Post-Laspeyres
The Case for a New Formula for Compiling Consumer Price Indexes

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Addresses: paularmknecht@msn.com and msilver@imf.org.

Consumer price indexes (CPIs) are compiled at the higher (weighted) level using Laspeyres-type arithmetic averages. This paper questions the suitability of such formulas and considers two counterpart alternatives that use geometric averaging, the Geometric Young and the (price-updated) Geometric Lowe. The paper provides a formal decomposition and understanding of the differences between the two. Empirical results are provided using United States CPI data. The findings lead to an advocacy of variants of a hybrid formula suggested by Lent and Dorfman (2009) that substantially reduces bias from Laspeyres-type indexes.

Abstract

Consumer price indexes (CPIs) are compiled at the higher (weighted) level using Laspeyres-type arithmetic averages. This paper questions the suitability of such formulas and considers two counterpart alternatives that use geometric averaging, the Geometric Young and the (price-updated) Geometric Lowe. The paper provides a formal decomposition and understanding of the differences between the two. Empirical results are provided using United States CPI data. The findings lead to an advocacy of variants of a hybrid formula suggested by Lent and Dorfman (2009) that substantially reduces bias from Laspeyres-type indexes.

I. Introduction

Most national statistical offices (NSOs) use in practice what they often describe as “Laspeyres-type” index formulas for aggregating their consumer price index (CPI) at the higher (weighted) level. These Laspeyres-type indexes include the Young and the Lowe indexes, both of which have serious shortcomings. It is argued here that Laspeyres-type indexes can be replaced at little cost by more suitable formulas that use the same data and can be compiled in real time.

A Laspeyres price index can be defined as a period 0-weighted arithmetic average of price changes between periods 0 and t. However, it takes time to compile the results of a household expenditure survey, so in practice statistical agencies use a prior period b survey weights to rebase a CPI that runs from the price reference period 0 (b < 0 < t). The Young index has as its weights the preceding survey period b expenditure shares and the Lowe index uses period b weights price-updated (and normalized) to the price reference period 0. Laspeyres is exceptionally used in practice for compiling CPIs.2

This paper outlines in section IIA the features of the widely used arithmetically-based Lowe and Young formulas. Both are considered to have major shortcomings. The Lowe index is principally used for CPI compilation in spite of theory and evidence of severe upward bias. However, the Lowe index has the virtue, as a fixed quantity basket index, of being simple to explain. Analytical shortcomings with the Young index include an uncertainty a priori about the extent and nature of its deviations from Laspeyres and relatively poor axiomatic properties.

Section IIB continues by considering the nature of and case for the geometric equivalents of Young and Lowe indexes, that is, the Geometric Young (sometimes referred to as the Cobb-Douglas) and Geometric Lowe indexes. These geometrically-based indexes share the advantage of their arithmetic counterparts of being able to be computed in real time and are thus practical alternatives to arithmetic versions. Existing empirical work on the differences between these formulas is outlined in section IIC.

In section III we focus on these geometric formulations. To better understand their properties, a formal exact decomposition is derived for the difference between the Geometric Young and Geometric Lowe indexes. However, the empirical arbiter of which is the most suitable is their proximity to a superlative index, such as the Törnqvist index, something also considered in this section.3

Section IV provides empirical results using CPI data from the United States. The relationships between the Laspeyres-Paasche interval and the arithmetically-weighted Young and Lowe indexes are considered followed by an examination of the relationship between the Törnqvist index and the Geometric Young and Geometric-Lowe indexes. We find the Geometric Young index, which is consistent with unitary elasticity of substitution, has a downward bias. The US data over the period studied demonstrate inelastic substitution (Greenlees, 2011). However, this bias can be substantially offset by averaging. The averaging of such indexes has a formal justification from Lent and Dorfman (2009) and we consider variants of this approach. Of note is that the Lowe price index, as used in the US and many other countries, is found to have a bias (against superlative indexes) several times that of some of these variants, all of which can be computed in real time using the same database as the Lowe index.

Laspeyres itself has the advantage of being an upper bound to a theoretical cost-of living index (COLI). The widely used Lowe index is likely to fall above Laspeyres. Its main advantage is that as a fixed quantity basket index it is easy to explain; biased but easily explained. We propose alternative formulas that can be readily computed in real time.

II. higher-level price index number formulas used in practice

A. Arithmetic formulas

The Laspeyres price index is given by:

ILt=Σi=1nPitqi0pi0qi0=Σi=1npi0qi0(pitpi0)Σi=1npi0qi0=Σi=1nsi0(pitpi0),wheresi0=pi0qi0Σi=1npi0qi0(1)

The first term of equation (1) is a standard representation of the Laspeyres formula as a fixed quantity basket index with pi0 and qi0 denoting, respectively, prices and quantities in period 0 for i = 1,…, n products/elementary aggregates. In practice CPIs are compiled as a weighted average of price relatives, given by the second and third terms in equation (1), where the weights are the expenditure shares in period 0, si0

It takes time to compile and process household expenditure survey data, so there is a lag between the expenditures share survey period, b, and their first use in the index, commencing at the price reference period 0. Thus, in practice, the Laspeyres is generally not used for real time CPI compilation and expenditure shares from the earlier period b may be used to weight period 0 to period t price changes. The resulting Young price index is given by:

IYt=Σi=1nsib(pitpi0),wheresib=pibqibΣi=1npibqib(2)

More typically, weights are price-updated between period b and the price reference period 0 to effect fixed period-b quantities. The resulting Lowe index is given by:

ILot=Σi=1n[pibqibpi0pib]pitpi0Σi=1n[pibqibpi0pib]=Σi=1npitqibΣi=1npi0qib=Σi=1npi0qib(pitpi0)Σi=1npi0qib(3)

The expression in square brackets in the first term are the period-b expenditures, pibqib, price-updated to period 0. The second term shows the Lowe index to be a period-b fixed-quantity basket price index, and the third term to be a weighted average of price changes where the weights are hybrid period 0 prices and period b quantities, with little economic meaning. Price-updating the expenditure shares for price changes is not to make the weights more up-to-date, but to transform the index from a fixed period b expenditure share-weighted index of price changes to a fixed period b quantity basket price index.

Balk and Diewert (2003), from the perspective of the economic theory of index numbers, establish the substitution bias of a Lowe CPI—see also ILO et al., (2004, chapters 15 and 17) and Balk (2010). Not only is the Lowe index shown to have a likely upward substitution bias against a Laspeyres index, but the Laspeyres index has an upward substitution bias against a superlative index. ILO et al., (2004, chapter 16) demonstrates that the Lowe index, however, has good axiomatic properties.4

The Young index fails the circularity and time reversal tests (ILO et al., 2004, Appendix 15.3 and chapter 16). The Young index between periods 0 and t will exceed its time antithesis, that is, its inverse between period t and 0, and in this sense is positively biased.5 ILO et al. (2004, chapter 15) demonstrate how the discrepancy between Laspeyres and Young is difficult to gauge. It is based on the covariance of the difference between expenditure shares between period b and 0 and the deviations of period 0 to t relative prices from their mean.6 A positive covariance would put Young above Laspeyres and negative covariance below Laspeyres, possibly closer to a superlative index. Analytical shortcomings with the Young index are thus the uncertainty a priori about the extent and nature of its deviations from Laspeyres and its relatively poor axiomatic properties.

B. Geometric counterparts

For elementary-level indexes, the CPI Manual recommends the use of the (geometric) Jevons index if weights are not available for individual varieties in the sample (ILO et al., 2004, chapter 20). Using a geometric formula at the higher level would be compatible with the currently widely used Jevons index at the lower level and would have the benefit of maintaining consistency in aggregation.

Formulas (4) and (5) are the geometric counterparts to (2) and (3) and can be readily adopted by statistical offices since they use the same weights and price relatives as the Young and Lowe indexes. The Geometric Young price index is given by:

IGYt=Πi=1n(pitpi0)Sib,wheresib=pibqibΣi=1npibqib.(4)

The geometric version of the Lowe price index with its price-updated weight is given by:

IGLot=Πi=1n(pitpi0)Sib0,wheresib0=pi0qibΣi=1npi0qib.(5)

The (superlative) Törnqvist index is given by:

ITt=Πi=1n(pitpi0)(si0+sit)/2(6)

for which current period expenditure shares, sit, are not available in real time. It is apparent that for constant expenditure shares over periods 0 and t, consistent with unitary elasticity of substitution, the Geometric Young index given by (4) equals the Törnqvist index given by (6).

Balk (2010) demonstrates that the substitution bias of the Geometric Young index is less than the substitution bias of the currently widely-used Lowe index. The CPI Practical Guide supports the use of the Geometric Young formulas (UNECE et al., 2009, page 160, ff. 50).7 The CPI Manual considers the Geometric Young index to be a serious practical possibility for CPI compilation; since the requisite weights are available in real time, and it is less susceptible to bias. With unitary elasticity of substitution, the Geometric Young can be shown to lie within the Laspeyres-Paasche interval. The Geometric Young index, as its name suggests, corresponds to cost-of-living indexes for utility-maximizing households with Geometric Young preferences. The CPI Manual cites as its main concern the unlikelihood of it gaining general acceptance in the foreseeable (then 2004) future since it cannot be interpreted as a fixed quantity basket index. (ILO et al., 2004, chapter 1 paragraphs 1.40 and 9.137).

Unlike the (arithmetic) Lowe index given by (3), the Geometric Lowe (and like the Geometric Young) indexes have no fixed quantity basket definition. The price updating of the weights has no rationale for the Geometric Lowe. Its standing is so low that neither the CPI Practical Guide nor the CPI Manual mentions it. However, the (arithmetic) Lowe is widely used in practice. It is invariably described in terms of a weighted average of price changes, albeit with little reference to such weights given in the last term of equation (3), which have little economic meaning. There is a prima facie case for some formal and empirical analysis of the geometric counterpart to the arithmetic Lowe.

C. Available empirical work

Given concern about arithmetic formulations and some positive aspects of geometric ones, we consider some of the available, albeit limited, empirical work on how close different formulations lie to a superlative index.

Hansen (2007) using Danish CPI data for 1996 to 2003 found increases for the Young and Lowe indices of 17.49 and 18.01 percent, respectively, compared with an increase in the Törnqvist index of 17.08 percent.8 The Geometric Young index was below Törnqvist at 16.51 percent. The differences between Young and Lowe are not always trivial.9 The annual inflation rate for 2004/5 and 2005/6 increased from 1.80 to 1.88 percent using Young but decreased from 1.99 to 1.90 percent using Lowe.

Greenlees and Williams (2010), in a major study of the US CPI over December 1990 through December 2008, found Lowe and Young increases to be quite similar, at 18.88 and 18.24 percent respectively, but the (chained) Törnqvist was much lower at 16.78 percent.10 The Geometric Young index was closer to, and again below, the chained Törnqvist at 15.84 percent.

Pike et al. (2009, Table 10)—using New Zealand CPI data for June 2006 to June 2008 with weights of 2003/4 and 2006/7 respectively price-updated to June 2006 and June 2008 quarters (the New Zealand CPI is quarterly)—found Lowe and Young to differ showing over this period increases of 6.26 and 5.60 percent, respectively. These arithmetic formulations were significantly higher than the 4.83 percent increase for the Geometric Young index which appeared to understate the 5.73 percent increase measured by a retrospective Fisher index.

So while Lowe and Young may generate similar results, their difference from a superlative Törnqvist index is marked and of concern. The Geometric Young index generally falls below (and there is some evidence that it is closer to) the superlative Törnqvist index.

Given the Geometric Young and Geometric Lowe are practical contenders for the CPI aggregation formula, we now present a formal analysis as to why they might differ.

III. Why Geometric higher-level price index numbers differ

A. Geometric Young vs. Geometric Lowe

Following on from equation (4) we first define a Geometric Young price index as:

IGY0t=Πi=1n(pitpi0)siband ln(IGY0t)=Σi=1nsiblnpitpi0=Σi=1nsibyi(7)

where sib=pibqibΣi=1npibqib are period b expenditure shares and yiln(pitpi0) is the natural logarithm of the ith price relative.

The difference between the logarithms of a Geometric Lowe and a Geometric Young price index is given by:

ln(IGLo0t)ln(IGY0t)=Σi=1npibqib(pi0pib)ln(pitpi0)Σi=1npibqib(pi0pib)Σi=1npibqibln(pitpi0)Σi=1npibqib=Σi=1nsibxiyiΣi=1nsibxiΣi=1nsibyiΣi=1nsib(8)

where xipi0pib. Adopting a Bortkiewicz (1923) decomposition:11

ln(IGLo0t)ln(IGY0t)=Σi=1nsibxiyiΣi=1nsibxiy¯isib=ρx,ysibcνxsibσysib(9)
IGLo0tIGY0t=exp(ρx,ysibcvxsibσysib)(10)

where ρx,ysib is the period-b weighted (sib) correlation coefficient between price relatives xi and yi (that extend respectively from b → 0 and 0 → t); cvxsib=σxsib/x¯sib is the period-b weighted (wib) coefficient of variation for xi, for which σxwib is the standard deviation and x¯wib is the wib-weighted mean of xi, that is, a Laspeyres price index between periods b and 0. First, it is apparent from (10) that ρx,ysib dictates whether IGLo0t is larger (positive) or smaller (negative) than IGY0t. For (weighted) price changes between periods b and 0 to be correlated with (weighted logarithms of) price changes between periods 0 and t, there must be some persistent uni-directional long-run price change over period b to t. A priori, a sign cannot be unambiguously attached to this correlation coefficient.

Second, the magnitude of IGLo0t/IGY0t is determined by

  • (a) The magnitude of ρx,ysib—smaller ratios of IGLo0ttoIGY0t would be expected from countries with longer time lags in utilizing and updating the weights, that is, longer lags between periods b and 0 and periods 0 and t.

  • (b) The dispersion of price changes, cvxsibandσysib—it is well established in economic theory and empirical work that dispersion in relative prices increases with increases in inflation.12 The Geometric Lowe will drift above the Geometric Young with higher rates of inflation. Note that σysib is likely to be the most potent driver of the drift since it is not corrected, as is the coefficient of variation, cvxsib, for changes in the mean. σysib is concerned with the often larger index changes between period 0 to t, than the constant cvxsib. over period b to 0.13

  • (c) The multiplicative nature of terms on the right-hand-side of equation (10)—for example, any chance lowering of ρx,ysib to near zero in a month will lead to the two formula being very similar in spite of higher cvxsibandσysib.

Third, we do not depict the difference between Geometric Young and Geometric Lowe indexes as substitution bias. It is clear from equation (10) that the differences stem from a correlation between price changes in one period and the (logarithm of) price changes in a subsequent period: not a correlation between price and quantity changes. It is the latter that defines substitution bias.

B. Comparisons with a superlative price index

Having examined how a Geometric Young differs from a Geometric Lowe price index, we turn to consider how both indexes, given by equations (4) and (5), differ from a superlative Törnqvist price index given by equation (6). The ratio of a Geometric Lowe to Törnqvist price index is by extension of equation (10):

IGlo0tIT0t=exp[(ρx,ysibcvxsibσysib)+(y¯isiby¯isi1/2(0+t))](11)

and the ratio of a Geometric Young to Törnqvist price index, by definition, equations (4) and (6) by:

IGY0tIT0t=Πi=1n(pitpi0)sibΠi=1n(pitpi0)(si0+sit)/2(12)

The Geometric Young and Törnqvist are equal if the shares in period b are equal to the average of the shares in periods 0 and t, that is, sib=(si0+sit)/2. As the index is progressively compiled across periods 0 to t, the implicit assumption is of a price elasticity of substitution of unity for comparisons between b to 0 continuing through between 0 and t. To evaluate the suitability of IGYt as an estimate of ITt we need to evaluate the elasticity of substitution in terms of its proximity to unity and its changes over time. One approach is to use a formula that simply assumes it is constant over time. The Lloyd-Moulton (constant elasticity of substitution—CES) index is given by:14

ILM0t=[Σi=1nsib(pitpi0)1η]1/(1η)(13)

for which η is the elasticity of substitution. The formulation is quite flexible: the Young index is consistent with η tending to zero and the Geometric Young index is consistent with η tending to unity. Greenlees (2011) used an approach proposed by Feenstra and Reinsdorf (2007) to estimate η for US data. He found values of η lie between 0 and 1, that is, inelastic substitution, though he also found occasional anomalous years; for 1999/2000 to 2005/6 estimated η varied between 0.521 and 0.655, but was close to (not significantly different from) unity for 2006/7 at 0.981, and close to (not significantly different from) zero for 2007/8 at 0.192; findings are at odds with an assumption of constant elasticity and, moreover, constant unitary elasticity. A finding of inelastic substitution argues against the implicit fixed baskets of (arithmetic) Lowe and Young indexes and implies that items with relatively higher price trends receive less importance in IGY0t than in IT0t, that is, IGY0t<IT0t.

Lent and Dorfman (2009) derive their formulation from a Taylor approximation to CES and superlative indexes. They find that a weighted average of arithmetic Laspeyres, ILas0t, and Geometric Laspeyres, IGLas0t, indexes (called an AG Mean index) can approximate a superlative target index:

IAG0t=ητΠi=1n(pitpi0)si0+(1ητ)Σi=1nsi0(pitpi0)(14)

The weights are not restricted to be constant. The authors demonstrate that the AG Mean can provide a close approximation to a superlative (Fisher) price index when 0 ≤ η ≤ 1. Estimators of η vary to be compatible with the target index number. For a Fisher price index as the target, IAG0t=IF0t, equation (14) is given by:

IF0t=ητIGLas0t+(1ητ)ILas0t.(15)

Solving (15) for ητ:

ητ=(IF0tILas0t)(IGLas0tILas0t).(16)

The estimated weights in equation (16) and used in equation (15) can vary. Lent and Dorfman (2009) suggest that a moving average of ητ be used over τ = t - T, t to smooth any volatility. We consider in the next (empirical) section how well the currently used arithmetic Lowe and Young indexes compare to (the bounds of) a superlative index. We then look at whether their geometric counterparts do any better and, if so, why they differ, leading to a real-time Lent-Dorfman approach.

IV. Empirical Results

A. The data

The data used are the elementary aggregate indexes for the U.S. Urban CPI and their weights over the period December 1997 to December 2010, provided by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). The elementary aggregate indexes are for about 211 item strata (product groups).. We stress that the compilation of the U.S. Urban CPI is based on 211 item strata (product groups) for 38 area strata, that is, 8,018 cells. The indexes for the individual item/area strata are for the large part derived using weighted geometric means, while the aggregation across areas uses the Lowe formula.15 Our analysis is, for simplicity, of the effect of using a different formula to measure the US Urban CPI if only the 211 weights for product groups were available, as is the case with many countries. The results of our estimates of a chained Törnqvist index are very close to the BLS’,16 a finding in itself of interest.17

The dates of the weights used over this period are given below. Following BLS procedures for their aggregation at the higher level, they were price updated from the expenditure period to the December prior to their use in the index. Note that the mean annual 1993-95 urban US expenditures for the 211 CPI item strata were the basis of the CPI weights for the four years from January 1998 through December 2001. Unlike subsequent expenditure weights, these expenditures were (i) from a 3-year period (not a 2-year period), (ii) were used in the CPI for a 4-year period (not a 2-year period), and (iii) were price-updated to December 1997 from about 3½ years (not 2 years) earlier—from the midpoint, June-July 1994.

article image

B. Results

Figure 1 shows the standard arithmetic price indexes: Lowe, Laspeyres, and Young and the harmonic Paasche. The target index is a superlative index Fisher price index, a symmetric (geometric) average of Laspeyres and Paasche price indexes that lies between them.18 The (arithmetic) Lowe price index, widely used by many countries for their CPI, is above Laspeyres. It performs poorly against the Young. Young is much closer to Laspeyres and, thus, to the desirable Laspeyres-Paasche interval.

Figure 1:
Figure 1:

Arithmetic indexes

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2012, 105; 10.5089/9781475502954.001.A001

The differences between the results of the formulas are not large. Some of this is due to the more frequent updating of weights undertaken by the US Bureau of Labor Statistics than in many other countries. Yet, the differences are not insubstantial, especially given the CPI is used extensively to escalate payments for rents, wages, alimony, child support and other such obligations. The Fisher price index increased in 2010 compared with 1998 at a (compound) annual average rate of 2.27 percent, compared with a Lowe price index increase of 2.44 percent.

As outlined in section II, arithmetic Lowe and Young indexes have counterpart geometric averages as practical alternatives, the Geometric Lowe and Geometric Young indexes respectively. Both formulas use the same data and can be compiled in real time.

Figure 2 shows results for the Geometric-Lowe, Geometric Young, and Törnqvist price indexes. At the beginning of the series, all indexes seem to track each other quite closely. After December 2003, the Geometric Lowe and Geometric Young indexes drift apart. The Geometric Lowe is closer to the Törnqvist from December 2003 to December 2007, providing evidence, at least for this data set, in its favor against the Geometric Young. Bear in mind that the Geometric Lowe has little conceptual support. The arithmetic Lowe had conceptual support as a fixed quantity basket price index and price updating took place with this in mind. However, price updating the weights for a geometric formulation does not yield a fixed basket index. It is the Geometric Young price index that has a conceptual foundation as a period-b weighted average of price relatives. But for these data, the Geometric Young price index has a marked downward bias against the Törnqvist index.

Figure 2:
Figure 2:

Geometric vs. standard price indexes

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2012, 105; 10.5089/9781475502954.001.A001

Two questions arise. First, what factors underlie the difference between the two geometric formulas and second, is the nature of the bias such that an average of formulas may be more suitable, similar to the averaging of Laspeyres and Paasche indexes. By inspection in Figure 2, Lowe overstates and Geometric Young understates the Törnqvist index and an average of the two may be suitable. We consider below, for US inflation rates, this and other combinations of formulas using the Lent-Dorfman (2009) framework, outlined in section IIIB above.

C. The Geometric formulas: differences and adjustments

The factors underlying the differences between the Geometric Lowe and Geometric Young are of interest as are averages of formulas that can make them better track superlative indexes. We consider the results for both in turn.

What factors underlie the difference between the two formulas?

Factors underlying the differences between the Geometric Lowe and Geometric Young can be understood based on the decomposition in equation (10). This decomposition is considered in Table 1 below. For brevity the results are only given from December 2007, re-referenced to December 2007=1.0000.

Table 1:

Decomposition of Geometric-Lowe to Geometric Young ratio

article image

The sign of ρx,ysib dictates which of the two formulas’ growth exceeds the other. From January 2008 to October 2008 it was positive, leading to the Geometric Lowe growing faster than the Geometric Young and from November 2008 onward it was negative leading to the reverse position, as shown in Table 1. These empirical runs in signs reflect long-run trends in price change between periods b to 0 (2004/5 to December 2007) being continued in sub-periods 0 to t (December 2007 to months up to October 2008) and then being reversed in subsequent sub-periods (to months after October 2008). This illustrates the dependency on long-run trends for the relative positioning of the two formulas.

The magnitude of the difference is determined by the magnitude of three factors. The correlation coefficient is not expected to be strong given price changes in one period are to be related to the logarithms of price changes in a subsequent one; cvxsib is a one-off factor for period b to 0—the higher it is, other factors equal, the larger the difference. If such dispersion increases over time, then lags between introducing weights from the survey period into the rebased index, between b and 0, will accentuate the difference between the two formulas. Finally, σysib and thus the difference between the two formulas, can be expected to increase over time. Of note is that the three factors are multiplicative: minimize any one factor, such as cvxsib by minimizing the time lag in the introduction of weights, and the difference between formulas becomes smaller. The results from Table 1 confirm this.

Averages of formulas that better track superlative indexes

An approach based on the Lent-Dorfman (2009) (hereafter L-D) framework uses averages of two formulas to more closely correspond to a superlative index.19

In Table 2 we consider average monthly percentage differences between the target indexes and alternative measures using the simulated US CPI data for January 2004 to December 2010. Lowe has the largest bias of about 1.7 percent from a superlative index and Young performs much better, reducing the bias to about 0.5 percent. Their geometric equivalents show mixed results with the Geometric Lowe being, on average, 0.2 percent above the Törnqvist while the Geometric Young is about 1.0 percent below. We also consider averaging of these indexes along with some variants of the L-D approach.

Table 2,

Average Monthly Percentage Differences between Alternative vs. Target Indexes:*

article image

Covers January 2004 to December 2010

First, use is made of approximations to Laspeyres and Geometric Laspeyres in equation (14) for which real-time data would not be available in practice. We use, in turn, Lowe and Young formulas to approximate Laspeyres and Geometric Lowe and Geometric Young formulas to approximate Geometric Laspeyres indexes in (14); for example, one variant would be the geometric average of the Young and Geometric Young and another, the geometric average of the Lowe and the Geometric Young.

Second, we tailor estimates of ητ in (15) to be based on a selected superlative benchmark, say the Törnqvist index. The Törnqvist index cannot be estimated in real time so the most recently available estimates are used to enable a real-time computation. For example, for January 08 to December 2009, using our US data, the most recent estimates of Törnqvist indexes are used, that is those available starting January 2008.

Third, the average ητ over January 2004 to December 2005 are used in equation (15) for January 08 to December 2009, and similarly over other periods. The Lent-Dorfman formulation has the advantage of allowing ητ to change on a monthly basis. However, we constrain such changes to the period of the rebasing of the index and then hold ητ constant until the next rebasing. This has practical advantages: the timing of such weight changes concurs with the rebasing of the index and CPI changes are not affected by changes in the weight ητ given in (14) to the different formulas used. Table 2 shows the results from using, in equations (15) and (17), different formulas as approximations to Laspeyres and Geometric Laspeyres benchmarked on the two superlative indexes, Fisher and Törnqvist. All formulations can be calculated in real time using the existing prices database.

Fourth, estimates of the ητ weights using equation (16) may be negative depending on the relative positioning of the Geometric Young (as a proxy for the Geometric Laspeyres) and the Young (for Laspeyres) indexes to the Fisher (superlative) index and that 0 ≥ ητ ≤ 1. Instead of (16) we use an adaptation, where ABS are absolute values:

ητ=ABS(IF0tICD0t)ABS(IF0tICD0t)+ABS(IF0tIY0t).(17)

In Table 2 four different variants of the L-D formulation are given each using the Fisher and Törnqvist indexes as benchmarks. This is preceded by the geometric mean of the two formulas—one arithmetic one geometric—used as an approximation.

These simple geometric means are highly successful (especially for Geometric Young:Lowe and GLowe:Young) in cutting the bias from using the Young index. The L-D approximations have similar effects in reducing the bias. The Lowe formula is used by the US and many other countries for CPI compilation. From Table 2 we can see that in real time using the same database as used by Lowe, we can cut Lowe’s bias from 1.7 percent to 0.3 percent. The Geometric Young:Lowe formulation has much to commend it as an adjustment, via the Geometric Young index, of the existing Lowe formula.

From our analysis in Figure 3, the L-D approximations (average of Lowe: Geometric Young and average of Young:Geometric Young) to the Törnqvist and Fisher indexes appear to work: they successfully track the Törnqvist index and alleviate the downward bias in the Geometric Young and the upward bias in the Lowe or Young indexes. The L-D index has a conceptual basis as a Taylor approximation to the Törnqvist (or Fisher) index that can be calculated in real time. As Lent and Dorfman (2009) note: the systematic updating of the index continuously picks up changes in consumer buying patterns as reflected in the data, while requiring no iterative numerical procedures and can therefore be easily programmed and automated in a statistical production setting.

Figure 3:
Figure 3:

Target indexes vs. L-D proxies

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2012, 105; 10.5089/9781475502954.001.A001

V. Concluding Remarks

The widely-used arithmetic Laspeyres-type aggregation formula at the higher (weighted) level for CPIs, the Young and Lowe indexes, have little justification in theory and in practice, something of major concern for this key macroeconomic indicator. The empirical work in Section IV used US data which benefited from relatively frequent rebasing and thus shows only some of the potential bias that may arise from these formulas. Nonetheless, we find the Lowe and the Young indexes to upward drift against (the already biased) Laspeyres, more so the Lowe. The Lowe index, like Laspeyres, has the advantage of ease of interpretation as a fixed quantity basket index. It provides a well-defined, but biased, result.

The two geometric formulations most readily available for compilers are the Geometric Young and the Geometric Lowe price indexes. The Geometric Young is easily explained as a weighted geometric average of price changes, using the survey period expenditure shares as weights. The Geometric Lowe has no meaningful interpretation. A formal exact decomposition of the difference between the Geometric Lowe and Geometric Young indexes found it to be based on long-run unidirectional price changes, equations (10) and (11), the nature of which made it unreliable as a basis for a predictable relationship between the Geometric Lowe and a Geometric Young/Törnqvist index.

The empirical work found all indexes considered improved on the Lowe index. Averages of geometric and arithmetic formulations were considered drawing on the L-D framework. We found these real-time L-D indexes tracked the Törnqvist and Fisher indexes very well. Even very simply formulations using geometric means of the two formulas were vast improvements on other standard arithmetic and geometric formulas.

The authors are well aware of the difficulties involved in changing the CPI formula from a long-standing and easily understood one to a more complex one. Similar issues arose when statistical agencies moved from arithmetic formulations to the widely adopted and conceptually sound geometric mean (Jevons index) at the lower level of CPI aggregation (Armknecht, 1996, Silver, 2007). However, it is time to debate moving on from Laspeyres-type indexes. One approach is to calculate retrospective indexes to identify the extent of the substitution bias.20 Yet the CPI is a key economic indicator and users would be better served by a real-time measure that more closely tracks a superlative index. It may well be that the public will accept a more complex formula if it can be demonstrated that it works much better. The Lowe index was found to have several times the bias of some of the geometric indexes and L-D approximations that could be compiled in real time using the self-same data.

References

  • Armknecht, Paul A., (1996), “Improving the Efficiency of the U.S. CPI,” IMF Working Paper WP/96/103, (International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C,), September.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balk, Bert M., (1983), “Does There Exist a Relation Between Inflation and Relative Price Change Variability? The Effect of the Aggregation LevelEconomic Letters, 13, 17380.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balk, Bert. M., (2010), “Lowe and Cobb-Douglas Consumer Price Indices and their Substitution Bias,” Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, Vol. 230, No. 6, 726740.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balk, Bert M. and W. Erwin Diewert, (2003), “The Lowe Consumer Price Index and its Substitution Bias,” Discussion Paper No. 04-07 (Department of Economics, University of British Columbia, Vancouver).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Laurence, and N. Gregory Mankiw, (1995), “Relative-Price Changes as Aggregate Supply Shocks,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 161193.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bortkiewicz, L.v., (1923), “Zweck und Struktur einer Preisindexzahl,” Nordisk Statistisk Tidsskrift, 2, 369408.

  • Feenstra, Robert C., and Marshall B. Reinsdorf, (2007), “Should Exact Index Numbers Have Standard Errors? Theory and Application to Asian Growth,” in Hard-to-Measure Goods and Services: Essays in Honor of Zvi Griliches (Ernst R. Berndt and Charles R. Hulten, eds.). National Bureau of Economic Research, October.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Glejser, Herbert, (1965). “Inflation, Productivity, and Relative Prices: A Statistical Study,” Review of Economics and Statistics 47, 7680.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greenlees, John S., (2011), “Improving the Preliminary Values of the Chained CPI-U,” Proceedings of the Business and Economic Statistics Section, Journal of Economic and Social Measurement, 31, 12, 118.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greenlees, John S. and Elliot Williams, (2010), “Reconsideration of Weighting and Updating Procedures in the U.S. CPI,” Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 230, 6, 741758..

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hansen, Carsten Bolden, (2007), “Recalculations of the Danish CPI 1996 – 2006,” Proceedings of the Tenth Meeting of the International Working Group on Price Indexes, (Ottawa, Canada). Available at: www.ottawagroup.org.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hercowitz, Zvi, (1982), “Money and Price Dispersion in the United States,” Journal of Monetary Economics 10, 2537.

  • International Labour Office (ILO), IMF, OECD, Eurostat, United Nations, World Bank, (2004), Consumer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice, (Geneva: ILO). http://www.ilo.org/public/english/bureau/stat/guides/cpi/index.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lastrapes, W.D., (2006) “Inflation and the Distribution of Relative Prices: The Role of Productivity and Money Supply Shocks,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 38, 8, December, 21592198

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lent, Janice, and Alan H. Dorfman, (2009). “Using a Weighted Average of Jevons and Laspeyres Indexes to Approximate a Superlative Index,” Journal of Official Statistics 25, 1, 129149.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pike, Chris, (2009), “New Zealand 2006 and 2008 Consumers Price Index Review: Price Updating,” Room document, Eleventh Meeting of the International Working (Ottawa) Group on Price Indexes, Neuchatel, Switzerland, May. Available under “Papers” at: http://www.ottawagroup.org/.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinsdorf, Marshall B., (1994), “New Evidence on the Relation and Price DispersionAmerican Economic Review 84, 3, 720731.

  • Silver, Mick and Saeed Heravi (2007), “Why Elementary Price Index Number Formulas Differ: Price Dispersion and Product Heterogeneity,” Journal of Econometrics, 140, 2, 87483.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Silver, Mick and Christos Ioannidis, C., (2001), “Inter-Country Differences in the Relationship Between Relative Price Variability and Average Prices,” Journal of Political Economy, 109, 2, 355374, April.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE), ILO, IMF, OECD, Eurostat, World Bank, Office for National Statistics United Kingdom, (2009), Practical Guide to Producing Consumer Price Indices (New York and Geneva: United Nations): http://www.imf.org/external/data.htm#guide.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Van Hoomisson, T., (1988), “Price Dispersion and Inflation: Evidence from Israel,” Journal of Political Economy, 96, 6, 13031314.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Vining, Daniel R., Jr., and Thomas C. Elwertowski, (1976), “The Relationship between Relative Prices and the General Price Level,” American Economic Review 66, 699708.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

The authors thank Walter Lane (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics) for his comments on an earlier draft and his assistance with the provision of data. Acknowledgements for helpful comments are also due to John Greenlees (US Bureau of Labor Statistics) and Jens Mehrhoff (Deutsche Bundesbank). The usual disclaimers apply.

2

Hansen (2007) notes that in the joint UNECE/ILO survey on the CPI Manual of the 47 respondents as at September 2007, 32 national statistical offices used the (price-updated) Lowe index and 15 the original (presumably survey period) Young weights. A few larger countries including Germany, Korea, and Japan use Laspeyres by retrospective revisions.

3

The Consumer Price Index (CPI) Manual (ILO et al., 2004) recommends superlative price indexes—the Fisher, Törnqvist, and Walsh indexes—as the target formulas for the higher-level indexes. These formulas generally produce similar results, use geometric averaging, and symmetric weights based on quantity or expenditure information from both the reference and current periods. They derive their support as superlative indexes from economic theory. A utility function underlies the definition of (constant utility) cost of living index (COLIs) in economic theory. Different index number formulas can be shown to correspond with different functional forms of the utility function. Laspeyres, for example, corresponds to a highly restrictive Leontief form. The underlying functional forms for superlative indexes, including Fisher and Törnqvist, are flexible: they are second-order approximations to other (twice-differentiable) homothetic forms around the same point. It is the generality of functional forms that superlative indexes represent that allows them to accommodate substitution behavior and be desirable indexes. The Fisher price index is also recommended on axiomatic grounds and from a fixed quantity basket perspective (ILO et al., 2004).

4

It passes the time reversal test and is transitive. However, as pointed out by ILO et al., (2004, paragraph 1.64), “Achieving transitivity by arbitrary holding the quantities constant, especially over a very long period of time, does not compensate for the potential biases introduced by using out-of-date quantities.”

5

It will exceed its time antithesis by a term equal to the Young index times the weighted variance of deviations of price relatives (between periods 0 and t) and their mean. Since the variance must be positive, the Young must exceed the inverse of its time antithesis except when there is no price change dispersion, a case that negates the purpose of an index number.

6

The concern is whether the share of expenditure increases over periods 0 and b with relative price increases over periods 0 and t. This would require long-run trends in prices and, for Young to be above (below) Laspeyres, very elastic (inelastic) demand (ILO et al. (2004, chapter 15, pages 275-6).

7

It does so in a footnote: the CPI Practical Guide focused on helping implement good practice rather than as a platform for change, but the authors/editors nonetheless considered the matter sufficiently important to footnote this point. As shown later, the Geometric Young is a good proxy for superlative indexes if the elasticity of substitution is unity.

8

Cited Törnqvist indexes are approximations as the current period weights are expenditure shares over a period longer than the current month or quarter t, due to lack of expenditure data (the expenditure survey not being continuous) and inadequate sample sizes for the single month or quarter.

9

Rebasing took place in 1994 (for January 1996-December 1999), 1996 (Dec. 1999-Dec 2002), 1999 (Dec. 2002-Dec 2005), and 2003 (Dec. 2005-Dec 2006). The lag for the price-updating varies from 2 to 3.5 years over the links of the index.

10

The Lowe and Young indexes are based on the US Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers, or CPI-U. Its weights, as from 2002, cover a two year period and are revised every two years. For example, the weights in January 2010 are expenditures from 2007-2008 that were price-updated to December 2009. There is approximately a two-year lag from the midpoint of the survey period to the price reference period.

11

See Bortkiewicz (1923; 374-375) for the first application of this decomposition technique: we define ∑uv/∑u = σuσvρu,v/ū +

article image
= cov(u, v)/ū +
article image
and ∑suv/∑su as s-weighted terms for the decomposition. Equation (10) can be formulated as a covariance, IGLo0tIGY0t=exp(covxi,yisibx¯isib),, a preferred stance pointed out by Jens Mehrhoff to an earlier draft since the dispersion in cvxsib is in part counterbalanced by the dispersion of x in the denominator of ρxi,yisib. Our position is that the correlation coefficient is meaningful in its own right, but draw attention to the point.

12

Early empirical research in this area includes Glejser (1965), Vining and Elwertowski (1976), and Parks (1978). Most of the evidence on this relationship relies on regressions of relative price dispersion on inflation with a common finding of a positive relationship, although this finding is not universal. The main two theoretical models to explain the relationship are signal extraction models in which inflation which is not correctly anticipated by economic agents leading to erroneous output levels inflation—Hercowitz (1982), Friedman (1977) and Lastrapes (2006)—and models with price-setting behavior and price-rigidities that vary across markets—see Ball and Mankiw (1995). Other models include search cost theory—see Van Hoomissen (1988).

13

A finding of an association between the dispersion in relative prices and their mean also applies to the coefficient of variation as a measure of dispersion (Reinsdorf, 1983 and Silver and Ioannidis, 2001).

14

The use of period 0 weights is required since for a comparison in real time from period 0, only period b weights are available. For equation (17) to equal a true Lloyd-Moulton index shares must remain constant over periods b to 0. Greenlees (2011) used a formula akin to (13) and price-updated the weights, from period b to 0.

15

For product groups using arithmetic means see BLS, January 2008 CPI Detailed Report, Table 3, ff. 6 at: http://www.bls.gov/cpi/#tables.

16

The US chained Törnqvist C-CPI-U is calculated in real time as a preliminary Geometric Young index and, when subsequent data on expenditure share data become available, the Geometric Young element is revised to a Törnqvist index. Greenlees (2011) develops an operationally feasible formula that can out-perform the Geometric Young component. He employs a constant-elasticity of substitution (CES) index number formula. First, support for the use of CES assumptions are validated by the closeness of the Sato-Vartia price index to superlative indexes. Second, he derives estimates of the elasticity of substitution (η) using the Feenstra-Reinsdorf (2007) approach, for use in a Lloyd-Moulton CES formula, equation (13). A clear improvement over using the GEOMETRIC YOUNG index is demonstrated. While the Lent-Dorfman estimates are not provided by Greenlees, he refers to deriving such estimates using his data and, encouragingly, yielding similar estimates of η as those from the Feenstra and Reinsdorf approach (Greenlees, 20111, ff. xiii).

17

We compared over the period December 1999 to December 2010 our calculated monthly Törnqvist index with the BLS’ monthly chained Törnqvist index (C-CPI-U)—see Greenlees and Williams (2010) for details—and found correlations of 0.99978 and 0.98855 between the two series for the levels and monthly annual changes respectively.

18

Lowe and Young are calculated following BLS procedures, for example for January 2006-December 2007 using 2003/04 expenditure weights, price-updated for Lowe, but not for Young. Laspeyres uses available weights most closely aligned with the reference period, in this example, for 2005/06. Paasche and Törnqvist use available counterpart symmetric weights most closely aligned to the current period, in this case, 2007/08. As noted in ff.15, this does not detract from the analysis.

19

Both Fisher and Törnqvist are used as target superlative indexes, tracking each other very closely: the former has an annual growth of 2.49033 and the latter 2.49316 over the period December 198 and to December 2010.

20

The US Chained Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers or C-CPI-U is a chained Törnqvist. Details are available at: http://www.bls.gov/cpi/.

Post-Laspeyres: The Case for a New Formula for Compiling Consumer Price Indexes
Author: Mr. Paul A Armknecht Jr. and Mick Silver