Bankruptcy and Firm Dynamics: The Case of the Missing Firms
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: jrodriguezdelgado@imf.org

Financial frictions have been documented as an important determinant of firm dynamics. In this paper I model bankruptcy procedures, liquidation in particular, as an institutional feature that affects both sides of financial transactions. I construct a model of firm dynamics that generate endogenous borrowing limits and I find that a) inefficient bankruptcy procedures can have quantitatively important aggregate effects, but more importantly; b) that such effects would not be directly visible in the firms that industrial censuses and surveys focus on. I conclude that to capture the effects of the legal framework we need to look beyond the existing firms.

Abstract

Financial frictions have been documented as an important determinant of firm dynamics. In this paper I model bankruptcy procedures, liquidation in particular, as an institutional feature that affects both sides of financial transactions. I construct a model of firm dynamics that generate endogenous borrowing limits and I find that a) inefficient bankruptcy procedures can have quantitatively important aggregate effects, but more importantly; b) that such effects would not be directly visible in the firms that industrial censuses and surveys focus on. I conclude that to capture the effects of the legal framework we need to look beyond the existing firms.

I. Introduction

Financial frictions have been documented to be an important factor behind the evolution of firms across the world. Within the theoretical strand of the literature, enforcement and information problems are now standard ways to rationalize the presence of such frictions. On the other hand, recently compiled cross-country indexes of legal and institutional development (e.g. Djankov, et al., 2006) have shed light on the particular legal areas that firms find most obstructive to their growth plans. In this paper I focus on a particular legal feature, the procedures followed after liquidation, to disentangle the effects that weak or inefficient procedures could have on the ability of firms to finance their operations, to grow and to recover from shocks.

At any point in time, a significant fraction of firms fail to remain profitable and exit the market. The subject of study of this paper is the process followed after such exit. I construct a model that provides a quantitative laboratory to evaluate the effects that the ability of such process to transfer the liquidated assets from the firm to the lender (its efficiency) has not only on the exiting firms, but also on any other firm looking for financing. The framework is one of complete enforcement and perfect information so that lenders will, when lending money, forecast the probability that a given firm will not pay and, if default were to occur, the fraction of assets it would collect. On a conceptual basis, I merge the recent literature on sovereign default (e.g. Arellano, 2008) with the canonical analysis of firm dynamics (e.g. Hopenhayn, 1992), to build a model in which differences in the bankruptcy procedures can be mapped directly into the financial transactions and consequently in the overall industrial structure. The model combines both the market incompleteness and the role of default probabilities in determining the individualized financial contracts a lender offers, with a standard dynamic model of firm’s investment and production decisions. In the simulations, the model is calibrated to match firm entry and exit statistics of the Mexican manufacturing sector.

My findings are as follows: a) inefficient bankruptcy procedures can have quantitatively important effects on the aggregate level of output, but more importantly, b) such effects would not be directly visible in the firms that industrial censuses and surveys focus on. The inefficiency would hurt the entry process the most, that is, it would limit the set of active projects undertaken in the economy. I conclude that to fully understand the role of the legal framework in the evolution of firms we need to look beyond the characteristics of the existing firms.

II. Related Literature

The literature dealing with firms’ financial (borrowing) constraints includes several empirical studies that, by discovering deviations from the frictionless neoclassical framework, point toward promising modifications of the basic model that could better reflect actual conditions. The existence of frictions is generally accepted; their quantitative role is still an open research field (Hubbard, 1998).

Empirical findings have also highlighted the need for richer structural models that could rationalize the existence of financial constraints and their implications on firms’ evolution. In an early attempt Cooley and Quadrini (2001) explore the interdependence of persistent productivity shocks with asymmetric information in explaining the conditional correlations among size and age within an incomplete markets environment. In more recent developments, Albuquerque and Hopenhayn (2004) put forward the lack of commitment as an important mechanism behind underinvestment, early termination and the absolute lack of financing for some projects. In their derivation of the optimal contingent contract between a lender and a given firm, they point toward the need to understand that borrowing constraints are not exogenous or static, but that they are derived from the lender’s expectations of future periods in which the financial friction binds. Cooley, Marimon and Quadrini (2004) extend the analysis to derive aggregate implications; they show how the presence of incomplete enforcement rationalizes both the amplification of aggregate temporary shocks and the slow response to aggregate permanent shocks. Clementi and Hopenhayn (2006) provide an alternative rationale behind borrowing constraints: asymmetric information between the lender and the firm. An important feature of both Clementi and Hopenhayn (2006) and Albuquerque and Hopenhayn (2004) is the derivation of the optimal contingent contract; in contrast, in this paper I derive endogenous borrowing constraints under incomplete markets and assuming perfect information and complete enforcement.

This paper also relates to the literature studying the legal framework as a determinant of financial development and economic activity in aggregate as well as at the firm level. Levine (1998) employs indicators of contract enforcement and the protection of creditor rights, that is, “the ability of banks to persuade firms to pay their loans”, to explain financial development (credit assigned to the private sector as a fraction of GDP). He finds both that cross-country variation in such legal metrics explains more than half of the variation in financial development and that financial development is an important determinant of economic growth. At the firm level, Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and Levine (2005), find that the adaptability of the legal system, “the extent to which judicial decisions are sources of law and whether judicial processes are based on principles of equity rather than purely on statutory law and legal formalities”, is an important determinant of the obstacles firms face when obtaining financing.

Furthermore, The World Business Environment Survey, a multi-country firm-level survey that asks firms how financial, legal or corruption-related issues restrict their operations and growth plans, has helped advance the research agenda in this area. Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, Maksimovic (2005) find that if these responses were combined with actual firm growth data, a clear pattern emerged: small firms are affected the most (see also Beck, et al., 2007). They also find that obstacles rated highest by the firms themselves did not necessarily appear as the most significant in their statistical analysis. In terms of the indicators of the legal framework they conclude that the “…mechanism by which the legal system affects firm performance is not yet well understood.” In this paper I attempt to help disentangle the connection between the legal framework and the evolution (entry, exit, growth) of firms by focusing on one of its elements, the liquidation process.

A third strand of literature related to this paper studies firms’ investment patterns to infer the presence of borrowing constraints using reduced form representation of financial frictions. Bayer (2006) and Whited (2006) are two recent examples. Whited (2006) targets the discrete choice of starting large investment projects when the firm combines costly external financing (equity) with internal savings. He imposes a cost function of issuing equity as a reduced form representation of information frictions. Bayer (2006) extends the analysis to also tackle the intensive margin of investment while assuming both that the firm has no access to equity and that borrowing is limited such that bankruptcy never occurs. In his model, interest rate is assumed to be a function of the debt/assets ratio. In this paper I contribute to this literature by deriving the interest rate premium and borrowing constraints from fundamentals.

The effects of bankruptcy procedures on firms were analyzed by Davydenko and Franks (2006) where they compare the creditor’s reaction to firms that defaulted in France, Germany and the UK. They find “that large differences in creditors’ rights across countries lead banks to adjust their lending and reorganization practices…” Furthermore, they document that despite such adjustments, recovery rates vary substantially. As my model shows, the distortions of bankruptcy laws are not exclusive to the firms undergoing liquidation. In the lifetime of a given firm, the financing options it receives would be more limited the more inefficient the bankruptcy procedure is notwithstanding it may never file for liquidation itself. In the model I develop below, the determination of firms’ bankruptcy decision becomes central to the analysis. Uhrig-Homburg (2005) also emphasizes the endogenous determination of such bankruptcy decision. She deals explicitly with both cash-flow shortages and overindebtedness as determinants of bankruptcy and derives credit spreads and debt levels using a partial equilibrium approach in which both firm’s assets value and the ongoing cash flows are exogenous.

III. Model Economy

The economy is populated by a unit mass of risk neutral entrepreneurs and by competitive and risk-neutral lenders and it is similar to the framework in Arellano, Bai and Zhang (2007). Each entrepreneur is either operating a single project or idle. Entrepreneurs become idle if: 1) in the previous period they filed for bankruptcy or, 2) in the previous period they were idle but failed to start a new project. In particular, all entrepreneurs who file for bankruptcy or fail to start a new project die and new idle entrepreneurs are born to replace them. When idle, entrepreneurs can costlessly draw a new project. Moreover, entrepreneurs face an outside option whose value is normalized to zero. Given these assumptions, I will characterize the economy as being populated by projects or firms whenever there is no risk of confusion.

When just started, projects are characterized by their initial productivity level z that follows a stochastic process; each entrepreneur maximizes the expected value of the project’s dividends through borrowing and the accumulation of capital subject to the available financing opportunities. Therefore, during their evolution projects are characterized by their capital stock k, debt holdings b, and productivity level z summarized in x = (k, b, z).

Projects face two sources of uncertainty: 1) their productivity level is governed by a Markov process Q(z′|z) and 2) their capital stock is potentially depleted by disruption shocks; with probability τ they would start the next period with zero physical assets. The latter feature is meant to capture the probability of strikes, natural disasters, or capital obsolescence and, as it will be explained below, has a close resemblance to the standard way of modelling exogenous exit rate. It could be useful to think of a project with k > 0 as a firm; on the other hand, a project with k = 0 could be thought of as a start-up waiting to be financed or a currently existing firm that lost its assets and could potentially reemerge. I will focus on the stationary equilibrium of this model where the central object of analysis is the distribution of projects that become active.

The only available financial instruments are loan contracts. Although loans can be made contingent on all the firms’ current characteristics, they still represent an incomplete markets environment given that they cannot be made contingent on the next period’s shocks. The environment is one of complete enforcement and perfect information. A central feature of the model is that both sources of uncertainty faced by the firms will be considered by the lenders when computing the likelihood of bankruptcy and therefore, when determining the corresponding interest rate charged (1/q(x, b′) − 1) on a given loan of size b′ as well.

A. Legal Framework

Bankruptcy laws are complex mechanisms and vary considerably across countries (see Hart, 2000 and Frank and Sussman, 2005) so that in order to present a tractable framework I make several simplifying assumptions. The legal framework is as follows:

  1. When a firm x = (k, b, z) files for bankruptcy it ceases operations and it exits the market irreversibly. The firm is then classified as solvent, if kb or as insolvent if k < b. In the case of a solvent firm, the lender receives its regular payment and the firm keeps the difference kb. We denote this first case as S (scrap value). In the second scenario, formal bankruptcy procedures are started, denoted as L (liquidation).

  2. Bankruptcy procedures involve costs in terms of legal fees and/or in terms of the time involved to satisfy all the legal requirements. We model these costs as an iceberg cost μ that represents the fraction of capital lost during this process.

In this context, I characterize bankruptcy procedures by their efficiency in transferring the borrower’s assets to the lender; the fraction of assets (1 − μ) that survive the procedures. I further define the firm’s value of filing for bankruptcy as:

BKU(x)=max(kb,0)(1)

Some remarks are in order. First, in this setup the lender will never seize assets of higher value than the existing debt. I also implicitly assume that the bank or lender cannot operate the firm and that it has the only option of selling the assets.1 A second important assumption is that each firm deals with one lender only. The coordination among the different classes of creditors (secured, senior, preferred, etc.) is undoubtedly a relevant factor in analyzing modern bankruptcy procedures. This paper provides a simple framework that could eventually be enriched with such features. Finally, the equation in (1) also reflects that in the model the entrepreneur’s liability is limited by the size of his project’s physical assets.

B. Firm’s Problem

This section describes the firm’s basic problem, taking as given the bond price schedule q(x, b′) that would be subsequently derived from the lender’s optimality condition. I also assume that firms do not have access to equity financing and that they do not save.2 In this section, I first present the problem for an existing firm followed by the problem faced by an entrepreneur drawing a new project.

1. Existing Project

Each firm has access to the decreasing returns to scale technology zka, 0 < α < 1 provided it covers the fixed costs of operations f that captures, in a reduced form, entry and regulation costs and working capital requirements. Capital is depreciated at rate δ and dividends are discounted by β. After the realization of the current period’s shock z and having in possession capital k and existing debt level b, the firm decides whether to file for bankruptcy or to pay and continue its operations. If it decides to pay, the firm then chooses its investment level (k′ − (1 − δ)k) and debt contract (q(x, b′), b′) from the menu of contracts being offered.

V(x=(k,b,z))=max{Pay(x),BKU(x)}(2)
Pay(x)=maxk,bzkα+(1δ)kkb+q(x,b)bf+βΕ[(1τ)V(k,b,z)+τV(0,b,z)|z](3)

subject to:

(k,b)B(x)={(k˜,b˜)|zkα+(1δ)kk˜b+q(x,b˜)b˜f0}(4)

The expression in (2) represents the recursive representation of the firm’s problem. The value of paying the existing debt is derived in (3) where the two sources of uncertainty are made explicit: the stochastic productivity shock and the possibility of facing a disruption shock. The set defined in (4) describes the fact that each firm must finance its investment and both the fixed cost and the payment of the existing debt out of its operating income zka or by obtaining new financing q(x, b′)b′.

There are two basic reasons for a firm to file for bankruptcy: 1) the set of available capital and debt pairs could be empty, B(x) = Ø in which case we set Pay(x) = − ∞, or 2) the combination of productivity level and debt holdings could make physical assets more valuable if they were sold rather than used in production, kb > Pay(x). In all the simulations presented in this paper this second possibility was, for all practical purposes, absent.

Along their evolution, firms face the fundamental trade-off of borrowing to increase their production capacity according to their productivity level, while facing the possibility of receiving a detrimental shock in the next period and failing to cover the fixed cost. Firms value capital not only because of its capacity to generate dividends in the next period but also because they would relax next period’s financial constraint. As the firms increase in size the financial constraint becomes less important and they eventually behave as unrestricted.

The solution of the firm’s problem generates its capital and debt policy functions gk(x), gb(x) as well as its optimal decision rule gd(x), which describes if the firm decides to file for liquidation either as solvent or insolvent. In particular, gd(x) takes on three values {P, S, L} corresponding to Pay, Scrap (file while being solvent) and Liquidate respectively.

2. New Projects

An idle entrepreneur faces the draw or birth of a new project drawn from Q(z). He/she will then face the challenge to cover the fixed cost and the initial level of investment exclusively from new borrowing as in (5). If the entrepreneur fails to obtain enough financing he/she will enjoy the outside option valued at zero. From (2) and (5) it follows that Ve(z) = V(x = (0, 0, z)) so in order to economize on notation, I will use V(x) and gk(x), gb(x), gd(x) to describe the solution of both problems.3

Ve(z)=max{Continue(x=(0,0,z),0}(5)
Continue(x)=maxk,bk+q(x=(0,0,z),b)bf+βΕ[(1τ)V(k,b,z)+τV(0,b,z)|z](6)

subject to:

k+q(x,b)bf0}(7)

C. Financial Contracts

The loans are given by risk neutral, competitive lenders so that in equilibrium they offer loans that will give them zero expected profits. The loan contracts are pairs (q(x, b′), b′) that specify the amount of money the firm receives today q(x, b′)b′ in exchange for paying back b′ tomorrow, provided it does not file for bankruptcy. The implicit interest rate charged on a loan of b′ becomes (1/q(x, b′) − 1). Each lender is able to observe all the firm’s characteristics x = (k, b, z) and it can charge different interest rates according to the firm’s physical assets, current debt holdings and/or productivity level.

For each firm and loan size, the lenders compute the expected payment for the next period. If the firm decides to continue or exit while being solvent the lender will recover b′. If instead, the firm files for liquidation the lender will receive the capital the firm would have net of the iceberg cost. In the (rational expectations) equilibrium each lender will correctly anticipate the capital level using the firm’s capital policy function gk(x). Using the firm’s policy functions the probability that the lender receives b′ from a firm x becomes:4

AP(x,b)=(1τ)χ(gdgk(x),b,z){P,S})Q(z|z)dz+τχ(gd(0,b,z){P,S})Q(z|z)dz(8)

The first term in (8) reflects the probability of repayment of a firm that does not suffer the disruption shock while the second term represents the corresponding repayment probability of a firm that arrives next period with its capital stock depleted.

Analogously, the probability that the firm would file for liquidation while holding positive assets5 is represented by:

AL(x,b)=(1τ)χ(gd(x)=L)Q(z|z)dz=(1τ)χ(gd(gk(x),b,z)=L)Q(z|z)dz(9)

Therefore, the zero profit condition implicitly defines the bond price schedule as:

q(x,b)b=ΑP(x,b)b+ΑL(x,b)(1μ)gk(x)(1+r)(10)

D. Equilibrium

I restrict my attention to stationary equilibria and, as it is standard in incomplete market models, I assume β < (1/(1 + r)). While the financial side of the equilibrium is summarized by equations (8 and 9), the characteristics of the real side of this economy are summarized by the distribution of firms across x, ψ(x).

Definition. A stationary equilibrium consists of an invariant distribution ψ(x) over the set of firms; a value function and policy functions {V(x), gk(x), gb(x), gd(x)}, payment and liquidation sets {A p(x, b′), A L(x, b′)} and a bond price schedule q(x, b′) such that

  1. Given the bond prices schedule q(x, b′), {V(x), gk(x), gh(x), gd(x)} solve the firm’s problem (2)

  2. {Ap(x, b′), AL(x, b′)} are derived from {gk(x), gh(x), gd(x)} as in equations (8) and (9)

  3. Given {Ap(x, b′), AL(x, b′)} and {gk(x), gd(x)}, q(x, b′) is such that the lenders make zero expected profits (10).

  4. The invariant distribution ψ(x) is derived from Q(z′|z) and {gk(x), gb(x), gd(x)} where in particular, new projects are drawn from the invariant distribution of Q(z′|z) that is, Q(z)

IV. Simulations

A. Calibration

The model is solved numerically using a nested fixed point algorithm (see equation (11)). In the ‘inside loop’, for a given q0(x, b′) I solve the firm’s problem by using the value function iteration method. This step generates Ap(x, b′|q0), AL(x, b|q0) and gk(x|q0). In the ‘outside loop’ equation (10) is checked and, in case it is not satisfied, a new guess q1(x, b′) is constructed. As a final step, the invariant distribution is computed from the transition matrix that summarizes the likelihood of all the possible paths x = (k, b, z) → x′ = (k′, b′, z′).

q(x,b)b=ΑP(x,b|q)b+ΑL(x,b|q)(1μ)gk(x|q)(1+r)(11)

I calibrated the benchmark model to roughly match some key firm dynamic statistics of the Mexican manufacturing sector (from Bertelasman, Haltiwanger and Scarpetta, 2004) and using data from Djankov, et al. (2006) to estimate the liquidation efficiency in Mexico. I then performed comparative statics changing the level of efficiency to illustrate its effects both on aggregate output and on individual firm’s characteristics.

1. Bankruptcy Efficiency

In this paper, I build on recent estimates constructed by Djankov, et al. (2006) that are available through the World Bank’s Closing a Business Database (World Bank, 2007). The authors presented insolvency practitioners of several countries with an identical case of debt default and they asked them to describe the legal steps to be followed. Using the responses from each country’s experts they constructed measures of the time, cost and the final disposition of the assets (e.g. preservation as going concern or piecemeal sale). Consistent with the simple legal framework in the model, I combined two of such indicators to construct an overall efficiency6 measure.

  1. Years that takes to complete the bankruptcy procedures, J.

  2. Cost as fraction of the estate that the bankruptcy procedures involve, λ

(1μ)=(1λ)(11+r)J(12)

The database includes both indicators for more than 160 countries. For illustration purposes, I present here the estimates computed using equation (12) for a subsample that includes OECD members (see Appendix Table for full list of OECD members) and the country that ranked lowest in the bankruptcy efficiency indicator. There are two main lessons to be obtained from these numbers: 1) even among relatively developed countries-OECD members-there is significant variation in the fraction of assets lost during the bankruptcy procedures and; 2) the difference between the countries with the more inefficient bankruptcy procedures and developed countries is substantial. Table 1 also includes results from the WBES survey that “asked managers to rate the extent to which financing, legal, and corruption problems presented obstacles to the operation and growth of their businesses” (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, Maksimovic, 2005). Managers selected a number between 1 and 4, where higher values indicate greater obstacles. The correlation between bankruptcy efficiency and financial and legal obstacles is statistically significant and positive; that is, in countries where the bankruptcy procedure takes longer or destroys a larger value of the estate, firms find greater financial and legal obstacles.

Table 1.

Bankruptcy Efficiency and Financial Constraints

article image
Source: Beck, Demirkguc-Kunt, Maksimovic (2005) and author calculations

2. Entry and Exit Statistics

Given the structure of the model, standard entry and exit statistics cannot be used without first performing some adjustments. The goal is to make comparable measurements taken in the Model Economy to the ones performed in the real-world. The central issue is that a firm in the model exists regardless of having capital stock while in the data, such firms would not be measured given the standard thresholds of the typical industrial census.

Entry=χ(k=0,gk(x)>0)ψ(x)dx(13)
Exit=χ(k>0,gd(x)P)ψ(x)dx(14)
+τχ(k>0,gd(x)=P)ψ(x)dx(15)
Incumbents=χ(k>0)ψ(x)dx(16)

where dx stands for (dk, db, dz)

Entrants (13) include all firms that with zero capital today managed to obtain financing and then, provided they are not hit by the disruption shock, will appear with positive assets tomorrow. I consider their size to be gk(x), that is, the amount of capital they would possess in the next period. The mass of firms that exit the market is composed of two separate groups: 1) the first line (14) represents the endogenous exit component, firms that decide to file for bankruptcy and 2) the firms that decide to keep operating today but that are hit by the disruption shock and then would appear as having zero assets tomorrow (15). The latter is equivalent to the standard assumption of exogenous exit or death. I compute entry and exit rates relative to the mass of incumbents (16).

Tables 2 and 3 present the values used in the benchmark model. The technology parameter α, the discount factor β, the depreciation rate δ and the interest rate r were taken from standard values in the macro literature with the only goal to provide plausible parameters for the Mexican economy. The stochastic process is assumed to be log-normal distributed (17) and discretized using an 11-state Markov chain as in Heer and Maurßer (2005). Such process is characterized by its autocorrelation ρz and standard deviation parameters σz. For technical reasons I selected an autocorrelation coefficient somewhat lower than recent estimates (0.53 in Whited (2006)); several experiments using higher values gave equivalent results.7 The variance of the productivity shock is calibrated to roughly match the average exit rate on Mexico’s manufacturing sector as reported by Bertelasman, Haltiwanger and Scarpetta (2004). The fixed cost is calibrated to match the relative size of entrants-ratio of average entrant size to average incumbent size as defined in (13) and (16). The resulting value of 0.3 is equivalent to 9.6% of the average firm size (see Table 3). Finally, the disruption shock is taken from Cooley, Marimon and Quadrini (2004).

In(z)=ρzIn(z)+ε,εΝ(0,σε)(17)
Table 2.

Parameter Values

article image
Table 3.

Calibration

article image
Table 4.

Comparative Statics

article image

B. Benchmark Model

1. Firm’s Decision to Liquidate

The mechanism of the model generates a set of bankruptcy thresholds (cf. Uhrig-Homburg, 2005), not only in terms of the firm’s productivity level but also in terms of the size of the firm’s capital stock and existing debt. Figures 1 and 2 summarize the basic properties of the firm’s liquidation decision. They present the pay or liquidate decision for different levels of capital and current debt levels, for the average productivity and the highest productivity level respectively. The typical firm that files for liquidation is the one with a low amount of capital stock and/or that is highly indebted. The higher the current debt level the higher the threshold in terms of physical assets that is needed for a firm to decide to continue operating. Furthermore, comparing Figures 1 and 2, another pattern is confirmed: firms with lower productivity level are more likely to file for liquidation

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Liquidation Decision, Average Productivity

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2010, 041; 10.5089/9781451962932.001.A001

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Liquidation Decision, High productivity Productivity

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2010, 041; 10.5089/9781451962932.001.A001

2. Bond Price Schedule

As mentioned before, the main reason for firm to file for bankruptcy in the model economy is its inability to cover the payment of its existing debt and fixed cost of operations using the contracts being offered to it. Figure 3 presents the schedule of prices offered to a firm with zero existing debt and being at the average productivity level. Driven by the higher probability of default next period, small firms (with zero physical assets) are charged a higher interest rate. On the other hand, large firms (highest value on the grid, equivalent to 4 times the average incumbent size from the benchmark model) are offered contracts that, for small loan amounts, only reflect the possibility of disruption, i.e. up to level 3.9 in the graph. For larger amounts, however, even large firms face the probability of facing detrimental productivity shocks low enough to induce them to file for bankruptcy, notwithstanding having a positive capital stock.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Bond Prices for Large and Small Firms

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2010, 041; 10.5089/9781451962932.001.A001

Bond price schedules give only a partial view, however. It is also important to consider the amount of effective financing a firm can obtain when asking for a loan of a given size b′. Figure 4 presents the amount of financing today that a firm with zero existing debt and average productivity level obtains for every possible loan size, that is q(x, b′)b′. As the nominal size of the loan increases so does the probability that the firm will not be able to pay back in the next period. In fact, the lender may adjust the price in a way that the amount of money received today could be larger if the firm asked for a smaller loan. The dashed lines in the graph show the largest size of a loan that a rational firm will ask for; exceeding that threshold will only increase the next period’s payment without providing any extra benefit. In the figure large firms could access up to three times the financing than small firms. Endogenous borrowing limits emerge from the model’s mechanism.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Effective Financing for Large and Small Firms

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2010, 041; 10.5089/9781451962932.001.A001

The interest rate premium charged to small firms is also present if we classify firms by their productivity level or current debt level. Low productivity firms and highly indebted firms are offered lower bond prices and smaller amount of effective financing, ceteris paribus.

3. Firm Dynamics

Limited access to financing obstructs the firms start-up process specially at low and medium level of productivity; if a firm is hit by a good productivity shock it might reach the first best level of capital and evolve practically as being unrestricted from that point on. In Figure 5, I simulate the evolution of a firm that starts at year 1 with no physical assets with no existing debt and at the average productivity level.8 As a reference I include the first best level of capital: the level of capital that results from the standard Euler equation proper of models in which firms face no financial restrictions, equation (18). Given the correlation of the shocks, it could be useful to think of the first best as also tracing down the level of the realized productivity shocks.

1=βΕ[(1τ)(zαkα1+(1δ))|z](18)
Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Firm Dynamics Benchmark and First Best

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2010, 041; 10.5089/9781451962932.001.A001

The financial friction imposed by the mechanism of this model affects this prototypical firm in its early years mostly. This pattern is consistent with the finding in Arellano, Bai and Zhang (2007) where enforcement constraints affect small firms disproportionately.

C. Comparative Statics

In order to illustrate the main obstacles imposed by inefficient liquidation procedures, I perform the following experiment. Holding the value of all other parameters constant, the efficiency level μ is changed from the calibrated value of 25% to 0% (perfect efficiency) and to 45 and 81%. The last two values correspond to the lowest efficiency among OECD countries and to the overall lowest efficiency reported in Table 1 respectively. I first present the effects on firms’ evolution, followed by the aggregate effects on output and average firm size.

1. Bond Price Schedules

Equation (10) establishes a link between the efficiency of the liquidation procedure and the loan contracts offered by the lenders. Consequently, the borrowing limits a given firm faces under different procedures change. As an illustration, Figure 6 shows that, a firm with large capital-corresponding to four times the average incumbent size in the benchmark model-zero existing debt and average productivity level, the maximum amount of money it can borrow changes monotonically with the level of efficiency. In particular, the lender adjusts its offering so that in an economy with μ = 0% such firm can borrow 33% more compared to an economy with μ = 81%.

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Effective Financing and Bankruptcy Efficiency

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2010, 041; 10.5089/9781451962932.001.A001

2. Firm Dynamics

Consistent with the changes in the bond prices caused by changes on the liquidation efficiency, Figure 7 shows that firm dynamics would also differ. Here, I exposed each firm to the same sequence of productivity shocks and followed them as if they were living under the four different environments. The evolutions of firms living under μ = 0% and 25% are very similar and a firm operating under μ = 45% would take approximately three more years to ‘catch up’ with the former two. However, the experience of a firm evolving under a highly inefficient bankruptcy code μ = 81% is very different; it is characterized by a long period of failed attempts to obtain financing9 only interrupted when a sequence of good productivity shocks arrived (around year 41). In summary, these results suggest that to measure the effects of the quality of the bankruptcy procedures we should look in the early stages of firms’ lives. In this simulation, after the year 41 the firms look identical.

Figure 7.
Figure 7.

Firm Dynamics and Bankruptcy Efficiency

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2010, 041; 10.5089/9781451962932.001.A001

3. Aggregate Statistics

The main result of this section is that the economy-wide consequences of having an inefficient liquidation procedure are not necessarily reflected in the size of the surviving firms but rather in the number (mass) of such firms. A movement from the benchmark case to a perfectly efficient liquidation generates 1.2% increase in output, while moving to an environment in which the lender barely seizes any assets at all in case of liquidation, decreases output by more than 40%. Beyond the output level, the key statistic to notice is the mass of firms that remained inactive or dormant, especially the group of firms (entrepreneurs) that failed to obtain enough financing to start (or re-start after disruption shocks) operations and will remain inactive in the next period. Almost half of the total mass of firms fell into this category under μ = 81%. An implication of this analysis is that, while reforms among OECD members generate up to 2.6% of output gains, countries that currently have highly inefficient procedures stand to gain considerably more.

To understand the quantitative implications of the changes in liquidation efficiency, we should look closely at the entry process. Intuitively, under more limited or expensive loan contracts (Figure 6), only highly productive firms will manage to start operating. Given the persistent productivity process, they will tend to become larger as they evolve. The results of the simulations supported this mechanism; as the bankruptcy procedure became less efficient the entry productivity thresholds-the minimum level of z such that an inactive firm entered the market-increased (Figure 810). On the other hand, given the positive correlation of productivity shocks, highly productive firms will have a larger ‘demand’ for capital; such demand will face different supplies of loans (Figure 6) depending not only on how likely is the firm to default but also on the expected asset recovery if the firm were to default. The interaction of these two forces govern the entry process.

Figure 8.
Figure 8.

Entrants Productivity Distribution

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2010, 041; 10.5089/9781451962932.001.A001

To further understand the role of the bankruptcy efficiency in the entry process it could be helpful to first consider the determination of the interest rate charged on a given loan of size b′. Intuitively, new projects, with no contribution from current operating income, would devote a larger fraction of that loan to cover the fixed cost leaving fewer resources for capital formation. Firms with a lower stock of capital in the next period will be more likely to be exposed to productivity shocks low enough to induce them to default on the payment b′ and file for bankruptcy, so lenders will charge such firms a higher interest rate. In the simulations, this interest rate premium requested from new entrants was such that entrepreneurs with low productivity projects failed to start because they were offered a maximum effective financing (i.e. maxbq(x, b′)b′) lower than the fixed cost. In an environment with no risk of default, the efficiency of the process followed after default would be of minor significance. In contrast, given that in my model new entrants are particularly likely to file for bankruptcy in the immediate future, changes in bankruptcy efficiency affects them the most.

Recent empirical studies provide partial support to the two main findings of this paper: 1) the potentially negative relation between the average firm size and the efficiency of the liquidation procedure, and, 2) the particularly strong effect of such efficiency on the entry process. Aghion, Fally, Scarpetta (2007) study the role of financial development in both entry rates and post-entry growth rates among industrialized and emerging economies. They find that financial constraints affect the entry of small firms the most. In fact, the length of the bankruptcy procedures is among the instrumental variables they use (besides overall measures of contract enforcement and creditor rights) to control for the endogeneity of financial development. They also find that conditional on entry, firm growth is affected by the level of financial development. Furthermore, Desai, Gompers, Lerner (2003) using a sample of European countries find a positive relation between interference of courts (“whether courts are fair and impartial”) and average firm size. They find the relation to be particularly strong for less developed countries. In this context, my paper presents a particular mechanism through which the institutional or legal development of a country affects firms size, entry (Figure 8), and post-entry growth (Figure 7).

These empirical studies, however, may be giving a partial view. Given the important role that bankruptcy efficiency plays on financing start-up projects, drawing conclusions from datasets of existing firms must be done with caution. As Figure 9 shows, an analysis focused on the distribution of existing firms (incumbents) generated from the model economy would find that the distribution under μ = 81% dominates, in the first order stochastic sense, the distribution generated from an an environment with μ = 0%. The observed higher average firm size would be, however, misleading. The former environment would have a large mass of entrepreneurs failing to start-up their projects.

Figure 9.
Figure 9.

Firm Size Distribution and Bankruptcy Efficiency

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2010, 041; 10.5089/9781451962932.001.A001

To further illustrate the differences in firms’ characteristics under the four scenarios, I performed a pseudo-survey that asks firms: ‘how restricted are your investment plans?’ In particular, I determine if their capital policy function gk(x) corresponds to the First Best as in equation (18). Among the firms that managed to finance their operation 70% would be labeled unrestricted under the scenario μ = 81%, while only 51.4% would be labeled as such under μ = 0%. The message obtained from this exercise confirms the previous finding; the main effect of inefficient bankruptcy procedures is on limiting the mass of firms obtaining financing (extensive margin). If we were to focus on the characteristics of such firms (intensive margin) it would be tempting to conclude that environments with less efficient legal procedures μ = 81% generate less investment obstacles (Table 5).

Table 5.

Bankruptcy Efficiency and Financial Frictions

article image

V. Concluding Remarks

This paper presented a simple model of firm dynamics in which the efficiency of the bankruptcy laws was summarized as the fraction of assets that survive the legal procedures, and where borrowing limits arose endogenously under perfect information and complete enforcement. My framework could be extended in several directions. One promising area of research studies the interaction of financial frictions with the occupational choice of entrepreneurs; that is, the outside option that here was normalized to zero, could include the alternative to invest in other sectors and/or to become a worker instead of an entrepreneur. Smith and Wang (2006) develop a model in which financial frictions arise from asymmetric information and where individuals consider the available financing opportunities in their decision to become workers or to start a new project. Furthermore, moving away from stationary equilibria could help understand better the role of the legal framework in the evolution of emerging economies (cf. Desai, Gompers, Lerner, 2003). Buera, Shin (2007) consider the role of financial constraints-modeled as an exogenous borrowing limit-in the transition toward the steady state. They find that the changes in (steady state) output caused by the financial frictions are small but that such frictions can have important consequences for the speed of convergence.

Debt is an important source for firms to finance their investment and growth plans, but its existence depends on the ability of lenders to exercise the contract, and in case of default, on the efficiency of the liquidation procedure. In this study, I have focused on the latter. The empirical literature has emphasized the role of the legal system as limiting the size of the firms operating in a country (e.g. Kumar, Rajan and Zingales, 1999). A central message of my paper is that average firm size should not be the only indicator to consider. Simulations for the Mexican manufacturing sector show that bankruptcy procedures that, by definition are constructed to deal with the firms’ exit process, could have important consequences for the entry process as well. The potential gains, in terms of output level, of reforming bankruptcy codes would not necessarily come from allowing the existing firms to grow further. The gains may very well come from allowing currently inexistent projects to be undertaken; in other words, the gains may come from the missing firms.

References

  • Aghion, P., Fally, T., Scarpetta,S., 2007. Credit Constraints as a barrier to the entry and post-entry growth of firms, Mimeo

  • Albuquerque, R., Hopenhayn, H.A., 2004. Optimal lending contracts and firm dynamics. Review of Economic Studies 71, 285-315

  • Arellano, C., 2008. Default risk and income fluctuations in emerging economies, American Economic Review 98, 690-712

  • Arellano, C., Bai, Y., Zhang, J., 2007. Enforcement, incomplete contracts, and firm dynamics. Mimeo

  • Berletsman, E., Haltiwanger, J., Scarpetta, S, 2004. Microeconomic Evidence of Creative Destruction in Industrial and Developing Countries, Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper, TI 2004-114/3

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayer, C., 2006. Investment dynamics with fixed capital adjustment cost and capital market imperfections. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 1909-1947

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., Laeven, L., Levine, R., 2007. Finance, Firm Size, and Growth. Mimeo

  • Beck, T., Levine,R., 2005. Law and Firms’ Access to Finance, American Law and Economics Review 7, 211-252

  • Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., Maksimovic, V., 2003. Financial and Legal Institutions and Firm Size, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2997

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., Maksimovic, V., 2005. Financial and Legal Constraints to Growth: Does Firm Size Matter?, The Journal of Finance 60, 137-177

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buera, F., Shin, Y., 2007. Financial Frictions and the Persistence of History: A Quantitative Exploration. Mimeo

  • Clementi, G.L., Hopenhayn, H.A., 2006. A theory of financing constraints and firm dynamics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 229-265

  • Cooley, T., Marimon, R., Quadrini, V., 2004. Aggregate consequences of limited contract enforceability. Journal of Political Economy 112, 817-847

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cooley, T., Quadrini, V., 2001. Financial markets and firm dynamics. American Economic Review 91, 1286-1310

  • Dadydenko, S. A., Franks, J. R., 2006. Do bankruptcy codes matter? A study of defaults in France, Germany and the UK. Mimeo

  • Desai, M., Gompers, P., Lerner, J., 2003. Institutions, Capital Constraints and Entrepreneurial Firm Dynamics: Evidence from Europe. NBER Working Paper 10165

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Djankov, S., Hart, O., McLiesh, C., Shleifer, A., 2006. Debt enforcement around the world. Mimeo

  • Franks, J., Sussman, O., 2005. Financial innovations and corporate bankruptcy. Journal of Financial Intermediation 14, 283-317

  • Hart, O., 2000. Different approaches to bankruptcy. NBER Working Papers, W7921

  • Heer, B., Maußner, A., 2005. Dynamic general equilibrium modelling, Springer

  • Hennessy, C., Whited, T., 2007. How costly is external financing? evidence from structural estimation. Journal of Finance 62, 1705-1745

  • Hopenhayn, H. A., 1992. Entry, exit and firm dynamics in long run equilibrium. Econometrica 60, 1127-1150

  • Hubbard, R. G., 1998. Capital-market imperfections and investment. Journal of Economic Literature 36, 193-225

  • Kumar, K., Rajan, R., Zingales, L., 1999. What determines Firm Size? NBER Working Paper No. 7208

  • Levine, R., 1998. The Legal Environment, Banks, and Long-Run Economic Growth. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 30, 596-613

  • Smith, A., Wang, C., 2006. Dynamic Credit Relationships in General Equilibrium. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 847-877

  • Uhrig-Homburg, M., 2005. Cash-flow shortage as an endogenous bankruptcy reason. Journal of Banking & Finance 29, 1509-1534

  • Whited, T., 2006. External finance constraints and the intertemporal pattern of intermittent investment. Journal of Financial Economics 81, 467-502

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2007, Closing a Business Database, http://www.doingbusiness.org

Table A.1.

Bankruptcy Efficiency for OECD members

article image
Source: World Bank (2007) and author calculations
1

Mr. Rodríguez-Delgado is an Economist in the Western Hemisphere Division of the IMF Institute. I thank Timothy J. Kehoe and Cristina Arellano for their constant encouragement and advice. Jose Victor Rios-Rull, Martin Schneider, Fabrizio Perri, Erem Atesagaoglu, Alma Romero-Barrutieta and Murat Seker provided many useful suggestions. Maria Julia Gutierrez provided excellent editorial assistance. The usual disclaimer applies

1

Hennessy and Whited (2007) present a model in which the lender takes posession of the operating firms and may decide to re-finance the firm adjusting its equity value.

2

See Arellano, Bai and Zhang (2007) for an example of the combination of equity and defaultable debt. Not allowing savings is for technical reasons only. It is also common to assume that the discount factor of the risk-neutral firms to be such that they prefer dividends today (cf. Bayer, 2006).

3

In particular, BKU (x = (0, 0, z)) = 0

4

I use χ to denote the indicator function. So that χ (Condition) takes value of 1 when the Condition is met and zero otherwise.

5

The case of a firm with no physical assets choosing to file for liquidation is of no interest for the lender.

6

My definition of efficiency is different than the one used in Djankov, et al. (2006) that is centered in whether the defaulting firm is correctly identified as going concern or piecemeal sale.

7

In the computations, that used finite grids, a higher autocorrelation coefficient impacted the capital policy functions in such a way that a wider grid of capital values was required. To make the calibration more manageable, I lowered this value to ensure the predefined grids were not binding for any of the parameter values.

8

Conditional on not being hit by the disruption shock all along.

9

To make the simulations comparable, when a firm exited the market endogenously I restarted it with zero capital and zero debt but inheriting the sequence of productivity shocks.

10

The productivity distribution of entrants for μ = 45% and μ = 25% were identical.

Bankruptcy and Firm Dynamics: The Case of the Missing Firms
Author: Jose Daniel Rodríguez-Delgado