Abstract
By issuing tax-exempt bonds, the government can incur debt and never pay back any principal or interest, even if the economy without public debt evolves on a dynamically efficient growth path. The welfare effects of such a Ponzi type borrowing scheme are mixed. The current young will unambiguously benefit.Depending on preferences and the aggregate technology, also a finite number of subsequent generations may benefit. The welfare of all generations thereafter, however, will be lower than in the economy without public debt.
I. Introduction
The Diamond (1965) overlapping generations model may generate competitive equilibria in which the growth rate of the labor force exceeds the long-run return on capital. In these cases the economy is said to be dynamically inefficient and the government can play a so-called Ponzi game. That is, the government can issue bonds and roll over interest and principal from period to period by perpetually issuing new bonds to render debt service. Such a Ponzi game is beneficial as it removes overaccumulation of capital associated with dynamic inefficiency.1
The present note demonstrates that the government can even run a Ponzi game if the economy without public debt is dynamically efficient. This becomes possible when the return on private bonds or equity is taxed and the government issues tax-exempt bonds.2 Unlike a traditional Ponzi game, however, the welfare effects of a Ponzi game based on the issuance of tax-exempt bonds are rather mixed. The current young will unambiguously benefit. Depending on preferences and the aggregate technology, also a finite number of subsequent generations may benefit. Thereafter, however, welfare is lower than in the economy without public debt.
II. The Model
Consider an overlapping generations economy in which at each time t a new generation, referred to as generation t, is born and lives for two periods. In the first period of life individuals supply one unit of labor, consume, and save for old-age by purchasing one period bonds in the capital market. In the second period of life individuals retire and consume out of the proceedings of their savings. The size of each generation is an N multiple of its forerunner, that is N is the economy′s exogenous growth factor.
Utility of a generation t individual is assumed to be ut = ln ct +β ln zt, where ct and zt are young- and old-age consumption and β > 0 is a discount factor. Young-age consumption is determined by ct = wt − st and old-age consumption by
where γ ≡β/(1 + β) is the marginal propensity to save out of labor income.
Competitive firms finance investment by issuing one period bonds and hire labor to produce a homogenous good which serves for both consumption and investment purposes. Aggregate production of all firms at time t is determined by
Each factor of production is rewarded by its marginal product. Assuming that capital fully depreciates within one period, the gross rate that competitive firms pay on one period bonds at time t thus reads
and the wage rate at time t is given by
The government imposes a capital tax at the rate τ so that the net rate that individuals receive on their savings at time t reads
Rather than paying back the debt, the government rolls over interest and principal from period to period by issuing new bonds at each time t. If such a Ponzi game is feasible, the amount of bonds issued by the government at time t + 1 will equal
Where
In contrast to private bonds, public bonds are tax-exempt. Therefore, non-arbitrage in the bond market requires
Equilibrium in the capital market obtains, when aggregate savings equal the amount of public and private bonds. As the latter determine the stock of capital at time t + 1, the capital market equilibrium condition may be written as
The evolution of the economy can be characterized by two difference equations determining the dynamics of public bonds and the stock of capital. It is convenient to express both magnitudes in intensive form. Thus, let kt = Kt/Lt denote the capital stock per unit of labor and bt = Bt/Υt the debt-GDP ratio at time t.3 Then, straightforward manipulation of eqs. (1) to (6) yields
III. The Feasibility of a Ponzi Game
Consider first, as a benchmark, an economy without public debt. Thus, let bt = 0 for all t = 0, 1, .... Proposition 1 establishes the condition which guarantees that the economy without public bonds is dynamically efficient.4
The present economy is dynamically efficient if limt→∞ Rt < N. When bt = 0 for all t, it follows from (7) that limt→∞ kt = [Aγ (1 −α)/N]1/(1−α). Therefore, considering (2), one gets limt→∞ Rt [Aγ (1 −α)/N]−1 It follows that limt→∞ Rt < N is equivalent to γ < α/(1 − α). Q.E.D.
Next, it will be analyzed under which condition the government can play a Ponzi game even though γ < α/(1 − α), that is, even though the economy is dynamically efficient. To start with, consider difference equation (8) and observe that it has a unique non-trivial fixed point at
Obviously,


If the government issues bonds at time 0 in an amount which satisfies
Things turn out to be completely different, if the government issues bonds at time 0 at a rate
Proposition 2 summarizes these results.
Note that (11) is equivalent to
when bt = 0 for all t, where R = limt→∞ Rt is the steady state return to capital. That is, in the presence of tax-exempt public bonds a Ponzi game is feasible if and only if in the absence of public bonds the steady state net of tax return to capital is smaller than the economy’s growth factor. In contrast, without tax exemption a Ponzi game would only be feasible if the gross of tax return to capital was smaller than the economy’s growth factor.
Compounding the results stated in Propositions 1 and 2, the following corollary can be established.
Condition (12) is equivalent to
when bt = 0 for all t. Thus, when the economy’s growth factor is just between the steady state net of tax return to capital and the steady state gross of tax return to capital, a Ponzi game is feasible and the economy is dynamically efficient.
There is a similarity between the result stated in Corollary 1 and a result derived by Grossman and Yanagawa (1993) and King and Ferguson (1993) in an endogenous growth model where an externality from investment in physical capital sustains long-run per capita income growth. The externality creates a wedge between the private and the social return to capital. If the endogenously determined growth rate lies between the private and the social return to capital, then a Ponzi game is feasible although the economy is dynamically efficient (as the growth rate is below the social return to capital).
IV. Welfare Implications
In the Diamond (1965) economy a Ponzi game – when feasible – is beneficial as it removes overaccumulation of capital associated with dynamic inefficiency.6 In contrast, under the condition stated in Corollary 1 there is no dynamic inefficiency despite the fact that a Ponzi game is feasible. In fact, a Ponzi game based on the issuance of tax-exempt bonds cannot be generally welfare improving as there is no such thing as overaccumulation.
However, as the next proposition states, a Ponzi game will unambiguously benefit generation 0 and, depending on preferences and the aggregate technology, a finite number of subsequent generations.
Let the government issue bonds at time 0 in an amount satisfying
the welfare ofgeneration 0 increases,
- the welfare of generation t, t = 1,2,… increases if and only if
if the welfare of generation t increases, the welfare of all generations j = 1,…, t − 1 will also increase.
Proof:
See the Appendix.
Members of generation 0 benefit because they are affected by the launch of the Ponzi game at time 0 only through an increase in the return on their saving at time 1. This is because the wage rate that the members of generation 0 receive when young is predetermined by the stock of capital accumulated at time −1. All subsequent generations are in two ways affected by the Ponzi game. Since the Ponzi game has a negative effect on capital accumulation, it both lowers the wage rate received when young and increases the return on saving received when old. For a finite number of generations the overall result of these two effects may be positive. In fact, the more generations will benefit the larger is γ and the smaller is α. A large γ implies a large saving and, thus, a large benefit from an increase in the return on saving. A small α, on the other hand, implies that aggregate production inelastically responds to a decrease in the capital stock, which dampens the negative effect of a Ponzi game on capital accumulation.
Since the sequence


Proposition 3 confines attention to the case
Let the government issue bonds at time 0 in an amount satisfying
the welfare of generation 0 increases,
- there is some
so that the welfare of all generations t decreases if
Proof:
See the Appendix.
The result is illustrated in Figure 3. Like in the case


V. Conclusion
The present note has shown that the government may issue bonds and roll over interest and principal, that is run a Ponzi game, even if the economy without public debt is dynamically efficient. This becomes possible when the government taxes capital income and the net of tax interest rate is smaller than the economy’s rate of growth, whereas the gross of tax interest rate is larger. Then, if the government exempts interest payment on public bonds from capital taxes, the total amount of public debt will grow at a lower rate than aggregate income and, as a consequence, a Ponzi game becomes feasible. Such a Ponzi game will benefit the current young generation and, depending on the parameters of taste and technology, a finite (maybe large) number of future generations. Thereafter, however, welfare is lower than in an economy without public debt. Thus, tax-exempt bonds may be employed by governments that want to please current generations and the generations that live in the not too distant future.
Appendix
In order to prove Propositions 3 and 4, the following Lemma will be established.
for t = 1,2,....
Transforming back yields eq. (13). Q.E.D.
Note that indirect utility at time t is, in fact, a 1 + β multiple of vt. Since the factor 1 + β is inconsequential, it has been omitted for simplicity.
Obviously, v0 is strictly increasing in b0.
By backward induction one gets
References
Ball, L., D.W. Elmendorf, and N.G. Mankiw, 1998, The deficit gamble, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30, 699-720.
Chalk, N.A., 2000, The sustainability of bond-financed deficits: an overlapping generations approach, Journal of Monetary Economics 45, 293-328.
Diamond, P., 1965, National debt in a neoclassical growth model, American Economic Review 55, 1126-50.
Galor, O. and H.E. Ryder, 1991, Dynamic inefficiency of steady-state equilibria in an overlapping-generations model with productive capital, Economics Letters 35, 385-390.
Grossman, G.M. and N. Yanagawa, 1993, Asset bubbles and endogenous growth, Journal of Monetary Economics 31, 3-19.
King, I. and D. Ferguson, 1993, Dynamic inefficiency, endogenous growth, and Ponzi games, Journal of Monetary Economics 32, 79-104.
Norregaard, J. (1997), The tax treatment of government bonds, IMF Working Paper 97/25.
O’Connell, S.A. and S.P. Zeldes, 1988, Rational Ponzi games, International Economic Review 29, 431-450.
Tirole, J., 1985, Asset bubbles and overlapping generations, Econometrica 53, 1499-1528.
Wigger, B.U., (2005), Public debt, human capital formation, and dynamic inefficiency, International Tax and Public Finance 12, 47-59.
Many authors have studied the properties of Ponzi games (or bubbles) in dynamically inefficient economies. See, e.g., Tirole (1985), O’Connell and Zeldes (1988), Ball et al. (1998), Chalk (2000), and Wigger (2005).
Some countries, e.g., India, exempt interest income on public bonds from income taxation. In the United States interest income on bonds issued by lower levels of government is exempted from federal income taxation. See Norregaard (1997) for a comprehensive survey on the ramifications of tax-exempting income on public bonds.
Expressing public debt in per GDP units (rather than expressing it in per labor units) facilitates the analysis as it allows to separate the bond dynamics from the dynamics of the capital stock per worker.
Galor and Ryder (1991) discuss a variety of conditions that guarantee dynamic efficiency in the overlapping generations model.
Note that when the economy with public debt converges to the economy without public debt, the absolut amount of public debt, Bt, still grows indefinitely at the rate
See Tirole (1985).