The Impact of the Global Financial Crisison Microfinance and Policy Implications
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: gdibella@imf.org

The global financial crisis affected microfinance institutions (MFIs) as lending growth was constrained by scarcer borrowing opportunities, while the economic slowdown negatively impacted asset quality and profitability. It also brought to the fore the relatively high interest rates that MFIs charge to their (low-income) customers. This paper revisits the issue of systemic risk of MFIs, and finds that contrary to the evidence before the crisis, MFI performance is correlated not only to domestic economic conditions but also to changes in international capital markets. It also presents an empirical analysis of lending rates with the purpose of informing policy decisions, and finds that loan sizes, productivity, and MFI age contribute to explain differences in lending rate levels. This suggest that regulation (and policies) promoting MFI competition, and innovation in lending technologies have a better chance to result in decreased lending rates.

Abstract

The global financial crisis affected microfinance institutions (MFIs) as lending growth was constrained by scarcer borrowing opportunities, while the economic slowdown negatively impacted asset quality and profitability. It also brought to the fore the relatively high interest rates that MFIs charge to their (low-income) customers. This paper revisits the issue of systemic risk of MFIs, and finds that contrary to the evidence before the crisis, MFI performance is correlated not only to domestic economic conditions but also to changes in international capital markets. It also presents an empirical analysis of lending rates with the purpose of informing policy decisions, and finds that loan sizes, productivity, and MFI age contribute to explain differences in lending rate levels. This suggest that regulation (and policies) promoting MFI competition, and innovation in lending technologies have a better chance to result in decreased lending rates.

I. Introduction1

Microfinance institutions (MFIs) provide financial services to low-income, economically active, borrowers who seek relatively small amounts to finance their businesses, manage emergencies, acquire assets, or smooth consumption (CGAP 2002). These borrowers usually lack credit histories, collateral, or both, and thus, do not have access to financing from mainstream commercial banks (Banerjee and Duflo, 2007). For this reason, MFIs are seen as playing a role in the creation of economic opportunity, and in poverty alleviation. Recognizing the importance that a number of donors had placed on microfinance as a tool to achieve the millennium development goals (MDGs), the United Nations declared 2005 as the “year of micro-credit”. (Morduch, 1999; United Nations, 2006).

MFIs are a heterogenous group that includes different types of institutions (e.g., banks, rural banks, non-bank financial institutions –NBFIs-, non-government organizations –NGOs-, credit unions, cooperatives), legal status (some are regulated and other unregulated), and purpose (including for profit and non profit institutions). MFIs lending portfolios vary greatly depending on the type of institution: banks and NBFIs usually concentrate on larger clients (including small enterprises), while loan sizes per client in cooperatives and NGOs are smaller (in particular as the latter are more likely to lend to groups). That said, lending portfolios of cooperatives and NGOs also differ, as the former are mostly member-based institutions that favor consumption smoothing to a larger extent than other microfinance providers.

Location contributes to heterogeneity, as MFIs adapt to different national regulations, and operate in countries with diverse access to international capital markets. Additionally, MFIs include both mature and young institutions, as the boom observed in this industry for the most part of the last two decades implied that a large number of new institutions entered into a market in which a number of mature institutions had operated for some time, and thus had time to build a reputation, and to “learn by doing”.

From a macroeconomic perspective, this boom has meant that for some countries, microcredit has come to represent a significant portion of both gross domestic product (GDP) and of total credit to the private sector (Figure 1). For these countries, that include low-income countries (LICs) (e.g., Bolivia, Cambodia, Kenya, Mongolia Nicaragua, Tanzania, Vietnam), transition economies (e.g. Armenia, Bosnia & Herzegovina, Kyrgyz Republic, Tajikistan) and emerging economies (e.g. Peru), abrupt changes in microcredit could have macroeconomic implications, as a large number of borrowers (usually larger than those served by banks) are either incorporated to or excluded from credit markets.2 Conversely, the increase in the size of MFIs balance sheets and a lower reliance on traditional financing sources (like aid agencies and non-profit entities) have increased the exposure of MFIs to changes in domestic and international economic conditions.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Microcredit in Selected Countries

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2011, 175; 10.5089/9781462313303.001.A001

Note: Values correspond to the average for 2008-09.Source: International Financial Statistics (IFS), Microfinance Information Exchange (MIX) and author’s calculations

Until the global financial crisis that erupted in late 2007, available data suggested at most a weak relationship between usual performance indicators in the microfinance industry and international capital market developments, and even domestic macroeconomic conditions (Krauss and Walter, 2006, 2009; Gonzalez, 2007; Ahlin, Lin and Maio, 2010). This was presented as an attractive feature of the microfinance sector as an asset class for fund managers interested in risk diversification. The lack of strong correlation was attributed to, among other things, to the apparent insulation of MFI clients to developments in formal domestic and international markets, and the lower financial leverage of MFIs in comparison with other types of financial institutions. However, these results were based on samples that, though rich from a cross section perspective, comprised a relatively short period of time. In this regard, the period analyzed largely coincided with a period of expansion of the world economy (except for the mild recession of 2001), and most importantly, with what seems to represent a period of “diffusion” of the microfinance industry (Figure 2).3 Both facts probably contributed to the apparent weak relationship between developments in microcredit and international capital markets (which are volatile, even during expansions) and domestic macroeconomic conditions (as most emerging and LICs were growing at relatively high rates during this period).

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Assets of the median MFI

(in US$ million)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2011, 175; 10.5089/9781462313303.001.A001

Source: Microfinance Information Exchange (MIX) and author’s calculations.

The global financial crisis changed all this. The boom growth rates observed in microcredit across the globe decreased strongly as MFI’s balance sheets were shocked both on the liability side, as fund providers of all types were affected by the abrupt decrease in liquidity, and on the asset side, as loan delinquency and write offs began to increase together with the deterioration of domestic macroeconomic conditions (Figure 3).

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Lending Growth

(in percent; over values in US$)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2011, 175; 10.5089/9781462313303.001.A001

Source: Microfinance Information Exchange and author’s calculations.

Additionally, as the financial crisis began to take its toll, the relatively high rates charged by MFIs (as well as their lack of transparency), gained the spotlight. This meant that in some countries, MFI deterioration was compounded by political initiatives aiming at introducing ceilings to interest rates or to force blanket restructurings of debts. The relatively high rates (even when justified by industry fundamentals) were difficult to defend in the context of uninformed public discussion, or when the issue was exploited for political advantage.

This paper revisits the issue of microfinance systemic risk, by analyzing the performance of a large sample of top MFIs against domestic economic conditions and international capital markets. This allows assessing whether previous results about the lack of a strong relationship between microfinance and general economic conditions are robust to the incorporation of data corresponding to the global financial crisis. The analysis is also carried over for alternative MFI groupings, in order to establish whether relative systemic risk is stronger (or weaker) depending on location, legal status, institution type, purpose, and age.

The empirical findings suggest that correlations between microfinance’s performance and both domestic and international economic conditions are stronger than previously found. In particular, MFIs in Central America and the Caribbean (including Mexico), Eastern Europe, and the Middle East and Central Asia appear most sensitive to changes in the domestic and international economic environment, while from an institutional perspective, banks and non-bank financial institutions show the closest links. These results suggest that the increasing attention that MFIs have given to “sustainablity”, a diversification in their funding structure towards more commercial sources, some commecialization of portfolios, and an increase in their scale (among other factors), have made them more similar to financial institutions with more traditional lending portfolios.

In addition, this paper presents an empirical analysis of the factors behind MFI lending rates and interest rate spreads. A better understanding of lending rate fundamentals is essential for informing policy decisions, and reducing the bias in public discussions (CGAP 2009). This could result in better regulation, and thus in an improvement in MFIs’ sustainability prospects. With this in mind, the paper discusses the MFIs’ cost structure, and estimates models of the lending rate and absolute spread in order to identify their fundamentals. As before, regressions are estimated for different MFI groupings, in order to assess whether the factors explaining interest rates are consistent (or not), regardless of location, institution type, legal status, purpose or age.

In this regard, the results of the empirical analysis suggest that the average loan size (as a proxy for administrative costs), and a number of variables tracking MFI productivity and efficiency (including the ratio of borrowers per staff, and the operational cost per staff), all have the expected signs (and are, in most cases, statistically significant), regardless of MFIs characteristics. The empirical evidence also suggest, in line with theory, that more mature MFIs charge lower lending rates. Other variables tracking assset quality and MFI funding structure, also appear to matter. There is no strong evidence, however, linking lending rates (spreads) with domestic economic conditions. These results suggest that if the aim of regulation is to reduce lending rates, it would likely produce better outcomes if it creates an enabling environment for MFIs to develop, and concentrates in promoting MFI competition, and innovation in lending technologies.

The paper is organized as follows. Section II provides a stylized description of global trends in microfinance before and after the global financial crisis of 2007-08. Section III describes the data and MFI groupings that are used in the paper. Section IV evaluates the empirical evidence to assess whether the absolute systemic risk of microfinance has increased during the last few years, and whether there are differences in the relative systemic risk of alternative MFI groupings. In turn, section V analyzes the empirical evidence on lending rates and spreads with a view of identifying their determinants for alternative MFI groupings. Section VI discusses the findings and concludes.

II. Global Trends in Microfinance 1998-2009

Overall Trends

Before the crisis (1998-2006), the median MFI’s performance was characterized by strong growth, good asset quality and profitability, regardless of region, institution type, or legal status (Table 1 and Figures 3 to 5). From an investor’s point of view, the period appears to correspond to one of diffusion of a new asset class, as lending to MFIs expanded strongly, (though from a low base), and new products and financing institutions specialized in lending to MFIs appeared.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Portfolio at Risk (PAR-30)

(in percent of Loans)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2011, 175; 10.5089/9781462313303.001.A001

Source: Microfinance Information Exchange and author’s calculations.Note: Trends for Write-off ratios are broadly similar.
Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Return on Equity (ROE)

(in percent)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2011, 175; 10.5089/9781462313303.001.A001

Source: Microfinance Information Exchange and author’s calculations.Note: Trends for Return-on-Assets (ROA) are broadly similar.
Table 1.

MFIs Performance Indicators, 1998-2009.

article image
Note:Shaded cells indicate a better performance than that for the median global MFI

Accordingly assets of the median MFI grew at an annual rate of 36 percent, and lending at a rate of almost 40 percent; in turn, borrowing increased at a median annual rate in excess of 50 percent, suggesting a decrease in capital-asset ratios as MFIs expanded. The profitability of the median MFI was high, with return on equity (ROE) close to 10 percent, and asset quality characterized by relatively low portfolio at risk (PAR-30) and write off ratios (3 and of 1 percent of total portfolio respectively).

From a regional perspective the median MFI in Eastern Europe (EUR) and in the Middle East and Central Asia (MCE) regions grew faster and had better asset quality ratios than those in other regions, though profitability was largest for the median MFI of Central America and the Caribbean (CAC) and of South America (SAC). From an institutional perspective, banks outperformed other types of institutions in terms of strength of expansion, asset quality and profitability, with NBFIs following banks. In turn, regulated institutions outperformed non-regulated MFIs in the strength of their expansion, in asset quality and profitability. Interestingly, the expansion of the microfinance industry appeared to be mostly untouched by the recession of 2001; this could be seen by a fairly consistent performance across the period for all regions, types of institutions and legal status (with, maybe, the exception of the median MFI for the CAC region which appeared to have been affected by the 2001 crisis).

In spite of the fact that overall performance of the median MFI was still characterized, on average, by continuing expansion during and after the global crisis (2007-2009), the expansion occurred at significantly lower (and decreasing throughout the period) rates when compared with those observed during 1998-2006. Assets of the median MFI increased at about 22 percent per year and lending by 24 percent, while borrowings grew by 23 percent, i.e. 28 percentage points lower than the rate observed during 1998-2006. Though profitability (measured by ROE) of the median MFI appeared only slightly lower than that observed during 1998-2006, the mean ROE was about 5 percentage points lower. Asset quality deteriorated, with both PAR-30 and write offs ratios showing increases. The median rates for the period mask, however, a strongly deteriorating situation as the effects from the crisis sunk in. Indeed, while performance during 2007 was broadly similar to that observed during the previous years, performance deteriorated sharply during 2008-2009.4

From a regional perspective, the impact of the crisis was felt most strongly in CAC and EUR, as these regions not only showed lower expansion rates, worse asset quality ratios and profitability indicators than other regions, but also the worse changes in performance with respect to the previous period; indeed, the median MFI for both regions showed negative rates of growth for lending and borrowing in 2009, coupled with sharp deteriorations in asset quality and profitability ratios when compared to other regions. In contrast, the median MFIs in the SAC and Asian-Pacific (ASP) regions appeared to have weathered the crisis better (though there was some deterioration in the ASP region during 2010, in particular in India).5 From an institutional perspective, banks and NBFIs performed better than other types of institutions, though the observed changes in asset quality and profitability for these types of institutions suggest a deterioration that was worse than that observed for the median MFI. Regulated institutions also performed better than the median unregulated MFI during the period.

A number of analyses by industry specialists indicate that in addition to the effects of the global financial crisis, the deterioration in MFIs’ performance responded to credit oversupply in some markets. In this regard, the marginal increases in lending during 2006-2007 were of lower quality, and for larger sized loans, so when the crisis hit, asset quality and profitability deteriorated on impact and also, through the increase in the operational costs needed to control delinquency. In the liability side, MFIs faced lower financing opportunities and deteriorated financing terms, including higher borrowing rates and shorter maturities (Multilateral Development Fund, 2010; CGAP, 2010; MIX, 2010a).

Lending rate trends

A look at the data shows that the lending rate charged by the median MFI was about 36 percent during 1998-2006, and decreased to 32 percent during 2007-2009 (Table 2 and Figure 6). Interest rate spreads also decreased, from about 31 percent to 27 percent. Median loan sizes almost doubled (increasing from about US$ 360 to US$ 630 per borrower). Productivity of the median MFI (as measured by the borrowers per staff ratio) increased slightly (from about 115 to 123) between periods, while operational costs per staff (in US$) increased by more than 30 percent. In turn, MFI expansion was consistent with a reduction in capital-asset ratios from about 34 percent to 22 percent.

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Lending Rate

(in percent; over values in US$)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2011, 175; 10.5089/9781462313303.001.A001

Source: Microfinance Information Exchange and author’s calculations
Table 2.

MFIs Lending Rate Fundamentals, 1998-2009.

article image
Note:Shaded cells indicate a better performance than that for the median global MFI. For loan sizes, shaded cells indicate groupings that present values larger than the global median.

Although these trends are broadly shared across regions, institution types and legal status, there are some differences that deserve to be highlighted. Interest rates and spreads were largest in CAC, with differences in excess of 6 percentage points with respect to the SAC region, which showed the second largest values; in turn, interest rates and spreads were lowest in EUR. There is a large dispersion in loan sizes among different MFI groupings. From a regional perspective loan sizes are lowest for MFIs in sub-Saharan Africa (AFR) and ASP, and largest for EUR; from an institutional perspective, they are lowest for NGOs and largest for banks, what in turn means that loan sizes for regulated institutions are higher than for unregulated MFIs. As expected, MFIs with lower loan sizes have the largest borrowers per staff ratios, though MFIs in the SAC region show both loan sizes that are larger than for the median MFI and a larger ratio of borrowers per staff. Measures of cost per staff also vary significantly; although from a regional perspective these differences also respond to differing cost of living, from an institutional perspective banks have the largest costs and NGOs the lowest; from a legal status perspective, unregulated MFIs have lower costs per staff than regulated ones. Looking at capital-asset ratios, it is possible to conclude that NGOs and unregulated institutions expanded more strongly during the last decade, as well as MFIs in the MCE, EUR, and CAC regions.

III. Data

All MFI data was obtained from the “Microfinance Information Exchange (MIX)” database (available online).6 This dataset covers the period 1995-2009 and includes information for 1774 MFIs in 107 countries. This dataset has been used in a number of studies including Gonzalez (2007), Kraus and Walter (2009) and various reports by industry analysts and the Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (CGAP). The MIX website points out that participation in this sample is voluntary, though participants need to provide supporting documentation (external audits, financial statements, annual reports, etc.) for the figures reported. Reporting serves the purpose of increasing MFI exposure, and implies that participating institutions have some form of information systems in place. In spite of problems of data comparability and quality (as reporting and accounting standards vary in each country and for MFIs of different legal status), Krauss and Walter (2009) conclude that the database represents the best available source of information for top MFIs.7

Sample. In order to ensure some minimum quality of the dataset, the paper uses a sample of 353 MFIs (out of the 1774) that report at least 7 years of data during the period 1998-2009; that also report three years of consecutive data for the period 2007-09 (as the paper is interested in analyzing the effect of the global crisis); and, that are included in the largest top 75 percent in terms of asset size, (as including smaller MFIs, which are subject to larger volatility, would potentially bring into the sample a relatively large number of outliers). These criteria imply that the sample will have entrants during the period but not exits, so there will be no survivorship bias. However, results could be biased by a different performance of younger (entrants) institutions during the period. The paper analyzes the performance of MFIs for different age groups to assess this possible bias.

MFI Groupings. The sample is diverse enough to allow analyzing the behavior of a number of different MFI groupings (Table 3). In this regard, MFIs are grouped by region (Sub-Saharan Africa –AFR-, Asia-Pacific –ASP-, Central America and the Caribbean -including Mexico, CAC-, Eastern Europe –EUR-, Middle East and Central Asia –MCE-, and South America –SAC-), institution type (banks, credit unions and cooperatives –CUCs-, non bank financial institutions –NBFIs-, non government organizations –NGOs-, and rural banks), legal status (regulated and non-regulated), purpose (for-profit and non-profit), and age (young and mature). Regarding the latter, mature institutions are defined as those that by 2009 had been in operation for 8 years or more.8

Table 3.

Selected MFI Sample

article image
NoteMFIs do not add up to 353 as the institution type of the remaining MFI (in the Middle East and Central Asia region) was labeled as “other”. MFIs by age do not add up to 353 as there are 3 MFIs for which this variable was unavailable.

Variables of MFI performance. Asset and lending growth are expressed in 2005 real annual (end of period) percentage terms; return on equity (ROE) is expressed in annual percentage terms over values in US$ terms; the portfolio at Risk (PAR-30) ratio denotes the percentage of loans that have been in arrears for the past 30 days, while the write-off ratio is calculated as percentage of lending.

Variables of global and domestic market risk. Following Krauss and Walter (2009), domestic economic conditions are represented by real GDP growth, which is expressed in percent per year for each country in the sample. In turn, global market conditions are represented by the annual average percentage change of three indices, the S&P Index, the Morgan Stanley Capital International (MSCI) World Index, and the MSCI Emerging Markets Index. The underlying assets that the three indices track are expressed in US$ terms.

Variables for lending rate (and spread) determination. Lending rates are calculated as total financial income divided by net lending portfolio (i.e., excluding non-performing loans), and are expressed in percent per year in US$ terms. Funding costs are calculated as total financial costs divided by total assets, and are also expressed in percent per year in US$ terms.9 The (absolute) spread is defined as the difference between lending and borrowing rates.10 The average loan size is calculated as total lending portfolio (in US$ terms) divided by the number of MFI borrowers. The ratio of borrowers per staff denotes the number of MFI active borrowers divided by the number of total staff. Operational cost per staff is calculated as total operational cost per year (in US$ terms) divided by the number of MFI staff. The capital-asset ratio (expressed in percent) denotes net-worth divided by total assets, both in US$ terms. Age is a qualitative variable; institutions that are less than 5 years old at any given year (“young”), were assigned a value of zero; institutions between 5 and 8 years old at any given year (“middle-aged”), were assigned a value of one; and institutions that were older than 8 years old at any given year (“mature”), were assigned a value of two.

Robustness of results. In order to have a measure of the robustness of the results reported, all regressions were also performed for alternative cross sections and time periods. Alternative cross-sections include all MFIs (when possible) and a sample that adds the lowest quartile (by asset size) to the main sample used (a sample of 390 MFIs). In addition, two alternative time periods were considered (1995-2009 and 2002-2009). Robustness checks were also performed by using the main cross-section sample for two alternative time periods (1995-2009, and 2002-2009). In turn, lending rate and spread regressions for 2002-2009 were also estimated with an alternative definition of borrowing rate (total financial cost divided by total borrowings, expressed in percent per year in US$ terms).

IV. An Empirical Analysis of Microfinance Systemic Risk

Krauss and Walter (2006) conducted the first empirical analysis of panel data covering large numbers of MFIs with the purpose of assessing the systemic risk of microfinance.11 Using emerging market commercial banks as a benchmark, they found low correlations between MFI performance and international capital markets, mainly due to low asset exposure. Their findings also suggest low correlation with domestic GDP due to lower income and profitability exposure. Gonzalez (2007) examined 639 MFIs in 88 countries during the period 1999-2005 using MIX data. After controlling for MFI and country characteristics, he found no evidence suggesting a strong (in magnitude) and statistically significant relationship between changes in gross national income per capita and several indicators of asset quality (portfolio at risk –PAR-30-, loan loss rate and the write-off ratio). He concluded that MFI portfolios have high resilience to domestic economic shocks.

In turn, Krauss and Walter (2009) further investigated the systemic risk of microfinance activity by regressing a number of key financial variables (related to profitability, asset value, and asset quality) against the S&P 500, MSCI Global and MSCI Emerging Markets indices (as proxies of global market risk) as well as against domestic GDP (as proxy for domestic market risk). For that purpose they used MIX data for 325 MFIs for the period 1998-2006, using emerging market commercial banks and emerging market institutions as benchmarks. They found that MFIs display no statistically significant relationship with global market movements, though they are not detached from their respective domestic economies. They also enumerated possible reasons that may explain the lack of correlation with global markets. In particular, they argued that the difference observed in market risk between MFIs and other emerging market financial institutions was based on a generally nonpublic ownership structure that reduced their dependence on capital markets, lower national and international exposure of MFI clients, and lower operational and financial leverage. With data through 2006, they concluded that the correlation with global markets may increase as, for instance, the difference in financial leverage between MFIs and other financial institutions diminished.

This paper follows Krauss and Walter (2009) methodology to analyze once more the systemic risk of microfinance when the period under consideration is extended so as to include the global financial crisis. The objective is to analyze the absolute systemic risk of MFIs and identify whether the relative risk of specific MFI grouping is higher (or lower) than for the general case, when a larger cross section of MFIs is considered and for a longer period of time (1998-2009). With that in mind, a number of key variables linked with MFI performance (asset and lending real annual growth in 2005 terms, loan portfolio at risk -PAR-30-, and return on equity –ROE-), are regressed against variables that track international capital markets and domestic economic conditions. The reason behind choosing a number of indicators is that calculating the historical market beta is not possible for the MFI industry.12 The working assumption is that changes in these variables must be associated with changes in the market value of these institutions.

In this regard, Table 4 shows the results of individual OLS panel regressions for the whole sample (All MFIs) and alternative MFI groupings. In particular, a horizontal look at Table 4 allows to see whether the performance of a specific sub-group within each MFI grouping is correlated to domestic and international conditions with the expected sign (and whether the coefficient is statistically significant at usual confidence levels); looking at the table vertically allows to see whether a specific variable linked to domestic conditions (GDP growth) or international market conditions (S&P, MSCI World, and MSCI Emerging Markets indices) are associated with the performance of different MFI groupings with the expected sign, and whether those coefficients are significant at usual confidence levels.13 In turn, Table 5 shows the results of OLS panel regressions using the whole sample and an interaction term of a dummy variable for different groupings and the explanatory variable. The significance level of the interaction term provides a test for differences between institutions in different regions, institution types, legal status, purpose, and age.14

Table 4.

Performance Regressions (Selected Sample, 1998-2009)

article image
NotesThe first number represents the regression coefficient; R2 =R-squared value. Shaded cells represent coefficients with both the expected sign and that are statistically significant.* 99% level of confidence.** 95% level of confidence.*** 90% level of confidence
Table 5.

Performance Regressions (Selected Sample, 1998-2009)

article image
NotesThe first number represents the regression coefficient; R2 =R-squared value. Shaded cells represent instances in which differences between regression coefficients is statistically significant.* 99% level of confidence.** 95% level of confidence.*** 90% level of confidence

All MFIs. Regressions for the whole sample indicate a relatively strong association between MFI performance and indicators of domestic economic conditions and international capital markets. In this regard, asset growth (in real terms) show positive and statistically significant coefficients when regressed against domestic GDP growth, world, US and emerging capital markets conditions. Asset quality regressions show negative and statistically significant coefficients for both domestic GDP growth and all (but one) capital market performance measures. Lending growth (in real terms) and profitability show positive (as expected) and statistically significant associations against domestic economic conditions, though in the case of capital markets, the association is statistically significant only in the case of the MSCI emerging markets index.

Regional Groupings. Performance of MFIs in the CAC, EUR and MCE regions show the most consistent associations with both domestic and international markets. Coefficients are all positive and statistically significant for regressions linking asset growth (in constant terms) with GDP and with US and international capital markets. They are also positive and statisically significant in all cases for lending growth regressions for the CAC and MCE regions. In turn, all coefficients are negative (as expected) and all (but one) are statistically significant for asset quality regressions in the cases of CAC and EUR regions. There is also some evidence of links between MFI performance and domestic economic conditions and international markets in the ASP and SAC regions, in particular for asset and lending growth as well as asset quality (in the ASP region), and profitability (in the SAC region). MFIs in AFR show the weakest links with general economic conditions, with some evidence of lending growth and asset quality being associated with domestic economic conditions. In turn, Table 5 shows highly significant differences for MFIs in CAC, EUR and MCE with respect to other regions as to how responsive asset growth and asset quality are to domestic economic conditions and international capital markets. Conversely, there are highly significant (but negative) differences for MFIs in SAC and ASP with respect to the strength with which asset and lending growth are associated with domestic economic conditions and international capital markets in comparison to other regions. In turn, there is evidence that asset quality in CAC is significantly more responsive to domestic and international market conditions than that for other regions (with some evidence pointing that MFIs in EUR are more responsive to changes in international capital markets). In turn, there is evidence that asset quality of MFIs in AFR and SAC are less responsive to changes in international capital markets, and MFIs in MCE are less responsive to changes in domestic economic conditions.

Institutional Groupings. Banks and NBFIs performance show the most consistent links with domestic economic conditions and those of US and international markets. In this connection, the coefficients of asset growth regressions for both banks and NBFIs are all positive and statistically significant, though lending growth regressions show positive and statistically significant coefficients only against domestic economic conditions and the MSCI emerging markets index. Asset quality regressions for banks and NBFIs all show the expected negative sign and are statistically significant against domestic economic conditions, while NGOs regressions show the expected negative sign in all cases, though they are statistically significant only against international market conditions. Profitability regressions show the expected positive sign and are all statistically significantly in the case of banks, with evidence that NBFIs profitability is linked to domestic economic conditions. There is no strong empirical evidence of links between MFI performance and domestic and international capital market conditions for CUCs and rural banks. Among the reasons that explain this result are that their funding is mostly domestic (and thus links between their funding and international markets is weaker), and that their lending is mostly for consumption smoothing. Table 5 confirms these results as it shows highly significant and positive differences in coefficients for asset growth in the case of banks and NBFIs with respect to other institution types. There is some evidence that asset growth for NGOs is significantly less responsive to domestic economic conditions than for other types of institutions.

Legal Status. Non regulated MFIs show the most consistent associations with domestic and international economic conditions. In this regard, profitability and asset quality regressions show the expected signs and are statistically significant in all cases, while asset and lending growth, show statistically significant coefficients against indicators of international market conditions. In turn, asset and lending growth, as well as asset quality regressions for regulated MFIs show coefficients of expected signs that are statistically significant in all cases (but two). However, profitability regressions for regulated MFIs show positive coefficients that are not statistically significant, except for that corresponsing to the MSCI emerging markets index. In turn, Table 5 shows some evidence that asset and lending growth for regulated MFIs are somewhat more responsive to changes in domestic and international economic conditions, while they are less responsive to changes in international capital markets in the case of asset quality.

Purpose. Non-profit MFIs performance are more consistently linked with domestic and international capital market conditions. In this regard, asset growth and asset quality regressions all show coefficients with the expected sign that also are statistically significant, with strong evidence of links also for lending growth. Profitability regressions, however, show positive signs which are statistically significant only for the S&P and the MSCI emerging markets indices. Asset growth regressions in the case of for-profit MFIs show coefficients that are positive in sign and statistically significant, though asset quality and profitability regressions show expected signs, that are not statistically significant in most cases; regarding the latter, the coefficient for asset quality is statistically significant only against domestic market conditions, with the same happening for the profitability regression. Table 5 shows, in turn, that in spite of the fact that regressions for non-profit institutions show more consistent links with both domestic economic conditions and international capital markets, coefficients in asset and lending growth regressions of for-profit institutions show positive and statistically significant differences with respect to those of non-profit MFIs. Moreover there is some evidence that asset quality in the case of for-profit MFIs is less responsive to changes in domestic economic conditions, while their profitability is less responsive to changes in international capital markets.

Age. The performance of mature MFIs show the most consistent associations with that of domestic and international economic conditions. Asset growth and asset quality regressions all show coefficients of the expected sign that also are statistically significant; lending growth also shows positive signs that are statistically significant against domestic economic conditions, though the evidence for linkages with international capital markets is more limited. In turn, profitability regressions all show coefficients that are positive in sign, but only the coefficient against the MSCI emerging markets index is statistically significant. Asset growth regressions for younger MFIs show positive and statistically significant coefficients in all cases, though lending growth regressions show positive signs that are statistically significant only for domestic economic conditions and emerging capital markets. Asset quality regressions show negative signs but no coefficient is statistically significant. Profitability regressions show coefficients that are positive but statistically significant only for GDP growth and emerging markets. In turn, Table 5 shows that in spite of the fact that mature institutions appear more consistenly linked with domestic and international market conditions, asset growth of mature MFIs are less responsive to changes to the economic environment.

Robustness of Results

The results are broadly similar when regressions are estimated extending the period to 1995-2009. However, the consistency of the relationship between MFI performance and domestic economic conditions and international capital markets improves when the period considered is shrunk to 2002-2009. In this regard, the number of coefficients with the right sign and that are statistically significant increases with respect to those obtained in regressions estimated using the period 1998-2009. In particular ROE regressions (which are the weakest for 1998-2009) show coefficients with the right sign and that are statistically significant in all cases for the CAC, MCE and SAC regions; banks and NBFIs; non-regulated MFIs; and for-profit institutions. Coefficients also show the right sign and are statistically significant in most cases for NGOs; regulated MFIs; non-profit institutions; and both young and mature MFIs. Lending growth and asset quality regressions also show the expected results at statistically significant levels in more cases than when the period 1998-2009 is considered. These results reinforce the notion that as MFIs mature, their linkages with domestic and international market conditions get stronger.

Results are also broadly similar, though somewhat weaker, when larger cross sections of MFIs are considered, in particular for the longer time periods (1995-2009 and 1998-2009). The weaker results are partially the consequence of the larger volatility introduced when smaller MFIs are considered.15

V. An Empirical Analysis of Microfinance Lending rate Determinants

Lending rates on micro-credits are significantly higher than those charged by mainstream commercial banks. As the effects of the financial crisis began to be felt, the relatively high rates charged by MFIs gained the spotlight. Public debate (including criticism from the press) concentrated on the small loan sizes, the high rates, and the large profits obtained by institutions whose stated objective was to help the poor.16

As CGAP (2002) points out, the relatively high rates (even when justified by industry fundamentals) are difficult to defend in the context of uninformed public discussion, or when politicians, with full awareness of the benefits that could be derived from the increasingly large MFI clientele, exploit the issue for political advantage.17 National legislatures and the public are usually not sufficiently informed about MFIs’ cost structure, so debates are biased even when the high rates are not the result of inefficiency or excessive profits.

In consequence, the policy response has been, at times, to establish interest rate ceilings using commercial banks as the benchmark, in spite of their substantially lower administrative costs per unit of dollar lent. Interest rate caps, when set at levels that are lower than the sustainable rate, result in limited access to formal financial services by the poor. This is the case as MFIs, unable to cover their costs, reduce the scale of their operations and concentrate in the market segments that are easier to serve (usually urban and for higher sized loans). Also, interest rate caps can lead to less transparency about the costs of credit, as MFIs need to add a number of fees and commissions to break even. It goes without saying that, high interest rates do reflect, at times, higher than warranted operational costs (CGAP 2002, 2004).18

The poor generally consider ongoing access to credit more important than its cost, as the alternatives (including moneylenders, local saving circles, etc.) are usually more expensive (CGAP 2004). It is then clear that as MFI lending rates turned into a political issue, lack of understanding of the factors that contribute to their determination could result in wrong policies, affecting the access to credit of large segments of the population with the associated losses in economic efficiency.

The Model

The cost structure of financial institutions that devote a substantial part of their portfolio to microcredit is fundamentally different than that of other more mainstream institutions. As CGAP (2002, 2004) point out, MFIs’ lending rates need to cover the cost of funds for on-lending, the cost of risk (i.e., the expected loan loss), and administrative costs (including searching, identifying, appraising and screening clients, processing loan applications, disbursing loans, monitoring and auditing clients, collecting repayments, and following up on non-repayment). While the costs of funding and risk are proportional to loan size, administrative costs are not. In other words, for two identically-sized financial institutions, the institution with a lower average loan size per borrower will, by necessity, have a larger number of accounts, and thus will have to charge a higher interest rate to break even.

In addition to having lower average loan sizes, MFI portfolios are of a significantly shorter duration than those of more traditional financial intermediaries. The combination of a larger number of accounts with lower portfolio duration implies that, for a portfolio of a given size, the number of transactions that MFIs need to process per unit of dollar lent are significantly higher than those for traditional commercial banks. Client and product characteristics add to administrative costs, as illiteracy, absence of formal collateral and of basic business documentation (including financial statements) make personal, face-to-face, interaction essential for loan recovery. Personal interaction can be very onerous when clients are geographically dispersed and communications are relatively costly.

Although the cost of risk is proportional to loan size, the nature of risk facing MFIs is different than that of conventional financial institutions. As CGAP (2002) highlights MFIs’ portfolios are more volatile and can deteriorate faster, as they are mostly unsecured. Borrowers’ incentive to repay is the expectation of future access to new loans, so delinquency can be contagious, as an increase in delinquency makes it less likely that the MFI will be able to provide future loans. As MFI costs per US$ lent are higher than those for commercial banks, a given level of delinquency will decapitalize an MFI more quickly.19 MFI institutions that maintain higher capital-asset ratios might be acknowledging this risk, and consequently, charge higher rates.

Interest rates are also influenced by MFI productivity. Even though administrative costs are usually proportionally higher for microcredit than for mainstream commercial bank lending, MFIs are much more productive than commercial banks, in the sense that each of their staff handles a significantly higher number of borrowers. Note, however, that in spite of how many clients each staff can handle, the larger the operational cost per staff (including staff compensation), the higher the lending rate that would have to be charged for the MFI to break even. Staff compensation is particularly important, because in the absence of proper supervision it could mask the payment of dividends.

Administrative costs may be higher for young MFIs that are too small to take advantage of economies of scale (CGAP 2004). Moreover, improvements in MFI productivity are likely to occur with the passage of time, as the lending technology is proven and improved through experimentation, development and adjustment, and staff becomes more experienced. Time also allows accumulating information about successful clients and the environment, establishing a stable clientele and a good reputation in the market (Caudill, Gropper and Hartarska, 2009).20 Moreover, the passage of time allows establishing connections with international networks, technology transfer, and improved access to financing. Thus, more mature MFIs would be in a position to charge lower interest rates, other things equal.

Finally, a stable macroeconomic situation is a critical pre-condition for competitive microfinance. Economies that grow more are, in principle, in a better position to undertake investments in telecommunications, roads and education, which are critical for MFI efficiency improvements (CGAP 2004). Better domestic economic conditions might then result in lower lending rates.21

Taking into account these considerations, the following two models are estimated:

lrit=c+γi+β1(+)·brit+β2()·szit+β3()·bsit+β4(+)·osit+β5(?)·kait+β6(+)·parit+β7()·yit+β8()·ageit+εit(1)
sprit=c+γi+β2·szit+β3·bsit+β4·osit+β5·kait+β6·parit1+β7·yit+β8·ageit+εit(2)

Expression (1) states that the lending rate at time t for the MFI i (lrit) depends on the borrowing rate (brit), the average loan size (szit), the number of borrowers per staff (bsit), the operating cost per staff (osit), the capital-asset ratio (kait), the portfolio at risk (parit-1), the real GDP growth (yit), and MFI age (ageit). Expression (2) is identical to (1), but includes the absolute spread (sprit) as the left hand-side variable, and assumes that βi =1. The results in all cases were obtained through the estimation of fixed effects regressions using OLS.22 This means that both (1) and (2) include MFI-specific constants (γi), in addition to a general constant (c).

The expected signs for each of the coefficients are indicated below expression (1). High interest rates (spreads) are explained by large administrative costs, usually as a consequence of small loan sizes, which result in large administrative costs per unit of US$ lent. Loan delinquency and borrowing costs directly affect lending rates. The lower the quality of the portfolio, the lower the probability of loan recovery, and thus, the larger lending rates (spreads) should be. The efficiency with which MFIs operate also influences on the rates charged: controlling for loan sizes, less efficient MFIs will have a larger cost per unit of lending, and thus, they would charge higher lending rates (spreads). The same argument applies for productivity: given an average loan size per borrower, MFIs with higher borrowers per staff member, will be in the position to charge lower lending rates (spreads). The impact of the funding structure on lending rates (spread) is uncertain, as higher capital-asset ratios may indicate the need for larger reserves, and thus be associated with larger lending rates (spreads); at the same time, better capitalized institutions could be perceived as stronger, and thus, be able to attract longer-term, cheaper, funding. In addition, more mature MFIs are usually in the position of exploit economies of scale, and better honed lending technologies, and thus lending rates (spreads) for older MFIs should be lower. Finally, MFIs operating in a better domestic economic environment should also be able to charge lower rates (spreads).

Tables 6 and 7 show the results of the estimation of expressions (1) and (2), respectively, for a number of MFI groupings. A horizontal look at Tables 6 and 7 allows to see whether the coefficient of a specfic explanatory variable has the expected sign (and whether the coefficient is statistically significant at usual confidence levels) across MFI groupings; looking at the table vertically allows to see whether lending rates (spread) for a specific MFI grouping are explained by the proposed explanatory variables in (1) and (2) (and whether the coefficients associated with those variables are significant at usual confidence levels). The estimated regressions for alternative groups of MFI would also allow to establish whether certain fundamentals influence lending rates (spreads) through a specific (or a number) of MFI characteristics, including location, institution type, legal status, purpose, and age.

Table 6.

Lending Rate Regressions (Selected Sample, 1998-2009)

article image
Table 7.

Spread Regressions (Selected sample, 1998-2009)

article image
NotesR2 =R-squared value. Shaded cells represent coefficients with both the expected sign and that are statistically significant.* 99% level of confidence.** 95% level of confidence.*** 90% level of confidence