Bank Ownership, Market Structure and Risk

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: gdenicolo@imf.org and eloukoianova@imf.org

This paper presents a model of a banking industry with heterogeneous banks that delivers predictions on the relationship between banks' risk of failure, market structure, bank ownership, and banks' screening and bankruptcy costs. These predictions are explored empirically using a panel of individual banks data and ownership information including more than 10,000 bank-year observations for 133 non-industrialized countries during the 1993-2004 period. Four main results obtain. First, the positive and significant relationship between bank concentration and bank risk of failure found in Boyd, De Nicolò and Al Jalal (2006) is stronger when bank ownership is taken into account, and it is strongest when state-owned banks have sizeable market shares. Second, conditional on country and firm specific characteristics, the risk profiles of foreign (state-owned) banks are significantly higher than (not significantly different from) those of private domestic banks. Third, private domestic banks do take on more risk as a result of larger market shares of both state-owned and foreign banks. Fourth, the model rationalizes this evidence if both state-owned and foreign banks have either larger screening and/or lower bankruptcy costs than private domestic banks, banks' differences in market shares, screening or bankruptcy costs are not too large, and loan markets are sufficiently segmented across banks of different ownership.

Abstract

This paper presents a model of a banking industry with heterogeneous banks that delivers predictions on the relationship between banks' risk of failure, market structure, bank ownership, and banks' screening and bankruptcy costs. These predictions are explored empirically using a panel of individual banks data and ownership information including more than 10,000 bank-year observations for 133 non-industrialized countries during the 1993-2004 period. Four main results obtain. First, the positive and significant relationship between bank concentration and bank risk of failure found in Boyd, De Nicolò and Al Jalal (2006) is stronger when bank ownership is taken into account, and it is strongest when state-owned banks have sizeable market shares. Second, conditional on country and firm specific characteristics, the risk profiles of foreign (state-owned) banks are significantly higher than (not significantly different from) those of private domestic banks. Third, private domestic banks do take on more risk as a result of larger market shares of both state-owned and foreign banks. Fourth, the model rationalizes this evidence if both state-owned and foreign banks have either larger screening and/or lower bankruptcy costs than private domestic banks, banks' differences in market shares, screening or bankruptcy costs are not too large, and loan markets are sufficiently segmented across banks of different ownership.

I. Introduction

The entry of foreign banks in emerging and developing economies has been intense since the early 1990s. During the same period, privatizations of state-owned banks have been also undertaken in several countries, while consolidation has advanced in many banking industries around the world. Understanding the financial stability implications of bank state-ownership and the increasing presence of foreign banks in host countries is a high priority in policymakers’ agendas. Yet, the literature has focused primarily on comparisons of bank efficiency and on the implications of bank ownership for growth and the provision of credit. 2 To our knowledge, no study has explicitly examined the joint effects of bank ownership and market structure on banks’ risk profiles, and addressed the following questions: Do risk profiles of private domestic, state-owned and foreign banks differ significantly across market structures? Do private domestic banks take on more risk as a result of larger market shares of either foreign or state-owned banks? Answers to these questions are essential for understanding the implications of bank ownership and market structure for financial stability.

This paper addresses these questions theoretically and empirically. It presents a model of a banking industry with heterogeneous banks that delivers predictions on the relationship between banks’ risk of failure, market structure, and bank screening and bankruptcy costs. The model guides the empirical analysis, in the sense that measures of market structure and bank risk are derived from the model, and a set of regressions is specified consistently with the model’s equilibrium conditions.

The empirical analysis aims at gauging the impact of market structure and bank ownership on the risk profiles, profitability, volatility of earnings, and on uses and sources of funding of private domestic, state-owned and foreign banks. This analysis is carried out using a panel of individual banks data and ownership information including more than 10,000 bank-year observations for 133 non-industrialized countries during the 1993-2004 period. The results of this empirical analysis are interpreted in light of theory, identifying under which assumptions, if any, theory may rationalize the evidence.

The model has two main features. First, banks compete both in the loan and deposit markets, and both the firms that borrow from banks and the banks themselves are subject to moral hazard, as in Boyd and De Nicolò (2005). Second, banks differ in two dimensions: the efficiency of the screening technology to identify borrowers’ quality, and the level of bankruptcy costs. The latter costs are interpreted as embedding managerial reputation costs as well as implicit or explicit government guarantees. Bank differences in screening and bankruptcy costs are then mapped into different bank ownership.

In equilibrium, the degree of bank heterogeneity may translate into either homogenous or heterogeneous responses of different banks to certain changes in parameters. If either banks’ screening and bankruptcy costs are markedly different among different bank types, then the model can predict bank responses of different sign. Conversely, if these bank characteristics are sufficiently similar, then the model can predict bank responses of the same sign.

For example, a ceteris paribus increase in market shares of banks of a certain type may result in more risk taking of banks of a different type. This kind of negative “externality” underpins many conjectures often made in policy discussions about the effects of competition of banks of a certain type, say foreign banks, on the stability of banks of a different types, say private domestic banks. Another example is provided by De Nicolò (2000), who finds that private banks operating in industrialized countries with a larger share of bank assets under state-ownership exhibit higher insolvency risk. This finding suggests the possible existence of another type of “negative” externality affecting private domestic banks. The model identifies conditions under which such externalities may arise, and the empirical analysis aims at assessing whether these externalities are quantitatively relevant.

The analysis of the data begins with simple tests of difference of unconditional means for measures of balance sheet composition, cost, profitability, capitalization, and loan quality of private domestic, state-owned and foreign banks. There are significant differences among private, state-owned, and foreign banks in terms of balance sheet composition and loan quality. In terms of profitability, costs, and capitalization, however, these differences vary greatly across countries, often with opposite signs. Subsequently, we present the results of a set of regressions that relate measures of overall and ownership-specific concentration measures to measures of bank risk of failure, profitability, volatility of earnings, capitalization, and asset and liabilities composition. These regressions also allow us to test differences of conditional means of all the indicators considered across bank ownership.

The following main results obtain. First, the positive and significant relationship between bank concentration and bank risk of failure found in Boyd, De Nicolò and Jalal (2006) (BDNJ henceforth) is stronger when bank ownership is taken into account, and it is strongest when state-owned banks have sizeable market shares. Second, conditional on country and firm specific characteristics, the risk profiles of foreign (state-owned) banks are on average significantly higher (not significantly different from) than those of private domestic banks. Third, private domestic banks do indeed take on more risk as a result of larger market shares of both state-owned and foreign banks.

Lastly, the model rationalizes this evidence under the assumptions that both state-owned and foreign banks have either larger screening and/or monitoring costs or lower bankruptcy costs than private domestic banks, banks’ differences in market shares, screening or bankruptcy costs are not too large, and loan markets are sufficiently segmented across bank of different ownership. These assumptions are consistent with standard incentive theory under moral hazard, as well as with the evidence of many empirical analyses of individual country data available in the literature.

The remainder of the paper is composed of four sections and an Appendix. Section II presents the model. Section III describes the data and carries out simple comparisons of unconditional means. Section IV presents the regression analysis, its results, and discusses under what conditions the model can rationalize the evidence. Section V concludes with a brief discussion of broad policy implications. Proofs of all propositions are detailed in the Appendix.

II. The Model

The economy is composed of three groups of agents: entrepreneurs, depositors and N banks. All agents are risk-neutral. There are two periods: 0 and 1.

Entrepreneurs

There is a continuum of entrepreneurs indexed by (a,b) ∈ [0,ā]x[0, 1]. Parameter a indexes the productivity of an entrepreneur, while parameter b indexes her reservation utility level. Entrepreneurs have no initial resources but have access to a project that requires a fixed amount of date 0 investment, standardized to 1. The project yields a random return at date 1 as a function of effort exerted by the entrepreneur at date 0. Specifically, at date 1 the project yields X(a) with probability P∈ (0,1) (the good state), and 0 otherwise, and projects returns are perfectly correlated across entrepreneurs, The output function in the good state X(a) is assumed to satisfy X(a) > 0 for all a ∈ [a*, ā], with a* > 0, X’ (a) > 0 and X”(a) < 0. An entrepreneur chooses P by incurring an effort cost of 0.5P2, and such choice is unobservable to outsiders.

Entrepreneurs learn their productivity parameter a (their type) only after investing at date 0. Thus, the expected return of the project of any entrepreneur who has chosen a level of effort P is ERP0a¯X(a)g(a)da,, where g (a) is the density of the distribution of entrepreneurs over [a*, ā]. We assume that ER is sufficiently small so that even with available financing at zero cost, no entrepreneur would undertake a project unless his productivity could be known prior to investing. The reservation utility level of any entrepreneur b is distributed on the unit interval with density f(.)and twice-differentiable, strictly increasing distribution function F(.) , with F′(.) > 0 and F” (.) ≤ 0.

Entrepreneurs of a certain productivity type a can be identified by banks at a screening cost prior to investing, and an entrepreneur’s productivity type becomes known to her once screened.3 If an entrepreneur can obtain a loan from a bank, this is granted under a simple debt contract. Such contract stipulates that if the project is successful, the bank receives a payment R(a). If the project is unsuccessful, the bank gets nothing. Under such contract, an entrepreneur would choose P∈ [0, 1] to maximize:

P(X(a)R(a))0.5P2(1)

The unique interior solution to (1) satisfies:

P(R,a)=X(a)R(a)(2),

and the relevant profit is given by 0.5(X(a) − R(a))2. An entrepreneur (a, b) who does not undertake the project attains a utility level b. Thus, an entrepreneur with reservation utility level b will accept the loan and undertake the project if

0.5(X(a)R(a))2b(3)

Let b* denote the value of b that satisfies (3) at equality, and let g(.) ≡F -1(.). If type-a entrepreneurs are financed, the total demand for loans is given by Let b* denote the value of b that satisfies (3) at equality, and let g(.) ≡F -1(.). If type-a entrepreneurs are financed, the total demand for loans is given by LF(b*)=0b*f(b)db.

This expression defines implicitly the inverse loan demand function of type-a entrepreneurs:

R(L,a)=X(a)2g(L)12(4)

The partial derivatives of this function satisfy RL < 0, Ra = X’(a) > 0, while the cross partial derivatives are zero. Substituting (4) in (2), the probability of a successful outcome is

P(L)=2g(L)12(5),

which satisfies P’ > 0 and P” < 0.

Depositors

Depositors cannot observe entrepreneurs’ types. Thus, they do not finance entrepreneurs directly. Instead, they deposit their funds in a bank at date 0 to receive interest plus principal at date 1. Deposits are fully insured, so that the total supply of deposits does not depend on risk, and it is represented by an upward sloping inverse supply curve, denoted by rD(∙), which is assumed to satisfy rD>0 and rD0.

Banks

On the funding side, banks collect insured deposits, and for this insurance, they pay a flat rate insurance premium, standardized to zero. On the lending side, banks choose which type of entrepreneurs to finance, and provide funds to them through simple debt contracts. Specifically, banks can identify entrepreneurs of type a at a “screening” cost σ a per unit invested. Thus, higher screening costs are incurred to identify entrepreneurs of higher quality. As noted, once screened by a bank, entrepreneurs learn their productivity type. However, banks cannot observe entrepreneurs’ effort choice P. In setting the lending rate, they take into account the best choice of effort of entrepreneurs in response to any offered loan rate.

Since banks invest only in loans, if the borrowers of a bank default, the bank itself defaults. In such an event, a bank incurs a “bankruptcy” costs per unit lent γ > 0. As noted, this cost can be interpreted as capturing net managerial reputation costs as well as implicit or explicit government guarantees.

The mechanics of the model with heterogeneous banks is best illustrated by analyzing first the version of the model with homogenous banks, which is described next.

A. Homogenous Banks

Suppose all banks incur the same screening, monitoring and bankruptcy costs per unit lent. Let Di denote total deposits of bank i, Zi=1NDi denote total deposits and Dij1Dj denote the sum of deposits chosen by all banks except bank i. Each bank chooses the entrepreneur type to finance (parameter a) and the amount of deposits to lend so as to maximize profits, given similar choices of the other banks and taking into account the entrepreneurs’ choice of P.

Thus, each bank chooses (a,D)R+2 to maximize

P(Di+D)(R(Di+D,a)rD(Di+D))D(1P(Di+D))γDσaD(6)

Let ZND denote total deposits, which equal total loans in equilibrium. Under the assumption that the objective function (6) is strictly concave in D, an interior symmetric Nash equilibrium is characterized by the following conditions:

R(Z,a)rD(Z)+γF(Z,a,N,σ,γ)=0(7),
P(Z)X(a)σ=0(8),

where

F(Z,a,N.σ,γ)(rD(Z)RZ(Z,a))P(Z)Z+(γ+σa)NP(Z)Z+P(Z)N.(9)

By the monotonicity of function X’(.), equation (8) can be inverted to yield the equilibrium choice of aas a function of total deposits and the screening cost parameter:..

a=X1(σ/P(Z))g(σ/P(Z))(10).

Note that aσ = g’/P(Z) < 0 since g’ < 0: for any given total amount of deposits, a is decreasing in screening costs σ. Note also that changes in a are positively associated with changes in total deposits Z, since aZ = −g’P’(Z)/(P(Z))2 > 0,

Substituting (10) in (7), we get

R^(Z,σ)rD(Z)μa+γF^(Z,N,σ,γ)=0(11),

Where R^(Z,σ)R(Z,g(σ/P(Z)) and F^(Z,N,σ,γ)F(Z,g(σ/P(Z)),N,σ,γ).

Totally differentiating equations (11) with respect to Z and the parameters N, σ, and γ, we obtain:

(R^ZrDF^Z)dZ=F^NdN+(F^σR^σ)dσ+adμ+(F^γ1)dγ(12),

Recall that the equilibrium probability of a successful outcome P(Z)=2g(Z)12 (equation (5)) and the equilibrium choice of a (equation (10)) are uniquely determined by, and strictly increases in, the equilibrium level of total deposits, Z. Therefore, the sign of dP and that of da) are the same as the sign of dZ., The comparative statics results with respect to N and σ are summarized in the following:

  1. (a)If dN > 0 and = = 0, then dZ > 0, dP > 0 and da > 0;
  2. (b)If dσ < 0 and dN = = 0, then dZ > 0, dP > 0 and da > 0.

The interpretation of these results is straightforward. As N increases (part(a)) competition increases. Hence, total deposits increase and bank risk of failure decreases (1−P decreases). This result is, essentially, that obtained by Boyd and De Nicolò (2005). When competition increases, banks charge lower loan rates, thereby giving entrepreneurs an incentive to take on less risk. Similarly, as screening costs σ decline (part (b)), banks’ optimally choose entrepreneurs of better quality (a larger a), and such quality’s improvement entails an upward shift of the inverse supply schedule (see equation (4)). As a result, banks expand total deposits, and their risk of failure (1−P) declines.

Differing from the foregoing results, the comparative statics with respect to bankruptcy costs γ can be non-monotonic, as shown in the following

Let ZM denote the total amount of deposits chosen by a monopolist and let dγ > 0 and dN = dσ = 0. If 1 < P’(ZM)ZM +P(ZM), then dZ > 0, dP > 0 and da > 0 for all N<N¯, while dZ < 0, dP < 0 and da < 0 for all N>N¯.

This result establishes an important interdependence between the degree of competition and the risk incentives associated with variations in bankruptcy costs. Recall that an increase (decrease) in these costs may be viewed as associated with smaller (larger) safety net guarantees and/or higher (lower) managerial reputation costs.

When the degree of competition is relatively low (N is not too large), as bankruptcy costs γ increase, the marginal option value of limited liability net of bankruptcy costs decreases. This gives banks an incentive to increase their expected profits by reducing their risk of failure through charging lower loan rates. In essence, this is the well known risk shifting result typically obtained by considering an individual firm and assuming there are no strategic interactions among firms. However, this result is reversed when the degree of competition is relatively high (N is sufficiently large). In this case, the marginal option value of limited liability net of bankruptcy costs increases, giving banks an incentive to rise expected profits by taking more risk through charging higher loan rates.

B. Heterogeneous Banks

We now consider two types of banks, indexed by j = 1, 2, which differ with respect to the “efficiency” of their screening technology (σ1σ2) and the “size” of their bankruptcy costs (γ1γ2).

Let DijkiDkdenote the sum of deposits chosen by all type-j banks except type-j bank i. As before, each bank chooses the entrepreneur type and deposits so as to maximize profits, given similar choices of the other banks and taking into account the entrepreneurs’ choice of P. Note that in choosing the type of entrepreneurs to finance, each bank type effectively chooses a different loan demand function. Loan markets are therefore endogenously segmented, and no entrepreneur of any type different from the one chosen by a bank type will ever be financed by any other bank type. Thus, the strategic interaction of banks of different types in the loan market is indirect, since it passes through the channel of competition in the deposit market. Of course, banks of the same type compete directly in both loan and deposit markets.

Thus, each type-j bank chooses (a,D)R+2 to maximize

Pj(Dij+D)(R(Dij+D,a)rD(Di+D))D(1Pj(Dij+D))γjDσjaD(13.j).

Denote with ZjNjDj total bank-j deposits (equal to total bank-j loans in equilibrium), and with ZZ1 + Z2 total deposits. For j= 1,2, an interior symmetric Nash equilibrium is characterized by the following conditions:

R(Zj,aj)rD(Z1+Z2)+γjFj(Z1,Z2,aj,Nj,σj,γj)=0(14.j),
P(Zj)X(aj)σj=0(15.j),

where

Fj(Z1,Z2,aj,Nj,σj,γj)(rD(Z1+Z2)RZj(Zj,aj))P(Zj)Zj+(γj+σjaj)NjP(Zj)Zj+P(Zj)Nj.(16.j)

Following the procedure described previously, we substitute the optimal level of a implied by (15.j) in (14.j) and (16.j), for j=1,2, and define:

R^(Zj,σj)R(Zj,gj(σj/P(Zj)),and
F^j(Z1,Z2,Nj,σj,γj)F(Z1,Z2,gj(σj/P(Zj)),Nj,σj,γj).

Totally differentiating the resulting equations (13.j). and (14.j), with respect to Zj the parameters Nj, σj, and γj, for j=1,2, we get

(R^Z1rDF^Z11)dZ1(rD+F^Z21)dZ2=F^N11dN1+(F^σ1R^σ1)dσ1+(F^γ111)dγ1H1(17),
(rDF^Z12)dZ1+(R^Z2rDF^Z22)dZ2=F^N22dN2+(F^σ2R^σ2)dσ2+(F^γ221)dγ2H2(18)

Let Δ denote the determinant of system (16)-(17). Applying Cramer rule, we get

dZ1=Δ1[H1(R^Z2rDF^Z21)+H2(rD+F^Z21)](19),

and

dZ2=Δ1[H2(R^Z1rDF^Z11)+H1(rD+F^Z12)].(20).

The sign of the determinant Δ depends on the size of the curvature of banks’ revenue functions. For example, |R^ZjrDF^Zjj|>rD+F^Zkj for j,k = 1,2, jk then Δ is strictly positive. In what follows we assume Δ > 0, noting that if Δ < 0 all results reported below hold with all implications reversed.

The comparative statics results with respect to changes in the number of banks are summarized in the following:

Assume Δ > 0, and let dN1 > 0, dN2 > 0 and dσj = j = 0, j=1,2.

  1. (a)If dN1 / dN2 ∈ (0, A1), then dZ1 < 0, dP1 < 0, da1 < 0, and dZ2 > 0, dP2 > 0, da2 > 0;
  2. (b)If dN1 / dN2 ∈ (A1, A2), then dZ1 > 0, dP1 > 0, da1 > 0, and dZ2 > 0, dP2 > 0, da2 > 0;
  3. (c)If dN1 / dN2 > A2, then dZ1 > 0, dP1 > 0, da1 > 0, and dZ2 < 0, dP2 < 0,da2 < 0,

Where 0<A1F^N22(rD+F^Z12)F^N11(R^Z2rDF^Z22)<A2F^N22(R^Z2rDF^Z11)F^N11(rD+F^Z21).4

Unlike the homogenous case, an increase in competition due to an increase in the number of both types of banks may result in either similar or different banks’ risk taking responses. Specifically, these responses will be similar (different) the smaller (larger) is the relative change in the number of banks. This is because when the number of banks of both types increases, the increase in competition in the deposit market will be symmetric for both bank types since they experience the same increase in funding costs, but it will be asymmetric in the loan market, since they choose different loan demand schedules, hence different marginal revenues. The asymmetric effect will dominate on net, generating different risk responses, the largest is the asymmetry in the change in the number of banks (parts (a)and (c)), while the symmetry effect will dominate on net whenever the relative change in the number of banks is not too large or too small (part (b)).

This result can be further explained as follows. As the increase in the number of type-1 banks is small relative to that of type-2 banks (part (a)), total deposits of both bank types increase, raising their funding costs symmetrically. However, type-1 banks’ reduction in revenues due to increased competition in the loan market is proportionally smaller than the corresponding reduction in revenues for type-2 banks. Thus, type-1 banks will have an incentive to reduce lending, increase lending rates and risk, since at the margin, the improvement in expected profits obtainable from this strategy is superior to the alternative of increasing lending and decreasing risk. The same mechanism, but in reverse, holds for type-2 banks, who will increase lending and decrease risk. Of course, the same effects, with the type of banks interchanged, will hold when the increase in the number of type-2 banks is small relative to that of type-1 banks (part (c)). In both these cases, the asymmetric change in competition in loan markets dominates. By contrast, if the relative changes in the number of banks is not too large (part (b)), the change in risk for both type of banks will move in the same direction. In this case, a uniform, albeit “asymmetric” increase in competition will generate a result similar qualitatively to the one obtained in the homogenous case, although the size of changes in deposit demand, supply and risk of failure of different bank types will clearly differ.

Similar results hold when screening costs change, but the range of variations differ from those defined previously, as shown in the following proposition:,

Assume Δ > 0 and let dσ1 < 0, 2 < 0 and dNj = j = 0, j = 1,2.

  1. (a)If dσ1/2 ∈ (0, B1), then dZ1 < 0, dP1 < 0, da1 < 0, and dZ2 > 0,dP2 > 0,da2 > 0;
  2. (b).If dσ1/2 ∈ (B1, B2), then dZ1 > 0, dP1 > 0, da1 > 0, and dZ2 > 0, dP2 > 0, da2 > 0;
  3. (c).If 1/2 > B2, then dZ1 > 0, dP1 > 0, da1 > 0, and dZ2 < 0, dP2 < 0, da2 < 0,

Where 0<B1(F^σ2R^σ2)a2(rD+F^Z12)(F^σ1R^σ1)(R^Z2rDF^Z22)<B2(F^σ2R^σ2)a2(R^Z1rDF^Z11)(F^σ1R^σ1)(rD+F^Z12)

It is important to note that an improvement in entrepreneurs’ quality due to a decline in screening costs of both bank types does not necessarily imply a reduction in bank risk (as in the model with homogenous banks), since banks trade-off at the margin both the marginal benefits of improving entrepreneurs’ quality and the rents that are obtainable from changes in market power in both loans and deposit markets.

Lastly, results qualitatively similar to the previous ones obtain when we consider changes in bankruptcy costs for both bank types. Here, however, we need to take into account the fact that the sign of banks’ responses will change depending on whether or not the number of banks of each type is below or above the relevant threshold levels N¯j as defined in Proposition 2.

Assume Δ > 0; 1 < P’(ZjM)ZjM + P(ZjM), j=1,2, and let dγ1 > 0, 2 > 0 and dNj = j = 0, j=1.2. Furthermore, let C1(F^γ221)(rD+F^Z12)(F^γ111)(R^Z2rDF^Z22);C2(F^γ221)(R^Z1rDF^Z11)(F^γ111)(rD+F^Z12);

(i) C1 > 0 and C2 > 0; and (ii) C1 < 0 and C2 < 0,

  1. (a)If (i) and dγ1/2 ∈ (0, C1), then dZ1 > 0, dP1 > 0, da1 > 0, and dZ2 < 0,dP2 < 0, da2 < 0;
  2. (b). If (i) and dγ1/2 ∈(C1, C2), then dZ1 > 0, dP1 > 0, da1 > 0, and dZ2 > 0,dP2 > 0, da2 > 0;
  3. (c). If (i) and dγ1/2 > C2, then dZ1 > 0, dP1 > 0, da1 > 0, and dZ2 < 0,dP2 < 0,da2 < 0
  4. (d)If (ii) and dγ1/2 > 0, then dZ1 > 0, dP1 > 0, da1 > 0, and dZ2 < 0, dP2 < 0,da2 < 0.

As in the case of changes in screening costs, note that an increase in bankruptcy costs does not necessarily imply a reduction in bank risk, since banks trade-off at the margin both the benefits of the option value of limited liability net of bankruptcy costs and the rents that derive from changes in market power in both loans and deposit markets.

In sum, this model predicts either similar or different changes in the risk profiles of different types of banks in response to changes in parameters. In reality, variations in the degree of competition and in screening and bankruptcy costs may occur simultaneously, and the model can yield a wide variety of predictions depending on the relative size of changes of parameters. However, the key difference among these predictions is whether changes in risk profiles of different types of banks will move in opposite or similar directions.

The empirical analysis, to which we now turn, reveals which of these two possibilities is consistent with the data, and which changes in parameter configurations of the model, if any, can rationalize the evidence when differences in banks’ screening and bankruptcy costs are mapped into different ownership structures.

III. A Helicopter Tour of the Data

We consider individual banks data for 133 countries excluding major developed countries for the 1993-2004 period taken from the Fitch IBCA’s Bank Scope database. There are between 10,000 and 18,000 bank-year observations with unconsolidated balance sheet information in our sample, depending on the availability of specific variables. The majority ownership of banks is identified using information from Bankscope, annual reports and other public information sources. We also cross-checked and used the ownership information contained in the smaller dataset for non-developed economies constructed by Micco, Panizza, and Yanez (2006), as well as the privatization database used by Boehmer, Nash and Netter (2005),5 and integrated this information with our dataset.

As our dataset on ownership information for non-industrialized economies is substantially larger than any other used in the literature to date, we find it informative to compare several indicators of bank asset shares by ownership, and examine differences in unconditional means of balance sheet composition indicators, costs and profitability, loan quality and capitalization.6 Statistics for these indicators are reported for the full sample, as well as for countries grouped by PPP-adjusted GDP per capita levels and by the following geographical regions: Africa, Middle East, Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), Central and Eastern Europe and Baltics (CEEB), Central America and Caribbean, South America, and Far East and Asia.

A. Bank Asset Shares by Ownership

Table 1 reports the evolution of bank asset shares by ownership since 1994. For the entire sample, the share of foreign-owned banks in the total sample increased, whereas the share of private and state-owned banks declined. While the share of foreign banks increased across all income groups except low-middle income group (i.e. countries with income between US$3,175 to US$5,860 at PPP), that of state-owned banks declined over time in the low income group, while it increased in other income groups. When these changes are examined by region, the share of foreign banks increased on average in most regions, while the share of state-owned banks has on average increased or not changed with the exception of Africa.

Table 1.

Market Shares of Banks by Ownership

P stands for domestic private banks, S – for state-owned banks, F – for foreign-owned banks, and U – for unclassified banks. The shares of banks are reported on average, and then averaged for the periods. Therefore, they do not sum up to one.

article image
article image

In sum, despite the notable increase in the number of privatization in some countries, the market share of state-owned banks remains still significant.

B. Balance Sheet Composition

On the asset side, the (gross) loan-to-asset ratio of state-owned banks is uniformly lower than that of both private domestic banks and foreign banks in total, as well as by income level and region (Table 2.1), with the exception of the high-middle income group and Middle East. This may in part reflect the role of state-owned banks in absorbing government issued bonds in most countries. On the other hand, the loan-to-asset ratio of private domestic banks is on average higher than that of foreign banks except in the CEEB region.7 Yet, we note that differences in loan allocations among the two groups are not large quantitatively in most regions, except in the CIS.

Table 2.

Asset and Liability Composition

* = p-value of less or equal to 5 percent.
article image
* = p-value of less or equal to 5 percent.

On the liability side (Table 2.2), state-owned banks exhibit a ratio of deposits to liabilities lower that of private domestic and foreign banks in the total sample and in all subgroups. Thus, deposits as a source of funding appear relatively less important for state-owned banks. By contrast, this ratio is uniformly higher for private domestic banks relative to foreign banks in the total sample and all subgroups, as well as in all regions except Africa, the CIS, and the CEEB.

C. Cost and Profitability

The cost-to-income ratios of state-owned banks are lower than those of private domestic and foreign banks in the total sample and for all income groups except the highest income group, where state-owned banks exhibit ratios higher than those of private domestic banks (Table 3.1). Yet, a great deal of heterogeneity emerges when we compare these ratios across regions. State-owned banks have ratios significantly higher than both private domestic and foreign banks in Central and South America, while they are significantly lower in the Middle East and the CEEB. Similarly, the same degree of heterogeneity is apparent when comparing these ratios for private domestic and foreign banks, whose differences vary both by income group and region.

Table 3.

Cost and Profitability

* = p-value of less or equal to 5 percent.
* = p-value of less or equal to 5 percent.
* = p-value of less or equal to 5 percent.
article image
article image
* = p-value of less or equal to 5 percent.

Regarding indicators of profitability, net interest margins of foreign and private domestic banks are higher than those of state-owned banks in all income groups, and all regions (Table 3.2) with the exception of CEEB, where state-owned banks exhibit a higher net interest margin than foreign banks. Foreign banks have a lower net interest margin than private domestic banks in the high middle income group, CIS, CEEB, and South America regions, while the reverse is true in the total sample as well as the rest of the subgroups.8

Return on average assets in the total sample is lower for state-owned banks than for foreign and private domestic banks (Tables 3.3), while return on average equity is lower for foreign banks than for state-owned and private domestic banks (Table 3.4). However, private domestic banks have a lower return on average assets than foreign banks in high middle income group, Middle East, and CIS. State-owned banks have higher return on average equity than private domestic banks in the CIS, the CEEB, and Far East and Asia, and in low income group. Also, private banks have a lower return on average equity than foreign banks in the low, middle, and high middle income groups, Middle East, CEEB, Central America and Caribbean, and Far East and Asia. The reverse relations holds for Africa, CIS, and South America.

Overall, heterogeneity in relative profitability of banks of different ownership across income levels and regions is pervasive.

D. Capitalization and Loan Quality

The capitalization of state-owned banks is significantly lower than that of private and foreign banks in the total sample, as well as in all income groups and most regions with the notable exception of Africa (Table 4.2), where these relationships are reversed. On the other hand, foreign banks exhibit a capitalization higher than private banks in the total sample, in most income groups and in the Africa, Middle East, Far East and Asia, and South America regions.

Table 4.

Loan Quality and Capitalization

* = p-value of less or equal to 5 percent.
article image
* = p-value of less or equal to 5 percent.

Regarding loan quality, we should observe that reported non-performing loans are notoriously difficult to compare across countries and we have information on only about one half of bank-year observations in our sample. Keeping these caveats in mind, we note that state-owned banks exhibit ratios of non-performing loans to total loans higher than those of private and foreign banks in the total sample, as well as in all income subgroups (Table 4.1), but these differences are not significant in several regions. On the other hand, private domestic banks exhibit a ratio higher than that of foreign banks in the high middle income group, as well as in the Africa, Middle East, CIS, and CEEB regions.

E. Summary

The picture emerging from these comparisons is one of significant differences among private, state-owned and foreign banks in terms of balance sheet compositions and loan quality, but also heterogeneity of these differences across both income groups and regions in terms of profitability, costs and capitalization. Yet, the differences identified here only pertain comparisons of unconditional means. Next, we turn to regressions which present comparisons and determinants of bank risk measures, their components, and asset and liability structure conditional on market structure, country and firm characteristics.

IV. Evidence

Our measure of bank risk is proxy of banks’ probability of failure. As in BDNJ, bank risk is measured by a Z-score defined at each date as Zt = (ROAt + EQTAt)/σ(ROAt), where ROAt is the return on average assets, EQTAt is the equity-to-assets ratio, and σ(ROAt)=|ROAtT1tROAt|.

Market structure and the relevant degree of competition are measured with concentration measures inclusive of all banks analyzed and conditional on bank ownership, given by the Hirschmann-Hirfendahl Indices (HHIs). A limitation of the HHI as a measure of competitive conditions is that the relevant market for each bank in a country is identified with the country itself. This is why we did not include in the sample banks from the U.S., Western Europe and Japan, since in these cases defining the nation as a market is problematic both because of the country’s economic size and because of the presence of many international banks.

Empirical counterparts of versions of the equilibrium conditions of our model are given by the specifications of panel regression models described next.

A. Regression Specifications

Let the dependent variable Xijt denote the Z-score, or one of its components, of bank’s i in country j at date t. The square asset market share of bank i in country j at date t is denoted by Sijt2, and the HHI index of country j at date t is given by HHIjtiSijt2. Let private domestic, state-owned, foreign banks and unclassified banks be indexed by kB ≡ {P, S, F, U}, and denote with Ik the relevant indicator functions.

The first set of regressions is given by the following country fixed effects specifications:

(1)Xijt=jajIj+A+βHHIjt1+γYjt1+δZijt1+εijt
(2)Xijt=jajIj+kB{U}AkIk+βHHIjt1+γYjt1+δZijt1+εjit
(3)Xijt=jajIj+kB{U}AkIk+kB{U}βkIkHHIjt1+γYjt1+δZijt1+εijt

The coefficients aj are country-specific intercepts, where Ij denotes the relevant indicator functions. The Ak coefficients are conditional means of the dependent variable by ownership. The coefficients β s measure the impact of a change in HHI on the dependent variable next period. Yjt is a vector of country-specific controls and Zijt a vector of bank-specific controls as of date t, which we detail below. All right-hand side time-varying variables are lagged one year so as to capture variations in the dependent variable as a function of pre-determined past values of independent variables.

In regression (1) the conditional means and the coefficient β are restricted to be the same, that is, irrespective of bank ownership. In regression (2) we allow the conditional means to differ by ownership, while in regression (3) both the conditional means and the coefficient βs are allowed to vary by ownership. These three regressions allows us to gauge the extent to which the relationship between the dependent variable and HHI varies when bank ownership is taken into account, and to test differences in the conditional means of the dependent variable.

The second set of regressions is the same as the first, except that we control for time invariant firm specific effects:

(4)Xijt=ai+βHHIjt1+γYjt1+δZijt1+εijt
(5)Xijt=ai+kB{U}βkIkHHIjt1+γYjt1+δZijt1+εjit

In regression (4), as in (2), we restrict the coefficient β to be ownership invariant, while in regression (5), as in (3), we allow the conditional means to differ by ownership. The results of these regressions are compared to regressions (2) and (3) to assess whether the relationship between the dependent variable and HHI continues to hold when a full set of time-invariant controls is introduced.

As noted, the regressions described so far can be interpreted broadly as statistical models consistent with the conditions characterizing Nash equilibria in our model. Yet, as illustrated in the model with heterogeneous banks, the effects of changes in parameters on the equilibrium choices of banks of each type can be either similar or different. Thus, we wish to measure the effects of changes in HHI on risk profiles when these changes are the result of changes in the combined market shares of all competitors of a banks of a given ownership type. To this end, we construct the concentration indexHHICijtmiSmjt2, which measures concentration of all competitors of bank i, and indexesHHICijtkmi,mkSmjt2, which measure concentration of all type-k competitors of bank i. Of course, such indexes satisfykBHHICijtkHHICijt.

Furthermore, let “ controls “ denoteai+kBαkIkSijt12+βUHHICijt1U+γYjt1+δZijt1, where we control for a bank’s market share by ownership and for the HHI of unclassified banks, in addition to country-specific and firm specific variables,. The third set of regressions is given by

(6)Xijt=kB{U}βkP(SF)IkHHICijt1P+controls+εijt
(7)Xijt=kB{U}βkS(PF)IkHHICijt1S+controls+εijt
(8)Xijt=kB{U}βkF(PS)IkHHICijt1F+controls+εijt

Coefficients βkl(qv) measure the sensitivity of the dependent variable of a type k bank to a change in the HHI of type-l competitors, when such a change is counterbalanced by a decrease in the sum of the HHIs of type-q and type-v competitors.9 For example, coefficient βPS(PF) measures the sensitivity of the dependent variable of a private domestic to a change in the HHI of state-owned bank competitors when this change is counterbalanced by a decline in the sum of the HHIs of private domestic and foreign bank competitors. These regressions allow us to gauge the extent of strategic interactions among banks of different ownership when the change in the HHI of one type competitor are occurring at the expense of the market shares of either one, or both other types’ competitors.

In addition, the informational content of the above regressions can be enhanced by considering counterbalancing changes of HHIs of one type of bank only. The last set of regressions is thus given by:

(9)Xijt=kB{U}βkP(F)IkHHICijt1P+kBβkS(F)IkHHICijt1S+controls+εijt
(10)Xijt=kB{U}βkP(S)IkHHICijt1P+kBβkF(S)IkHHICijt1F+controls+εijt
(11)Xijt=kB{U}βkS(P)IkHHICijt1S+kB{U}βkF(S)IkHHICijt1F+controls+εijt

Here, coefficients βkl(q) measure the sensitivity of the dependent variable of a type k bank to a change in the HHI of type-l competitors, when such a change is counterbalanced by a decrease in the HHIs of type-q competitors. For example, coefficient βPS(F) measures the sensitivity of the dependent variable of a private domestic to a change in the HHI of state-owned bank competitors conditional on the HHI of private domestic banks competitors being constant, when this change is counterbalanced by a decline in the HHIs of foreign bank competitors. These regressions complement regressions (6)-(8) since they allow us to gauge the strategic interactions among banks of different ownership when the increase (decrease) in the HHI of one type competitor are counterbalanced by a decline (increase) in the HHI of only one other bank type competitor.

In all regressions, the country-specific variables that control for cross-country differences in the evolution of the macroeconomy, in the supply of and demand for banking services and for market size are GDP per capita at PPP, real GDP growth, inflation and the nominal exchange rate. Cross-country differences in the risks of the macroeconomic environment are controlled for with the volatility of GDP growth, inflation and the nominal exchange rate. The firm-specific variables are the logarithm of asset size, and the loan-to-asset, deposits- to-liabilities and cost-to-income ratios, which control for banks’ differences in size, asset and liability structure, and cost efficiency. The definitions of all variables are summarized in Table 5. As our focus is on estimates of parameters A s and β s, to save on space we do not report estimates of the coefficients of the control variables.

Table 5.

Description of Variables

article image

B. Z-Score Regressions

The regressions with the Z-score as the dependent variable are presented in Table 6. As in BDNJ, the relationship between bank risk and concentration is positive (recall that a decrease in the Z-score denotes higher risk) and significant in both regressions (1) and (4). Importantly, this positive and significant relationship also holds when we use a measure of loan portfolio risk, given by the ratio of non-performing loans to gross loans,10 as well as when we use an indicator of systemic risk in the banking system, given by the average Z-score across banks (Table 6, Appendix).

Table 6.

Dependent Variable: Z(t)

Regressions 1-3 are with country fixed effects. Regressions 4-11 are with firm fixed effects. All regressions include lagged country specific variables (GDPPC, GROWTH, INFL, ER, GROWTHV, INFLV and ERV) and lagged firm-specific variables (LASSETS, GTLA, DEPL and CIR). Regressions 6-11 also include lagged Share2(I) and HHIU (see Table 5). The coefficients with p-values of robust t-statistics less than 0.05 are marked in bold, those with p-values of robust t-statistics greater than 0.05 and less than 0.10 are marked in bold italics

article image

When we control for bank ownership, the coefficient β (regression (2)) and those associated with each bank type becomes larger in absolute value in both regressions (2) and (3), indicating that such positive relationship is stronger when bank ownership is taken into account. Furthermore, note that the coefficients associated with HHI satisfy 0 ≥ βF > βP > βS (regressions (3) and (5)). Thus, the coefficient of state-owned banks is the largest in absolute value, the second largest is that of private domestic banks, while that of foreign banks is not significantly different from zero at standard significance levels. Overall, these results indicate that the positive impact of concentration on bank risk profiles is the largest, the larger is the market share of state-owned banks.

With regard to conditional means, the Z-score’s mean of state-owned banks is significantly lower than that of private domestic banks in regression (2), but becomes not significantly different from that of private domestic banks’ in regression (3). This result indicates that comparisons of conditional means that do not take into account differences in both market and ownership structures may conceal important information. Effectively, the comparatively higher conditional mean of the risk profiles of state-owned banks found with regression (2) appears primarily driven by market structure, that is, it depends on whether state-owned banks have or do not have significant market shares. By contrast, the conditional mean of the Z-score of foreign banks is significantly lower than that of private banks in both regressions (2) and (3), indicating significantly higher risk profiles for these banks compared to private domestic banks.

Next, we consider the coefficients measuring the (strategic) risk interactions among private domestic, state-owned and foreign banks (regressions 6-11).

Private domestic banks increase risk most, and significantly so, in response to an increase in the HHI of foreign bank competitors (coefficients βPF(.)); their second largest, and significant, increase in risk is in response to an increase in the HHI of state-owned bank competitors (coefficients βPS(.)). By contrast, the coefficients measuring their change in risk in response to changes in the HHI of private domestic bank competitors are not significantly different from zero (coefficients βPP(.)).

Turning to state-owned banks, they increase risk most when the HHI of state-owned bank competitors increase (coefficients βSS(.)). Moreover, they increase risk in response to an increase in the HHI of private domestic bank competitors, but they decrease it in response to an increase in the HHI of foreign bank competitors.11 Yet, both sets of coefficients associated with these responses (coefficients βSP(.) and βSF(.)) are not statistically significant at conventional confidence levels.

Finally, foreign banks decrease risk in response to a positive change in the HHI of private domestic bank competitors, but increase risk in response to a positive change in the HHI of state-owned bank competitors, although the relevant set of coefficients βFP(.) and βFS(.)) are not statistically significant. Interestingly, they also decrease risk in response to an increase in the HHI of their foreign bank competitors.

For robustness, we run all the above regressions controlling for banking crises, and obtained results essentially identical to those just presented. Thus, our key findings can be summarized as follows:

  1. The positive relationship between concentration and bank risk of failure uncovered in BDNJ, and found here with a slightly smaller sample, is stronger when bank ownership is taken into account, and it is the strongest when state-owned banks have sizeable market shares.

  2. The risk profiles of foreign banks are on average higher than those of private domestic banks, while the risk profiles of state-owned banks are not significantly different than those of private domestic banks;

  3. Private domestic banks turn out to be riskier the larger are the combined market shares of either their state-owned bank competitors, or their foreign bank competitors, or both.

C. Theory and Evidence

Under what conditions the model can rationalize these three findings? Note first that the implications of the model turn out to be consistent with the data only if the determinant Δ of the system (16)-(17) is strictly positive.12 As noted in the previous section, sufficient conditions for Δ > 0 are that at an optimum, the curvature of a bank’s revenue function with respect to its own choice of lending is larger in absolute value than the change in revenues implied by a change in the deposits of competitors. In other words, if Δ > 0 the loan markets of banks of different ownership are sufficiently segmented. Indeed, this assumption is theoretically reasonable and consistent with the evidence available for many countries.13

The first finding can be rationalized by the model if a state-owned bank is assumed to be characterized by either larger screening costs, or lower bankruptcy costs than a private domestic bank. Lower bankruptcy costs for state-owned banks can be associated with larger government guarantees, which in turn may give less incentives for these banks to invest in better screening technologies.

The second finding can be rationalized if foreign banks are assumed to have either larger screening costs than private domestic banks because of their unfamiliarity with local markets, or lower bankruptcy costs associated with comparatively larger “guarantees” from their parents, or a combination of both. Yet, differences in screening costs, if they exist, are likely to be temporary, since foreign banks can acquire local expertise by buying local banks or can accumulate local knowledge through experience.14 Another complementary explanation for the finding of the relatively higher riskiness of foreign banks may be simply that the risk profiles of foreign subsidiaries are just a component of the risk profile of the group they belong to, and international diversification of such a group could be easily consistent with each of its components being more risky.

Lastly, the third finding can be rationalized by all comparative statics exercises summarized in parts (b) of Propositions 3-5, which assume that cross-sectional variations in “relative” competition, screening, and bankruptcy costs are not too large.

In sum, under reasonable assumptions consistent with standard incentive theory under moral hazard and available evidence, our model can deliver predictions consistent with our key findings.

D. Regressions of Z-Score Components

We now look at each component of the Z-score, returns on assets, capitalization and volatility of earnings. The goal here is to gain insights on which differences in these components may explain differences in overall risk of banks with different ownership, how they are related to market structure, and through which channels strategic interactions among different types of banks are at play.

Returns on Assets (ROA)

Tables 7 report regressions with ROA as the dependent variable. Note first that there is no robust relationship between bank profitability and concentration when strategic interactions are not taken into account. This is true when the coefficient associated with HHI is not allowed to differ by bank ownership (regressions (1), (2) and (4)). When we control for bank ownership in the country fixed effect regression (3), the coefficient βS is negative and significant, while the coefficient βF is positive and significant. However, in the firm fixed effect regression (5) these coefficients are both positive but not significant.

Table 7.

Dependent Variable ROA(t)

Regressions 1-3 are with country fixed effects. Regressions 4-11 are with firm fixed effects. All regressions include lagged country specific variables (GDPPC, GROWTH, INFL, ER, GROWTHV, INFLV and ERV) and lagged firm-specific variables (LASSETS, GTLA, DEPL and CIR). Regressions 6-11 also include lagged Share2(I) and HHIU (see Table 5). The coefficients with p-values of robust t-statistics less than 0.05 are marked in bold, those with p-values of robust t-statistics greater than 0.05 and less than 0.10 are marked in bold italics.

article image

With regard to conditional means, the ROA of state-owned banks is significantly lower than that of private domestic banks in regression (2), but becomes not significantly different from that private domestic banks’ in regression (3). As in the case of the Z-score, this result indicates that when profitability is compared conditionally on market structure, state-owned banks are not less profitable than private domestic banks. In other words, state-owned banks are less profitable only when they have sizeable market shares. By contrast, the conditional mean of foreign banks’ ROA is significantly lower than that of private banks in both regressions (2) and (3). This may be in part due to relatively large entry costs these banks may have borne in the first years of their operations.

When we consider strategic interactions (regressions (6)-(11)), the following results obtain. The profitability of private domestic banks improves significantly in response to an increase in the HHI of both private domestic bank and foreign bank competitors (coefficients βPP (.) and βPF(.)). The same is true for state-owned banks in response to a positive change in the HHI of private domestic bank competitors (coefficients βSP(.)). One interpretation of these results is that the strategic interaction among private domestic, state-owned and foreign banks may have resulted in an increase in market segmentation, allowing banks to enhance their “local” market power and the associated rents, boasting their profitability through this channel. Another complementary explanation is that the competitive pressure of other bank types may induce private domestic banks to improve their efficiency. Nevertheless, these positive effects suggests that differences in profitability are not likely to account for the differences and strategic responses in risk profiles uncovered earlier.

Bank capitalization

In the regressions of Table 8, the dependent variable is the transformation of the ratio of equity to assets LEQTAt = Ln(EQTAt/(1 − EQTAt)), which guarantees that the regressions’ predicted values of the equity-to-assets ratio lie in the unit interval.

Table 8

Dependent Variable: LEQTA(t)

Regressions 1-3 are with country fixed effects. Regressions 4-11 are with firm fixed effects. All regressions include lagged country specific variables (GDPPC, GROWTH, INFL, ER, GROWTHV, INFLV and ERV) and lagged firm-specific variables (LASSETS, GTLA, DEPL and CIR). Regressions 6-11 also include lagged Share2(I) and HHIU (see Table 5). The coefficients with p-values ofrobust t-statistics less than 0.05 are marked in bold, those with p-values of robust t-statistics greater than 0.05 and less than 0.10 are marked in bold italics

article image

Two main results obtain. First, as in BDNJ, there is a negative and significant relationship between bank capitalization and concentration, but it is the strongest for stateowned banks (regressions (1)-(5)), despite the fact that, conditionally on market structure, state-owned banks have on average larger capitalization ratios (regressions (2) and (3)). Second, the capitalization of private domestic banks declines significantly in response to an increase in the HHI of state-owned bank competitors (coefficients βPS(.)), and the same result obtains for state-owned banks in response to a positive change in the HHI of state-owned bank competitors.

These findings suggest that differences in capitalization partly account for the differences and strategic responses in risk profiles of private domestic and state-owned banks.

Volatility of earnings

In the regressions of Table 9, the dependent variable is the transformation Ln[σ(ROA(t))], which guarantees that the regressions’ predicted values of the volatility of earnings are nonnegative.

Table 9.

Dependent Variable: Ln[σ(ROA(t))]

Regressions 1-3 are with country fixed effects. Regressions 4-11 are with firm fixed effects. All regressions include lagged country specific variables (GDPPC, GROWTH, INFL, ER, GROWTHV, INFLV and ERV) and lagged firm-specific variables (LASSETS, GTLA, DEPL and CIR). Regressions 6-11 also include lagged Share2(I) and HHIU (see Table 5). The coefficients with p-values of robust t-statistics less than 0.05 are marked in bold, those with p-values of robust t-statistics greater than 0.05 and less than 0.10 are marked in bold italics

article image