Development of Financial Markets in Central Europe: the Case of the CE4 Countries
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

Authors’ E-Mail Addresses: aadarov@walton.uark.edu, rtchaidze@imf.org

Financial markets in the CE4 countries are still shallow compared to other advanced EU countries. While the government bond markets are comparable in size, measured by capitalization in percent of GDP, the private bond, private credit, and equity markets lag behind. Empirical analysis in this paper helps identify factors that explain this phenomenon. We find that the observed differences cannot be explained by macroeconomic variables only, but incorporating indicators of institutional development and external funding eliminates the gap in the case of the equity and private credit markets. However, for the private bond market a significant gap remains even after accounting for these factors.

Abstract

Financial markets in the CE4 countries are still shallow compared to other advanced EU countries. While the government bond markets are comparable in size, measured by capitalization in percent of GDP, the private bond, private credit, and equity markets lag behind. Empirical analysis in this paper helps identify factors that explain this phenomenon. We find that the observed differences cannot be explained by macroeconomic variables only, but incorporating indicators of institutional development and external funding eliminates the gap in the case of the equity and private credit markets. However, for the private bond market a significant gap remains even after accounting for these factors.

I. Introduction

It is widely recognized that financial development is one of the critical driving forces of economic development2 and significant efforts have been devoted to explaining existing differences across countries. Despite sizeable literature, empirical evidence is still rather mixed and consensus has not been reached with respect to specific factors that facilitate financial development or with respect to optimal policy prescriptions that would stimulate it.

In this paper we focus on financial markets in the CE4 nations (the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, and the Slovak Republic), which represent a rather appealing case to investigate for several reasons. These are the countries that not so long ago have been transition economies, and thus, share many common features in their institutional background and policy experiences with other emerging markets. In particular, that is the case with respect to their financial systems where financial intermediation is dominated by the banking sector, while security markets are relatively less important. However, on the other hand, the CE4 countries are already sound market economies, belonging to the high or the upper-middle-income group,3 which suggests maturity of decision-making processes both in the private and public sectors.

Despite considerable efforts undertaken to facilitate financial development, it is frequently argued that financial systems in the CE4 countries are underdeveloped, possibly due to weak governance and other institutional impediments. Indeed, as can be seen from Figure 1, while public bond markets in the CE4 nations are comparable to those of the other advanced economies, the private financial segments—the private credit market, the private bond market, and the stock market—are considerably smaller in size.4 However, the small size of the financial markets itself is not necessarily an indication of their underdevelopment in the sense that they fail to meet the financing needs of resident borrowers. A more careful investigation requires benchmarking financial development of the CE4 nations against performance of comparable economies controlling for the stage of economic development and other relevant macroeconomic fundamentals.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Financial Markets in the CE4 Countries Relative to the EU Economies, 2004–08 Averages

Country groups are defined as follows: CE4 (the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, the Slovak Republic), Large EU members (Germany, Spain, France, United Kingdom, Italy), Small EU members (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Greece, Ireland, Netherlands, Portugal, Sweden), New EU members (Bulgaria, Estonia, Lithuania, Latvia, Romania, Slovenia). Data for public and private bond markets are not available for New EU members. Data for private bond market are not available for Poland and the Slovak Republic. Denmark is excluded from the sample in the case of the private bond market, given its large mortgage bond market.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2011, 101; 10.5089/9781455254323.001.A001

Source: Database on Financial Development and Structure (Beck and Demirgüç-Kunt, 2009).

In order to do that, we resort to panel data analysis of high-income and upper-middle-income economies establishing benchmark relationships between macroeconomic fundamentals and financial development indicators. Then we compare de-facto financial performance of the CE4 countries with the expected levels given their macroeconomic conditions. We also analyze to what extent underperformance, if any is found, can be explained by inadequate institutional development, as is often argued.

Overall, our paper contributes to the literature along the following dimensions. First, our analysis is based on the most recent data available, providing an up-to-date perspective on financial market development in the CE4 countries. Second, while most of the literature focuses on private credit and stock markets, we also assess performance of private bond markets. Third, we use several alternative techniques for robustness and address econometric issues often neglected in the literature. Finally, we benchmark performance of each of the financial segments against the same set of macroeconomic fundamentals for a broad sample of countries, which ensures that impacts of particular factors are evaluated on the same comparable basis for all of these financial segments.

We find that in the CE4 economies all of the three financial segments examined are significantly below the expected levels given the countries’ macroeconomic fundamentals. While the macroeconomic variables by themselves cannot explain the observed differences, incorporating indicators of institutional development and external funding eliminates the gap in the case of the stock and the private credit markets. In the case of the private bond market, however, a significant gap remains even when accounting for these factors.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows: Section II provides a brief overview of the existing literature, Section III describes data and empirical framework, Section IV discusses estimation results and additional analysis performed for robustness, while Section V concludes.

II. Literature on Determinants of Financial Development

The existing literature outlines a range of factors affecting development of financial markets that can be split into two categories: “macroeconomic fundamentals” that reflect broad macroeconomic characteristics (economic development measures, inflation, exposure to global trade and capital flows, etc.); and “institutional factors” that reflect the state of regulatory and supervisory institutions (legal framework, extent of corruption, protection of the property rights, political stability, etc.). Both of these categories seem to matter. Moreover, they are interrelated as the evolution of institutional parameters is directly reflected in macroeconomic conditions, and favorable macroeconomic environment facilitates development of institutions. Therefore, such a division of the literature is purely provisional and does not imply alternative views on the determinants of financial development.

Under the “macroeconomic” approach, favorable macroeconomic conditions are emphasized as essential for healthy financial systems. Strong association has been well documented between development of financial markets and macroeconomic parameters such as income levels, savings, economic openness, inflation, and macroeconomic volatility.

Many studies find that the overall level of economic development, often measured by per capita income or income growth measures, is the strongest predictor of financial progress. The significance of per capita income for financial development is reported, for example, in Levine (1997, 2003) and Claessens et al. (2006). Garcia and Liu (1999) find that income growth, domestic investment, and financial intermediary development have significant implications for stock markets, while macroeconomic volatility does not seem to matter. Focusing specifically on the development of emerging capital markets, El-Wassal (2005) finds that economic growth, financial liberalization policies, and foreign portfolio investments are important for financial development.

A large pool of literature investigates the impact of inflation on capital markets. High levels of inflation, ceteris paribus, are associated with less liquid and smaller financial markets as financial intermediaries tend to lend less and allocate capital less efficiently. Among the recent works, Boyd et al. (2001) find negative effects of inflation on the private credit and equity markets. They also argue that the relationship between financial development and inflation could be nonlinear with a particular threshold level after which financial sectors experience an abrupt drop in performance. Similar inflation effects are also investigated empirically in Khan et al. (2001) and theoretically in Choi et al. (1996) and Huybens and Smith (1999).

Economic openness is also frequently argued to be relevant for domestic capital market development, but the distinction is often drawn between capital and trade openness. For example, the importance of trade openness for financial development is emphasized in Svaleryd and Vlachos (2002), Do and Levchenko (2007), whereas Chinn and Ito (2006) discuss the significance of capital openness.5 Rajan and Zingales (2003) move the discussion of economic openness effects to the political economy dimension and argue that domestic interest groups oppose financial development to avoid higher competition, and that both trade and capital openness are necessary to reduce their opposition to financial development. However, Baltagi et al. (2009) find only limited support for this hypothesis and, while confirming the importance of trade and capital openness for financial development, suggest that those do not necessarily have to be simultaneous in order to trigger growth of capital markets.

A range of other macroeconomic factors are used to explain capital market differences, including macroeconomic volatility, which decreases incentives to engage in financial contracting, and related policy variables, e.g. public debt burden, fiscal deficits, and tax burden on businesses. However, specifications are often ad-hoc, while results rather inconclusive.

The “institutional” strand of literature emphasizes the role of property rights, contract enforcement, and corruption in explaining cross-country variation in financial development.6 La Porta et al. (1997, 2000), for example, demonstrate a deep impact of investor protection rights, measured by the quality of legal rules and law enforcement, on the development of both debt and equity markets. Contracting rights institutions are found to be a significant contributing factor in Djankov et al. (2007), property rights institutions are discussed in Acemoglu and Johnson (2005), and Roe and Siegel (2009) emphasize the importance of overall political stability for financial development.

Overall, while the literature looks at a variety of macroeconomic and institutional factors, no consistent view on the determinants of financial development that summarizes the model in a single framework has been developed. The range of factors important for financial systems could be roughly aggregated to the overall level of economic development, social and economic stability, political and legal framework, economic openness, whereas the marginal effect of each of these categories is difficult to isolate as they are interrelated and the causality between them and the level of financial development is a complex phenomena characterized by feedback effects and lags.

III. Data and Methodology

We evaluate financial sector performance in the CE4 nations relative to countries comparable in terms of their economic development. Since according to the World Bank income group classification, the Czech Republic, Hungary, and the Slovak Republic are high-income economies and Poland is an upper-middle-income economy, our analysis is based on a panel dataset comprising 68 upper-middle-income and high-income countries worldwide (Table 1) and spanning the period of 1994–2008 at annual frequency.

Table 1.

Sample of Countries

article image

It is important to compare financial development both across time and across countries. Focusing only on a cross-section for an individual year could result in incorrect judgment of relative performance for some countries as they could be affected by short-term idiosyncratic downturns of financial development due to business cycle effects or policy changes. Comparing across countries is important as it allows assessing performance relative to peer economies with similar macroeconomic structural characteristics and similar level of overall economic development. The global scope of the sample and the time span help reduce the risk that results are heavily influenced by either region-specific characteristics or macroeconomic circumstances of particular years. At the same time, focusing on relatively well-established market economies makes analysis less prone to problems stemming from incomplete or low-quality data.

Financial development variables characterizing the size of the private credit sector, stock and private bond markets are obtained from the Database on Financial Development and Structure7 introduced in Beck and Demirgüç-Kunt (2009). The earlier version of the dataset, introduced in Beck et al. (2000), has been extensively used in the empirical research assessing financial markets in a panel data setting.

Macroeconomic data are obtained from the World Economic Outlook and International Financial Statistics databases of the IMF, the World Development Indicators of the World Bank, and the UNCTAD Foreign Direct Investment Database, associated with the World Investment Report.

In our measurements of institutional development we use the Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) produced by the World Bank (Figure 2). We use the indices of government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law, and control of corruption to measure different aspects of institutional environment. Each of the indices is measured in units ranging from approximately -2.5 to 2.5, with higher values corresponding to better governance outcomes. We believe these indices to be superior to alternative measures of institutional development as they are constructed from raw metrics from a wide range of sources8 and are continuous, rather than cross-country rankings or low-range discrete index values, hampering regression results.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Institutional Development Indicators, 2007

The governance indicators are measured in units ranging from about -2.5 to 2.5, with higher values corresponding to better governance outcomes. Control of corruption measures the extent to which public power is exercised for private gain. Rule of law measures the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide by the rules of society, e.g. the quality of contract enforcement and property rights. Regulatory quality measures the ability of the government to provide sound policies and regulations. Government effectiveness measures the quality of public services and policy formulation.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2011, 101; 10.5089/9781455254323.001.A001

Source: World Bank.

In our empirical analysis we use the following variables (summary statistics in Table 2; cross-correlations in Table 3):

  • Financial development is one of the three measures of financial sector development for a country in a given year:

    • Private credit/GDP—claims on the domestic private sector by deposit money banks as a share of GDP;

    • Private bond market capitalization/GDP—the total value of outstanding domestic debt securities9 issued by financial institutions and corporations as a share of GDP;

    • Stock market capitalization/GDP—the total market value of stocks listed on domestic stock exchanges as a share of GDP.

  • Among the explanatory variables we use:

    • Log of real GDP per capita—natural logarithm of real GDP per capita in PPP terms;

    • Trade openness—the sum of exports and imports of goods and services as a share of GDP;

    • Inflation—annual inflation rate (GDP deflator);

    • Inflation volatility—the change in the rate of inflation between the current and previous years, averaged over the corresponding 3-year periods for estimations involving 3-year non-overlapping averages; the standard deviation of annual inflation over the 10-year period for estimations involving 10-year averages data; and the change in the rate of inflation between the current and previous years for specifications based on annual frequency data;

    • Public bond market capitalization/GDP—the total value of public domestic debt securities issued by the government as a share of GDP;

    • Government effectiveness—an index, measuring the quality of public services, the capacity of the civil service and its independence from political pressures, and the quality of policy formulation;

    • Regulatory quality—an index, measuring the ability of the government to provide sound policies and regulations that enable and promote private sector development;

    • Rule of law—an index, measuring the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide by the rules of society, including the quality of contract enforcement and property rights, the police, and the courts, as well as the likelihood of crime and violence;

    • Control of corruption—an index, measuring the extent to which public power is exercised for private gain, including both petty and grand forms of corruption, as well as “capture” of the state by elites and private interests;

    • CE4—the dummy variable that takes the value of unity for the CE4 nations and zero otherwise.

Table 2.

Summary Statistics for the Variables Used in the Regression Analysis

article image
Table 3.

Pairwise Correlations. 3-year Non-Overlapping Averages, 68 Countries, 1994–2008.

article image
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels correspondingly

As we attempt to benchmark financial performance against relevant macroeconomic indicators, rather than explain cause-effect relationships of particular factors, we examine the relationship between the fundamentals and financial development indicators in order to establish the financial development “norms”—expected values of financial development indicators, contingent upon the assumption that levels of financial development can be consistently related to the overall economic development levels, controlling for other relevant macroeconomic parameters.10 The general form of our baseline model is:

article image

The baseline model is estimated with the pooled OLS with cluster-robust standard errors with the annual data transformed to 3-year non-overlapping averages, which reduces the size of the dataset to 68 countries observed over 5 periods. For robustness, the specification is also estimated using the data averaged over the years 2005–2008, 10-year averages, pooled OLS, and fixed effects for the panel data.

The baseline model satisfies econometric problems to the extent possible for the purposes of our analysis and takes advantage of the time dimension. 3-year averaging of annual data, common to financial literature, reduces the short-term cyclical effects. The major impediment in econometric analysis comes from potential endogeneity of regressors. Endogeneity associated with potential two-way causality is addressed by lagging the macroeconomic variables by one period, again a common approach used in the literature.

A number of problems arise due to the panel nature of data. Specifically, intra-group correlations may lead to inconsistent estimates for the least squares estimation, something addressed by employing cluster-robust standard errors. The analysis is further complicated by the fact that many relevant variables are jointly determined and correlated, which is addressed by grouping variables and consecutive inclusion of variables in the model so that the collinear terms do not enter the same specification.

Yet another complication is non-stationarity of some of the variables. However, most of the techniques, addressing this issue (e.g., estimation in differences), would eliminate time-invariant effects, including the CE4 dummy. Thus, we also did estimations for the most recent 3-year averages cross-section, to ensure that the observed results are not spurious.

Our main interest is the sign of the CE4 dummy variable throughout alternative specifications. If the hypothesis of underdeveloped financial markets in the CE4 markets is correct, the dummy should have a negative and statistically significant coefficient.

IV. Empirical Results

Step 1: Macroeconomic Fundamentals

As a first step, we plot real GDP per capita against each of the financial development indicators and examine the relative position of the CE4 nations. Figure 3 plots data for the entire panel data as well as for the latest 3-year average period used in our analysis (2006–2008). A few observations are worth making. First, financial development is strongly positively associated with economic development. Second, all of the CE4 countries lie below the fitted linear regression lines that signify the reference levels of financial development expected based on the experiences of the entire sample. Finally, the figure suggests that the relationship between economic development and financial markets could have a non-linear nature.11

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Financial Development Indicators Plotted Against Real GDP Per Capita

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2011, 101; 10.5089/9781455254323.001.A001

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Second, we regress financial development indicators on a wider group of macroeconomic variables.

Since it is widely recognized that the overall level of economic development is best captured by per capita income and that economic development stimulates demand for financial services, leading to higher volumes of financial intermediation and increasing the scope of financial services, we start with real GDP per capita as the primary predictor of financial development. However, although per capita income is a catch-all parameter capturing a broad range of structural macroeconomic characteristics strongly associated with national income, it may not pick up the effects of certain other factors important for financial markets. Thus, we control for other factors that may cause deviations from the levels predicted by the stage of economic development.

In particular, we control for the rate of inflation and macroeconomic volatility, measured by instability of inflation rate, as both high inflation rates and inflation volatility prevent full-scale financial intermediation. High levels of inflation make agents less interested in engaging in contractual obligations leading to less liquid markets, while frequently changing inflation would discourage financial intermediation via higher risks and inability to plan in the uncertain environment, in contrast to a situation with high, but stable inflation.

Next, we include trade openness as a proxy for the effects of overall economic integration into the world economy. Higher integration into the world economy should increase efficiency of the financial sector, while higher scale of economic activity and higher exposure to foreign competition may spur investment needs, leading to higher financing needs through debt or equity.

Given the contrast between relatively well developed public bond segment and less developed other financial market segments in the CE4 countries, we explicitly test whether public bond market development has any significant implications for the private capital markets and thus include a ratio of public bond market capitalization to GDP as a regressor in a range of specifications. As government bond issuance by definition is determined primarily by fiscal considerations, i.e. by factors different from those for the private sector, it should not create empirical difficulties. The expected effects could be either positive or negative. On the one hand, government bonds, being a risk-free asset, may stimulate private financial markets by providing a reference yield curve. On the other hand, too large public bond markets may be crowding-out the private markets.

Tables 4-6 report the benchmark relationships between macroeconomic fundamentals and each of the financial market development measures.

  • As expected, GDP per capita enters positively and highly significantly in most specifications and is robust to inclusion of additional control variables.

  • For the private credit market, inflation enters negatively and significantly, trade openness is positive and weakly significant, inflation volatility is negative and weakly significant.

  • In the case of the private bond market, only GDP per capita enters positively and significantly, while other variables are insignificant.

  • Finally, for the stock market development, GDP per capita enters positively and statistically significantly; in some specifications inflation enters negatively and inflation volatility enters positively, but both are weakly significant.

  • Interestingly enough, we do not find any significant effects of the public bond market on any of the private financial markets. It might be helping the development of the private bond market, crowding out the other segments; however, this effect is not pronounced as the variable is insignificant throughout specifications.

  • Most importantly, the CE4 dummy variable is negative and highly significant throughout specifications for all financial market segments, indicating weak financial development relative to peer economies after controlling for the relevant macroeconomic characteristics. Specifically, the magnitudes suggest that financial markets in the CE4 economies are at least some 20 percent below the levels predicted by the model.

Table 4.

Private Credit Market, 3-year Non-overlapping Averages Pooled OLS.

Dependent variable: private credit/GDP. Pooled OLS estimation with cluster-robust standard errors (reported in parenthesis). Panel dataset comprises 68 high income and upper-middle income economies over the period 1994–2008. Observations are 3-year non-overlapping averages. Macroeconomic explanatory variables are lagged one year.

article image
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels correspondingly.
Table 5.

Private Bond Market, 3-Year Non-Overlapping Averages Pooled OLS.

Dependent variable: private bond market capitalization/GDP. Pooled OLS estimation with cluster-robust standard errors (reported in parenthesis). Panel dataset comprises 68 high income and upper-middle income economies over the period 1994–2008. Observations are 3-year non-overlapping averages. Macroeconomic explanatory variables are lagged one year.

article image
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels correspondingly.
Table 6.

Equity Market, 3-year Non-overlapping Averages Pooled OLS.

Dependent variable: stock market capitalization/GDP. Pooled OLS estimation with cluster-robust standard errors (reported in parenthesis). Panel dataset comprises 68 high income and upper-middle income economies over the period 1994–2008. Observations are 3-year non-overlapping averages. Macroeconomic explanatory variables are lagged one year.

article image
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels correspondingly.

Step 2: Adding Institutional Variables

The following step is to test whether the observed negative residual effect, persistent throughout the private financial markets in the CE4 countries, can be explained by institutional factors, which we expect to be positively related to financial development outcomes and hence, to reduce the effect of the CE4 dummy variable, if it is indeed the effect of weak institutions that is preventing proper financial development in these nations.

We include the institutional variables—indicators of government effectiveness, control of corruption, rule of law, and regulatory quality—to test whether their presence reduces the magnitude and significance of the CE4 dummy variable. However, since the institutional variables are highly correlated with each other as well as with real per capita income (Table 3), including them into the regression would not allow disentangling the effect of the stage of development (measured by real GDP per capita) and the effect of individual institutional development characteristics. Thus, to avoid multicollinearity issues, we re-estimate the model by including institutional variables one-by-one but dropping real per capita GDP (Tables 79).

Table 7.

The Effects of Institutional Development Variables on the Private Credit Sector, 3-Year Non-Overlapping Averages Pooled OLS.13

Dependent variable: private credit/GDP. Pooled OLS estimation with cluster-robust standard errors (reported in parenthesis). Panel dataset comprises 68 high income and upper-middle income economies over the period 1994–2008. Observations are 3-year non-overlapping averages. Macroeconomic explanatory variables are lagged one year.

article image
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels correspondingly.
Table 8.

The Effects of Institutional Development Variables on the Private Bond Market. 3-Year Non-Overlapping Averages Pooled OLS.

Dependent variable: private bond market capitalization/GDP. Pooled OLS estimation with cluster-robust standard errors (reported in parenthesis). Panel dataset comprises 68 high income and upper-middle income economies over the period 1994–2008. Observations are 3-year non-overlapping averages. Macroeconomic explanatory variables are lagged one year.

article image
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels correspondingly.
Table 9.

The Effects of Institutional Development Variables on the Equity Market. 3-Year Non-Overlapping Averages Pooled OLS.

Dependent variable: stock market capitalization/GDP. Pooled OLS estimation with cluster-robust standard errors (reported in parenthesis). Panel dataset comprises 68 high income and upper-middle income economies over the period 1994–2008. Observations are 3-year non-overlapping averages. Macroeconomic explanatory variables are lagged one year.

article image
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels correspondingly.

As expected, institutional variables enter positively and significantly for all of the financial markets, while their presence decreases the CE4 dummy in magnitude, which however remains significant. This implies that the institutional variables have superior explanatory power relative to real GDP per capita and that to some extent shallowness of the financial markets in the CE4 countries can be explained by their weak institutional development. In particular, in the sense of reducing the CE4 dummy variable the most, lagging private credit and private bond market in the CE4 countries is best explained by control of corruption, whereas for the stock market government effectiveness appears to be the most relevant factor.

Step 3: Robustness Checks

For robustness, we check the significance of alternative macroeconomic variables, such as real GDP, GDP growth rate, GDP growth volatility, the ratio of savings to GDP, population size, the ratio of current account to GDP, the ratio of inward FDI stock to GDP, and marginal corporate tax rate. Yet, these variables either do not explain the cross-country variation in financial development better than the “original” macroeconomic fundamentals or turn out to be insignificant.

We also estimate the baseline model with several other techniques that include:

  • Pooled OLS model with cluster-robust standard errors for the annual frequency panel dataset (1994–2008).

  • Fixed effects model with heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for the annual frequency panel dataset (1994–2008). The model includes time-invariant fixed effects for individual countries, including the CE4 countries in lieu of the CE4 dummy variable.12

  • OLS with heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for the 10-year averages cross-section. This approach emphasizes long-term relationships between financial development and macroeconomic fundamentals that still hold after medium-term variations in the cross-section data are removed.

  • OLS with heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for the most recent pre-crisis 3-year period available (2006–08). This approach allows assessing effects of relatively tranquil years and alleviates potential problems of averaging over a long time horizon, when the earlier years could be driving the regression results.

The results are rather similar to the ones reported earlier. Real GDP per capita is the most significant predictor of financial development, entering positively and significantly for most of the specifications and the financial segments. Inflation enters negatively significantly in most specifications and inflation volatility enters negatively, but is significant only for the private credit market specifications. Public bond market capitalization as a share of GDP is negative and significant in the fixed effects model, while in most other specifications it is negative, but insignificant. Institutional variables are significant and positive in almost all the cases. Most importantly, and similarly to the results reported earlier, the CE4 dummy variable enters negatively and significantly across all specifications, but its magnitude and/or significance is reduced when institutional variables are controlled for.

Step 4: Incorporating IIP Variables

The final empirical exercise we perform is testing whether external financing affects development of domestic financial markets. Existence of external funding may stimulate development of the financial markets or prevent it, depending on the way funds are channeled into the economy. For example, ability of corporates to borrow from abroad would have a negative effect on the development of the financial markets, as in the presence of external funding sources the importance of domestic financial intermediation declines. Meanwhile, borrowing from abroad by financial institutions would increase the supply of capital available domestically, as these funds are eventually re-circulated, and thus would stimulate development of the financial markets.

Recourse to external financing is, of course, dependent on the state of domestic financial markets, the level of economic development, and macroeconomic stability, which are already included in the regression specifications. Thus, resorting by domestic entities to external financing sources could be a reflection of inability to raise funds domestically and hence, an indication of less developed domestic capital markets. Alternatively, having access to external funding and capacity to consequently process these funds domestically may be an indication of maturity of these markets. For these reasons, the results reported in this section should be interpreted with caution.

We include international investment position (IIP) variables on liabilities to non-residents: direct investment, equity portfolio investment, and debt (including bonds, loans, financial derivatives, trade credit, etc.). We exclude general government and monetary authorities and distinguish between the banking and non-banking sectors when possible.

We find (Tables 1012) that in the case of private credit, the stock of external debt and equity investment from abroad into the banking sector enters the regression positively and significantly, suggesting recirculation of the external funds. Similarly, for the stock market, the total stock of external debt (invested into the banking and the non-banking sectors) enters positively and significantly, possibly for the same reasons (e.g., recirculation). Finally, in the case of the private bond market, the stock of equity investment from abroad into the non-banking sector enters negatively and significantly suggesting that domestic funding is replaced by foreign.

Table 10.

The Effects of IIP Variables, 3-Year Non-Overlapping Averages Pooled OLS.

Regression results dropping insignificant variables and including IIP variables. The sample includes high income and upper-middle income economies (68) over the period 1994–2008. Observations are 3-year non-overlapping averages based on complete 3-year observations. Macroeconomic explanatory variables are lagged one year. Cluster-robust standard errors are reported in parenthesis.

article image
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels correspondingly.
Table 11.

The Effects of IIP and Institutional Development Variables, Dropping GDP Per Capita.

Regression results dropping insignificant variables and including IIP variables. Institutional development is assessed by the government effectiveness variable for brevity as the institutional variables are highly correlated. The sample includes high income and upper-middle income economies (68) over the period 1994–2008. Observations are 3-year non-overlapping averages based on complete 3-year observations. Macroeconomic explanatory variables are lagged one year. Cluster-robust standard errors are reported in parenthesis.

article image
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels correspondingly.
Table 12.

The Effects of IIP And Institutional Development Variables, with GDP Per Capita Included.

Regression results dropping insignificant variables and including IIP variables. Institutional development is assessed by the government effectiveness variable for brevity as the institutional variables are highly correlated. The sample includes high income and upper-middle income economies (68) over the period 1994–2008. Observations are 3-year non-overlapping averages based on complete 3-year observations. Macroeconomic explanatory variables are lagged one year. Cluster-robust standard errors are reported in parenthesis.

article image
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels correspondingly.

Meanwhile, inclusion of the IIP variables reduces the magnitude of the CE4 dummy variable and makes it insignificant for the private credit market and the stock market, but not for the private bond market. Including institutional variables after controlling for the IIP variables only marginally changes the magnitude of the CE4 dummy variable. However, in the case of the private credit and the stock markets, both the institutional and the IIP variables enter significantly, which suggests that the setbacks in the institutional development do play role. In the case of the private bond market the result is different—inclusion of the institutional variables makes the IIP variable insignificant, but not the CE4 dummy.

As mentioned earlier, the results should be interpreted cautiously as the direction of causality is ambiguous, but these results may signify that the misalignment between macroeconomic fundamentals and the level of financial development reflects the use of external financing at least in the case of the stock and private credit markets.

V. Conclusion

Financial development in the CE4 countries is lagging relative to economies that are similar in terms of their economic development. While the sizes of the public bond markets are comparable to those in the peer countries, the other financial segments—the market for the private credit, the private bond, and the stock markets—are significantly smaller.

We attempt to establish benchmark values for depth of these markets by linking it to macroeconomic fundamentals and indicators of institutional development. We find that the financial markets in the CE4 countries are significantly shallower than what one would expect given their stage of economic development as measured by real GDP per capita and controlling for other relevant macroeconomic characteristics. An explanation could be underdevelopment of institutions and access to external funding that renders unnecessary further development of some of the financial markets at the scale seen in the peer countries. When accounting for these factors, the gap is eliminated in the case of the equity and the private credit markets. However, the gap of some 15–20 percent remains for the private bond markets.

Rferences

  • Acemoglu Daron and Simon Johnson , 2005.“Unbundling Institutions,” Journal of Political Economy, 113 (5), pp. 949-95.

  • Baltagi Badi H., Panicos O. Demetriades, and Siong Hook Law , 2009. “Financial Development And Openness: Evidence From Panel Data,” Journal of Development Economics, 89 (2), pp. 285-96.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck Thorstenand Asli Demirgüç-Kunt , 2009. “Financial Institutions and Markets Across Countries and over Time: Data and Analysis,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4943.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck Thorsten, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Ross Levine , 2000. “A New Database on Financial Development and Structure,” World Bank Eceview, 14 (3), pp. 597-605.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck Thorsten, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Ross Levine , 2003a. “Law and finance: why does legal origin matter?Journal of Comparative Economics, 31 (4), pp. 653-75.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck Thorsten, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Ross Levine , 2003b. “Law, Endownments and Finance,” Journal of Financial Economics, 70 (2), pp. 13781.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bencivenga, Valerie R. and Bruce D. Smith , 1991, “Financial Intermediation and Endogenous Growth,” The Review of Economic Studies, 58 (2), pp. 196-209.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boyd John H., Ross Levine, and Bruce D. Smith , 2001. “The Impact of Inflation on Financial Sector Performance,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 47 (2), pp. 221-48.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chinn, Menzie D. and Hiro Ito , 2006. “What Matters for Financial Development? Capital Controls, Institutions, and Interactions,” Journal of Development Economics, 81 (1), pp. 163-92.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Choi, Sangmok, Brice D. Smith, and John H. Boyd , 1996. “Inflation, Financial Markets, and Capital Formation,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 78 (3), pp. 9-35.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Claessens, Stijn, Daniela Klingebiel, and Sergio L. Schmukler , 2006. “Stock Market Development and Internationalization: Do Economic Fundamentals Spur Both Similarly?Journal of Empirical Finance, 13 (3), pp. 316-350.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Do Quy-Toan and Andrei Levchenko, 2007.”Comparative Advantage, Demand for External Finance, and Financial Development,” Journal of Financial Economics, 86 (3), pp. 796-834.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Demetriades, Panicos O. and Khaled A. Hussein , 1996. “Does Financial Development Cause Economic Growth? Time-Series Evidence from 16 Countries,” Journal of Development Economics, 51 (2), pp. 387-411.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Djankov, Simeon, Caralee McLiesh, and Andrei Shleifer, 2007. “Private Credit in 129 Countries,” Journal of Financial Economics, 84 (2), pp. 299-329.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • El-Wassal, Kamal A. , 2005. “Understanding the Growth in Emerging Stock Markets,” Journal of Emerging Market Finance, 4 (3), pp. 227-261.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia, Valeriano F. and Lin Liu, 1999, “Macroeconomic Determinants of Stock Market Development,” Journal of Applied Economics, 2 (1), pp. 29-59.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goodhart, Charles A.E. (ed.), 2004. Financial Development and Economic Growth: Explaining the Links, Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke and New York.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greenwood, Jeremy and Boyan Jovanovic , 1990. “Financial Development, Growth, and the Distribution of Income,” Journal of Political Economy, 98 (5), pp. 1076-1107.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Huybens, Elisabeth and Bruce D. Smith , 1999. “Inflation, Financial Markets, and Long-Run Real Activity,” Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (2), pp. 283-315.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF, 2006. “Methodology for CGER Exchange Rate Assessments,” http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2006/110806.pdf

  • Kaufmann Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi , 2009. “Governance Matters VIII: Governance Indicators for 1996-2008,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4978.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., Abdelhak S. Senhadji, and Bruce D. Smith , 2006. “Inflation and Financial Depth,” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 10 (2), pp. 165-182.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny , 1997. “Legal Determinants of External Finance,” Journal of Finance, 52 (3), pp. 1131-1150.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, 2002. “Investor Protection and Corporate Valuation,” Journal of Finance, 57 (3), pp. 1147-1170.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, Ross . 1997. “Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda,” Journal of Economic Literature, 35 (2), pp. 688-726.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, Ross , 2003. “More on finance and growth: more finance, more growth?Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 85 (4), pp. 31-46.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, Ross and Sara Zervos , 1998. “Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth,” American Economic Review, 88 (2), pp. 537-58.

  • Rajan, Raghuram G. and Luigi Zingales , 2003. “The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial Development in the Twentieth Century,” Journal of Financial Economics, 69 (1), pp. 5-50.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roe Mark J. and Jordan I. Siegel , 2009. “Finance and Politics: A Review Essay Based on Kenneth Dam’s Analysis of Legal Traditions in The Law-Growth Nexus,” Journal of Economic Literature, 47 (3), pp. 781-800.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Singh, Ajit , 1997. “Stock Markets, Financial Liberalization and Economic Development,” Economic Journal, 107 (442), pp. 771-82.

  • Svaleryd, Helena and Jonas Vlachos , 2002. “Markets for risk and openness to trade: how are they related?Journal of International Economics, 57 (2), pp. 369-95.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

The authors would like to thank Mark De Broeck, Adam Gersl, Petr Hlavac, Dusan Hradil, Christoph Klingen, Amine Mati, Josef Mladek, James Morsink, Zuzana Murgasova, Damiano Sandri, and Financial System Development Division staff of the National Bank of Poland for useful comments and suggestions.

3

In particular, according to the IMF classification both the Czech Republic and the Slovak Republic have been advanced economies since 2008.

4

In fact, in the case of Poland and the Slovak Republic, the private bond market data are not even available from the database that we use.

5

Specifically, they argue that financial openness has beneficial effects for domestic capital markets only when institutions are sufficiently developed.

6

Legal theories of financial development are discussed extensively, for instance, in Beck et al. (2003a, 2003b).

7

April 2010 revision.

8

The sources include surveys of firms and individuals, assessments of commercial risk rating agencies, non governmental and multilateral aid agencies. For methodology, see Kaufmann et al. (2009).

9

Domestic debt securities constitute issues by residents in domestic currency targeted at resident investors.

10

The model, thus, is similar to cross-country macroeconomic benchmarking exercises used in the literature, e.g. the CGER methodology for exchange rate assessment based on the macroeconomic balance approach (IMF, 2006).

11

When splitting countries into the OECD and non-OECD subsamples, we observe steeper trend lines for the former.

12

The fixed effects estimations are hampered by the nature of some explanatory variables—they exhibit low variability over time with most variation along the cross-country dimension and thus, estimation yields inconsistent results. Moreover, fixed effects estimation assumes idiosyncratic time-invariant effects for each country, which conceptually does not fit well into the benchmarking approach as we attempt to understand common patterns across countries for a common benchmark.

13

In Tables 7-9, column (1) corresponds to one of the regressions in Tables 4-6 respectively, while column (2) presents results of the same regression but with real GDP per capita dropped.