Assessing Dsge Models with Capital Accumulation and Indeterminacy

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: vkhramov@imf.org

The simulated results of this paper show that New Keynesian DSGE models with capital accumulation can generate substantial persistencies in the dynamics of the main economic variables, due to the stock nature of capital. Empirical estimates on U.S. data from 1960:I to 2008:I show the response of monetary policy to inflation was almost twice lower than traditionally considered, as capital accumulation creates an additional channel of influence through real interest rates in the production sector. Versions of the model with indeterminacy empirically outperform determinate versions. This paper allows for the reconsideration of previous findings and has significant monetary policy implications.

Abstract

The simulated results of this paper show that New Keynesian DSGE models with capital accumulation can generate substantial persistencies in the dynamics of the main economic variables, due to the stock nature of capital. Empirical estimates on U.S. data from 1960:I to 2008:I show the response of monetary policy to inflation was almost twice lower than traditionally considered, as capital accumulation creates an additional channel of influence through real interest rates in the production sector. Versions of the model with indeterminacy empirically outperform determinate versions. This paper allows for the reconsideration of previous findings and has significant monetary policy implications.

Introduction

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models with nominal rigidities (“New Keynesian” models) became very popular in the analysis of monetary policy in the last decades. Canonical versions of these models are well-studied and estimated. As these models are micro-founded, their estimation using the Bayesian approach, which allows us to specify prior distributions for parameters, became very popular. As multiple equilibria can arise in these models under a wide set of parameters, only is a limited set of econometric estimation methods can be applied.

Traditionally, papers estimated canonical models only under determinacy, ruling out possibilities for indeterminacy. The standard result is that determinacy arises mainly under active monetary policy rules (the nominal interest rate increases more than one-to-one with inflation) in New Keynesian DSGE models, while passive monetary policy (the nominal interest rate increases less than one-to-one with inflation) leads to indeterminacy (see Kerr and King (1996), Rotemberg and Woodford (1998), and Christiano and Gust (1999)). Clarida, Gali and Gertler (2000) estimate monetary policy rules in the U.S. for different periods of time and show that U.S. monetary policy was passive during the pre-Volcker period (1960-1979) and active into the Volcker-Greenspan period (1979-1996). Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) were the first to estimate a standard New Keynesian model allowing for indeterminacy.

In contrast to canonical New Keynesian models, where the interest rate affects output only through the consumption and saving decisions of households, in this paper the investment decisions of firms are added. The no-arbitrage condition between the real return on bonds and the real return on capital implies that the capital rental rate increases when monetary policy responds to higher inflation by increasing the interest rate. This response increases the cost of renting capital, leading to cost-push inflation. Dupor (2001), Carlstrom and Fuerst (2005), Kurozumi and Zandweghe (2008), Kurozumi (2006), Huang and Meng (2007), and Xiao (2008) study properties of models with capital accumulation and show that this crucial feature changes the stability structure and dynamics of the models and makes indeterminacy likely.

This paper studies New Keynesian DSGE models with capital accumulation, different Taylor rules, and the potential for indeterminacy. While the stability properties of models with capital accumulation are well-analyzed1, there appear to be no papers that simulate and estimate these models allowing indeterminacy to occur. This paper is offered to fill this gap. The analysis is distinguished from the conventional New Keynesian studies in three ways. First, different versions of New Keynesian models with capital accumulation are simulated, and their dynamic properties are discussed. Second, the models are estimated on U.S. data from 1960:I to 2008:I. Following Lubik and Schorfheide (2004), passive monetary policy (consistent with indeterminacy) is assumed a priori for the pre-Volcker period and active monetary policy (consistent with determinacy) for the post-1982 period. Using state-space decomposition and the Kalman filter, the overall likelihood of the model is maximized taking into account prior distributions of the parameters, and inferences are made with a likelihood-based approach by adopting the Metropolis-Hastings techniques. Third, the estimated models are compared using the Bayesian approach. While some explanations of the results are consistent with the recent findings of Mavroeidis (2010), the empirical estimates of this paper differ from the results of Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) and Clarida, Gali and Gertler (2000).

Though baseline New Keynesian models have become very popular in the analysis of monetary policy, many authors show that these models are unable to generate enough persistence in inflation and output. Fuhrer and Moore (1995) show that a sticky wage model can generate persistence in the price level but not in the inflation rate. Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan (2000) point out that models with nominal rigidities do not generate enough persistence in output following a monetary shock. The simulated results of this paper show that models with capital accumulation can generate substantial persistencies among the major economic variables, as the stock nature of capital adds persistency to the dynamics of all other variables in the models.

Later research attempts to determine whether there were switches in monetary policy or structural changes in the fundamental parameters of the economy. Sims and Zha (2006) use a vector autoregression (VAR) approach to estimate a multivariate regime-switching model for U.S. monetary policy. They find that the main changes were in the monetary policy rules. Smets and Wouters (2003) and Smets and Wouters (2007) find most of the structural parameters are stable over those two periods. The biggest difference concerns the variances of the structural shocks. The main drawback of the VAR approach is that, due to rational expectations, agents can anticipate changes in parameters of the economy, leading to inconsistent estimates. One method to overcome this problem is to estimate a fully-specified DSGE model that can be re-solved for alternative policy rules. Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) exogenously split data into two sets and show that U.S. monetary policy during the post-1982 period was consistent with determinacy, whereas during the pre-Volcker policy was not. Schorfheide (2005) estimates a basic New Keynesian monetary DSGE model, in which monetary policy follows a regime switching process, and confirms the switch in monetary policy between the pre-Volcker and post-Volker periods.

There are identification issues with estimation of forward-looking Markov-switching rational expectations models. Beyer and Farmer (2007) argue that it is not always possible to decide whether the data are generated from determinate or indeterminate models. Farmer, Waggoner and Zha (2008) provide a set of necessary and sufficient conditions for determinacy in a class of forward looking Markov-switching rational expectations models. Mavroeidis’s (2010) model shows that policy before Volcker led to indeterminacy, however, the model is not accurately identifiable using data after 1979.

The paper is structured as follows. In Section 1, a New Keynesian DSGE model with capital accumulation and different monetary policy rules is derived. In Section 2, different versions of this model are simulated and their dynamic properties are analyzed. In Section 3, the model is fitted to quarterly U.S. data on output, inflation, nominal interest rates, consumption, and capital from 1960:I to 2008:I and the estimation methodology and prior distributions of the parameters are discussed. The empirical results are presented in Section 4. Estimated models are compared in Section 5. The last section contains concluding remarks.

1. Model

Following Yun (1998), Carlstrom and Fuerst (2005), and Kurozumi and Zandweghe (2008), a New Keynesian DSGE model with sticky prices and capital accumulation in discrete time is constructed. The economy consists of a large number of households, monopolistically competitive firms, and a monetary authority that changes the nominal interest rate in response to inflation and output.

1.1. Households

Households seek to maximize their expected life-time utility function:

(1)EtΣt=0βtU(Ct,Mt+1Pt,1Lt)

where Et is the conditional expectations operator on the information set available at date t, β is the discount factor, Ct is consumption, Mt+1 is nominal money holdings and the beginning of the period (t+1), Pt is a price level, Mt+1Pt is real money balances2, and (1 - Lt) is leisure.

The utility function is separable in leisure and takes the following functional form:

(2)U(Ct,Mt+1Pt,1Lt)=Ct1σ1σ+θlnMt+1Pt+ΦLt

At the beginning of each period t, a household has Mt cash balances and Bt-1 nominal bonds. A household starts period t by trading bonds and receiving a lump-sum monetary transfer Tt from the government. A household receives interest payments on bonds Bt-1 with gross interest rate Rt-1 and spends money on new bonds Bt. A household also receives real factor payments from the labor market wtLt and capital market [rt + (1 - δ)]Kt, receives firm’s profits Πt, and spends money on next period capital Kt+1 and current consumption Ct at current prices Pt. Each household chooses Ct, Mt+1, and Lt to maximize (1) subject to the sequence of intertemporal budget constraints:

(3)Mt+1+Bt+PtCt+PtKt+1=Mt+Tt+Bt1Rt1+Pt{wtLt+[rt+(1δ)]Kt}+Πt

The first order conditions for the household’s maximization problem are the following:

(4)UCUL=1w
(5)UC(t)=βEt{UC(t+1)[rt+1+(1δ)]}
(6)UC(t)Pt=βRtEt(UC(t+1)Pt+1)
(7)Um(t)UC(t)=Rt1Rt

Equation (4) is a standard consumption-labor condition. Equation (5) is the Euler equation of consumption dynamics. Equation (6) is the Fisher equation that connects inflation and interest rates. Equation (7) is a money demand equation.

1.2. Firms

Firms are monopolistic competitors in the intermediate good market. The final output Yt is produced from intermediate goods yt (i) with Dixit-Stiglitz (1977) technology:

(8)Yt={01[yt(i)η1η]i}ηη1

The corresponding demand for an intermediate good i possesses constant price elasticityη:

(9)yt(i)=Yt(Pt(i)Pt)η

where Pt (i) is the price of the intermediate good and Pt is the price of the final good.

The production function of each firm exhibits constant returns to scale:

(10)f(K,L)=KαL1α

The first order conditions for the cost minimization problem are the following:

(11)rt=ztfK(Kt,Lt)
(12)wt=ztfL(Kt,Lt)

where zt is the marginal cost of production (see Appendix 1 for details).

With the Cobb-Douglas production function (10) the first order conditions take the form:

(13)rt=αztYt/Kt
(14)wt=(1α)zt(Yt/Kt)α(1α)

The Calvo (1983) staggered pricing model is used, assuming that each period a fraction (1-ν) of firms gets a signal to set a new price. Therefore, each firm maximizes the sum of discounted profits taking into account the probability of changing its price. The optimization problem of a firm takes the form:

(15)EtΣj=t(νΠi=0jRi)j[(Pt(i)Pt)ηYt(Pt(i)Ptzt)]maxPt(i)

The profit maximization conditions give a log-linearized New Keynesian Phillips Curve3 of the form:

(16)π^t=βEtπ^t+1+λz^t

where π^t is inflation and λ=(1ν)(1βν)ν is the real marginal cost elasticity of inflation.

1.3. Monetary policy rules

Monetary policy reacts to inflation and output with interest rate smoothing:

(17)Rt=(Rt1)ρR[R(Etπt+kπ)Ψπ(YtY)Ψπ](1ρR)

where R,π, Y are the steady-state values of the interest rate, inflation, and output, respectively. Parameters ψπ and ψY are the elasticities of the interest rate with respect to inflation and output, respectively. Two basic specifications of the monetary policy rule are considered: with response to current inflation (k=0) and future expected inflation (k=1). Interest rate smoothing is introduced with the autocorrelation coefficient ρR. In this framework, the monetary policy is active if the nominal interest rate increases more than one-to-one with inflation (ψπ>1), otherwise, it is passive (ψπ< 1). Also, a model with ψY=0 would give a standard model with capital in discrete time as in Carlstrom and Fuerst (2005)—an analog of the Dupor (2001) continuous time model.

1.4. Dynamics of the model

The dynamics of the model are represented by a system of first order conditions log-linearized around the steady state for households and firms (18-23), the monetary policy rule (24), shocks of preferences and marginal cost (25-26) (see Appendix 2 for details):

(18)R^tEtπ^t+1=σ(EtC^t+1C^tɛg,t)
(19)R^tEtπ^t+1=[1β(1δ)](Etz^t+1+EtY^t+1K^t+1)
(20)σC^t=z^t+α1α(K^tY^t)
(21)K^t+1=(1δ)K^t+δI^t
(22)Y^t=sCC^t+sII^t
(23)π^t=βEtπ^t+1+λz^t+ɛz,t
(24)R^t=ρRR^t1+(1ρR)(ΨπEtπ^t+k+ΨYY^t)+ɛR,t
(25)ɛg,t=ρgɛg,t1+νg,t,νg,t is iid(0,σg2)
(26)ɛz,t=ρzɛz,t1+νz,t,νz,t is iid(0,σz2)

Equation (18) is the Euler equation for the household’s dynamic optimization problem with a preference shock εg, t, which follows an AR(1) process with an autocorrelation coefficient of ρg (Equation 25). Equation (19) is the Fisher relation between the nominal interest rate, expected future inflation, and real interest rate, where the latter is determined in the production sector. Equation (20) is the wage-equilibrium relation of the log-linearized equations (4) and (14). Equation (21) is the capital accumulation relation with a depreciation rate δ. Equation (22) is the division of the steady-state output between consumption and investment with shares sC and sI, respectively. Equation (23) is a New Keynesian Phillips Curve derived from the Calvo staggered-pricing model with a marginal cost shock εz, t, which follows an AR(1) process with an autocorrelation coefficient of ρz (Equation 26). Equation (24) is the log-linearized monetary policy rule (17) with an interest rate shock εR, t. As the money supply is endogenous and the Ricardian equivalence holds in this model, the hidden government budget constraint and the equation for the evolution of government debt are implicitly satisfied.

Straightforward re-arrangements of the variables t and I^t in the model give a system of variables C^t,R^t,π^t,Y^t,K^t,ɛg,t,ɛz,t:

(27)C^t=EtC^t+11σ[R^tEtπ^t+1]+ɛg,t
(28)R^tEtπ^t+1=[1β(1δ)](σEt(C^t+1)+11α[EtY^t+1EtK^t+1])
(29)K^t+1=(1δ)K^t+δsI(Y^t(1sI))C^t)
(30)π^t=βEtπ^t+1+λ(σC^tα1α(K^tY^t))+ɛz,t
(31)R^t=ρRR^t1+(1ρR)(ΨπEtπ^t+k+ΨYY^t)+ɛR,t,ɛR,tisiid(0,σR2)
(32)ɛg,t=ρgɛg,t1+νg,t,νg,t is iid(0,σg2)
(33)ɛz,t=ρzɛz,t1+νz,t,νz,t is iid(0,σz2)

Adding capital accumulation to the model makes real interest rate connected to the marginal product of capital, this is contained in the Fisher equation (28). Also, output does not equal consumption in the absence of capital, as in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004), but is split between consumption and investment in this model. This is incorporated in the New Keynesian Phillips curve equation (30) through the output equation (22). By including investment, this model has the capital accumulation equation (29), which influences interest rates through the equations (26) and (28).

To compare, the canonical New Keynesian model can be presented by a system of three equations: the IS equation, the Phillips curve, and a monetary policy rule, similar to equations (27), (30), and (31), respectively. In that way, the interest rate affects output only through the consumption-savings decision of the household and not through the production sector.

2. Model simulations

The model (27)-(33) exhibits different types of dynamics depending on its parameter values (see Carlstrom and Fuerst (2005), Sosunov and Khramov (2008), Kurozumi and Zandweghe (2008), Kurozumi (2006), Huang and Meng (2007), and Xiao (2008)). Under a wide set of parameters, the model is determinate if the monetary authority implements an active monetary policy (Ψπ> 1), and the model is indeterminate if the monetary policy is passive (Ψπ< 1). Therefore, two major versions of the model (27)-(33), with active and passive monetary policies, are simulated.4 For the baseline calibration most of the parameter values are the same as prior means used by Lubik and Schorfheide (2004); the rest of the parameters are calibrated according to stylized facts (Table 6). The Matlab-based computer package Dynare was used to calculate theoretical moments for the endogenous variables of the model. The simulation results of the two versions of the model with current-looking passive and active monetary policy rules and corresponding moments of consumption, interest rate, inflation, output, and capital are presented in Tables 1-4.

The version of the model with passive monetary policy demonstrates substantially higher volatility of interest rate and inflation compared to the version with active monetary policy (Table 1). This can be explained by the existence of indeterminate equilibria. As long as the monetary policy authority is unable to respond sufficiently to changes in inflation by raising interest rates substantially, the volatility of inflation and, therefore, nominal interest rates, is higher. Both models reproduce a similar volatility of capital to that of U.S. data with lower volatilities of consumption, interest rate, and inflation (Table 5).

The crucial differences between the two versions of the model arise from the variance decomposition of shocks, correlation matrices of endogenous variables, and impulse response functions (IRFs). First, the preferences (demand) shock is the main drivers of volatility in the version of the model with passive monetary policy, explaining more than 90 percent of the volatility of endogenous variables (Table 2). In contrast, the marginal cost (supply) shock explains more than 50 percent of variance in the model with active monetary policy. These results are similar to the findings of Smets and Wouters (2007), who show that “demand” shocks can explain a substantial share of the variance in output in the general version of a New Keynesian model.

The two versions of the model demonstrate different correlations among the major variables (Table 3). In the version of the model with active monetary policy, the nominal interest rate plays the role of the active monetary policy instrument and is negatively correlated with output and capital. These theoretical results are consistent with the stabilizing role of a nominal interest rate in the economy. In contrast, in the version of the model with passive monetary policy, the nominal interest rate is positively correlated with output, capital, and consumption. Passive monetary policy is unable to respond sufficiently to shocks, indeterminacy and additional shock propagation. A response of the monetary authority to supply and demand shocks leads to co-movements in the dynamics of the interest rate and real variables as changes in the nominal interest rate are not enough to diminish the effect of shocks and reverse the dynamics of the economy. Therefore, the version of the model with passive monetary policy demonstrates substantially higher volatility among the economic variables, which is consistent with U.S. data for the pre-Volcker period (1960:I to 1979:II). Theoretical IRFs support this intuition (Appendixes 3-4).

As stated in the Introduction, while the baseline “New Keynesian” models became very popular in the analysis of monetary policy, many papers show that these models are unable to generate enough persistencies in inflation and output (see Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2000), Fuhrer and Moore (1995), Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramirez (2004)). First-order autocorrelation coefficients for consumption, interest rate, output, and capital are more than 0.85 in the U.S. data (Appendix 6). Most of the New Keynesian models fail to replicate even half of these correlation levels (see Rubio-Ramirez and Rabanal (2005)). In contrast, the simulated results of this paper show that models with capital accumulation can, in fact, generate substantial persistencies (Table 4). The autocorrelation coefficients for consumption and capital are more than 0.9 in both active and passive monetary policy rule versions of the model. The autocorrelations of nominal variables, such as inflation and the nominal interest rate, are also very high due to the stock nature of capital, which adds persistency to the dynamics of all other variables. The autocorrelation coefficients for consumption and capital are very high, representing substantial consumption smoothing and slow adjustment of capital stock. In the version with passive monetary policy, the interest rate and output autocorrelation coefficients are higher than in the version with active monetary policy, again, due to the fact that passive monetary policy is unable to adjust the interest rate sufficiently to control shock propagation.

Table 1.

Simulation results of the model. Theoretical moments.

article image
Note: all variables are in log deviations from their steady-state values.
Table 2.

Simulation results of the model. Variance decomposition (in percent).

article image
Note: all variables are in log deviations from their steady-state values.
Table 3.

Simulation results of the model. Matrix of correlations.

article image
Note: All variables are in log deviations from their steady states.
Table 4.

Simulation results of the model. Coefficients of autocorrelation.

article image

3. Empirical Approach

3.1. Data

The system of equations (27)-(33) is fitted to quarterly postwar U.S. data on output, inflation, nominal interest rates, consumption and capital from 1960:I to 2008:I. As in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004), output is a log of real per capita GDP (GDPQ), inflation is the annualized percentage change of CPI (CPI-U), and the Federal Funds Rate (FYFF) in percent is used as the nominal interest rate. Real Personal Consumption Expenditures (PCECC96) is used for consumption from the St. Louis Fed database. The time series for capital is constructed using Real Gross Private Domestic Investment (GPDIC96) starting from 1947, taking the initial amount of capital consistent with the steady state level of capital and iterating it forward with a depreciation rate of 2 percent.

The Hodrick-Prescott filter is used to remove trends from the consumption, output, and capital series to make the analysis comparable with Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) (see the sample moments in Table 5, Appendices 5-6, and graphs in Figure 1). Consistent with earlier papers, the data sample 1960:I to 2008:I can be analyzed according to the following sub-samples:

  • 1. the pre-Volcker period (1960:I to 1979:II)—the period of passive monetary policy is used in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004);

  • 2. the post-1978 period (1978:III to 1997:IV)—the Volcker disinflation period (commonly excluded from estimates);

  • 3. the post-1982 period (1982:IV to 1997:IV)—the period of active monetary policy analyzed in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004);

  • 4. the post-1982 period (1982:IV to 2008:I)—the period of active monetary policy, before the financial crisis, included in this paper.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Dynamics of U.S. output, inflation, nominal interest rate, consumption, and capital (in log deviations from the Hodrick-Prescott filtered trend), 1960:I -2008:I.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2012, 083; 10.5089/9781475502350.001.A001

Table 5.

Sample moments for quarterly postwar U.S. data on output, inflation, nominal interest rates, consumption, and capital.

article image

In log deviations from the Hodrick-Prescott filtered trend.

Data sample used in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004).

3.2. Estimation approach

The Bayesian approach is used to estimate the model by constructing prior distributions of the parameters and maximizing the likelihood of the model. The Kalman filter with state and measurement equations is used to fit the data to the model. The Bayesian approach takes advantage of the general equilibrium approach and outperforms GMM and ML in small samples. Furthermore, it does not rely on the identification scheme of the VAR, though does follow the likelihood principle.

The model (27)-(33) is a system of the variables C^t,R^t,π^t,Y^t,K^t,ɛg,t,andɛR,t, with a vector of parameters presented in Table 6. The observed capital, consumption, and output deviations from the trends, along with inflation and interest rate are stacked in the vector Yt=[C^t,R^t,π^t,Y^t,K^t]T, such that the measurement equation is of the form:

yt=[0r*+π*π*00]+[10000000400000004000000010000000100]st=y*+Sst

The state equation is:

(34)st=Fst1+Qɛt

where r* and π* are the steady-state inflation and real interest rate, respectively, st=[C^t,R^t,π^t,Y^t,K^t,ɛg,t,ɛz,t]T is a vector of system variables, r* is determined from β = (1 + r*)1/4, F and Q are the system matrixes, and εt is a vector of shocks.

As the posterior distribution of the estimated model is proportional to the product of the likelihood function and the prior, the overall likelihood of the model is maximized taking into account the prior distributions of the parameters and using the state-space decomposition with the Kalman filter. The inference is made with a likelihood-based approach by adopting the random walk Metropolis-Hastings algorithm to obtain 100,000 draws and estimate the moments of the parameter distributions.

3.3. Prior Distributions

The specification of the prior distributions is summarized in Table 6. Most of the priors are the same as in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004). The model is estimated separately for the pre-Volcker period from 1960:I to 1979:II, assuming a priori passive monetary policy (consistent with indeterminacy), and for the post-1982 period, assuming a priori active monetary policy (consistent with determinacy). The beta distribution is used as a prior for the response of the monetary policy rule to the inflation parameter (ψπ) centered around 0.5 and 1.5 for the pre-Volcker and post-1982 periods, respectively.

The response of the monetary policy rule to the output parameter (ψY) is centered around 0.25, which is consistent with empirical findings in the range of 0.06 to 0.43. Persistency of the interest rate parameter in the monetary policy rule (ρR) is centered around 0.5 and bounded by the beta distribution to be in the interval (0,1). The steady state inflation (π *) and the interest rate (r*) are centered around 4 and 2 percent per annum, respectively. The real marginal cost elasticity of inflation (λ) is centered around 0.3, assuming that firms reset optimal prices once every three or five quarters, on average. The prior for household risk aversion parameter (σ) is centered around 2, which makes households more risk averse than in the case of logarithmic utility. Shocks of preferences and technology are assumed to follow an AR(1) process with autocorrelation parameters centered around 0.7 and to have a zero prior correlation. Variances of shocks are considered to have inverse gamma distributions.

Adding capital and investment activity to the model makes it necessary to specify parameters related to capital accumulation activity and production sector. The priors for capital share in output (α) and investment share in output (SI) are centered around 0.3 with the standard deviation of 0.1 and are bounded by the beta distribution to be in the interval (0,1).

Table 6.

Baseline calibration and prior distributions of the parameters of the model.

article image

4. Estimation Results

The model is estimated separately for the pre-Volcker and post-1982 periods, assuming a priori passive monetary policy (ψπ < 1), consistent with indeterminacy during the pre-Volcker period, and active monetary policy (ψπ > 1), consistent with determinacy during the post-1982 period. For both data samples the versions of the model with current and forward looking monetary policy rules (29) are estimated:

  • current-looking monetary policy rule (response to current inflation)

(35)R^t=ρRR^t1+(1ρR)(Ψππ^t+ΨYY^t)+ɛt
  • forward-looking monetary policy rule (response to expected inflation)

(36)R^t=ρRR^t1+(1ρR)(Ψππ^t+ΨYY^t)+ɛR,t

The priors, the posterior parameter estimates, and the confidence intervals for the pre-Volcker period (1960:I to 1979:II) and for the post-1982 period are presented in Tables 7-8. The inference is made with a likelihood-based approach by adopting the Metropolis-Hastings techniques5. The pre-Volcker period posteriors are conditional on indeterminacy and passive monetary policy rules, the post-1982 posteriors are conditional on determinacy and active monetary policy rules. For comparison, the estimates of Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) for a standard New Keynesian model without capital are included.

For the pre-Volcker period the estimates of the response of monetary policy to inflation (ψπ) are 0.385 in current-looking version and 0.644 in the forward-looking version. For the post-1982 period these estimates are about 1.1 in all cases. These estimates are almost twice smaller than those in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) or in Clarida, Gali and Gertler (2000), explained by the fact that in the model with capital accumulation there is an additional channel of monetary policy influence through the real interest rate in the production sector. Therefore, the monetary policy can respond less aggressively to changes in inflation to obtain the same goals.

While the response of the monetary policy rule to output (ψY) is about 0.5 for the pre-Volcker and the earlier post-1982 (1982:IV to 1997:IV) periods in the case of current-looking monetary policy rule, it is substantially higher for the 1982:IV to 2008:I period, where the pre-crisis years are added. The estimates of the response of the monetary policy rule to output are much higher for the pre-Volcker period than in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004).

Adding capital accumulation activity into the model makes returns in production sector dependent on the amount of output and capital in the economy. As the capital dynamics is persistent over time, it translates additional persistency into real interest rates. Therefore, monetary policy becomes more focused on smoothing interest rates by increasing the value of ρR, estimated to be about 0.8 in the model. While the steady-state inflation and real interest rate estimates are very close to those in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) for the pre-Volcker period, the steady-state inflation rate is substantially lower and the real interest rate is a marginally lower the for post-1982 period, depending on the model specifications.

Another striking result of this paper is the shift in preferences of households. Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) find that households increased the degree of risk aversion (inverse elasticity of intertemporal substitution of consumption) between the pre-Volcker and post-1982 periods only slightly. It is shown in this paper that risk aversion (σ) increased substantially between these periods from about 0.4 for the pre-Volcker period to about 2.5 for the post-1982 period. This result arises from the fact that investment activity permits breaking the direct connection between interest rate and consumption dynamics in the Euler equation, due to the no-arbitrage condition between bonds and real sector returns. This allows for the explaination of consumption dynamics not only in terms of changing interest rate but changing preferences as well. The decrease in the levels of elasticity of intertemporal substitution of consumption can be connected with the development of financial markets and the decreasing tightness of borrowing constraints in the U.S. over time.

In the model with capital, the inflation dynamics described by the expectational Phillips curve is more complicated than in the standard model due to a direct connection between output and marginal cost through capital markets. Therefore, the estimates of real marginal cost elasticity of inflation (λ) are different from those in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004). First, they are substantially lower than in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) for the pre-Volcker period and higher for the post-1982 period. Second, in the model with capital they increased over time, while in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) they fell.

As neither government expenditures nor net exports are included in the model directly, some fluctuations in output are not explained by changes in investment and consumption. This influences the estimates of capital share in output (α), which are about 0.4 and 0.65 for the pre-Volcker and post-1982 periods, respectively. Also, the estimate of the share of investment in output (sI) is lower than expected—about 0.07 in the baseline specification of the model.

The standard deviations estimates (σ g,σz, and σR) as well as those for the degree of persistence of shocks(ρg and ρz) are consistent with other empirical findings. The correlation between shocks (ρgz) is slightly positive for the pre-Volcker period and very negative (about -0.98) for the post-1982 period.

Table 7.

Priors and posterior estimation results of the model with indeterminacy tor the pre- Volcker period (1960:I to 1979:II).

article image
Notes: Two specifications ot the monetary policy rule (17)—with a response to current inflation (k=0) and to future expected inflation (k=1)—are considered. The estimates ofLubik and Schorfheide (2004) are of the standard New Keynesian model without capital.
Table 8.

Priors and posterior estimation results of the model with indeterminacy for the post- 1982 period.

article image
Notes: Two specifications of the monetary policy rule (17)—with a response to current inflation (k=0) and to future expected inflation (k=1)—are considered. The estimates of Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) are of the standard New Keynesian model without capital.

5. Model comparison

The four versions of the model are estimated and compared on the three data samples in order to evaluate the odds of each model for a certain period of time (Table 10). The Bayesian approach is used to evaluate the probability of each model. In a simple two-model case, the ratio of the posterior probabilities of the two models is calculated as:

P(A1|YT)P(A2|YT)=P(A1)P(A2)P(YT|A1)P(YT|A2)

where P(A1|YT)P(A2|YT) is the posterior odds ratio, P(A1)P(A2) is the prior odds ratio, and P(YT|A1)P(YT|A2) is the Bayes factor that uses the models’ estimates.

In the case of more than two models, the posterior probability of a model Ai is calculated as:

P(Ai|YT)=P(Ai)P(YT|Ai)ΣjP(Aj)P(YT|Aj)

where ΣjP(Aj)P(YT|Aj) is the sum across all models. Equal prior probabilities are assumed for each model and Bayes factor probabilities are calculated using empirical distributions of the estimated parameters:

P(YT,A)=θAp(θA|YT,A)p(θA|A)θAp^(YT,A)=2πk/2|ΣθM|1/2p(θAM|YT,A)p(θAM|A)

The probability p(θA | YT,A) is integrated over the set θA of k estimated parameters, assuming a normal distribution for the estimation of p^(YT,A).

A comparison of the versions of the model with indeterminacy and determinacy under current-looking monetary policy rules is presented in Table 9. In contrast to Lubik and Schorfheide (2004), the model with indeterminacy dominates the determinate model with a posterior probability of 1.000 for all sample periods. In the case of comparison of all four versions of the model, the version with indeterminacy and a forward-looking monetary policy rule dominates all other models (Table 10). For the post-1982 period (1982:IV to 1997:IV) only, the probability of the model with indeterminacy and current-looking monetary policy rule is about 0.2.

Table 9.

Bayesian comparison of versions of the model with determinacy and indeterminacy.

article image
Table 10.

Bayesian comparison of the four versions of the model.

article image

Conclusions

Different versions of the New Keynesian model with capital accumulation, different Taylor rules, and the possibility of indeterminacy are simulated and estimated in this paper. Capital accumulation activity introduces new channels of influence for monetary policy on the economy through the no-arbitrage condition between bonds and real sector returns. In canonical models, interest rates affect output solely through the consumption-savings decision of the household in the absence of investment. It is shown in this paper that investment activity changes the monetary transmission mechanisms and allows for the reconsideration and re-estimation of monetary policy.

The approach of the paper is threefold. First, different versions of a New Keynesian model with capital accumulation are simulated and their dynamic properties are discussed. While most of the canonical Keynesian models cannot replicate high autocorrelation levels among the main economic variables, the simulation results of this paper show a model with capital accumulation can generate substantial persistencies in major economic variables. The stock nature of capital adds persistency to the dynamics of all other variables in a model. In the simulated versions of the model the autocorrelation coefficients for consumption and capital are more than 0.9, and the autocorrelations of inflation and nominal interest rate are also very high. Also, interest rate and output autocorrelation coefficients are higher in the model with passive as opposed to active monetary policy due to the fact that passive monetary policy is unable to adjust the interest rate sufficiently to phase out shock propagations.

Simulated dynamics show that preferences (demand) shocks are the main drivers of volatility in the version of the model with passive monetary policy, explaining more than 90 percent of volatility in endogenous variables. In contrast, marginal cost (supply) shocks explain more than 50 percent of variance in the version with active monetary policy. Also, the versions with passive monetary policy demonstrate substantially higher interest rate and inflation volatility than the version with active monetary policy, which can be explained by the existence of indeterminate equilibria in the version with passive monetary policy.

Second, different versions of the model with capital accumulation were fitted to the quarterly postwar U.S. data on output, inflation, nominal interest rates, consumption, and capital from 1960:I to 2008:I. The versions were estimated separately for the pre-Volcker and post-1982 periods assuming, a priori, passive monetary policy, consistent with indeterminacy during the pre-Volcker period, and active monetary policy, consistent with determinacy during the post-1982 period.

For the pre-Volcker period the estimates of the response of monetary policy to inflation are almost twice lower than in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) and in Clarida, Gali and Gertler (2000). The main argument for this lower response is that in models with capital accumulation there is an additional channel of monetary policy influence on the economy through the real interest rate in the production sector. For the pre-Volcker period the estimates of the response of monetary policy to inflation are 0.385 for the current-looking and 0.644 for the forward-looking monetary policy rules. For the post-1982 period, these estimates are about 1.1 for various model specifications.

The estimated response of the monetary policy rule to output is about 0.5 for the pre-Volcker and post-1982 (1982:IV to 1997:IV) periods in the case of the current-looking monetary policy rule. However, it is substantially higher for the 1982:IV to 2008:I period, when the pre-crisis years were included in the sample. Also, it was found that the steady-state inflation and real interest rate values are very close to those in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) for the pre-Volcker period, while the steady inflation rate is substantially lower and the real interest rate is a marginally lower than in Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) for the post-1982 period depending on model specifications.

A striking finding of the paper is that risk aversion increased substantially over time in the U.S. from about 0.4 for the pre-Volcker period to about 2.5 for the post-1982 period. This differs from the findings of Lubik and Schorfheide (2004), who found that households increased the degree of risk aversion between the pre-Volcker and post-1982 periods only slightly. This result arises from the fact that the investment activity allows us to break the direct connection between interest rate and consumption dynamics in the Euler equation due to the no-arbitrage condition between bonds and real sector returns. This explains the consumption dynamic not only in terms of interest rate changes but in terms of preferences as well. The decrease in the levels of elasticity of intertemporal substitution of consumption can be connected with the development of financial markets and loosening of borrowing constraints in the U.S. over time.

Finally, in contrast to Lubik and Schorfheide (2004), it was found that the version of the model with indeterminacy dominates the determinate version for all sample periods. Comparing the version with indeterminacy and determinacy with current- and forward-looking monetary policy rules, the version with indeterminacy and forward-looking monetary policy rule dominates all other versions.

Appendix 1. Firm’s problem.

The first order conditions for the cost minimization problem are:

rt=ztfk(Kt,Lt)wt=ztfL(Kt,Lt)

where zt is the marginal cost of production.

Proof:

min: wtL + rtKt

s.t.: f(K,L)=f¯

£=wtL+rtKtλ(f(K,L)f¯)£=wtL+rtKtλ(f(K,L)f¯)

FOC:

wt=λtfL(Kt,Lt)rt=λtfK(Kt,Lt)

Dual problem:

£=c(f(K,L))λ(f(Kt,Lt)f¯)

FOC:

c(f(Kt,Lt))=λt=zt

Combining:

rt=ztfK(Kt,Lt)wt=ztfL(Kt,Lt)

Appendix 2. Log-linearization of the model.

Consumption Euler equation

Uc(t)Pt=βRt(Uc(t+1)Pt+1)

as UC (t) = C

CtσEtCt+1σ=βRt(PtPt+1)

In the log-linearized form:

(EtC^t+1C^t)=1σ[R^tEtπ^t+1]C^t=EtC^t+11σ[R^tEtπ^t+1]

Fisher equation

From

Uc(t)=β{Uc(t+1)[rt+1+(1δ)]}Uc(t)Pt=βRt(Uc(t+1)Pt+1)

we have

Uc(t)Uc(t+1)=βRt(PtPt+1)=β[rt+1+(1δ)]

asrt+1=zt+1αYt+1Kt+1

Rt(PtPt+1)=rt+1+(1δ)

As in the steady state: rss=1β1+δ, the log-linearized form is:

R^tEtπ^t+1=1β1+δ1β1+δ+(1δ)(Etz^t+1+EtY^t+1K^t+1)=[1+β(1δ)]Etz^t+1+EtY^t+1K^t+1R^tEtπ^t+1=[1β(1δ)](Etz^t+1+EtY^t+1K^t+1)

Consumption-labor condition

From UcUL=1w

As U linear in L:

Uc=1wCtσ=zt(1α)YtL1

In the log-linearized form:

σC^t=z^t+(Y^tL^t)C^t=1σz^t+1σα1α(K^tY^t)

Capital accumulation equation

Kt+1=(1δ)Kt+ItK^t+1=(1δ)KssKssK^t+IssKssI^tIssKss=δK^t+1=(1δ)K^t+δI^t

Output

Y=C+IY^t=scC^t+(1sc)I^t

where sc=CssYss is the share of consumption in output

New-Keynesian Phillips curve

From the Calvo model:

π^t=βEtπ^t+1+λz^t

Monetary policy rule

R^t=ρRR^t1+(1ρR)(ψπEtπ^t+k+ψYY^t)+ɛR,t

Model

Ct^=EtC^t+11σ[R^tEtπ^t+1]R^tEtπ^t+1=[1β(1δ)](Etz^t+1+EtY^t+1K^t+1)C^t=1σz^t+1σα1α(K^tY^t)K^t+1=(1δ)K^t+δItY^t=sCC^t+sII^tπ^t=βEtπ^t+1+λz^tR^t=φRR^t1+(1φR)(φπEtπ^t+j+φYEtY^t+j)

substituting z^t andI^t

from (3) z^t=σC^tα1α(K^tY^t)

and (5) (Y^tscC^t)/sI=I^t

Ct^=EtC^t+11σ[R^tEtπ^t+1]R^tEtπ^t+1=[1β(1δ)](σEt(C^t+1)11α[EtY^t+1EtK^t+1])K^t+1=(1δ)K^t+δsI(Y^t(1sI)C^t)π^t=βEtπ^t+1+λ(σC^tα1α(K^tY^t))R^t=ρRR^t1+(1ρR)(φπEtπ^t+k+φYEtY^t+j)+ɛR,t

Appendix 3. Theoretical IRFs, model with indeterminacy.

A01ufig01

Theoretical IRFs to the interest rate shock.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2012, 083; 10.5089/9781475502350.001.A001

A01ufig02

Theoretical IRFs to the preference shock.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2012, 083; 10.5089/9781475502350.001.A001

A01ufig03

Theoretical IRFs to the marginal cost shock.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2012, 083; 10.5089/9781475502350.001.A001

Appendix 4. Theoretical IRFs, model with determinacy.

A01ufig04

Theoretical IRFs to the interest rate shock.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2012, 083; 10.5089/9781475502350.001.A001

A01ufig05

Theoretical IRFs to the preference shock.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2012, 083; 10.5089/9781475502350.001.A001

A01ufig06

Theoretical IRFs to the marginal cost shock.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2012, 083; 10.5089/9781475502350.001.A001

Appendix 5. Empirical correlation matrices.

article image

Appendix 6. Empirical autocorrelations.

article image

References

  • An, Sungbae, and Frank Schorfheide (2007). Bayesian Analysis of DSGE Models. Econometric Reviews, Taylor and Francis Journals Vol. 26 (2-4), pp. 113172.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beyer, Andreas, and Roger E. A. Farmer (2007). Testing for Indeterminacy: An Application to U.S. Monetary Policy: Comment. American Economic Review 97 (1), pp.524529.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A. (1983). Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12, pp.383398.

  • Carlstrom, Charles T. and Timothy S. Fuerst (2005). Investment and interest rate policy: a discretetime analysis. Journal of Economic Theory 123, pp. 420.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chari, V.V., P. Kehoe, E. McGrattan (2000). Sticky price models of the business cycle: can the contract multiplier solve the persistence problem? Econometrica 68, pp.11511181.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Christiano Lawrence J. and Christopher J. Gust (1999). Taylor Rules in a Limited Participation Model. NBER Working Paper 7017.

  • Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali and Mark Gertler (1999). The science of monetary policy: a new Keynesian perspective.Journal of Economic Literature Vol.XXXVII, pp.16611707.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali and Mark Gertler (2000). Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: evidence and some theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115, pp.147180.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dixit, Avinash K. and Joseph E. Stiglitz (1977). Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review 67, pp.297308.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dupor, Bill (2001). Investment and interest rate policy. Journal of Economic Theory 98, pp.81113.

  • Farmer, Roger E.A. & Waggoner, Daniel F. & Zha, Tao (2009). Understanding Markov-switching rational expectations models. Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, Vol. 144 (5), pp.18491867.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fernandez-Villaverde, J., Rubio-Ramirez, J.F. (2004). Comparing dynamic equilibrium economies to data: a Bayesian approach. Journal of Econometrics 123, pp.153187.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fuhrer, J.C. and G. Moore (1995). Inflation persistence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, pp.127160.

  • Gali, Jordi and Mark Gertler (1998). Inflation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (2), pp.195222.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Huang, Kevin X.D. and Qinglai Meng (2007). Capital and macroeconomic instability in a discretetime model with forward-looking interest rate rules. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31, pp.28022826.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Huang, Kevin X.D., Qinglai Meng and Jianpo Xue (2009). Is forward-looking inflation targeting destabilizing? The role of policy’s response to current output under endogenous investment. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 33 (2), pp.409430.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kerr, William R. and Robert G. King (1996). Limits on interest rate rules in the IS-LM model. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kurozumi, Takushi (2006). Determinacy and expectational stability of equilibrium in a monetary sticky-price model with Taylor rules. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, pp.827846.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kurozumi, Takushi and Willem Van Zandweghe (2008). Investment, interest rate policy, and equilibrium stability. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32 (5), pp.14891516.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lubik, Thomas A. and Frank Schorfheide (2004). Testing for indeterminacy: An application to U.S. monetary policy, American Economic Review 94 (1), pp.190219.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mavroeidis, Sophocles (2010). Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Some New Evidence. American Economic Review 100 (1), pp.491503.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rotemberg, Julio J. and Michael Woodford (1998). An Optimization-Based Econometric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy: Expanded Version. NBER Technical Working Paper No. 233.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rubio-Ramirez, J.F. and Pau Rabanal (2005). Comparing New Keynesian Models of the Business Cycle: A Bayesian Approach. Journal of Monetary Economics 52, pp.11521166.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schorfheide, F. (2005). Learning and Monetary Policy Shifts. Review of Economic Dynamics 8 (2), pp.392419.

  • Sims, Christopher A. and Tao Zha (2006). Were There Regime Switches in U.S. Monetary Policy? American Economic Review 96 (1), pp.5481.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Smets, Frank and Raf Wouters (2003). An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area. Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (5), pp. 112375.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Smets, Frank and Rafael Wouters (2007). Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach. American Economic Review 97 (3), pp.586606.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sosunov, Kirill and Vadim Khramov (2008). Monetary policy rules and indeterminacy. MPRA Paper 11996, University Library of Munich, Germany.

    • Search Google Scholar