues can be modeled as a function of the corresponding commodity prices:

revscenc=revBLc*(pscencpBLc)(5)

where revScenc(revBLc) are commodity-related revenues and pScenc(pBLc) are world commodity prices under a specific scenario (under the baseline).

Finally, a constant non-commodity revenue-to-GDP ratio is assumed (i.e., an elasticity equal to one), such that: revNC = η. Then, the dynamics of the public debt ratio is simply given by four endogenous domestic variables {s,g,reer,exp} and a set of exogenous global variables.

External Debt Dynamics

Similarly, to derive the set of variables that determine the path of the external debt-to-GDP ratio, one can start from the law of motion of external debt:

Dj,tE=Ej,tDj,t1E,FC(1+rj,t1)+Dj,t1E,LC(1+ij,t1)NICAj,tNDCFj,t(6)

where Dj,tE is the nominal stock of total external debt (expressed in local currency); Dj,t1E,FC(Dj,t1E,LC) is the stock of foreign (local) currency-denominated debt; rj,t-1 (ij,t-1) is the average interest rate on foreign (local) currency-denominated debt; NICAj,t is the current account balance excluding interest payments; and NDCAj,t are the non-debt-creating flows (FDI and equity portfolio).

Then, defining αj,tE=Dj,tE,LC/Dj,tEandij,te=αj,tEij,t+(1αj,tE)rj,t, we can derive the path of external debt in terms of a small set of factors:

Δdj,tE=ij,teσj,tgj,tσj,t+{(1αj,tE)(1+rj,t)εj,t}σj,tnicaj,tndcfj,t(7)

where σj,t=dj,t1E(1+gj,t)(1+πj,t). The first term reflects the contribution of interest payments; the second term captures the contribution of real GDP growth; the third component measures the valuation effect arising from movements in the real exchange rate; and the last two terms reflect the contributions of the current account balance (excluding interest payments) and non-debt financing flows respectively.

Modeling the non-interest current account as NICAj,t = tbt + θ (where tbt is the trade balance in period t) and using our previous assumption on the behavior of the real exchange rate (Δ In (reerj,t)= -εj,t), the external debt dynamics can be fully characterized by the path of a set of few domestic variables: {s,g,reer,tb,ndcf}.21

Treating ndcfj as exogenous (as we are primarily interested in externally-triggered shocks), and putting together the systems of equations derived for public and external debt, one can show that both debt ratios are ultimately driven by five domestic variables, {s,g,reer,tb,exp}, and a set of exogenous global variables. The next section discusses how to estimate the impact of external variables on the first four variables in this set, while the behavior of the last variable (exp) is evaluated under different policy rules.

B. Conditional Forecasting of Key Domestic Variables: a VAR approach

We estimate country-specific VAR models in order to quantify the sensitivity of the variables (specified above) that characterize debt dynamics to external conditions. Specifically, the VARs are used to obtain forecasts of these domestic variables, conditional on a set of assumed global variables (global scenarios). A key feature of our framework is that primary balances and debt levels are included in the VAR in order to allow feedback effects from these variables to the other domestic variables that determine debt dynamics.

Each (reduced form) country-specific VAR model can be written as:

yt=B(L)yt1+H(L)zt+ut(8)

where yt = (gt dTBt dln(reer))' is a vector of endogenous variables and zt = (1gtwvixtptAptEptEptMpbt1dt1p) is a vector of exogenous variables. The vector yt includes real GDP growth (gt), the change in the trade balance in percent of GDP (dTBt), and the (log difference of) the real effective exchange rate (dln(reert)).22 The vector zt, in turn, includes global real GDP growth (gw), the S&P 500 Chicago Board Options Exchange Market Volatility Index (vix) as a proxy for international financial conditions,23 the (log differences of) agriculture, energy, and metals prices (PtA,PtE,andPtMrespectively),24 the primary balance, in percent of GDP (pb), and the debt-to-GDP ratio (dp). B(L) and H(L) are lag polynomial matrices, which include up to four lags.25

The VAR models are estimated using quarterly data from 1990:Q1 through 2012:Q1. The data sources are primarily the IMF’s International Financial Statistics (IFS) and World Economic Outlook (WEO), and Haver Analytics.

It is worth noting that since our main interest resides in obtaining conditional forecasts and not standard VAR tools such as impulse response functions and variance decompositions, there is no need for identification restrictions to recover the structural parameters of the model. Similarly, as our interest is on the conditional forecasting performance of the model during bad external scenarios, specifications are selected based on their out-of-sample forecast power during the Lehman event (Figure A5 in the Annex).26

Unlike that of other papers in the literature, our approach does not entail estimating a fiscal reaction function, (i.e., there is no equation for the primary balance). This is deliberate, as our objective is not to obtain alternative debt paths under the assumption that fiscal responses to the negative shocks mirror those of the past—which may have been constrained (or sub-optimal) in many cases—but rather under broadly unconstrained (either neutral or countercyclical).27 This does not mean that the VAR does not control for the fiscal stance but instead that the primary balance is treated as exogenous for the purpose of estimation only. For projections, the primary balance under alternative scenarios is constructed as follows: revenues are projected based on the forecast for output (conditional on the exogenous path of the foreign variables) and on standard assumptions about the output elasticity of non-commodity revenues. Commodity-related revenues, in turn, are projected based on the exogenously determined path of the relevant commodity prices. On the expenditure side, we consider alternative responses—both neutral and countercyclical (explained in detail later)—to the negative shock. This approach allows us to better assess the impact of different components of the primary balance (commodity revenues, revenues linked to economic activity, and expenditure). Finally, as stated before, the primary balance enters the growth equation, so our approach incorporates the feedback effects of different fiscal responses on output.

C. Sovereign Spreads Module

A sovereign spread equation—one of the variables that determine debt dynamics—is estimated separately since data availability is significantly more limited (starting only after 1998, and varying by country)28 than in the case of other variables included in the model. The spread equation includes key macroeconomic fundamentals and exogenous global variables:

Δsi,t=βi,o+ΣβΔzit1+ΣγiΔxi,t1+εi,t(9)

where zi,t=(pdi,tpbi,tpdi,t2edi,tcai,tfxresi,tlnreeri,t) is a vector of potential predetermined and exogenous variables, which are expected to have similar impact across countries, and xi,t=(vixtit*lnptw) is a vector of predetermined and exogenous variables with different effects across countries. We consider three different estimation methods: OLS (without constant), panel with fixed effects and panel with random effects.

Of the country fundamentals considered only the level of public debt, international reserves and the real exchange rate appear to have a statistically significant role. Of the exogenous variables considered, only the VIX produces statistically significant and robust results, with important differences across idiosyncratic coefficients. Surprisingly, commodity prices do not appear to be important, perhaps because of their close correlation with the VIX and the fact that the real exchange rate captures much of the impact of changes in trade prices.

As before, our interest resides primarily in the forecast properties of the model, especially during bad external scenarios. Thus, we choose a specification that displays good forecasting performance both for crisis periods as well as subsequent normal times. We do this by evaluating the out-of-sample forecasting accuracy of the different specifications and estimation methods for the period 2008:M6 to 2012:M12. Specification 6 with OLS estimation (Table A2 in the Annex) displays the best properties in this regard.

IV. Debt Dynamics Under Alternative Global Scenarios

A. Scenarios

We first focus on debt dynamics under “baseline” global assumptions (i.e. IMF’s World Economic Outlook latest projections).29 Then, we study how debt sustainability in the region would change under four alternative (adverse) global scenarios, each defined by exogenously determined paths for the exogenous variables. We explore two scenarios of temporary shocks and two others where shocks have more permanent effects. A brief characterization of each scenario is as follows:30

Scenario 1: Temporary Financial Shock

This scenario entails a temporary ‘pure’ financial shock, reflected in a spike of the VIX in 2013 of similar magnitude than the one observed after the Lehman event, with the VIX returning to baseline levels in 2014. Real variables, such as global growth and commodity prices are assumed to remain unchanged at baseline levels. While the latter is a strong assumption, it is meant to allow the scenario to capture the effect of a shock that is mostly financial.

Scenario 2: Temporary Real Shock

This scenario assumes a temporary global recession, with lower growth and commodity prices during 2013-14, returning to the baseline path afterwards. This scenario can be characterized as a backdrop where global uncertainties remain somewhat elevated for some time—leading to a global economic slowdown, but no crisis—and are eventually resolved.

Scenario 3: A Protracted Global Slowdown

This scenario entails a relatively high level of uncertainty (as reflected by current levels of the VIX), lower commodity prices and lower global growth (all relative to the baseline). The scenario does not assume abrupt changes, but rather protracted weakness in real global variables.

Scenario 4: A Tail Event

In contrast to scenario 3, this is an extreme event meant to study the implications of a crisis with an impact on global variables (VIX, global GDP growth, and commodity prices) of magnitudes similar to those observed after the Lehman event. Unlike that episode—which displayed a quick rebound of commodity prices, and, to a lesser extent, global growth—this scenario assumes that a new Lehman-like event would have more protracted effects on the global economy, as fiscal and monetary space in advanced economies is today much more limited than in 2008.

For each of these scenarios, a path of global exogenous variables is assumed (Table 1 and Figure 6). These variables include: global growth, the VIX index, the 10-year U.S. T-bill interest rate, commodity prices (food, energy and metals). Some general assumptions on the extent of non-debt creating capital inflows and on reserve accumulation are also made in order to fully specify the set of exogenous variables.

Table 1.

Key Global Assumptions under Alternative Scenarios

article image

Temporary financial shock affecting 2013 only. Financial variables return to projected path under the baseline in 2014.

Temporary real shock (commodity prices and world growth) in 2013-14. Variables return to projected path under the baseline in 2015.

Globals lowdown over the whole forecast horizon.

Lehman-like event in 2013-14, with pro tracted impact on global growth, commodity prices and the VIX.

Relative to 2012 level.

As projected by country desks for each country.

Reported gap vis-à-vis baseline is reached by end-2013. Prices recover gradually afterwards to reach baseline by end-2014.

Reported gap vis-à-vis baseline is reached by 2013-Q2. Prices recover gradually afterwards to reach new path by end-2014.

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Global Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2003-17

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

The VAR model (together with the spread equation) and the debt motion equations capture the key linkages between domestic and external variables. To fully determine the dynamics of debt ratios, however, a few assumptions on domestic policy are also necessary, as noted in section III. These include: (i) the output elasticity of non-commodity fiscal revenue; (ii) real public expenditure policy; and (iii) the extent of reserve accumulation31. Table 2 details these key assumptions under each of the four alternative scenarios.

Table 2.

Key Domestic Policy Assumptions under Alternative Scenarios

article image

Temporary financial shock affecting 2013 only. Financial variables return to projected path under the baseline in 2014.

Temporary real s ho ck (commodity prices and world growth) in 2013-14. Variables return to projected path under the baseline in

Global s lowdown over the whole forecast horizon.

Lehman-like event in 2013-14, with pro tracted impact on global growth, commodity prices and VIX.

As projected by country des ks fo r each country.

The assumptions on real expenditure growth deserve special attention as they determine the degree of cyclicality of the fiscal stance, given the endogeneity of the other components of the primary balance.32 For each scenario we study three different expenditure rules:

Baseline fiscal policies. In this case, real expenditure growth behaves as in the baseline projection, regardless of the scenario under consideration. The idea is to focus on the ‘pure’ impact of changing external conditions, maintaining policies unchanged.

Neutral fiscal policy. Fiscal policy, however, is likely to react to negative external shocks. Thus, we consider an expenditure rule that implies a broadly neutral stance—i.e., expenditure growing at potential GDP growth rates under each of the four scenarios; thus only allowing for automatic stabilizers to operate.33

Counter-cyclical fiscal policy. Finally, we consider the possibility of counter-cyclical policies beyond the effect of automatic stabilizers. To make policies comparable across countries, we specify a simple rule such that, in each scenario, expenditure grows above potential GDP growth rate by a margin that is proportional (one-to-one) to the gap between actual GDP growth and potential GDP growth.

Exploring these alternative rules allows us to assess the extent to which, under each of the negative external scenarios, fiscal buffers are large enough to (i) respond by deploying countercyclical fiscal policy, (ii) just enough to allow automatic stabilizers to work, or (iii) there is no fiscal space for stimulus and a fiscal tightening is necessary to ensure debt sustainability. Our assessment focuses on sustainability, leaving aside risks related to possible financing (i.e., liquidity) shocks. It is important to stress that, for countries with well-established fiscal rules (e.g. Brazil, Chile, Mexico), the reported dynamics under the different scenarios should be interpreted as an illustration of how fiscal variables would behave in the event of a temporary deviation from the existing rules and, as such, of the magnitude of the fiscal adjustments that would be required to return to the target under the corresponding rule after the shock.

B. Key Results

Latin America’s overall picture

WEO Baseline projections

We first examine the projected trajectories of public and external debt under the baseline, with the path of global variables as in the Fall 2012 IMF’s World Economic Outlook (WEO). The dynamics under the baseline sheds light on the region‘s debt sustainability in the absence of unexpected foreign shocks. It also plays a role in assessing debt sustainability under the alternative scenarios, as projected debt ratios are computed by adding to the WEO baseline the estimated impact of changes in external conditions. The latter is computed as the difference between the debt projection under each VAR scenario forecast and the projection under the VAR baseline forecast.34 By focusing on the ‘marginal’ impact of changes in global conditions on WEO‘s baseline projection, this approach ensures that country-specific information embedded in the latter—such as revenue measures or investment plans already in the pipeline—is incorporated in the scenario projections.

dt|Scenarioi=dt|WEOBaseline+(dt×|VARForecastidt|VARForecastBaseline)(10)

Under the baseline both public and external debt ratios are, on average, expected to decline only slightly (less than 2 percentage points of GDP) through 2017, continuing with the trend observed since 2009 (Figure 7). In the case of public debt, commodity-related revenues will continue to be a major factor pushing debt down, although they will be mostly offset by the continuation of non-commodity primary deficits. With (non-interest) current accounts broadly balanced on average, Latin America‘s external debt dynamics will be largely determined by the offsetting forces of still large non-debt-creating capital inflows (FDI and equity portfolio flows) and further foreign asset accumulation.

Figure 7.
Figure 7.
Figure 7.
Figure 7.

Latin America. Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics under Alternative Global Scenarios, 2003-17 1/

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Sources: IMF International Financial Statistics and authors' estimations.1/ Simple average for Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Peru, Uruguay and Venezuela.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.4/ Deviation in percent of baseline.

Alternative downside scenarios

Next, we analyze the results across different scenarios, considering baseline policies—to identify the ‘pure’ impact of changes in external conditions, maintaining expenditure policy unchanged—as well as policies that entail a neutral stance or a counter-cyclical fiscal stance.

(i) Baseline policies

The results suggest that the impact of temporary negative external shocks (either financial or real, as depicted by scenarios 1 and 2) both on public and external debt would be, in general, limited (Figure 7). A temporary financial shock (scenario 1) would lead to an increase of public debt of about 7 percentage points of GDP by 2017 (relative to the baseline), with most of the impact arising from the deterioration in economic activity and the associated weakening of primary balances, reinforced by the effect of the real depreciation in countries with foreign-currency denominated debt. A temporary real shock (scenario 2) would have a much more muted impact on public debt. Transitory shocks would not have visible effects on external debt dynamics. In the case of a financial shock (scenario 1) the effects of the associated real depreciation and rise in external interest rates (due to an increase in spreads) would be non-negligible, but they would be fully offset by the projected current account adjustment that would accompany this shock. Interestingly, the sharp increase in sovereign spreads under scenario 1 (Figure 7, lower panel) would induce only a mild effect on average interest rates—and thus on debt dynamics—as a result of the relatively low levels of short-term debt.

The impact of more persistent shocks to foreign variables (scenarios 3 and 4) on public debt trajectories would be, however, significantly higher. Under scenario 4, public debt would increase, on average, by 20 percentage points of GDP (to around 55 percent) by 2017, due to the combination of a sharp decline in output and the associated weakening of non-commodity primary balances, considerably lower commodity revenues, and a non-negligible effect stemming from the real depreciation. External debt, on the other hand, would remain at manageable levels under these scenarios, with increases of only 5-6 percentage points of GDP by 2017—mainly reflecting lower growth, the effects of real depreciations, and a likely drop in non-debt capital inflows, offset partially by projected current account improvements.

(ii) Active (Neutral and Countercyclical) Policies

If authorities were to respond to the negative shocks of scenarios 1 and 2 by implementing either neutral or countercyclical policies (as defined earlier) the impact on public debt levels would be more pronounced, with stocks reaching about 46-51 percent and 41-44 percent of GDP by 2017, respectively (Figure 8, upper panel). While representing a sizeable impact, these levels do not appear to be particularly worrisome, especially given that primary balances would deteriorate only marginally and would not require to be adjusted significantly to keep public debt on a sustainable path. These scenarios would not entail a significant impact on external debt paths even under active policies.

Figure 8.
Figure 8.

Latin America. Public and External Debt under Alternative Scenarios and Policies, 2012-17 1/

(In percent of GDP, simple averages)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Source: authors' estimations.

Interestingly, under scenario 3, the debt trajectory associated with a counter-cyclical fiscal policy response would be very similar to the one resulting from a policy reaction that is essentially neutral. This reflects the fact that this scenario would imply not only a decline in actual GDP growth but also in potential growth, and thus the output gap—measured relative to the new potential—would be rather small (Figure 7, lower panel), and so would be the scope for expansionary fiscal policy. It is also worth highlighting that, if authorities failed to recognize that under this scenario the new potential growth rate is lower than previously estimated, what may be intended as a neutral stance would, in fact, be stimulative and would lead to a worsening of the primary balance and thus public debt dynamics.

Under scenario 4, there would be more scope for expansionary countercyclical policies, as output would fall significantly below (the new lower) potential levels. Both a neutral policy response—allowing automatic stabilizers to operate—and a countercyclical one would lead to substantial increases in public debt (of more than 20 and 30 percentage points of GDP by 2017, relative to the baseline, respectively). At those levels (65 percent of GDP in the case of countercyclical policies), concerns about fiscal sustainability may emerge, especially in countries where the required adjustment in the primary balance to stabilize debt ratios would be large.

Finally, external debt would increase to around 35 percent of GDP in the face of more persistent negative external shocks (scenarios 3 and 4), irrespective of policies. As discussed earlier, this partly reflects that current accounts in Latin America tend to improve after negative external (financial) shocks.

Country-specific results

Averages for the region, however, mask some important differences across countries.35

WEO Baseline projections

Under baseline external conditions, public debt ratios will continue to decline moderately in most countries (Brazil and Uruguay, starting from higher initial levels, would experience the largest decreases), with primary balance gaps generally improving. A notable exception is Venezuela, where debt is projected to increase by 30 percentage points of GDP, reaching 80 percent of GDP, by 2017.36 External debt, in turn, is projected to remain broadly stable in most countries under the baseline external scenario.

Alternative downside scenarios

Most countries in the region should be in a position to undertake an expansionary countercyclical policy response in the event of temporary shocks (scenarios 1 and 2), without raising debt sustainability concerns (i.e., high debt and primary gap levels). An exception would be Venezuela, which would likely have limited or no scope for countercyclical policy, reflecting the combination of relatively weak initial positions and high sensitivity to these shocks (that could rapidly lead to large deficits).

In case of external shocks with more protracted effects (scenarios 3 and 4), countries can be classified into three different groups based on the extent of fiscal buffers to implement either neutral or countercyclical fiscal policy responses (Figure 9):

  • First, a group of countries (Argentina and Venezuela) that would likely need to undertake sizeable fiscal consolidation in the face of adverse shocks, including—although to a lesser extent—moderate ones, to keep public debt on a sustainable path.37

  • Second, a group (including Brazil, Mexico, Uruguay, and—to a lesser extent—Ecuador), which public debt dynamics would be less vulnerable to moderate shocks, although still significantly sensitive to tail events. In particular:

    • This group should be in a position to deal with a moderate deterioration of the external environment (scenario 3), although debt ratios could reach levels (ranging from 55 to 65 percent of GDP) that—while manageable—would be relatively high for emerging market standards, and could make these economies vulnerable to possible subsequent adverse shocks.38

    • Under a more severe event (scenario 4), scope for counter-cyclical policy, and to some extent even for neutral policies, would be limited without raising concerns about debt sustainability, as indicated by the sharp deterioration in debt levels and/or primary balance gaps.39

    • In countries with well-established fiscal rules (Brazil, Mexico), adherence to the rule following a temporary deviation at the time of the adverse shock would, of course, ensure that public debt remains on a sustainable path. In some cases, however, returning to the fiscal targets under the rule could entail significant fiscal consolidation.40

    • Finally, a group of countries (Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Paraguay, and Peru) that, to varying degrees, appear to be in a position to weather a marked worsening of external conditions—even undertaking countercyclical policies—without jeopardizing fiscal solvency. Peru appears to exhibit the strongest position, even under the described extreme circumstances. While in Chile and Paraguay, under scenario 4 and assuming countercyclical policies, both the primary balance gap and debt ratios could increase significantly, debt would still remain at relatively moderate levels.41 Colombia, with debt levels reaching over 50 percent of GDP and the primary balance gap -4 percent of GDP, appears to exhibit a somewhat less solid fiscal position, though those figures should not raise concerns about fiscal solvency.

Figure 9.
Figure 9.

Key Fiscal Indicators under Different Scenarios, 2012-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Series indicate the path of public debt and primary balance gap from 2012 to 2017 for each country. Solid lines denote path under neutral policies. Dotted lines corresponds to counter-cyclical policies.2/ Primary balance at year t minus debt-stabilizing primary balance at 2017, as defined in IMF DSA template.

On the external front, even under the more extreme scenarios (3 and 4) countries in the region would be in a position to maintain external sustainability under check (Figure 10).42 In fact, under both scenarios (and even assuming active policy responses) debt levels would remain moderate, and current account balance gaps would be either closed or positive. A key factor driving this result is—as noted earlier—the fact that current accounts tend to improve in the face of large negative external shocks (especially financial ones).

Figure 10.
Figure 10.

Key External Indicators under Different Scenarios, 2012-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Series indicate the path of external debt and non-interest current account balance gap from 2012 to 2017 for each country. Solid lines denote path under neutral policies. Dotted lines corresponds to counter-cyclical policies.2/ Non-interest current account (NICA) balance at year t minus debt-stabilizing NICA balance at 2017, as defined in the IMF DSA template.

V. Conclusions

Latin America experienced a sharp improvement in key macroeconomic fundamentals over the last decade, although these gains were, to some extent, the result of a highly favorable external environment. With prospects of less favorable conditions going forward, and even the possibility of a sharp deterioration (in the event of an escalation of the European financial crisis), the region‘s fundamentals may change drastically. This paper proposes a simple framework to undertake debt sustainability analysis focusing on the impact of changes in external variables. Using this framework, we examine how public and external debt sustainability indicators (both in terms of stocks and flows) would look like under alternative negative external scenarios. The results are used to assess whether current levels of policy buffers (especially fiscal) in the region are adequate to withstand a deterioration of the global environment.

The main results indicate that while external sustainability does not appear to be source of concern for Latin America in general, fiscal space to deal with a protracted deterioration of the external environment may still be limited in several countries. These results suggest that the region would benefit from further strengthening buffers, while favorable conditions last, to be in a position to actively use fiscal policy should the external environment deteriorate markedly.

There are, however, some important differences across countries and three groups can be identified according to the degrees of fiscal space to deal with negative external shocks: (i) a group (Argentina and Venezuela) that would face tight fiscal constraints even in the face of relatively moderate shocks, likely precluding the deployment of counter-cyclical policy; (ii) a group (Brazil, Mexico, Uruguay, and—to a lesser extent—Ecuador) that would have some space to run countercyclical fiscal policy but would benefit from building further space to be able to respond actively without raising concerns about fiscal sustainability or requiring large subsequent fiscal consolidations, specially under severe scenarios; and finally (iii) a group (Bolivia, Chile, Paraguay, Peru, and—to a lesser extent—Colombia) that appears to be today in a position to weather sizeable shocks with counter-cyclical policies without compromising debt sustainability.

Annex Figure A1.
Annex Figure A1.
Annex Figure A1.

Factors Driving Public Debt Dynamics, 2002-12 1/

(cumulative contributions, percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Sources: IMF International Financial Statistics, IMF country desks and authors' calculations.
Annex Figure A2.
Annex Figure A2.

Components of Primary Balance Dynamics, 1995-2012 1/

(Index, 2003=100 unless otherwise states, in real terms)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Source: IMF International Financial Statistics and authors' calculations.1/ Using GDP deflator for all series. Data on commodity-related revenues for Ecuador, Mexico and Venezuela (Chile) are avilable from 2000 (2005).2/ Expenditure base year equals percent of revenues in that year.3/ Based on projected growth for 2015-17.
Annex Figure A3.
Annex Figure A3.
Annex Figure A3.

Factors Driving Primary Balance Dynamics, 2002-12 1/

(cumulative contributions, percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Sources: IMF International Financial Statistics, IMF country desks and authors' calculations.
Annex Figure A4.
Annex Figure A4.
Annex Figure A4.

Factors Driving External Debt Dynamics, 2002-12 1/

(cumulative contributions, percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Sources: IMF International Financial Statistics, IMF country desks and authors' calculations.
Figure A5.
Figure A5.
Figure A5.
Figure A5.
Figure A5.
Figure A5.

Forecasting Power of VAR Model During the Lehman Event

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

Figures A6-A16
Figures A6-A16

Argentina: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig01

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
A01ann01ufig02

Bolivia: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig03

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
A01ann01ufig04

Brazil: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig05

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
A01ann01ufig06

Chile: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig07

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
A01ann01ufig08

Colombia: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig09

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
A01ann01ufig10

Ecuador: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig11

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
A01ann01ufig12

Mexico: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig13

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
A01ann01ufig14

Paraguay: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig15

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
A01ann01ufig16

Peru: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 /

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig17

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
A01ann01ufig18

Uruguay: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig19

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
A01ann01ufig20

Venezuela, Rep. Bol.: Factors Driving Public and External Debt Dynamics, 2003-17 1/

(percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Public and external debt dynamics under alternative global scenarios.2/ Country desk projections (based on WEO baseline assumptions).3/ Based on differential between VAR forecasts and VAR baseline. Bars denote contributions of different factors to the deviation of the debt ratios from the baseline.
A01ann01ufig21

Key Domestic Variables under Alternative Scenarios, 2012-17

(deviations from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 027; 10.5089/9781475588835.001.A001

1/ Deviation in percent of baseline.
Table A1.

VAR Estimation Results

article image
Standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10, + p < 0.15