Resource Windfalls and Emerging Market Sovereign Bond Spreads
The Role of Political Institutions
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: rarezki@imf.org; markus.bruckner@upf.edu

We examine the effect that revenue windfalls from international commodity price shocks have on sovereign bond spreads using panel data for 30 emerging market economies during the period 1997-2007. Our main finding is that positive commodity price shocks lead to a significant reduction in the sovereign bond spread in democracies, but to a significant increase in the spread in autocracies. To explain our finding we show that, consistent with the political economy literature on the resource curse, revenue windfalls from international commodity price shocks significantly increased real per capita GDP growth in democracies, while in autocracies GDP per capita growth decreased.

Abstract

We examine the effect that revenue windfalls from international commodity price shocks have on sovereign bond spreads using panel data for 30 emerging market economies during the period 1997-2007. Our main finding is that positive commodity price shocks lead to a significant reduction in the sovereign bond spread in democracies, but to a significant increase in the spread in autocracies. To explain our finding we show that, consistent with the political economy literature on the resource curse, revenue windfalls from international commodity price shocks significantly increased real per capita GDP growth in democracies, while in autocracies GDP per capita growth decreased.

I. Introduction

Some researchers have argued that international commodity price booms may spawn an over-accumulation of external debt in commodity exporting countries that increases the risk of external debt default (e.g. Krueger, 1987; Berg and Sachs, 1988).2 We examine this hypothesis empirically by analyzing how the spread on sovereign bonds reacted in these countries to the booms and slumps of the export-relevant commodity prices. Changes in the spread on sovereign bonds reflect changes in investors’ beliefs of the risk that a country defaults on its external debt. An increase in the spread on sovereign bonds is in turn a cost for the bond issuing country that may trigger in a self-fulfilling way the default on its external debt. Both for investors and policy makers, it is therefore important to have knowledge about how international commodity price shocks, which induce large upturns and downturns in foreign currency revenues in emerging market economies, affect the spread on sovereign bonds.

We find that increases in international commodity prices for exported commodity goods are associated with a significant reduction in sovereign bond spreads on average. However, the reduction in the spread on sovereign bonds is particularly large in countries with sound democratic institutions and strong political checks and balances. In autocratic regimes and countries where the political rule is characterized by weak checks and balances, windfalls from international commodity prices lead to a significant increase in the spread on sovereign bonds.

The heterogeneous response of sovereign bond spreads to international commodity price shocks sheds new light on the resource curse literature, that has argued for the importance of political institutions in determining whether windfalls from natural resources are a curse or a blessing for the economic development of resource exporting countries (e.g. Melhum et al., 2006; Robinson et al., 2006). We provide further evidence in this direction by showing that, consistent with the political economy model developed in Mehlum et al. (2006), positive international commodity price shocks significantly increased real per capita GDP growth in countries with sound democratic institutions. In countries with autocratic institutions, revenue windfalls from international commodity price shocks led to a significant decrease in output growth. Hence, while our empirical results are consistent with general equilibrium models that predict a countercyclical relationship between sovereign bond spreads and the business cycle in emerging market economies (e.g. Arellano, 2008), our results highlight the importance of political economy factors in shaping the relationship between commodity price shocks and sovereign bond spreads in these countries.

The remainder of our paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 discusses the estimation strategy. Section 4 presents the main results. Section 5 concludes.

II. Data

We constructed a country-specific international commodity price index that captures revenue windfalls from international prices of exported commodities as:

Com  PriceShocki, t=cCθi,cΔ log(Com  Pricec,t)

where ComPricec,t is the international price of commodity c in year t, and θi,c is the average (time-invariant) value of exports of commodity c in the GDP of country i. Annual international commodity price data are from UNCTAD Commodity Statistics, and data on the value of commodity exports are from the NBER-United Nations Trade Database.3

The data on the spread on sovereign bonds are from the Emerging Markets Bond Index Global (EMBI Global) that is available for 30 emerging market economies for the period 1997-2007.4 Bond spreads are measured against a comparable US government bond and are period averages for the whole year. Our two main measures of political institutions are the average (time-invariant) Polity2 score from the Polity IV database (Marshall and Jaggers, 2009) and the average (time-invariant) checks and balance score from the Database of Political Institutions (Keefer and Stasavage, 2003). The real per capita GDP data are from the Penn World Tables, version 6.3 (Heston et al., 2009). Descriptive statistics of these variables are provided in Table 1

Table 1.

Descriptive Statistics

article image

III. Estimation Strategy

To examine the effects that international commodity price shocks have on sovereign bond spreads, we estimate the following econometric model:

Δ log( Spread )i, t=αi+βt+η(Com PriceShocki,t)+ui, t

where αi are country fixed effects and βt are year fixed effects. ui,t is an error term that is clustered at the country level. As a baseline regression, we estimate the average marginal effect η that commodity price shocks have on sovereign spreads. We then examine how this marginal effect varies as function of countries’ political institutions by estimating:

Δ log( Spread )i, t=ai+bt+c(Com PriceShock i, t)+d(Com PriceShock i, t)*Pol i+ui, t

where Poli is a measure of cross-country differences in political institutions.

IV. Main Results

Table 2 presents our estimates of the average marginal effect that commodity price shocks have on sovereign bond spreads using our sample of emerging market economies. The main finding from the fixed effects estimates is that positive international commodity price shocks lead on average to a significant reduction in commodity exporting countries’ spread on sovereign bonds. Panel A presents the estimates of the link between international commodity price shocks and the spread on sovereign bonds when controlling for country fixed effects; Panel B presents corresponding estimates when controlling in addition to the country fixed effects for year fixed effects. The fixed effects estimates yield that a positive commodity price shock of size 1 standard deviation significantly reduced the spread on sovereign bonds on average by over 0.1 standard deviations.

Table 2.

Commodity Price Shocks, Political Institutions, and the Spread on Sovereign Bonds

article image
Note: The method of estimation is least squares. t-values (in brackets) are based on Huber robust standard errors that are clustered at the country level. In Panel A the regressions control for country fixed effects; Panel B for country fixed effects and year fixed effects. The dependent variable is the log-change in the spread on sovereign bonds. *Significantly different from zero at 90 percent confidence, ** 95 percent confidence, *** 99 percent confidence.

Column (2) shows that the marginal effect of international commodity price shocks on the spread on sovereign bonds significantly varies across countries as function of cross-country differences in political institutions. The estimated interaction effect between international commodity price shocks and the Polity2 score is negative and statistically significant at the 5% level. The point estimate on the interaction term implies that at the sample maximum Polity2 score (democracies), a positive commodity price shock of size 1 standard deviation significantly reduced the spread on sovereign bonds by over 0.4 standard deviations. On the other hand, at the sample minimum Polity2 score (autocracies), a shock of similar magnitude was associated with a significant increase in the spread on sovereign bonds by 0.3 standard deviations.

Column (3) shows that we obtain similar heterogeneity in the marginal effect of international commodity price shocks on sovereign bond spreads when discretizing the Polity2 score into an indicator function that is 1 for strictly positive Polity2 scores and zero else.5 Column (4) shows that windfalls from international commodity price shocks significantly decrease sovereign bond spreads in countries with strong checks and balances, while they lead to a significant increase in the sovereign bond spread in countries with weak checks and balances.

To explain the heterogeneity in the marginal effect that international commodity price shocks have on sovereign bond spreads, we show in Table 3 the effect that international commodity price shocks have on countries’ real per capita GDP growth. Not surprising, we find that higher international prices for exported commodity goods were associated with a significant increase in real per capita GDP growth on average (the “terms of trade effect”). However, the positive effect of international commodity price shocks on growth was particularly large for countries with strong democratic institutions. In countries with deep autocratic regimes, windfalls from international commodity prices were a curse as they were associated with a significantly lower per capita GDP growth rate. The results in Table 3 therefore show that while in democracies plausibly exogenous windfalls from international commodity price shocks were significantly positively associated with real per capita GDP growth, in autocracies they were associated with a significant decrease in real per capita GDP growth.

Table 3.

Commodity Price Shocks, Political Institutions, and Economic Growth

article image
Note: The method of estimation is least squares. t-values (in brackets) are based on Huber robust standard errors that are clustered at the country level. In Panel A the regressions control for country fixed effects; Panel B for country fixed effects and year fixed effects. The dependent variable is the log-change in real per capita GDP. *Significantly different from zero at 90 percent confidence, ** 95 percent confidence, *** 99 percent confidence.

The political economy model developed in Mehlum et al. (2006) can provide an explanation for this heterogeneous response in real per capita GDP growth: in countries with grabber friendly political institutions, revenue windfalls from international commodity price shocks increase rent-seeking activity and lead to a crowding out of production activity. Democratic institutions, in particular, stronger checks and balances constrain politicians in their policy space. Relative to an autocratic regime, politicians are also held more accountable to the public. Hence, in a more democratic regime the expected returns to rent-seeking activities are lower. This in turn means that production activity will remain strong in the democratic regime despite the high rents that are realized in the commodity exporting sector when international commodity prices are booming. In the autocratic regime, on the other hand, where there are relatively high gains from specializing in grabbing activities, production activity will be crowded out in the presence of a revenue windfall. Thus, revenue windfalls from international commodity prices may be associated with lower per capita GDP growth in more autocratic regimes.

V. Conclusion

We investigated in this paper the effects that international commodity price shocks have on sovereign bond spreads using panel data for 30 emerging market economies during the period 1997-2007. Our main finding is that revenue windfalls from international commodity price shocks lead to a significant reduction in sovereign bond spreads in emerging market economies with sound democratic institutions. In countries with more autocratic institutions revenue windfalls lead on the other hand to a significant increase in the sovereign bond spread.

To explain this heterogeneity in the marginal effect that international commodity price shocks have on sovereign bond spreads, we showed that revenue windfalls from international commodity price booms lead to a significant increase in real per capita GDP growth in countries with sound democratic institutions. In countries with deep autocratic regimes, revenue windfalls lead to a decrease in real per capita GDP growth. Our empirical results are consistent therefore with general equilibrium models that predict a countercyclical relationship between sovereign bond spreads and the business cycle in debtor countries (e.g. Arellano, 2008). However, our empirical results also highlight the importance of political economy factors in shaping the relationship between commodity price shocks and sovereign bond spreads. Further research, in particular, theoretical contributions along the lines of Cuadra and Saprinza (2008) may therefore be of interest in advancing our understanding of the relationship between revenue windfalls from international commodity price shocks, economic growth, and the spread on sovereign bonds in emerging market economies.

References

  • Arellano, C. (2008). “Default Risk and Income Fluctuations in Emerging Markets.” American Economic Review 98: 690-712.

  • Berg, A. and J. Sachs (1988). “The Debt Crisis: Structural Explanations of Country Performance.” Journal of Development Economics 29: 271-306.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cuadra, G. and H. Sapriza (2008). “Sovereign Default, Interest Rates, and Political Uncertainty in Emerging Markets.” Journal of International Economics 76: 78-88.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heston, A., R. Summers and B. Aten (2009). “Penn World Table Version 6.3”, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania, August 2009.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keefer, P. and D. Stasavage (2003). “The Limits of Delegation: Veto Players, Central Bank Independence, and the Credibility of Monetary Policy.” American Political Science Review 47: 407-423.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, A. (1987). “Origins of the Developing Countries’ Debt Crisis, 1970 to 1982.” Journal of Development Economics 27: 141-163.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Marshall, M. and K. Jaggers (2009). Polity IV Project: Dataset Users’ Manual. Center for Global Policy, George Mason University (www.cidcm.umd.edu/polity). [Polity IV Data Computer File, Version p4v2004. College Park, MD: Center for International Development and Conflict Management, University of Maryland.]

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mehlum, H., K. Moene, and R. Torvik (2006). “Institutions and the Resource Curse.” Economic Journal 116: 1-20.

  • Persson, T. and G. Tabellini (2006). “Democracy and Development. The Devil in Detail.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 96 (2): 319-324.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robinson, J., R. Torvik, and T. Verdier (2006). “Political Foundations of the Resource Curse.” Journal of Development Economics 2: 447-468.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

International Monetary Fund (Arezki) and Universitat Pompeu Fabra (Bruckner). Contact e-mails: rarezki@imf.org; markus.bruckner@upf.edu. We thank Amine Mati for providing us with his dataset on sovereign bond spreads. The views in this paper are those of the authors alone and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. All remaining errors are our own.

2

The recent concern that Dubai may default on its external debt is an example par excellence that higher commodity prices may be associated with a higher risk of external debt default.

3

The commodities included in our index are: aluminum, beef, coffee, cocoa, copper, cotton, gold, iron, maize, oil, rice, rubber, sugar, tea, tobacco, wheat, and wood. In case there were multiple prices listed for the same commodity we used a simple average of all the relevant prices. The functional form of the commodity price shock variable is motivated by taking logs and derivatives of output with respect to the commodity export prices.

4

The availability of the sovereign bond spread data limit are sample size to the following countries: Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Czech Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Jordan, Lebanon, Malaysia, Mexico, Nigeria, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Russia, South Africa, South Korea, Thailand, Turkey, Ukraine, Uruguay, Venezuela, and Vietnam.

5

The binary democracy indicator has been frequently used in the political economy literature. See, for example, Persson and Tabellini (2006).

Resource Windfalls and Emerging Market Sovereign Bond Spreads: The Role of Political Institutions
Author: Mr. Rabah Arezki and Markus Bruckner