Rapid Growth in Transition Economies: Growth-Accounting Approach

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: giradian@imf.org

This paper uses the growth-accounting approach to determine the sources of growth in transition economies. The central conclusion is that the estimated total factor productivity (TFP) growth for the former Soviet Union republics were significantly higher than other fast growing economies. A key question for prospective growth is whether the TFP gains achieved thus far have already eliminated most of the inefficiencies of central planning-and will therefore soon fade away. Underutilized labor combined with the recent trend of faster capital accumulation may play a more important role in the medium-term growth.

Abstract

This paper uses the growth-accounting approach to determine the sources of growth in transition economies. The central conclusion is that the estimated total factor productivity (TFP) growth for the former Soviet Union republics were significantly higher than other fast growing economies. A key question for prospective growth is whether the TFP gains achieved thus far have already eliminated most of the inefficiencies of central planning-and will therefore soon fade away. Underutilized labor combined with the recent trend of faster capital accumulation may play a more important role in the medium-term growth.

I. Introduction, Purpose, and Scope of Study

This study analyzes the sources of the recent rapid growth in the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) and the prospects for its continuation.2 In the past six years, unweighted average growth of the CIS and the three Baltics countries have been above that of most other regions. The contraction in output during the first half of the 1990s, however, was so deep that, as of end-2006 real GDPs of Moldova, Georgia, Tajikistan, Ukraine, and Kyrgyzstan were still well below their 1990 levels.

The extent to which output collapsed in some CIS countries far exceeded expectations, partly due to special factors including regional political conflicts and the absence of support institutions to manage the transition to a market economy. By the time output had bottomed, it had fallen by more than 50 percent in Armenia, Azerbaijan, Georgia, Moldova, and Tajikistan.3 The pick up in growth rates since the output troughs has been impressive. But it would take until 2010 for Ukraine, 2012 for Georgia and Tajikistan, and 2015 for Moldova to regain the previous the 1990 real GDP level assuming that these countries manage to grow steadily at about eight percent a year (close to their annual average for the past five years). This would imply that the transition to regain the

previous peak in output (1990) has lasted more than two decades for some of the former Soviet Union republics (FSU). In this connection, a few historical points provide useful perspective to the fall in output and the length of the transition: (i) in the United States during the Great Depression, output per capita fell by 31 percent and recovered to its pre crisis level in 10 years; and (ii) the output fall from pre-World War II (1938) to postwar trough was 51 percent in West Germany and 45 percent in Japan; both of these countries regained their 1938 level of output by 1953—eight years after the end of the war4.

The experience of fast-growing economies shows that to sustain economic growth of at least six percent a year for a long period, high investment (more than 25 percent of GDP) is needed (examples include China, South Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, and Vietnam). But investment outlays for the CIS, excluding Azerbaijan and Mongolia, 5 averaged about 20 percent of GDP in 1996–2006, and total employment for the region as a whole at end-2006 was about 10 percent below its 1990 level.

In the economic literature there are mainly two approaches with regard to sources of growth, namely the cross-section growth-accounting approach and the panel regression approach. This paper uses the growth accounting approach to analyze the sources of the recent rapid growth in transition economies and compare these with other fast growing economies.6 The research questions include the following: What explains the strong economic recovery in the CIS? Is either investment or TFP growth responsible for the major shifts in economic growth? 7 What can be learned from the experiences of other countries that sustained rapid growth for a long time?

The main contributions of this paper are as follows. First, it examines the sources of recent growth for all transition economies and compares them with other fast growing economies in East Asia over the past three decades, and Western Europe and Japan during the “Golden Age” (post-war period). The data used for transition economies are the latest covering 1991–2006. Second, instead of the arbitrary assumptions regarding the share of capital in income that were often made in the growth literature, the paper adopts the most up-to-date econometric techniques to properly estimate it, including fixed effects, 2SLS, and cointegration techniques. However, the estimation is regional rather than country-specific, given the short time span of reliable and comparable national accounts statistics. Third, for the sake of sensitivity analysis, the sources of growth were also estimated under different assumptions of capital shares and initial capital output ratios.

The growth-accounting exercise suggests that the CIS’s recent strong growth has been driven largely by growth in TFP. On average, capital accumulation made a modest contribution and employment rates continued to drop till recently in some countries in the region. Looking ahead, the critical question is whether the rapid TFP growth can be sustained. Assuming that TFP growth slows down, other sources of growth will be essential to sustain a rapid catch-up. In this connection, the recent trend of faster capital accumulation and the improvement in employment in some of the CIS countries are expected to play a more important role in future growth.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II records the region’s growth performance both on the expenditure and production sides with brief overviews of individual countries. Section III reviews the various growth-accounting methodologies and data issues. Section IV uses the growth-accounting approach to identify the sources of growth. The contribution of the estimated TFP growth to output in the CIS is compared with other fast-growing economies in Europe, Latin America, and East Asia. Section V summarizes the findings and draws conclusions.

II. Overview of Output Development

During 2001–06, real GDP growth for the CIS region picked up strongly to an unweighted average of eight percent a year, outperforming the average growth in other regions (including the fast growing economies of East Asia, with the exception of China). The rapid growth has been driven by domestic demand. Real private consumption grew by about nine percent per year for the region as a whole, underpinned by large hikes in real wages (Figure 2). In some CIS countries, the substantial increase in remittances also supported the rise in private consumption. While the benign global environment and higher commodity prices have encouraged a rapid increase in exports, the sharp increase in consumption has led to an even higher growth in imports. The contribution of net exports to GDP growth, therefore, was negative in some CIS countries and marginally positive in others.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Real GDP Index in 2006 (1990=100)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2007, 164; 10.5089/9781451867282.001.A001

Source: Derived from the IMF’s World Economic Outlook (WEO).
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Real Private Consumption, 1996–2005

(Average percentage change)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2007, 164; 10.5089/9781451867282.001.A001

Source: Authors’ calculations from the UNECE’s database.

While real investment grew by double-digits levels in several CIS countries, the ratio of investment to GDP remained relatively low (Figure 3). Despite the very favorable growth performance, the average investment to GDP ratio for the CIS was about five percentage points below the simple average for the three Baltics, three percentage points below the five Central European (CE) economies, and some 10 percentage points below

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Investment, 1996–2006

(In percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2007, 164; 10.5089/9781451867282.001.A001

Source: Derived from the IMF WEO database.

the fast-growing countries in East Asia. In particular, the level of investment remained low in sectors other than oil, gas, and metallurgy. FDI inflows outside the commodity sectors remained low.

What were the country special factors explaining the rapid growth in the CIS?

Turning to individual countries, Russia experienced eight years (1999–2006) of strong economic growth. Beyond 2000, the impetus to growth was mainly private consumption fuelled by rising incomes following the sharp rise in international oil and gas prices. The rising domestic demand led to significant increase in imports. As in other energy exporting countries, the income and wealth effects associated with high oil and gas prices lifted non-energy output. The latter reflected the rebound in real wages from the depressed levels in the wake of the 1998 financial crisis. While real fixed investment grew by an annual average rate of nine percent, the investment-to-GDP ratio remained relatively low, particularly in the non-energy sectors.

The strong growth in Ukraine in 2000–06 was due to the cumulative effect of structural reforms introduced in 2000–01 and positive terms-of-trade shocks. An export-led upturn in key manufacturing sectors (particularly in steel and chemicals), which benefited from increased external demand and higher international prices of metal products, contributed to an overall surge in real industrial output. Foreign direct investment has soared since 2004 to an estimated US$10 billion in 2005–06—more than the cumulative total for all preceding years. The bulk of the recent inflow is accounted for by the privatization of Kryvorizhstal, the steel mill sold in 2005 to Mittel Steel, and a handful of bank deals. Other sectors have been barely touched by foreign capital due to high bureaucratic interference and influence of domestic oligarchs.

FDI-led reconstruction of the energy sector has also contributed to the strong economic performance in Azerbaijan and Kazakhstan. The completion of the Baku-Tbilisi-Ceyhan oil pipeline (with a capacity of one million barrels a day) and the extraction from the large Azeri-Chriag-Guneshi oilfield raised the annual growth rate in 2005–06 to 27 percent in Azerbaijan. In Kazakhstan, high oil prices helped boost economic growth to an average of about 10 percent a year in 2001–06.

Growth in Armenia, Georgia, Moldova, and Tajikistan was also strong. On the expenditure side, economic growth has been driven by private consumption and small scale private investment. On the production side, construction and services accounted for most of the growth. High levels of remittances from workers living abroad combined with substantial growth in real wages have fueled private consumption growth. In Georgia, the economy benefited greatly from its role as a transit corridor for oil and natural gas. The construction sector was boosted by the work on the Baku-Tbilisi- Ceyhan oil pipeline and the Shah-Deniz gas pipeline, which have provided employment and generated demand for business services. Growth in Kyrgyzstan was much lower than in the other CIS countries due to the accident in 2002 at the Kumar gold mine, which accounts for a large share of the country’s industrial output and exports, and to political upheaval of 2005 (Tulip Revolution).

Belarus, with limited market reforms, has experienced 10 years of uninterrupted strong growth averaging about seven percent a year. Unlike other CIS countries, this rapid growth has occurred from a relatively high initial base—Belarus suffered a smaller drop in output in the early 1990s than most other CIS countries. The rapid growth reflected the country’s ability to import energy from Russia at below-market prices while the prices for its energy-intensive exports grew markedly. Belarus used the trading gains to pay large wage increases, subsidize state enterprises, and finance large-scale investment projects that underpinned a policy of strong government interference in the economy.

Strong growth has also been recorded in Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan, also nonreformed economies, underpinned by higher commodity prices. According to official figures, real GDP growth in Turkmenistan averaged more than 15 percent in 2000–06, but it is likely that these estimates have a significant upward bias.8 Uzbekistan’s average growth of five percent in 2001–06 has been driven by favorable world market prices for gold and cotton—Uzbekistan’s main exports—and increasing exports of natural gas and cotton. The binding constraint on higher economic growth in Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan (in the nonresource sectors) continues to be the extensive state intervention and the relatively closed nature of these two economies, which hold back private sector development.

III. Methodology and Data Issues

Growth accounting helps explain economic growth by decomposing output growth into the contributions of capital, labor, and a residual measure of gains in the efficiency with which capital and labor are used. This residual is an estimate of the changes in total factor productivity (TFP) that reflect, in addition to biases due to methodological assumptions and measurement errors, a wide range of factors affecting input efficiency. The residual is defined as the growth in output that occurs with unchanged levels of the factor inputs. The interpretation of this residual depends on the definition of factor inputs employed in the analysis. Labor’s productivity is affected, among other things, by educational attainment and work experience. The productivity of capital is affected, among other things, by the age of the equipment, the level of technology embodied within it, and whether the capital good is publicly or privately owned.

Any measurement errors present in the variables used to measure labor (i.e., employment in the informal sector was not captured) and capital (for example the extent of capacity utilization) are mechanically imputed to TFP. Also a failure to account for improvements in the quality of the capital stock (including age of capital stock) or labor (including hours worked, education, and training) will lead to an overestimation of the TFP component. The organizing principle of growth accounting is the Cobb-Douglas aggregate production function:

y=EθKαLβ(1)

where Y is GDP in real terms, θ is the rate of productivity growth (TFP), α represents the share of capital in GDP, β represents share of labor, K is capital stock, and L is employment. Output growth is then divided into components attributable to changes in the factors of production. Differentiating the logarithm of equation (2) with respect to t, we obtain

g=θ+α(growth rate of capital)+β(growth rate of labor)(2)

where g is the growth rate in output, θ is the growth rate of TFP, α is the elasticity of output with respect to capital, and β is the elasticity of output with respect to labor. The question then is how to estimate α and β.

Measuring capital stock

Measuring capital stock is fraught with difficulties as most developing and transition countries have no official capital stock estimates. The World Bank data set on capital stock is based on Nehru and Dhareshwar (1993), which uses the perpetual inventory method (PIM) to estimate physical capital for a group of 92 developing and industrial countries. Nehru and Dhareshwar estimated the initial capital stock from investment data going back to 1950, where available.9 They assume an identical share of capital in output of 0.40 for all countries. According to the PIM the value of the capital stock in a given year is equal to the value of the capital stock of the previous year, plus the real gross investment during the year, minus the depreciation of the initial capital during the year.

K(t+1)=Kt+Itδ*Kt(3)

where K is the capital stock, I is the investment, and δ is the depreciation rate of capital. Equation (3) implies that the initial capital would be needed to calculate the capital stock series from accumulation of investments. In the literature, one popular approach to generate an estimate of the initial capital stock is based on Harberger (1978). This approach begins with the observation that if the capital-output ratio is constant in a given period, the capital and output growth rates are equal during that period. From equation (3) the rate of growth of capital could be derived as:

(KtKt1)/Kt=δ+(It/Kt1)(4)

which is here assumed to be equal to the rate of growth of output. Thus, equation (4) can be written as:

Kt1=It/(g+δ)(5)

In the growth literature, g (growth in output) in equation (5) is estimated by using the three-year or five-year average annual growth rate of real GDP with the view to avoid short-run fluctuations. The base-year capital stock would then be centered in the middle of the three or five-year period, and the recursion formula (3) for capital accumulation would have to be applied in reverse to arrive at the initial capital stock. The effect of the estimate of initial capital stock on growth accounting estimates is significant in the early years, but then it gradually fades away with time.10 Nevertheless, this paper also estimates the TFP growth using different levels of initial capital stock to GDP ratios.

Measuring capital and labor shares in output

There are several approaches in the growth literature to estimating the shares of capital and labor in output. The first approach assumes that factor markets are perfectly competitive so that earnings of the factors (capital and labor) are proportional to their productivities. However, this approach cannot be used for most CIS and developing countries due to unavailability of detailed national accounts statistics. The second approach uses a priori measure of capital in the range of 0.3–0.4 (most commonly used in the growth literature).11 But many studies have found that the share of capital for developing countries is significantly larger than 0.4. The third approach would be to estimate the coefficients of the production function by regressing the growth rate of output on the growth rate of inputs and on the growth rates in capital and labor. The intercept (θ) then measures the growth in TFP, and the coefficients on the factor growth rates measure the shares of capital and labor, respectively. The main advantage of this process is that it dispenses with the assumption that factor social marginal products coincide with the observable factor process. The disadvantage of the regression approach, however, is that the growth of capital and labor cannot usually be regarded as exogenous with respect to variations in TFP—in particular, the factor growth rates would receive credit for correlated variations in unobservable technological change.

Also, the regression framework has to be extended from its usual form to allow for time and cross-section variations in factor shares and in the TFP growth rate (Barro, 1998).

Shigeru, Khan, and Murao (2003) proposed a fourth approach that does not need the assumption of perfectly competitive factor markets nor assumes any particular functional form of the aggregate production function. Their approach is based on nonparametric kernel derivative estimation techniques developed in the statistics and econometrics literature (see Pagan and Ullah, 1999). This approach estimates much lower elasticity of output with respect to capital (around 0.20) for several East Asian countries, thus emphasizing even more the role of the residual (growth in TFP) in explaining growth.

Finally, in recent years few studies used the cointegration technique to estimate the share of capital in output in nontransition economies. If the factor inputs in equation (2) are nonstationary, then the parameter estimates using standard techniques do not have standard asymptotically normal distributions and are prone to spurious correlations. Econometrically, the cointegration approach is useful because of the following: (i) it is robust to endogeneity; (ii) robust to many forms of simultaneity; (iii) robust to many forms of measurement error; and (iv) can isolate long run steady state relationships from short run dynamics.

Shares of capital and labor in output used by the growth-accounting literature

Boseworth and Collins (1996) adopted the Nehru and Dhareshwar data and extended it to 1994 using PIM. The share of physical capital and labor was assumed to be identical across countries at 0.35 and 0.65, respectively. Boseworth and Collins (2003), using again identical physical capital share of 0.35 in output across countries, estimated the sources of growth for 84 countries during the four decades from 1960–2000. For 1960–70, they find that TFP accounted for 42 percent in the OECD; 29 percent in Latin America; and 23 percent in East Asia. For 1990–2000, their estimate show that productivity growth slowed down in all regions of the world, including OECD to 20 percent and Latin America to 12 percent.

Senhadji (2000), while using the same sample, estimated the share of capital for individual countries and for different regions by applying the Fully Modified estimator in levels and first differences. The estimated shares for physical capital by regions were as follows: East Asia 0.48, South Asia 0.56, Latin America 0.52, Middle East and North Africa 0.63, and sub-Saharan Africa 0.43.

In a study on the sources of growth in ten Middle Eastern and North African (MENA) countries over the period 1960–98, Abu-Qarn and Abu Bader (2006) estimate the long-run share of capital in output using cointegration (country specific) and panel data (region-specific) methods. They find that the share of capital in the MENA countries is much higher than the conventional share of 0.3–0.4. Their analysis of the sources of growth showed that the role of TFP in determining economic growth is insignificant and negative in some of the MENA countries and that most of the growth was due to the accumulation of factor inputs.

As to transition countries, and in the absence of information on factor prices that would allow to approximate the elasticities of output with respect to capital and labor, De Broeck and Koen (2000) assumed shares of 0.3 for capital and 0.7 for labor. Loukoianova and Uigovskaya (2004) extended the period used by Broeck and Koen but using the same elasticities of output with respect to capital and labor for all transition countries. To the extent that capital share in output is underestimated, it is no surprise that the results in their papers showed that most of the decline in output in 1991–97 and recovery in output in 1998–2002 are explained by the movement in TFP growth. A more recent study on the sources of recent rapid growth in Central and Eastern European countries (Schadler and others, 2006) also assumed shares of 0.35 and 0.65 for capital and labor, respectively.

Data issues

The appropriate use of growth accounting techniques depends on the availability of reliable statistics on output and factor inputs. With reference to the CIS, this may pose some constraints on the application of more elaborate approaches, including those comprising multiple production factors (i.e. in addition to labor and capital). In view of these constraints, this paper’s approach is limited to the traditional measure of TFP, that is the Solow residual. With this caveat in mind, the calculation of TFP in this paper covers 27 transition countries (comprising thirteen CIS, three Baltics, five Central European (CE), and six Southeast European (SEE) countries covering the 1991–2006 period. For comparison purposes the growth accounting for several fast-growing economies, including Chile, China, Ireland, and South Korea is also performed.

A new database has been compiled from a number of sources including the IMF’s, World Economic Outlook (WEO), the International Labor Organization (ILO), and the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE). The data set on the CIS, in particular, suffers from various serious weaknesses due to underreporting by private enterprises to avoid taxes and regulations, particularly in the early years of transition. The decline in output in the CIS during the first half of the 1990s could be overstated because the statistical system was designed to collect information only on publicly-owned enterprises. Beyond the mid-1990s, the information on the emerging private sector gradually became available and was incorporated into the statistical system. Also, the data for Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, and Uzbekistan are still incomplete and not always of good quality, hence data from these countries should be interpreted cautiously. The initial capital stock, K(0), is estimated using equation (3).12 But, one major concern about the measurement of the capital stock is that a significant portion of the communist capital stock may have been permanently scrapped. If so, this would cause the contribution of capital accumulation to be underestimated during the subsequent recovery. In order to address this concern, a one-time adjustment for the permanent scrapping of a significant portion of the capital stock during the communist era is applied; that is, the capital stock for the CIS countries is reduced by the same rate as output between 1990 and 1995 so that the capital-output ratio is not allowed to rise during the course of the sharp contraction in output. Also, this paper treats the quality of capital the same over time and across countries. An example for improvement in the quality of capital would include a shift from long-life capital (buildings) to short-life capital (machinery and equipment).

This paper treats all workers as if they were identical over time and across countries. In reality, there are major differences in the quality of labor. Obviously, workers in different countries have different levels of skills. Typically, education and number of hours worked are emphasized as key components of effective labor. Such data, however, are not available for most CIS countries.

Alternatively, the inputs are also adjusted for utilization of capital stock and labor. Failure to make adjustments for capacity utilization of capital and labor, such as the failure to account for improvements in capital and labor quality, tend to overestimate growth in TFP.13 But among the CIS countries, capacity utilization estimates are only available for Russia, based on industry surveys industry.14 These surveys suggest a “U-shaped” pattern of capital utilization that falls until 1996 and rising from 1999 onward. High capacity utilization in recent years may have been spurred by structural reform as well. These surveys also show that labor utilization increased from around 70 percent during 1994–98 to around 85 percent during 2000-04. In this paper, the results of the capacity utilization for Russia are used as proxy for capital stock and labor utilization in other CIS countries.

Few growth-accounting studies on nontransition economies made adjustments to labor quality by including education, age, or gender (Young, 1994, and Boseworth and Collins, 2003). Such information is available only for selected years and is limited for industrial countries as well as for some emerging countries. More importantly, the education level in transition economies, as measured by secondary school attainment or average years of study, is relatively high as compared with other developing and emerging economies, and there is little variation among them. Thus, the correlation between the education level and growth is expected to be weak in this case. In the absence of adequate indicators that reflect changes in the quality of labor over time and across countries, the growth in total factor productivity will therefore be overestimated.

Estimated results of the shares of capital and labor

The estimated TFP growth during 1996–2006 was the highest for the Baltics (3.0 percent), followed by the CIS (2.3 percent), and CE (1.6 percent). For the CIS sample, using the fixed effects econometric technique with cross-section weights, the estimated elasticity of capital is 0.63 and of labor 0.51.15 Ideally, separate production function for each country should be used. But given the short historical period (1991–2006), this paper assumes that the production functions are similar for each region. The countries included in each region (CIS, CE, and Baltics) share some common characteristics and are likely to have similar production functions. The sum of the capital and labor elasticities reported in Table 2 is not far away from unity for the three Baltics and the five Central European countries, but slightly higher than one for the CIS. The endogeneity problem is partially addressed by using 2SLS or instrumental variables, although finding good instruments remains a challenge. The estimates of the shares of capital and labor using the 2SLS are almost identical with the fixed effect technique.

Table 1.

Output Decline and Recovery

article image
Source: Authors’ own calculation from the WEO.

The sharp fall in output is partly due to civil conflicts over the autonomous region of Ossetia and Abkhazia in Georgia, and Transnistria in Moldova.

Table 2.

Regional Estimates of the Shares of Inputs

(1996-2006)

article image
Source: Authors’ own calculations.Note: All coefficients are significant at least at 1 percent confidence level. The instruments for 2SLS are the lagged capital and labor growth rates.Baltics-3: includes Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania.CE-5: includes Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovaka, and Slovenia.SEE-6: includes Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, Macedonia, and Romania.

Labor Market

The transition from central planning to market economy has involved large losses in employment as unproductive firms have been closed, state enterprises were privatized, and production processes became more efficient. For the region as a whole, employment declined by about 20 percent from 1990 to 1997. The economic expansion that started in most countries of the region after the Russian crisis in 1998 has led only to modest employment increases in Russia, Ukraine, and Central Asia. As of 2006 and relative to the pre-transition level of 1990, the region still lost slightly more than 10 percent of its employment (Figure 8).

Most transition economies have experienced large shifts in labor between the public and private sectors. But, the reduction in employment in the public sector was not offset by the increase in private sector, except for Azerbaijan, Kyrgyzstan, Mongolia, Tajikistan, and Uzbekistan. By 2006, the private sector generally accounted for between 60–80 percent of total employment. It is noteworthy that the share of employment in the public sector remains higher in the slower-reforming economies (such as Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan).

In 1995–2006, population and labor force growth rates increased in the range of 1-2 percent a year in Uzbekistan, Tajikistan, Kyrgyzstan, and Azerbaijan. In contrast, population and labor force rates declined by 1 to 1½ percent a year in Armenia, Georgia, Moldova, Russia, and Ukraine due to reduced fertility, increasing mortality and emigration. With respect to the quality of the labor force, the secondary school enrollment rate in the CIS countries is still much higher than in most low- and middle-income developing countries. The human capital stock inherited from the Soviet era was very high.

The jobless recovery in some CIS countries may reflect the poor quality of labor market statistics. Official statistics fail to fully capture fully the improvement in employment in small and medium-size enterprises and in service sectors that are less well-monitored in the industry. A difficult business environment in some of the CIS countries appears to have limited the ability for small and medium-sized enterprises to play a key role as employment generators. Self employment has increased substantially and is mainly concentrated in farming, wholesale and retail trade, and construction.

The registered unemployment rates, according to an ILO definition, are relatively low. But, the labor force survey data indicate high rates of unemployment rate (varying from 9 percent in Kazakhstan, Russia, and Ukraine to 20 percent in Armenia, Georgia, and Moldova). Engagement in the informal sector by those officially listed as unemployed or economically inactive is widespread in the CIS countries. According to the ILO, the size of the informal sector employment accounts for about one-half of all employment in the CIS as compared to about a quarter in Central European (CE) economies. Informal sector jobs are defined as value-adding activities outside the tax net and regulation. These activities may be unregistered and untaxed by their nature (household subsistence economy) or emerge because of purposeful evasion and noncompliance.

IV. Growth Accounting Results

A. Transition Economies

The contribution of factor inputs (capital and labor) to growth in output, measured by factor growth rates weighted by their income shares, is presented in Figure 4 and Table 3 as is the rate of growth of TFP. Unlike previous studies on transition economies, results indicate that for 1996-2006 the most important source of growth by far has been capital accumulation, with the exception of Armenia, Tajikistan, and Ukraine, where the contribution of TFP growth was higher. At the same time, the contribution of labor has been remarkably low, given the sharp decline in employment in the 1990s (improvements in quality of labor are reflected in TFP growth).

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Sources of Growth in Transition Economies, 1996–2006

(In percentage points of GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2007, 164; 10.5089/9781451867282.001.A001

Sources: Authors’ own calculations based on the IMF World Economic Outlook database.Baltics (Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania).CE: Central Europe (Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovak Republic, and Slovenia).SEE: Southeast Europe (Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, Macedonia, and Romania).
Table 3.

Growth Accounting Results for Transition Economies

(In percent, annual averages, 1996–2006)

article image
Sources: Authors’ own calculations.Note. Annual depreciation rate of capital stock is assumed at 5 percent; elasticity of output with respect to capital 0.6 for the CIS and Southeast Europe, 0.5 for Baltics, and 0.40 for Central Europe; and initial capital stock to GDP ratio of 2.

The results also indicate that growth differences across countries and over time were driven by labor productivity as well. Growth in labor productivity can be decomposed into capital deepening (i.e., increases in physical capital) and growing TFP, which in this study includes improvement in labor quality. During 1996-2006, average annual TFP growth in the CIS was higher than in CE and SEE, but lower than in the Baltics. There is significant variation in the estimate of TFP growth among CIS countries, with Armenia and Azerbaijan above 4 percentage points, Georgia and Belarus between 2–3 percentage points, Moldova, Russia, and Ukraine from 1 to 2 percentage points. TFP growth was less than one percentage point in Uzbekistan and negative in Mongolia.

Overall the estimated TFP growth for CIS countries is high compared with the results found in the literature on growth accounting for other countries. A natural question is then, what were the factors that led to these high TFP growth?

  • The inefficiencies inherited from central planning left much scope for managerial improvements, labor shedding, and gains from inter-industry resource reallocation.

  • Higher TFP growth could also be explained by the scale of some of the CIS economies, which are relatively poor economies with very low endowment of technology. Hence, for a given technological innovation, the smaller the initial endowment the higher the growth of TFP. When capital is scarce, its marginal productivity is considerable. Therefore, for similar investment rates, the contribution of capital deepening should be larger in economies with less capital.

  • Increases in capacity utilization could also raise TFP growth. Most CIS countries experienced significant increases in capacity utilization from their low levels reached in the mid-1990s.

  • There is a strong correlation between the successful macroeconomic stabilization and the progress made in market reforms in the late 1990s and total factor productivity growth (see Iradian, 2007).

  • More importantly, a significant portion of the high productivity growth is attributable to the rebound effect after the sharp fall in output in the first half of the 1990s (see Iradian, 2007).

To test for the robustness of the TFP growth estimates, other scenarios are also prepared based on different assumptions of initial capital to output ratio (k) and elasticities of output with respect to capital (α). An increase in k from 1.5 to 2.5 (with share of capital of 0.6) raises the estimated TFP growth for the CIS region from 0.9 to 3.2 percentage points. A decrease in the capital share (α) from 0.6 to 0.4 (close to the share of capital used in the literature) increases average annual TFP growth from 2.1 to 3.5 percentage points (equivalent to 57 percent of output growth in 1996–2006). In general, countries with higher capital shares (α) will tend to have lower TFP growth (for the same growth rates of capital and labor); a higher α would result in a rise of the contribution of physical capital and a decline in the contribution of TFP growth.

Appendix Table 6 reports the results for the three sub-periods (1991–95, 1996–2000, and 2001–06) with and without adjustment for capacity utilization. TFP growth was sharply negative in the early years of the transition but turned to significantly positive after the mid-1990s, indicating that part of the initial sharp productivity decline was temporary, with production factors being less than fully utilized. During the sharp contraction of 1991–95, TFP fell dramatically, and accounted for about half of the contraction in output. Factor contribution was also negative in the CIS and the Baltics during the first half of the 1990s, reflecting the reduction in employment and investment. With the exception of Mongolia and Uzbekistan, total labor employment fell in all CIS and Baltic countries.

The increase in capital contribution in 2001–06 as compared with 1996–2000 is attributable to a rebound in savings that has taken place in most CIS countries since 2001. The average ratio of investment to GDP for the CIS increased by about four percentage points from 1996–2000 to 2001–06. Finally, with adjustment for capacity utilization (Scenario B in Table 6), the average TFP growth in 2001–06 went from 3.8 to 2.9 percentage points.

Table 4.

Sensitivity of TFP Growth Estimates, 1996–2006

article image
Source: Authors’ own calculations.Note. Annual depreciation rate of capital stock is assumed at five percent.
Table 5.

Sources of Growth, Historical Perspective, 1950–2006

(In percent, annual averages)

article image
Sources: Authors’ own calculations for Chile, China, Ireland, and Korea Republic of.

Christenson et al (1980) for the period 1951-60.

Young (1995); simple average for Hong Kong, Singapore, Korea, and Taiwan.

Table 6.

Growth-Accounting Results for Transition Economies, 1991–2006

article image
Sources: Authors’ own calculations, as explained in text, based on the IMF World Economic Outlook and the ILO databases.

Adjusted for capacity utilization based on the results of surveys of the Russian industry.

Includes Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania

Includes Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovak Republic, and Slovenia.

Includes Albania, Bulgaria, Croatia, Macedonia, and Romania.

Table 7.

Real GDP Growth, 1991–2006

article image
Sources: IMF World Economic Outlook database with some revisions for the early 1990s based on national authorities.
Table 8.

Gross Fixed Capital Formation, 1991–2006

(Calculated at constant prices)

article image
Sources: IMF World Economic Outlook database, and for missing earlier years from the respective IMF staff reports.
Table 9.

Employment, 1991–2006

(In thousands)

article image
Sources: International Labor Organization and IMF World Econmic Outlook databases.

Includes Mongolia but excludes Turkmenistan.