Consolidated Regulation and Supervision in the United States
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: abhatia@imf.org

This paper builds on a Technical Note produced as part of the IMF’s 2010 Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) review of the United States. It addresses enterprise-wide oversight of financial groups, a key tool to mitigate systemic risk. Focusing on legal arrangements, it recommends eliminating exceptions for holding companies owning certain limited-purpose banks, harmonizing arrangements for bank and thrift holding companies, and bringing into the net a few systemic nonbank financial groups, with the Federal Reserve as the sole consolidated regulator and supervisor.

Abstract

This paper builds on a Technical Note produced as part of the IMF’s 2010 Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) review of the United States. It addresses enterprise-wide oversight of financial groups, a key tool to mitigate systemic risk. Focusing on legal arrangements, it recommends eliminating exceptions for holding companies owning certain limited-purpose banks, harmonizing arrangements for bank and thrift holding companies, and bringing into the net a few systemic nonbank financial groups, with the Federal Reserve as the sole consolidated regulator and supervisor.

I. Introduction And Context

1. Regulatory and supervisory failures and gaps rank high among the causes of the global financial crisis of 2007–09. This is now widely accepted, not least by the U.S. Administration, the Congress, the Fed, and the financial regulatory agencies.

2. Reforms to financial regulation and supervision thus form a major part of the post-crisis policy response. Building on detailed proposals and legislative language tabled by the Administration in 2009, the Congress passed, and President Obama signed into law, the Dodd–Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010. The FSAP team was highly supportive of the reform effort, weighing in on priorities and advocating, where merited in its view, for even bolder action.

3. A key focus of the reforms is on arrangements to better mitigate systemic risk. Broadly defined, systemic risk is the risk that the actions of one financial intermediary, or set of similar placed financial intermediaries, will adversely affect others in the system and thence the economy at large—at best, through the formation of macro-significant asset price bubbles in good times; at worst, by triggering asset fire sales and funding panics in crises.

4. The Congress has established a Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC) to serve as the “systemic risk regulator. Constituted as a council of the Treasury, the Fed, and essentially all of the federal financial regulatory agencies, this FSOC is to be the apex decision-making body on matters of financial stability, with member agencies expected to execute its information-gathering, analytical, supervisory, and regulatory directives.

5. Key to the success of this principle–agent construct will be a strong role for the Fed as “lead executor” of the FSOC. Not only is the Fed uniquely qualified to take on this responsibility, given its monetary policy and lender-of-last-resort duties and associated skill sets, it is also uniquely equipped with the tools needed to execute it, given its longstanding consolidated supervisory authorities over bank holding companies (BHCs).

6. With consolidated supervision providing a powerful means of influencing behavior ex ante, the FSAP team views it as a key tool for systemic risk mitigation. The outgoing U.S. regulatory system had three federal consolidated supervisors: the Fed, the OTS, and the SEC. This note discusses how to strengthen that architecture, concluding—as the Congress has—that there should be only one consolidated supervisor: the Fed.

II. Regulation, System Structure, and the Role of Conglomerates

7. The structure of the U.S. financial system reflects the forces of regulation and taxation on the one hand, and innovation and regulatory arbitrage on the other. In many respects, the basic contours drawn during the Great Depression persist to this day. These include a Congressionally mandated separation of banking from full-scope securities underwriting and commerce, and the notion of retail deposit-taking institutions as a special type of firm meriting access to Fed standing facilities and federal deposit insurance—the federal financial safety net—with the attendant moral hazard sought to be offset by especially stringent regulation and supervision, complemented wherever possible by market discipline.

8. The key delivery vehicle for market discipline was and is uninsured funding. The justification for the lighter emphasis on direct supervisory “command and control” of financial intermediaries outside the federal safety net was that they, unlike the commercial banks, savings institutions, and credit unions within, did not benefit directly from government support, and were thus subject to the (harsher) strictures of sophisticated creditors, counterparties, and credit rating agencies, as reflected in the cost and availability of funding. To the extent that depositories chose to supplement their federally insured deposit bases with uninsured funds, they too were viewed as coming under what Chairman Bernanke has called the “invisible hand” of market discipline, as a complement to supervision. Safety-and-soundness oversight was intended to limit—not eliminate—the risk of failure, the specter of which was seen as an essential precondition for the proper functioning of the markets.

9. As reliance on market funding increased over time, the visible hand of regulation reached a smaller share of the system. Wholesale funding activity was spurred by many factors, including liberalizations of regulatory policy, advances in technology (notably computers), a quest by financial intermediaries for size and market power, and a search for yield that led many retail savers to choose investments over bank deposits and many intermediaries to choose trading activities over end-user lending. These factors, and an undercurrent of regulatory arbitrage that tended to drive financial business toward less- or unregulated spaces, fuelled rapid growth in derivatives, securitization, and the originate-to-sell paradigm, giving rise to a so-called “shadow banking system.”

10. Thus were the lines drawn that shaped the world’s most complex financial sector. As stressed recently by New York Fed President Dudley, the sector truly is a system, bringing together a unique diversity of actors, each type regulated differently, each with its own portfolio preferences. Indeed, it is precisely this heterogeneity that allows transactions to flourish—one side long, the other short, buying, selling, hedging, and price-discovering.

11. Today, this system can be divided into three broad segments (Figure 1):

  • The government-supported core. This consists of federally insured depository institutions and, with a different set of privileges, the housing government sponsored enterprises (GSEs). These financial firms, together still the most influential in the system, are subject to safety-and-soundness regulation and supervision and dedicated resolution schemes that exempt them from the automatic stay of the U.S. Bankruptcy Code while imposing prompt corrective action requirements:

    • To reiterate, depositories are “special” because public policy has made them so; to quote Chairman Greenspan, “The real difference between banks and [other financial firms] is the difference we have made for banks.” They, and they alone, enjoy all three privileges of the safety net: the ability to place deposits at the Fed and settle through the Fedwire Funds Service; to borrow from the Fed through the discount window; and to accept deposits insured by the FDIC or the National Credit Union Administration (NCUA). There were 6,622 FDIC-insured commercial banks, 1,138 FDIC-insured savings institutions, and 10 FDIC-insured branches of foreign banks in the system as of end-September 2010, and 7,445 NCUA-insured credit unions as of end-June. By number, the vast majority of these depositories are community or regional institutions.

    • Although their share of U.S. financial sector assets has fallen from about one-half in 1980 to close to one-fifth currently, federally insured depository institutions remain key players in many areas. Given the prevalence of originate-to-sell activities in recent years, metrics based on asset size (even with off-balance sheet assets) do not capture the totality of depository institution influence in the intermediation process. Indeed, some of the best data on “what banks do” (especially big banks) are in the noninterest income section of their financial statements, providing a window into activities ranging from bundling and servicing to trading and wealth management.

    • The housing GSEs, in turn, owe their privileges to their Congressional charters, which, inter alia, classify securities they issue or guarantee as “exempt securities” under the Securities Act of 1933, making them eligible for settlement through the Fedwire Securities Service, use by the Fed in open market operations, and special treatment across a range of financial regulations. The share of U.S. financial sector assets owned or guaranteed by the three housing GSEs—Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Bank system—has doubled from about one-twentieth in 1980 to over one-tenth currently, with GSE mortgage backed securities accounting for essentially all residential mortgage securitization in the system post-crisis.

  • The shadow banking system. This is usually taken to include mortgage brokers and finance companies, private-label asset backed security (ABS) and asset backed commercial paper issuers, structured investment vehicles (SIVs), money market funds, securities broker-dealers and futures commission merchants, derivative product companies, hedge funds, holding companies, and any other types of financial entities engaged in leveraged maturity transformation outside the federal financial safety net. The share of U.S. financial sector assets owned by these intermediaries has increased from about one-tenth in 1980 to about one-quarter currently:

    • Wholesale funded by definition, these entities form in essence a secured short-term funding chain—through repurchase and security lending transactions—with collateral often substituting for due diligence on counterparties. Most entities in the chain are actively managed and, if they default, are subject to the automaticity of the Bankruptcy Code. Money market mutual funds must inter alia obey Rule 2a-7 of the Investment Company Act of 1940, which is intended to support their stability (they are thus often referred to as “2a-7 funds”), but are not subject to daily onsite supervision of the sort applied to big wholesale-funded banks. Securities broker-dealers and futures commission merchants are subject to a comprehensive regulatory framework that includes a net liquid assets standard that protects creditors in addition to customers and is designed to minimize harm to the securities markets; the standard requires liquid assets to exceed all liabilities, i.e., that there be net capital, in order for the entity to self-liquidate without the need for a formal bankruptcy proceeding. Hedge funds are unregulated, with their investment advisors required neither to register nor to report (though many are CFTC-registered commodity pool operators).

    • ABS pools are, in many senses, the keystone of this shadow system, the special purpose vehicles for a technology that transforms illiquid loans into tradable (if not always traded) securities. At their pre-crisis peak, they held over one-fifteenth of U.S. financial sector assets. What makes them unique is their corporate structure: typically set up in the legal form of a trust, with no controlling shareholders and no dedicated management or staff; engineered to have carefully delimited decision-making power; owning often-opaque portfolios of self-liquidating assets that by their terms may not be actively managed; and issuing liabilities “softened” to avoid formal events of default (replaced by provisions such as “early amortization”) and thus to not invoke the provisions of the Bankruptcy Code. These are the ultimate “robot” intermediaries, a reality that remains under-appreciated.

  • The “real money” periphery. The third and final broad segment of the U.S. financial system consists of pension funds, mutual funds, commodity pool operators, and a raft of other types of collective investment schemes that tend to have little or no leverage and are subject to conduct-of-business rules (but not safety-and-soundness requirements) and to the Bankruptcy Code. Insurance companies arguably also belong in this broad category, because they too tend to have limited leverage (but are subject to some safety-and-soundness requirements and are resolved under state-level carve outs from the Bankruptcy Code). The asset share of this “periphery” has consistently remained at over one-third of the system since 1980.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

United States: Financial System Structure and the Role of Holding Companies, 1952–2010

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2011, 023; 10.5089/9781455211920.001.A001

Sources: Fed, Bank Holding Company Performance Reports (FR Y-9C data) and Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States (Z.1 data); and Fund staff estimates.

12. The U.S. “regulatory perimeter” may thus be stylized as two concentric circles. The inner ring encircles the depositories and the housing GSEs; these firms are subject to intensive, hands-on, safety-and-soundness regulation and supervision as well as consumer protection, investor protection, and access-to-finance rules. The outer ring encircles all other types of regulated financial entities (including insurers, real money investors, and many “shadow banks”); these firms are regulated in that they must obey consumer and investor protection rules, but generally not supervised under an explicit safety-and-soundness mandate. Outside the outer ring, certain private pools of capital (e.g., derivative product companies and hedge funds) and instruments (e.g., credit derivatives and “144A” securities marketed only to “qualified institutional buyers,” the latter including many private-label ABSs) have been left entirely unregulated.

13. Financial groups can and do straddle both these perimeters. These networks may bring together insured depositories, securities broker-dealers, futures commission merchants, insurers, servicers, managed funds, ABS pools, derivative product companies, and other types of legally distinct entities under centralized enterprise-wide management, to serve one franchise, even if in ways not always visible in the formal group structure. Here one enters a world of “implicit recourse” and operational and reputational risks, where to “sponsor” an SIV or “operate” a hedge fund may rest not on beneficial ownership but on similar brand names, cross-selling, and game-theoretical commitments to provide mutual support. A large—and previously under-appreciated—share of the U.S. financial system is controlled, in one way or another, by a few key holding companies.

14. Much of the systemic risk that has manifested during this crisis has arisen from a few large complex groups. Systemic risk may flow from one or several legal entities formally or informally within the group structure, regulated or unregulated, at home or abroad—or (as with franchise value) from the interactions between the many moving parts. Yet, when large complex groups face funding difficulty, they tend to fail as one, at speed, with systemic impact. All of the most consequential U.S. crisis interventions—Bear Stearns, American International Group (AIG), the Capital Purchase Program, the Temporary Liquidity Guarantee Program, etc.—thus included provisions of federal support at the ultimate holding company level. Indeed, it is this recognition of the “shared destiny” of legally separate entities within a group structure that motivated landmark reforms to create a consolidated resolution mechanism for systemic groups (as discussed in the U.S. FSAP’s Technical Note on Crisis Management Arrangements; IMF Country Report No. 10/120).

15. In the event, uninsured funding, the presumed enforcer of market discipline, was first underpriced, then flighty—calling for better regulatory oversight. Small banks funded predominantly by federally insured deposits were more likely to suffer capital-related regulatory intervention than liquidity failure: deposit insurance worked. But large BHCs with significant short-term uninsured funding, and essentially all of the shadow banking system, proved deeply vulnerable to institutional runs. These runs were a herd response, against a backdrop of chronic data gaps—on counterparties and collateral, especially in the derivative and unregistered ABS realms—and came after a prolonged period of poorly managed risk-taking. Thus not only did regulation and supervision fall short, so too did market discipline—underscoring the need for more effective oversight going forward.

III. U.S. Consolidated Regulatory and Supervisory Arrangements

16. Consolidated supervision is the form of financial sector oversight that best mirrors how financial intermediaries are managed in practice. The emphasis on group-level interactions in a sense “peers through the corporate veil” of the de jure separation of affiliated firms, to the enterprise-wide risk management that controls them from the holding company level. Organizationally, all U.S. consolidated oversight programs have involved multiple regulators working together, with the consolidated supervisor as the nodal point, vested with critical powers to inspect any entity within the group, regulated or not.

17. The United States has a longstanding system of consolidated regulation and supervision, albeit one that has been highly bank-centric. In principle, all holding companies that own insured depositories, no matter how large or small, are regulated and supervised. BHCs have been under the Fed since 1956, and savings and loan holding companies (SLHCs) under the OTS (previously the Federal Home Loan Bank Board) since 1967. There were 4,861 BHCs and 436 SLHCs in the system as of end-September 2010. Statutorily, the oversight programs for BHCs and SLHCs have had a single-point mandate: to protect the safety and soundness of federally insured depositories within the group. Indeed, there is a “source of strength” doctrine, codifying supervisory expectations that holding companies stand ready to support their insured depository subsidiaries.

18. There are, however, several important statutory gaps in this system, which undermine its effectiveness. Over the years, Congress created a labyrinth of activity restrictions, exceptions, and grandfathering arrangements. These reflected the legacy of the Glass–Steagall Acts of 1933–34, periodic regulatory changes, competitive equality and other industry concerns, and a tendency to diffuse regulatory responsibility and power. They also reflected a predilection to reform by quid pro quo, e.g., by liberalizing activity restrictions while tightening supervisory requirements, and so on. The main complexities have been:

  • Exceptions to BHC status. Both unitary and multibank BHCs are required to limit their business to banking and activities “closely related to banking.” But thrifts and certain limited-purpose banks—industrial loan companies (ILCs) chartered in only a few states, credit card banks, trust companies, and “nonbank banks,” several of which themselves are products of grandfathering clauses in the Competitive Equality Banking Act of 1987—are deemed not to be banks for the purposes of the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956, such that companies that own them are not BHCs and are exempt from both BHC activity restrictions and Fed oversight. All of the former “big five” U.S. investment banking groups availed of this exemption to own both FDIC-insured depositories and significant commercial interests without having to come under the consolidated regulation and supervision of the Fed.

  • Exceptions to SLHC activity restrictions. SLHCs are subject to activity restrictions substantially similar to those applicable to BHCs. But companies that have owned a single insured thrift since before the passage of the Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act of 1999 are grandfathered under the preexisting provisions for unitary SLHCs and thus exempt from SLHC activity restrictions (but not OTS oversight). Several of the former “big five” investment banking groups availed of this exemption also, as did a few other large financial conglomerates (e.g., AIG and GMAC) as well as several of the largest (predominantly) nonfinancial firms in the country (e.g., GE and John Deere). These commercial firms created regulatory and supervisory challenges for the OTS that the Fed has not faced, notably, the impracticality of imposing consolidated prudential requirements on a (predominantly) nonfinancial group. As a result, SLHCs have not been subject to any consolidated capital floor (although case-by-case capital adequacy reviews form a part of SLHC examinations).

  • The financial holding company (FHC) construct. In its famous repeal of the Glass–Steagall Act of 1933, the Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act created a new type of BHC known as the FHC, with permissible business expanded to include activities determined to be “financial in nature or incidental to such” or “complementary to a financial activity”—thus allowing the full-scope affiliation of banking, securities broker-dealing, and insurance underwriting. Only BHCs whose depository subsidiaries were all classified as “well-capitalized” and “well-managed” could elect to become FHCs, with the Fed as the “umbrella supervisor” of all FHCs. In this role, however, the Fed was directed to defer “to the fullest extent possible” to functional regulators of nondepository affiliates (the SEC, the CFTC, and the states) and to not examine such firms unless it had “reasonable cause to believe” they posed “material risk” to insured depository affiliates. There were 512 FHCs in the system as of end-September 2010.

19. The history of U.S. consolidated supervision of investment banks is even more complex. Here, the focus has been on securities broker-dealers within the group, despite the fact that there are no safety-and-soundness requirements per se for such firms: Rule 15c3-1 of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (the “net capital rule”), which is the key regulation governing SEC-registered broker-dealers, merely seeks to “protect customers and other market participants from broker-dealer failures and to enable those [securities broker-dealers]…to liquidate in an orderly fashion without the need for a formal proceeding or financial assistance from the Securities Investor Protection Corporation.” There were two consolidated protocols, both elective:

  • The supervised investment bank holding company (SIBHC) program. The GLBA amended the Exchange Act to create a new type of broker-dealer holding company known as the SIBHC, with the proviso that such firms could not own any FDIC-insured depository, including those limited-purpose banks excluded from the definition of bank under the Bank Holding Company Act. Eligible holding companies could elect to become SIBHCs, with the SEC as consolidated supervisor. Analogous to the restrictions on Fed umbrella supervision of FHCs, however, the SEC was directed to defer “to the fullest extent possible” to the functional regulators (e.g., the CFTC and the states) and self-regulatory organizations (e.g., the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority and the National Futures Association) of the subsidiaries, and to restrict its examinations of the holding company and its affiliates to assessing risks that could have a “materially adverse effect” on securities broker-dealers within the group. There was only ever one SIBHC (Lazard).

  • The consolidated supervised entity (CSE) program. The statutory arrangements above left two of the former “big five” U.S. investment bank holding companies (Bear Stearns and Goldman Sachs) with no consolidated host supervisor. These firms owned a trust company and a Utah-chartered ILC, respectively, but no thrift, and thus were not BHCs or SLHCs nor were eligible to become SIBHCs. When the European Parliament promulgated its Directive 2002/87/EC requiring financial conglomerates operating in the European Economic Area to have a consolidated home or host supervisor beginning in 2005, the SEC responded by creating a nonstatutory regime. This, the CSE program, involved two new appendices to Rule 15c3-1 (one of which defines a value at risk-based “alternative net capital rule” with a Basel capital computation) which were intended to improve oversight of large securities broker-dealers and provide incentives for them to implement strong risk management practices; the program also involved certain prudential requirements at the holding company level (including two liquidity standards). All of the “big five” U.S. investment banking groups became CSEs.

20. These arrangements underlined the difficulties of operating in an environment of multiple, overlapping regulatory regimes, with insufficient statutory guidance:

  • Neither the SIBHC nor the CSE program imposed activity restrictions (nor do the various rules that apply directly to registered securities broker-dealers impose affiliation restrictions);

  • The CSE program, in seeking to be a protocol tailored specifically to large investment banking groups, resorted to absolute capital norms that required participating holding companies to own at least one securities broker-dealer with net capital and “tentative net capital” of not less than $500 million and $1 billion, respectively (and introduced a $5 billion early warning requirement for tentative net capital)—and, as the value at risk-based alternative net capital rule provided relief, these became the binding floors;

  • Whereas the alternative net capital rule was not an option for securities broker-dealers owned by SIBHCs (moot as Lazard has no proprietary positions), it was available to all other securities broker-dealers that met its absolute capital thresholds and all other requirements imposed by the rule—several broker-dealers owned by FHCs (e.g., JPMorgan Chase and Citigroup) opted in; and

  • Whereas the CSE program recognized “the comprehensive, consolidated supervision” of the Fed and so exempted FHCs from SEC consolidated oversight, it drew no such equivalency with the supervisory regime for SLHCs—three of the “big five” investment banking groups were supervised by both the SEC and the OTS, with coordination between the two agencies being minimal, a point noted by the Government Accountability Office (GAO).

IV. Outcomes, Reform Proposals, and Risks

21. The SLHC and CSE programs were weak points during the crisis. Despite the CSE program having borrowed from well-established capital standards used by numerous regulators, the unprecedented stress of the crisis had harsh results for the CSEs: two had to be acquired by FHCs (Bear Stearns by JPMorgan Chase and Merrill Lynch by Bank of America); two converted their limited-purpose bank subsidiaries into “regular” commercial banks and so became FHCs in haste (Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley); and one collapsed with systemic impact (Lehman Brothers). Among the major SLHCs, one was taken over by an FHC (Countrywide, by Bank of America); one was resolved at no cost to the Deposit Insurance Fund (Washington Mutual, bought by JPMorgan Chase); and one was bailed out (AIG). In its annual Article IV Selected Issues papers on the United States for 2007 (IMF Country Report No. 07/265) the IMF had suggested the CSEs be reconfigured as FHCs; in the event this did occur, and the CSE program was wound up.

22. Supervision of the risk-management processes of some of the largest, most complex groups in the system proved a serious challenge for the OTS and the SEC. In the case of the OTS, the absence of consolidated capital requirements proved a handicap, as did the agency’s small size and relatively heavy budgetary reliance on supervisory assessments paid by a few large institutions (though it bears noting that the OTS had reserves to support its operations for several years without reliance on what were the largest thrift institutions at the time). In the case of the SEC, it was a combination of a mission that stresses ex post enforcement over ex ante prudential guidance and the nonstatutory nature of the CSE program (which meant that, ultimately, the only binding enforcement action at the holding company level was disqualification from the program, with potentially serious ramifications for business conducted in Europe).

23. Fed umbrella supervision also fell short, but remained the most robust among the various group-level arrangements. The program stresses continuous onsite supervisory interaction with the holding company and its depository subsidiaries, with procedures laid out in an extraordinarily detailed supervisory manual. Nonetheless, revealed fragilities at a few large and diversified FHCs point to a need for more muscular oversight, especially in the form of more, and more effective, examinations of nonbank affiliates. In part, the paucity of such examinations was as directed by the “functional deference” clauses of the GLBA; but it also reflected the light touch reserved for firms outside the safety net, with the Fed concerned that overt interactions might create unwanted perceptions of federal support (a “halo effect”). As the Fed opened a tap facility to primary dealers during the crisis, however, it also began to directly examine them—a practice the FSAP team supported memorializing in law.

24. Appropriately, therefore, U.S. reforms seek to build upon the FHC program (Appendix Table 1). The Dodd–Frank Act leaves in place only one consolidated regulator, with the Fed to cover holding companies that own FDIC-insured depositories as well as holding companies that own no depositories but are considered potentially systemic; the latter set of firms, as well as “large, interconnected BHCs” (with group assets of $50 billion or more), are to be held to higher standards focused on systemic risk. The Administration had pushed for exceptions for limited-purpose banks and unitary grandfathered thrifts to be closed—with FSAP interlocutors stressing that past grandfathering arrangements were by Congressional choice, not constitutional compulsion—but here the Act merely imposes a moratorium on new charters for and ownership transfers of limited-purpose banks, pending the findings of a GAO review, and preserves unitary grandfathered thrifts. The unification of consolidated oversight at the Fed is welcome, but the exceptions are a disappointment.

25. There are risks, however, in identifying firms as systemic. Even if public designation had been avoidable (which the Act rejects), the inclusion of nonbank groups in a program populated mostly by depository institution holding companies would have been visible, and would have risked cementing market expectations of possible federal support for them in times of duress. Equally, the specter of large, leveraged, and interconnected conglomerates with no depository subsidiaries being left unsupervised—or of firms that are FHCs divesting such subsidiaries to escape supervision—was and is unacceptable:

  • A third option might have been to cast a much wider net—say, to include all holding companies owning FDIC-insured depositories, securities broker-dealers, or futures commission merchants—and to thereby have allowed the consolidated supervisor to concentrate on systemic groups (with or without FDIC-insured depository institution subsidiaries) while not automatically identifying them; this would have been analogous to the current system in which all BHCs are supervised by the Fed while its risk-based focus is on the largest and most complex amongst them. Such an approach, however, would potentially have brought a large number of nonsystemic nondepository holding companies under the Fed.

  • A variant of this third option, then, might have been to resort to some size threshold, along the lines of that created for BHCs in the Act—those with group assets of $50 billion or more to be automatically held to higher standards focused on systemic risk—to limit the number of nondepository groups swept into the supervisory net. Several FSAP interlocutors pointed out, however, that this too had the potential to create a self-defeating halo effect. The final legislation includes a system to designate nondepository holding companies as potentially systemic, and thence to bring them under the consolidated supervision of the Fed, subject to an appeals process. This, while perhaps not the conceptual first-best, is a good outcome.

V. Recommendations and Conclusion

26. In sum, the first-best recommendation for U.S. consolidated regulation and supervision was (is) to pursue the following seven goals:

  • To have one, and only one, federal program of consolidated regulation and supervision, grounded in statute and housed at the Fed;

  • To cover in this program all holding companies that own one or more FDIC-insured depository institutions, regardless of charter type and without exception, plus any other financial firms deemed jointly by the Fed and FSOC to be potentially systemic;

  • To give this program the dual mandate of supporting the safety and soundness of the covered groups individually and mitigating systemic risk they create collectively;

  • To impose and require the Fed to enforce strict activity restrictions on groups covered by this program, prohibiting them from engaging in most commercial activities;

  • To require the Fed, through this program, to impose and enforce prudential norms at the consolidated level, with a system of mandatory supervisory actions, and to subject the largest and most interconnected of the covered groups to stricter standards;

  • To authorize the Fed, through this program, to impose additional requirements on any regulated or unregulated subsidiary, with due attention to regulatory differences by type of firm, softening but not eliminating deference requirements; and

  • To vest the Fed, through this program, with additional, discretionary enforcement authorities, up to and including orders to divest business lines or subsidiaries.

27. Even with severalbut by no means allof these objectives met, financial sector oversight in the United States has taken a significant step forward. Having one, and only one, program of consolidated regulation and supervision, enshrined in law and housed at the Fed, creates a robust organizational framework around which to build a new generation of prudential requirements and risk-management controls. Financial conglomerates, especially those that are large and complex, are managed at the enterprise level. Appropriately, U.S. regulatory and supervisory arrangements are continuing to adapt to reflect this.

28. Even so, difficult implementation issues lie ahead. The U.S. system has long accepted the principle of consolidated regulation and supervision of groups including federally insured depositories. Extending that system, now, to systemic nonbank consortia poses a key challenge. Not only must group-level supervision be effective, so too must be the group-level regulations that, per Chairman Greenspan, “prescribe and proscribe what must be done and what may not be done in specific areas” and so set the parameters for leverage and liquidity. Getting these right, in terms of melding rules conceived for banks with those for broker-dealers or insurers with very different business models and risk profiles, will not be easy. Similarly, on the supervisory side, the Fed will need to reallocate resources from the banking to the securities and other nonbanking operations of the groups that it oversees.

29. Ultimately, consolidated supervision will remain but one part of the regulatory armory. Arguably, no matter how muscular the group-level supervisor, entity-level regulation will remain the “coal face,” the place where sectoral regulatory expertise meets industry reality. Plus there will always be the tail risk of potentially systemic players slipping through the consolidated supervisory net—a standalone hedge fund perhaps, or some AIG Financial Products-type derivative company. Thus the regulatory system will continue to require not just robust consolidated supervision, but also careful, case-by-case consideration of the appropriate regulatory treatment of all financial intermediaries by legal form. Although a full discussion falls well beyond the scope of this note, it is worth observing, in closing, that this is currently most relevant to certain “bank-like” entities in the shadow system.

Glossary

ABS

Asset backed security

AIG

Amercan International Group

BHC

Banking holding company

CFTC

Commodity Futures Trading Commission

CSE

Consolidated supervised entity

FDIC

Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation

Fed

Federal Reserve

FHC

Financial holding company

FSAP

Financial Sector Assessment Program

FSOC

Financial Stability Oversight Council

GAO

Government Accountability Office

GSE

Government sponsored enterprise

ILC

Industrial loan company

NCUA

National Credit Union Administration

OCC

Office of the Comptroller of the Currency

OTS

Office of Thrift Supervision

QFC

Qualified financial contract

SEC

Securities and Exchange Commission

SIBHC

Supervised investment bank holding company

SIV

Structured investment vehicle

SLHC

Savings and loan holding company

SSHC

Supervised securities holding company

t1FHC

Tier 1 financial holding company

References

  • Bernanke, B.S., 2007a, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Financial Regulation and the Invisible Hand,” Remarks at the New York University Law School (April 11).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhatia, A.V., 2007, New Landscape, New Challenges: Structural Change and Regulation in the U.S. Financial Sector,” in United States—Selected Issues, pp. 1536, IMF Country Report 07/265 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • DeFerrari, L.M., and D.E. Palmer, 2001, “Supervision of Large Complex Banking Organizations,” in Federal Reserve Bulletin (February), pp. 4757.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Nicoló, G., P. Hayward, and A.V. Bhatia, 2004, “U.S. Large Complex Banking Groups: Business Strategies, Risks, and Surveillance Issues,” in United States—Selected Issues, IMF Country Report 04/228, pp. 7286 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dudley, W.C., 2009, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, “More lessons from the crisis,” Remarks at the Center for Economic Policy Studies Symposium, Princeton, New Jersey (November 13).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Federal Register, 2004a, “Alternative Net Capital Requirements for Broker-Dealers That Are Part of Consolidated Supervised Entities; Final Rule,” Part II, Volume 69, No. 118 (June 21)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Federal Register, 2004b, “Supervised Investment Bank Holding Companies; Final Rule,” Part II, Volume 69, No. 118 (June 21)

  • Gorton, G.B., and N.S. Souleles, 2007, “Special Purpose Vehicles and Securitization,” in The Risks of Financial Institutions, pp. 549602 (University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Government Accountability Office, 2007, Report to Congressional Committees, “Agencies Engaged in Consolidated Supervision Can Strengthen Performance Measurement and Collaboration,” GAO-07-154 (March).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greenspan, A., 2005, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Bank Regulation,” Remarks at the Independent Community Bankers of America National Convention (March 11).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2010a, United States: Publication of Financial Sector Assessment Program Documentation—Technical Note on Crisis Management Arrangements, IMF Country Report 10/120 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2010b, United States: Publication of Financial Sector Assessment Program Documentation—Financial System Stability Assessment, IMF Country Report 10/247 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2010c, United States: Publication of Financial Sector Assessment Program Documentation—Reports on Observance of Standards and Codes, IMF Country Report 10/250 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2010d, United States: Publication of Financial Sector Assessment Program Documentation—Technical Note on Consolidated Regulation and Supervision, IMF Country Report 10/251 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Library of Congress, 1933a, “Banking Act of 1933.”

  • Library of Congress, 1933b, “Home Owners’ Loan Act of 1933.”

  • Library of Congress, 1933c, “Securities Act of 1933.”

  • Library of Congress, 1934, “Securities Exchange Act of 1934.”

  • Library of Congress, 1940, “Investment Company Act of 1940.”

  • Library of Congress, 1956, “Bank Holding Company Act of 1956.”

  • Library of Congress, 1967, “Savings and Loan Holding Company Act of 1967.”

  • Library of Congress, 1987, “Competitive Equality Banking Act of 1987,” H.R. 27.ENR, Enrolled Bill, August 10.

  • Library of Congress, 1999, “Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act of 1999,” S. 900.ENR, Enrolled Bill, November 12.

  • Library of Congress, 2010a, “Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2009,” H.R. 4173.RFS, Referred in Senate, January 20.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Library of Congress, 2010b, “Restoring American Financial Stability Act of 2010,” H.R. 4173.PP, Public Print, May 27.

  • Library of Congress, 2010c, “Dodd–Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010,” H.R. 4173.ENR, Enrolled Bill, July 15.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States Department of the Treasury, 2009, “Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation,” white paper, June 17.

  • White House, Office of the Press Secretary, 2010, “President Obama Calls for New Restrictions on Size and Scope of Financial Institutions to Rein in Excesses and Protect Taxpayers,” statements and releases, January 21.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

Appendix Table 1.

United States: Key Financial Stability Proposals and Outcomes

(As of July 21, 2010)

article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
Sources: Administration proposals: United States Department of the Treasury, 2009, “Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation,” white paper, June 17; and White House, Office of the Press Secretary, 2010, “President Obama Calls for New Restrictions on Size and Scope of Financial Institutions to Rein in Excesses and Protect Taxpayers,” statements and releases, January 21. House-passed bill: Library of Congress, 2010, “Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2009,” H.R. 4173.RFS, Referred in Senate, January 20. Senate-passed substitute: Library of Congress, 2010, “Restoring American Financial Stability Act of 2010,” H.R. 4173.PP, Public Print, May 27. Final House- and Senate-passed bill: Library of Congress, 2010, “Dodd–Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010,” H.R. 4173.ENR, Enrolled Bill, July 15.
1

The author thanks Nicholas Le Pan (IMF Consultant and former Superintendent of Financial Institutions of Canada) and Aditya Narain (Division Chief, Monetary and Capital Markets Department, IMF) for thoughtfully reviewing the U.S. FSAP Technical Note on Consolidated Regulation and Supervision (IMF Country Report No. 10/251) upon which this paper builds; the U.S. authorities for providing meticulous comments on that Note; and Sean Cogliardi (Strategy, Policy, and Review Department, IMF) for able research assistance.

Consolidated Regulation and Supervision in the United States
Author: Mr. Ashok Vir Bhatia