In Search of Equilibrium: Estimating Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates in Sub-Saharan African Countries

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address:ac474@cam.ac.uk; jmongardini@imf.org

This paper presents a methodology to estimate equilibrium real exchange rates (ERER) for Sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries using both single-country and panel estimation techniques. The limited data set hinders single-country estimation for most countries in the sample, but panel estimates are statistically and economically significant, and generally robust to different estimation techniques. The results replicate well the historical experience for a number of countries in the sample. Panel techniques can also be used to derive out of sample estimates for countries with a more limited data set.

Abstract

This paper presents a methodology to estimate equilibrium real exchange rates (ERER) for Sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries using both single-country and panel estimation techniques. The limited data set hinders single-country estimation for most countries in the sample, but panel estimates are statistically and economically significant, and generally robust to different estimation techniques. The results replicate well the historical experience for a number of countries in the sample. Panel techniques can also be used to derive out of sample estimates for countries with a more limited data set.

I. Introduction

A significant development challenge facing Sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries is determining, and achieving, an exchange rate that balances a country’s external competitiveness2 against its macroeconomic stability. The resulting equilibrium real exchange rate (ERER)—a rate that is consistent with an economy’s medium-term fundamentals and macroeconomic stability—can therefore be a key indicator for macroeconomic policy.

In its Medium-Term Strategy, the Fund has renewed its efforts to refine its analysis of ERERs in its surveillance of macroeconomic policies in member countries.3 While most ERER research focuses on advanced and emerging economies, there has been relatively few studies estimating ERERs in low-income countries, mostly owing to lack of reliable data. This paper attempts to fill that gap by deriving a methodology to estimate the ERER for 39 SSA countries using both single-country and panel-data estimation techniques.

The paper finds that the results are less reliable when it comes to single-country estimations—with the exception of a few countries. However, panel estimation techniques provide statistically significant results for oil-importing and, to a lesser extent, for oil- exporting countries. Panel estimation techniques also permit the derivation of the ERER for countries like Eritrea, where the sample period is limited to 14 annual observations.

The paper is organized as follows: Section II provides a description of the theoretical background on the determinants of the equilibrium real exchange rates. Section III applies this approach to SSA countries. Section IV discusses data issues and econometric methodology. Section V and VI describe the empirical evidence from single-country and panel estimations, respectively. Section VII presents an extension of panel estimation for countries with limited data, like Eritrea. Section VIII presents the conclusions.

II. Theoretical Background on Determinants of the ERER in Low-Income Countries

In the extensive theoretical and empirical research on the determination of ERERs, two main approaches have emerged: (i) the “macroeconomic balance” approach (MB), pioneered by John Williamson (1994), and (ii) the “behavioral equilibrium exchange rate” (BEER) approach, including the seminal work by Edwards (1989). While there are advantages and disadvantages to either approach, this paper focuses exclusively on the BEER approach.4

The MB approach is based on econometric estimates of the impact of a set of fundamental variables on the external current account. Equilibrium in this framework is defined as the level of current account (“current account norm”) that would be consistent with the levels of these fundamentals projected over the medium term. In advanced economies, for example, current account norms are often related to, among other factors, the achievement of potential output. They are then translated into the level of real exchange rate that would bring about the required adjustment in the current account to reach its norm. Such translation requires the estimation of relatively stable trade elasticities—an avenue that has provided some useful results so far in the empirical literature for low-income countries.5

The alternative BEER approach directly estimates the structural relationship between economic fundamentals and the ERER. In the seminal work by Edwards (1989, 1994), the ERER is defined as the relative price of tradables to nontradables that, all else equal, results in the simultaneous attainment of internal and external equilibrium. Internal equilibrium is defined in the model as the clearing of all nontradable markets (static equilibrium). External equilibrium is attained when the net present value of future current accounts is nonnegative, given the level of exogenous long-run capital inflows (dynamic equilibrium). These two equilibrium conditions identify a unique ERER,6 which can be estimated empirically on the basis of the following reduced form equation:

log(et)=γ0+j=1rγjlog(FUNDjt)+(1θ)log(et1)k=1sλk(ZktZkt*)+vt(1)

where all variables are in logarithms, et is the real exchange rate, {FUNDit} is a set of fundamental variables, {Zkt} is a set of policy variables (which may deviate from the variables that are consistent with the medium-term equilibrium Zkt*), and vt is an error term. This is a dynamic autoregressive function that requires the use of time-series estimation techniques.7 The rest of this paper uses this reduced form equation to derive an ERER for SSA countries.

The question at the heart of our analysis is what set of fundamentals is relevant for determining the ERER of low-income African countries. While most estimations of currency misalignments in low-income, emerging, and advanced economies are similar, low-income African countries have several unique features that affect the choice of fundamentals. First, capital markets are less advanced, and cross-border capital flows tend to be limited or heavily restricted. Hence, unlike in the case of emerging and advanced economies, the real interest rate differential is unlikely to play a significant role. Second, low-income countries tend to be heavily indebted, with debt service and/or official grants constituting a sizable fraction of GDP. Both debt service and official grants are likely to have an impact on the real exchange rate determination, as they impact the underlying foreign exchange rate flows that determine the ERER. Third, because low-income SSA countries tend to be commodity exporters with only a small share of manufacturing exports, world prices of certain commodities are likely to affect both the external current account and the equilibrium real exchange rate.

Most of the literature has focused on the set of fundamental variables that determine the ERER. Drawing on existing theoretical models (Edwards 1989, 1994; and Hinkle and Montiel 1999), Box 1 lists the likely determinants of ERER in low-income SSA countries and briefly highlights how each may impact the ERER.

III. Empirical Applications to Low-Income Countries

Although empirical applications of Edwards’ model and subsequent revisions to developing countries have yielded generally meaningful results, relatively few papers have applied the model to SSA countries. Notable exceptions are Edwards and Ostry (1990, 1992), Ostry (1988) and Ostry and Reinhart (1992). Hinkle and Montiel (1999) provide an overall overview of estimating equilibrium real exchange rates in developing countries. For the specific case of SSA, Ghura and Greenes (1993) present panel estimation for 33 SSA countries. They find that high levels of misalignment between the real exchange rate and the ERER are associated with periods of macroeconomic instability, while lower levels of misalignment correspond to better economic performance. The results of Elbadawy (1994), who applies a simplified framework of Edwards’ model to Chile, Ghana, and India, reveals a similar association between misaligned real and equilibrium exchange rates and weak economic performance. More recent research on growth accelerations (Haussman et al., 2005) shows that a real exchange rate overvaluation appears to be one factor that makes it difficult to sustain growth spurts.

    ERER Determinants for Developing Countries

  • The external terms of trade (tot), defined as the ratio of the price of a country’s exports over the price of its imports. Most African countries mainly export primary commodities, such as oil, lumber, metals, and diamonds, and/or agricultural products (e.g., coffee and cocoa). The price for these primary commodities is determined in world commodity markets and subject to significant volatility affecting the terms of trade. An improvement in the terms of trade will positively affect the trade balance, and thus lead the ERER to appreciate.

  • Productivity relative to foreign trading partners, proxied by total factor productivity (tfp), where available, or relative per capita real gdp (gdp). Developments in relative productivity capture well-known Balassa-Samuelson effects. Countries with higher productivity growth in the tradables sector (where such growth tends to concentrate) can sustain an ERER appreciation without losing competitiveness.

  • Government consumption as a share of GDP relative to that of foreign trading partners (gov). An increase in government consumption biased toward nontradables creates higher demand for nontradables (relative to the tradable sector). This greater demand boosts the relative prices of nontradable goods, causing the equilibrium real exchange rate to appreciate. However, if the increase in overall government consumption is biased toward the tradable sector, an increase in spending will cause the ERER to depreciate.

  • The severity of trade restrictions, proxied by openness to trade (open). Openness to trade is defined as the sum of exports plus imports as a share of GDP. Protection of domestically produced goods via restrictions on cross-border trade (e.g. import tariffs and nontariff barriers) leads to higher domestic prices and thus ERER appreciation. Consequently, lifting existing trade restrictions (proxied by an increase in openness to trade) should cause the ERER to depreciate.

  • The ratio of investments to GDP (invs) relative to that of foreign trading partners. Investments in low- and middle-income countries have high import content and thus a direct negative impact on the trade balance. Because this variable may also capture technological progress, its overall impact on the ERER is ambiguous.

  • Debt service as a share of exports (ds). An increase in debt service payments leads the external balance to deteriorate; thus, subsequent price adjustments should restore equilibrium. Higher debt service payments should therefore cause the ERER to depreciate.

  • Net foreign assets as a share of GDP (nfa), a proxy for the country’s net external position. An increase in capital inflows from abroad implies higher demand for domestic currency, thus causing the ERER to appreciate.

The following variables, which are not included in the empirical estimations owing to data limitations, could also have a significant impact on the real exchange rate in developing countries:

  • Aid flows as a share of exports. Similar to debt service payments, aid flows can represent a significant fraction of GDP in low-income countries. An increase in aid flows improves the external balance and thus causes the ERER to appreciate.

  • Controls over capital flows. Similarly to tightening restrictions on the movement of goods across borders, easing controls on capital flows could impact the ERER. The direction of this impact depends on (i) how much the real interest rate in the domestic economy differs with those of its foreign trading partners and (ii) the country’s risk profile.

  • Fiscal and monetary policy. In Edwards’ model, both fiscal and monetary policies affect the real exchange rate. However, it is not clear whether changes in macroeconomic policies have a long-run impact on the ERER.

The increased focus on exchange rate assessments in Fund surveillance has led to a number of empirical studies, including for some African countries. For example, according to Mongardini (1998), debt relief significantly affected Egypt’s equilibrium real exchange rate in the first half of the 1990s. Cerra and Saxena (2000) show that India’s current account deficit and investor confidence played a key role in the 1991 currency crisis. For SSA countries, Mathisen (2003) finds that Malawi’s ERER was positively related to the terms of trade, government spending (excluding wages and salaries), per capita GDP growth, and investment. In addition, misalignments between the real exchange rate and the ERER were relatively short lived (11 months). A more recent paper by Saadi-Sedik and Petri (2006) shows the importance of official external grants in the determination of the ERER for Jordan. The paper also stresses the sensitivity of the misalignment results to smoothing techniques, which introduce an element of potential bias in interpreting the results. The authors therefore argue that less smoothing is preferable in developing countries.

The estimation of ERERs has more recently found its way into the Fund’s operational work. For example, estimates of the U.S. ERER, recently published in the 2006 Article IV staff report for the United States, showed a significant misalignment between the U.S. dollar and the ERER. In SSA countries, according to a recent selected issues paper for the Central African Economic and Monetary Union (CEMAC) (IMF 2005), the real effective exchange rate for the region is broadly in line with its ERER. In addition, the CEMAC paper finds relatively slow mean reversion (a half life of nine years), suggesting there are rigidities in relative prices. For the West African Economic and Monetary Union (WAEMU), a more recent selected issues paper (IMF 2006) finds that the ERER misalignment for the region is marginal and the set of fundamentals different from the CEMAC region. Finally, a paper by Abdih and Tsangarides (2006) summarizes these findings by showing that mean reversion to equilibrium is twice as fast in West African Monetary Union (WAEMU) than in CEMAC, while both regions were broadly in line with their ERERs in 2005. The paper also identifies differences between CEMAC and WAEMU long-run elasticities, which can be extended to imply differences in the fundamentals’ marginal impacts between oil (CEMAC) and non-oil (WAEMU) producers (see below).

IV. Data Issues and Econometric Methodology

Limited data availability hinders the estimation of the ERER in SSA countries. Reliable data are available only since 1980 for a subset of countries. Eritrea, Liberia, Lesotho, Sao Tome and Principe, and Zimbabwe are excluded from the analysis. Botswana and South Africa are also excluded because of the predominance of capital flows in determining the ERER. That leaves 39 SSA countries with yearly data spanning the 1980–2005 period (though not all the variables in Box 1 are available for each country or for the entire period).8 The econometric methodology for the single-country estimations is summarized in Box 2. Following the recommendation in Saadi-Sedik and Petri (2006), the fundamentals are not smoothed to avoid influencing the misalignment results in an arbitrary fashion.

One additional complication in the determination of a meaningful measure of misalignment could arise from abrupt changes in the real exchange rate associated with trade liberalization, the lifting of capital controls, or the elimination of multiple exchange rate practices. The use of an HP filter on the RER data for the 39 SSA countries in the sample suggests that abrupt changes were mostly associated with changes in the exchange rate regime (e.g., the 1994 CFA devaluation) or large shocks to the economy (e.g., the famine in Ethiopia in 1984), which can be accounted for in the econometric estimations below. Trade liberalization is also captured through the explanatory variable on trade openness, which turns out to be highly significant in virtually all regressions.

V. Estimation Results: Single-Country Approach

Following the methodology described above, the estimation results are derived using the model that best fits the data. Every possible combination of four variables is estimated for each country in the sample, yielding 70 possible specifications for countries for which all eight fundamental determinants are available. For each specification, the optimal lag structure is also determined through a search procedure. The models are then ranked according to the following criteria:

Econometric Methodology for Single-Country Estimations

The relatively short sample period (only 26 yearly observations) presents serious challenges to estimating the ERER using single-country estimation techniques. First, equation (1) cannot be reliably estimated with all eight potential ERER determinants defined in Box 1. Data limitations impose, at most, four dependent variables for reliable statistical inference.9 Thus, the traditional approach of using a general-to-specific estimation strategy cannot be applied here.

Second, the short sample period makes the variables’ order of integration uncertain, as it is well known that unit root tests for short samples perform very poorly. Typical econometric techniques (such as Johansen’s cointegration tests) require knowing whether or not the variables are stationary and are thus subject to the above-mentioned uncertainty.

To address these challenges, the following econometric methodology is used in this paper. First, to estimate the long-run relationship between the fundamental determinants and the real exchange rate, we follow the bound-testing approach developed by Pesaran, Shin, and Smith (2001). This methodology, which tests for a long-run relationship between the real exchange rate (et) and fundamentals (FUNDit) in equation (1), is independent of whether the variables are stationary, integrated of order one, or a mixture of the two. Furthermore, small-sample performance of the bound-testing approach has been shown to be superior to the conventional Johansen cointegration test.

Second, we use an Autoregressive Distributed Lag Modeling approach (ARDL) pioneered by Pesaran and Shin (1999). The ARDL has superior small sample performance and provides a correct inference regardless of the variables’ order of integration. Mongardini (1998) uses a similar modeling strategy for the estimation of currency misalignment. Other estimation techniques (Johanssen’s cointegration test and vector error-correction model) are then used as robustness checks.

  • bound test of the level relationship (modified F-test) between the ERER and the fundamentals;

  • the number of statistically significant long-run elasticities at a 5 percent significance level; and

  • the number of correct signs of the coefficient, as predicted by the Edwards model.

Based on these rankings, only a few single-country estimation results pass all three tests (Table 1).10 These results suggest that single-country ERER estimations are unlikely to yield robust estimates of exchange rate misalignments for SSA countries in the given sample. More specifically:

  • Only 11 out of the 39 sample countries have a combination of fundamental determinants that pass all three criteria.

  • In 3 of the 11 countries, the estimation results do not provide a single model that is economically and statistically significant; as many as 3 potential models may fit for these countries. Further economic analysis based on other empirical evidence would be required to determine which one of these models is the relevant one for the estimation of the ERER.

  • Even for the eight countries with a unique preferred combination of fundamentals, the estimations are generally sensitive to time-period selection and variable specification. For example, the preferred model for Ethiopia using data for 1980-2005 is11

Table 1:

Single-Country Estimations: Model Selection

article image

F-test refers to bound testing approach to the analysis of level relationship developed by Pesaran, Shin and Smith (2001).

Long-run elasticities were derived from more parsimonious ARDL specification. All combinations of lags up to 2 for real exchange rate and up to 1 for each explanatory variable were estimated and the best model according to the Schwartz- Bayesian criterion was chosen. About 92,400 different regressions were computed in the estimation stage alone.

ERERETH=45%(8.4).tot+56%(5.3).gov107%(7.9).inv29.7%(.3.8).ds+const(2)

After expanding the sample by two years (i.e., starting in 1978) and replacing the gdp variable with a better proxy for the Balassa-Samuelson effect—relative total factor productivity (tfp)—the model with the best fit (according to the criteria described above) becomes:

ERERETH=26%(23).tot+45%(3.2).opn+102%(4.4).tfp+55.6%(2.9).gov+const(3)

The estimated exchange rate misalignments based on models (2) and (3) are plotted in Figure 1.12 While both predict a similar alignment of the RER to its equilibrium level in 2003, the two models have a fundamental difference, a finding that demonstrates the model’s uncertainty and highlights the sensitivity of the results to the selected sample. While using the longest possible time period is ideal, the historical data before 1980 contain large measurement errors, and the comparability of earlier data and more recent data is questionable.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Exchange Rate Misalignments for Ethiopia: Model Uncertainty

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2007, 090; 10.5089/9781451866544.001.A001

Figure 2:
Figure 2:

Exchange Rate Misalignments for A Sample of Non-Oil Exporting Countries (4 variables)21

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2007, 090; 10.5089/9781451866544.001.A001

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Exchange Rate Misalignments for A Sample of Non-Oil Exporting Countries (5 variables)22

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2007, 090; 10.5089/9781451866544.001.A001

These caveats notwithstanding, most estimations that pass the above criteria show similar characteristics. Indeed, for most, three variables—terms of trade (tot), productivity (tfp), and openness (open)—are significant consistently throughout different model specifications. In certain cases, government consumption (gov) is also significant. This findings points to commonalities that could be exploited to improve the robustness of the estimation using panel techniques.

To conclude, single-country estimations for SSA countries are not likely to provide robust evidence to determine exchange rate misalignments. More thorough empirical investigation and robustness analysis could yield promising results for some countries;13 however, the uncertainty associated with data limitations is, in general, substantial. Moreover, though a longer time period would yield more observations, the use of pre-1980 data, which are of questionable quality, would likely distort the regression results.

VI. Estimation Results: Panel Evidence

Panel estimations can circumvent the limitations of single-country estimations by exploiting the commonalities across countries. For SSA countries, for example, heavy reliance on commodity exports implies a similarly strong long-run relationship between the terms of trade and the equilibrium real exchange rate across countries. We therefore pool countries, assuming that the long-run elasticities are homogenous, while allowing short-run dynamics to differ across countries. The assumption that countries have homogenous long-run elasticities is then tested to see if pooling is statistically sound. The drawback of panel techniques is that country-specific idiosyncrasies may be lost, even if the homogeneity test is not rejected. Box 3 describes the econometric methodology for the panel estimations.

Econometric Methodology for Panel Estimation

The first step in the panel approach is to conduct unit root tests to determine the order of integration. For the SSA sample, the results in the Appendix (Table A3) suggest that all variables can be treated as integrated of order 1. Some uncertainty also surrounds the order of integration of relative government consumption; only two of the six panel unit root tests argue in favor of nonstationarity.

Second, three different econometric techniques are used to estimate the panel’s long-run elasticities: (1) the Pooled Mean Group (PMG) estimator proposed by Pesaran, Shin, and Smith (1999); (2) the Fully-Modified OLS (FMOLS) estimator proposed by Pedroni (2000); and the Panel Dynamic OLS (PDOLS) estimator by Mark and Sul (2003). The PMG, which is based on the ARDL approach, is a maximum likelihood estimation technique, while FMOLS and PDOLS are based on a modified least squares. These panel estimation techniques also treat heterogeneous short-run dynamics differently. There is currently no paper available studying intensively and conclusively the small-sample properties of these estimators, but in a time series context, the Monte Carlo simulation by Pesaran and Shin (1997) suggests that the small-sample properties of the ARDL outperform those of the FMOLS procedure, a finding that is likely to be reinforced in a panel framework. The treatment of short-run dynamics in the DOLS estimation technique suggests that DOLS is not likely to perform well in panels with short time periods. In addition, following Pedroni (2000), four cointegration tests (panel PP and ADF tests, and group PP and ADF tests) are conducted to check for a long-run relationship between the ERER and the fundamentals.

Finally, we test the homogeneity assumption underlying the data pooling. The Hausman (1978) test compares pooled mean group estimates with mean group estimates. If the null hypothesis is rejected, one can infer that the panel is too heterogeneous to be pooled. On the other hand, if the Hausman test is not rejected, the countries in the panel are homogenous enough from a statistical perspective to assume common long-run elasticities.

A. Estimation Results

The selection of the proper set of fundamentals poses the same problem as in single-country estimations. Owing to the short time period, no more than four to five explanatory variables can be used for reliable inference. In view of the above results, and considering the nature of SSA economies, the following three fundamentals are always included in the regressions: terms of trade, openness, and productivity (proxied here by real per capita GDP relative to foreign trading partners). Regarding the remaining five fundamentals, all possible sets of explanatory variables consisting of four (tot, opn, gdp plus one remaining variable) and five (tot, opn, gdp plus two remaining variables) fundamentals were constructed, and the corresponding models were estimated. In all cases, only balance panels—i.e., panels in which all country data series had the same starting and ending periods—were used to estimate the cointegrating vector under the three estimation techniques.14

The assumption of homogeneity of all long-run relationships is found to be violated in the panel that includes all countries with available data.15 As an example, the estimation results for the panel featuring tot, opn, gdp, and gov as explanatory variables (36 countries have available data) are presented in Table A5 in the Appendix. The Hausman test strongly rejects long-run homogeneity, implying that the 39 SSA countries are too heterogeneous to be pooled. This result likely reflects the fact that ERERs in oil importing countries would respond differently to oil price shocks than would those in oil producing countries. It therefore seems reasonable to split the panel into two subgroups: 32 oil-importing countries and 7 oil producing countries (Angola, Cameroon, Republic of Congo, Côte d’Ivoire. Equatorial Guinea, Gabon, and Nigeria).16

Estimation Results for Oil-Importing Countries

The panel of oil-importing countries shows enough similar characteristics to warrant pooling. The Hausman test for the long-run homogeneity is generally not rejected, and panel cointegration tests generally confirm the existence of a cointegrating vector (Table A5 in Appendix). In addition, the models with four and five explanatory variables commonly have at least three statistically significant nonstationary regressors. Panel cointegration tests alone provide only weak guidance for model selection.17

Models with Four Fundamental Determinants

The panel evidence confirms the significance of a similar set of fundamental determinants as in the single-country estimations. The ranking of the estimation results for models with four explanatory variables suggests the following preferred combination of fundamentals: tot, opn, gdp, and gov. This combination yields statistically significant estimates of a cointegrating vector for both PMG and FMOLS estimators (Table 2). The signs for the long- run coefficients are in line with theory, and the Hausman test does not reject the assumption of long-run homogeneity. Not surprisingly, the PDOLS estimator does not perform very well; however, the magnitude and signs of the PDOLS coefficients are broadly in line with the PMG and FMOLS estimations. The half-life corresponding to the average speed of the mean reversion to the estimated equilibrium declines further, to 2.2 years.

Table 2:

Estimates of Cointegrating Vector for Balanced Panel of Non-Oil Exporting Countries

article image
Notes: PMG refers to pooled mean group estimator developed by Pesaran, Shin and Smith (1999). FMOLS refers to the fully modified OLS estimator by Pedroni (2000) and PDOLS refers to the panel dynamic OLS estimator by Mark and Sul (2002).

As an additional robustness check, we re-estimate the model to include incidental trends (i.e., heterogeneous linear trends). The findings are encouraging: the estimated long-run elasticities are still significant and close to the original PMG estimates with one exception (gdp’s elasticity drops from 1.05 to 0.60). The heterogeneous country-specific trend can also serve as a crude proxy for potentially omitted variables.

The estimated long-run elasticities are broadly in line with the literature summarized in Hinkle and Montiel (1999). Gilles and Yehoue (2005) employ similar dynamic panel estimation techniques in a sample of 64 countries. In their sub-sample of 28 low-income countries, the estimated elasticities are in the range of 0.05 to 0.27 for terms of trade, -0.71 to -0.23 for openness, 0.12 to 0.34 for productivity proxied by GNP per worker, and government consumption is found to be significant only in one model with the corresponding elasticity of 0.10. Interestingly, estimates of the long-run impact of the fundamentals on ERER for low-income countries are not that much different from advanced and transition economies. Kim and Korhonen (2005) use data from 29 middle and high-income countries spanning 25 years, and estimate long-run elasticities in the range of (0.41, 0.82) for real GDP per capita, (0.07,0.44) for government consumption and (-0.82, -0.36) for openness.18

The panel estimates also confirm the well-known result that changes in productivity have the largest impact on the ERER (Table 3). On average, SSA countries experienced an ERER depreciation of 2.5 percent over the sample period (1980-2005). Changes in productivity (GDP) contributed 61 percent of this equilibrium depreciation, followed by trade liberalization (Open) with 18 percent, changes in terms of trade (ToT) with 13 percent, and changes in government consumption with 8 percent.

Table 3:

Average Annual Change in ERER and Contributions from Fundamentals

article image
Notes: Period 1980-2005, 28 oil importing countries. PMG estimates of long-run elasticities are used.
Models with Five Fundamentals

There is a trade-off between having a more parsimonious specification—which risks omitting important variables—and a larger set of fundamentals—which risks producing a more imprecise estimation. Pedroni’s panel cointegration tests does not resolve this problem, as the results appear to be biased toward selecting fewer explanatory variables in the samples with a short time dimension.

The preferred five-variable model features tot, opn, gdp, gov, and ds. Only 19 countries have available data. Again, only the estimates using the PMG and FMOLS methodology are statistically significant (Table 4). The signs of the coefficients are in line with theory, and the Hausman test does not reject the long-run homogeneity at a 5 percent confidence level. The estimated long-run impact of these fundamentals is also robust to specifications that include incidental trends (Table 4). As suggested by comparing Tables 2 and 4, estimated long-run elasticities for tot, opn, gdp, and gov are similar, suggesting an underlying relationship that is robust to different model specifications. The largest difference is for the long-run impact of government consumption, where the elasticity increased from 28 percent to 53 percent.

Table 4:

Estimates of Cointegrating Vector: Preferred Five-Variable Model

article image
Notes: PMG refers to pooled mean group estimator developed by Pesaran, Shin and Smith (1999). FMOLS refers to the fully modified OLS estimator by Pedroni (2000). PDOLS refers to the panel dynamic OLS estimator by Mark and Sul (2002).

The minimum and maximum estimates of RER misalignments across all specifications in Table 2 (models with 4 fundamentals) and Table 4 (five fundamentals) are plotted in Figures 2 and 3 for three countries in the sample, namely Burkina Faso, Ethiopia, and Tanzania. Further analysis on the rest of the sample is required before a meaningful statement on their ERER misalignment can be made.

The econometric results above capture some interesting historical features that give credence to the results, although they would need to be followed up with country-specific models to draw more definite conclusions:23

  • For Burkina Faso, the policy of structural reforms adopted since the mid 1980s in the context of CFA monetary union led to an appreciation of the ERER, which in turn helped realign the RER to its equilibrium level by the early 1990s. The 1994 CFAF devaluation resulted in an undervaluation that has broadly persisted until 2003. More qualitative assessments by Fund staff concur with the undervaluation immediately following the 1994 devaluation, but suggest a broadly adequately valued level for Burkina Faso’s real exchange rate in more recent years. The difference could be partly due to an inadequate intercept for Burkina Faso resulting from the panel estimation, which could bias the results towards an undervaluation. This would also be consistent with the generally accepted assessment that Burkina Faso’s real exchange rate was still overvalued in 1994. A Burkina Faso specific analysis would thus be a useful area for further research.

  • For Ethiopia, the two peaks in the RER overvaluation reflect the economic collapse associated with the famine of 1984-85 and the end of the Derg regime in 1991, while the official exchange rate had been held fixed to the U.S. dollar during the period 1973-92. The subsequent nominal devaluation of the birr and structural reforms to move to a market-oriented economy led to an undervaluation of the RER exchange that persisted up to 2003.

  • For Tanzania, the economic adjustment program started in 1986 to dismantle socialist economic controls, devalue the Tanzanian shilling, and encourage more active participation of the private sector in the economy. This led to a gradual convergence of the RER to its equilibrium level in the second half of the 1980s. The RER has been fluctuating around its equilibrium level since the early 1990s.

Estimation Results for Oil Exporters

Estimations for the panel of oil exporting countries yields somewhat less reliable results because only 7 of the 39 countries are oil exporters. The short period and group dimensions also preclude the use of models with more than four explanatory variables. The panel cointegration tests cannot confirm the existence of a cointegrating relationship between the ERER and any combination of four fundamentals (Table 2A). Furthermore, many of the Hausman test results suggest that the panel may be too heterogeneous to justify pooling the data.

However, the inclusion of the real price of oil (deflated by US CPI) as a fundamental determinant minimizes some of these analytical limitations. In view of the different shares of oil production in GDP, the long-run elasticity coefficient is allowed to vary across countries (an assumption that can only be estimated using the PMG methodology). Therefore, the long-run impact of oil prices is allowed to be country specific, while the elasticities on tot, open, and gdp are restricted to be homogenous over the long run. The cointegration tests confirm the existence of a long-run cointegrating vector, and the Hausman test does not reject the homogeneity assumption with the heterogeneous elasticity on oil.

The results of the estimation show limited robustness (Table 5). In the more parsimonious specification (with a maximum of one lag24), tot, opn, and gdp are significant, and the signs are in line with theory. The negative sign on the elasticity on the real price of oil for Cameroon and Congo reflects only the implied decomposition of the tot into oil- and non-oil exports. The overall impact for both countries of higher oil prices in real terms is still positive, given the weight of oil in the terms of trade. However, a richer lag structure seems to have a nonnegligible impact on the country-specific long-run elasticity of the real oil price in the case of Equatorial Guinea and Gabon. Thus, we conclude that, while the panel results are subject to less uncertainty than the single-country estimations, the results for oil exporting countries are not very robust, reflecting this group’s small size and the panel’s limited time dimensions.

Table 5:

Estimates of Long-Run Elasticities for Oil Exporters

article image
Notes: PMG refers to Pooled Mean Group Estimator developed by Pesaran, Shin and Smith (1999).

The estimated misalignment for the Republic of Congo is shown in Figure 4 as an example.25 The results show the gradual overvaluation of the real exchange rate brought about by the unsustainable fiscal policy of the 1980s. The abandonment of social planning in the early 1990s and the CFAF devaluation led to a significant undervaluation by 1994, which was partly reversed by 1997 through the negative effects on economic activity of the civil wars in 1993-97. Economic recovery, together with relatively prudent macroeconomic policies has led to broad convergence back to the ERER in recent years.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Exchange Rate Misalignment for the Republic of Congo

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2007, 090; 10.5089/9781451866544.001.A001

VII. Application for Countries with Limited Data: Out-of-Sample Estimation of Eritreas ERER

The panel estimation techniques used here can be extended to derive estimates of the ERER for countries with limited data availability (Kim and Korhonen 2005). This extension involves assuming the same long-run elasticities as estimated in the panel and deriving a constant (γ0) in equation (1) above from an estimated relationship between the panel’s constant and average per capita GDP.

This extension is particularly useful for Eritrea, for which data are available starting only in 1992 (as it gained independence in 1991). Although excluded from the above estimations, Eritrea and other non-oil exporting SSA countries have similar economic characteristics, suggesting that the same long-run elasticities estimated in the panel can be applied to Eritrea. For the purpose of this exercise, we use the estimated elasticities from the model with four fundamentals (tot, gdp, open, gov) derived through the PMG methodology.

The challenge is to determine the constant (γ0) to derive the ERER for Eritrea. Using the panel data for the 39 countries, we estimate the following cross-sectional regression using a standard ordinary least squares technique:

γ0=0.79650.00047(12.0)YiPPP(4)

which has an adjusted R2 of 85 percent and a t-ratio on the coefficient for average GDP per capita (measured in U.S. dollars in purchasing power parity) of 12. The results suggest a very strong linear relationship (Figure 5). The resulting ERER for Eritrea suggests a significant overvaluation starting in 2000 (Figure 6).

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Estimated Relationship between Constant and Average GDP per Capita in Panel

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2007, 090; 10.5089/9781451866544.001.A001

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Estimated ERER Misalignment for Eritrea26

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2007, 090; 10.5089/9781451866544.001.A001

VIII. Conclusions

This paper provides a methodology to estimate the ERERs for SSA countries. Drawing on Edwards’ (1989) seminal model, it derives a reduced-form equation and a set of fundamental ERER determinants. Owing to SSA countries’ limited data availability, after deriving single- country estimations, we employ panel estimation techniques that assume the cointegrating (long-run) relationship between the ERER and its fundamental determinants is the same across SSA countries. This assumption is found to be valid for non-oil exporters and, to a lesser extent, for oil exporters (though it is rejected for the panel of 39 countries).

Appendix

Table A1:

Construction of Variables

article image
Notes: WEO stands for World Economic Outlook database (summer 2006 version).IMF IFS is International Financial Statistics published by IMF.
Table A2:

Data Availability

Table A3:

Single-Country Estimation of Long-Run Elasticities

article image
Notes: (*) Standard errors and corresponding t-ratios were not derived according to the asymptotic formula but by means of Bewley’s regression. This approach is identical to the delta method. As suggested by Pesaran, Shin and Smith (1999), standard errors estimated in this way have advantage that they are consistent in both I(0) and I(1) processes.
Table A4:

First generation unit root tests

article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
(**) See Levin, Lin and Chu (2002), Breitung (2000), Im, Pesaran and Shin (2003), Maddala and Wu (1999), Choi (2001) and Hadri (1999) for details.
Table A5:

Example of Cointegrating Vector Estimates for The Balanced Panel of All Countries in The Dataset

article image
Notes: PMG refers to Pooled Mean Group Estimator of Pesaran, Shin and Smith (1999). FMOLS refers to panel Fully Modified OLS estimator of Pedroni (2000) and PDOLS refers to Panel Dynamic OLS estimator of Mark and Sul (2002). Insignificant estimates of long-run elasticities are in red font.(*) Rejection of the null of no-cointegration at 5% level is highlighted
Table A6:

Pedroni’s ADF and PP Residual Based Cointegration Tests (Balanced Panel of Non-Oil Exporting Countries)

article image
Notes: Rejection of the null of no cointegration at 5% level is highlighted.
Table A7:

Pedroni’s ADF and PP Residual Based Cointegration Tests: Oil Exporting Countries

article image
Notes: Rejection of the null of no cointegration at 5% level is highlighted.

References

  • Abdih, Y., and C. G. Tsangarides, 2006, “FEER for the CFA Franc,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper No. WP/06/236, Washington, DC, October 2006.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boltho, A., 1996, “The Assessment: International Competitiveness,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 12, No. 3, pp. 1-6.

  • Breitung, Jörg, 2000, “The Local Power of Some Unit Root Tests for Panel Data,” Advances in Econometrics, Vol. 15 (Amsterdam: JAI Press), p. 161-78.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chinn, Menzie, and Eswar Prasad, 2003, “Medium-Term Determinants of Current Accounts in Industrial and Developing Countries: An Empirical Exploration,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 59, pp. 47-76.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Choi, I., 2001, “Unit Root Tests for Panel Data,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 20: 249-72

  • Dufrenot Gilles J. and Etienne B. Yehoue, 2005, “Real Exchange Rate Misalignment: A Panel Co-Integration and Common Factor Analysis,” IMF Working Paper WP/05/164 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1989, Real Exchange Rate Devaluation and Adjustments (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press).

  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1994, “Real and Monetary Determinants of Real Exchange Rate Behavior: Theory and Evidence from Developing Countries,” in Estimating Equilibrium Exchange Rates, edited by J. Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics, pp. 6191.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian and Jonathan D. Ostry, 1990, “Anticipated Protectionist Policies, Real Exchange Rates and the Current Account,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 9, pp. 206-19.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian and Jonathan D. Ostry, 1992, “Terms of Trade Disturbances, Real Exchange Rate and Welfare: The Role of Capital Controls and Labor Market Distortions,” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 44, pp. 20-34.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, and Miguel Savastano, 2000, “Exchange Rates in Emerging Economies: What Do We Know? What Do We Need to Know?” in Economic Policy Reform: The Second Stage, edited by Anne O. Krueger (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Elbadawy, Ibrahim A., 1994, “Estimating Long-run Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates,” in Estimating Equilibrium Exchange Rates, edited by J. Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics, pp. 6191.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Faruqee, Hamid, 1995, “Long-Term Determinants of the Real Exchange Rate: A Stock-Flow Perspective,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 42 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ghura, Dhaneshwar, and Thomas J. Grennes, 1993, “The Real Exchange Rate and Macroeconomic Performance in Sub-Saharan Africa,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 42, pp. 155-74.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hadri, Kaddour, 2000, “Testing for Stationarity in Heterogeneous Panel Data,” Econometric Journal, Vol. 3, 148-61.

  • Hausman, J., 1978, “Specification Tests in Econometrics,” Econometrica, Vol. 46, pp. 1,251-71.

  • Hausmann, R., Pritchett L. and D. Rodrik, 2005, “Growth Accelerations,” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 10, No. 4, pp. 303-29.

  • Hinkle, L. and P. Montiel (1999) Exchange Rate Misalignment, Concept and Measurement for Developing Countries. London: Oxford University

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Im, K. S., M. H. Pesaran, and Y. Shin, 2003, “Testing for Unit Roots in Heterogeneous Panels,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 115, 53-74.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Isard, Peter, and Hamid Faruqee, 1998, “Exchange Rate Assessment–Extensions of the Macroeconomic Balance Approach, IMF Occasional Paper No. 167 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2005, “Central African Economic and Monetary Community: Selected Issues,” (Washington: International Monetary Fund), available on the Internet at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.cfm?sk=18676.0

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2006a, “A Medium-Term Strategy for the IMF: Meeting the Challenge of Globalization,” Issues Brief, available on the Internet at http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/ib/2006/041806.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2006b, “West African Economic and Monetary Union—Selected Issues” (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnson, Simon, Jonathan D. Ostry, and A. Subramanian, 2006, “Levers for Growth: Policy Lessons from Earlier Bouts of Growth in Developing Countries”, in IMF Finance and Development, Vol. 43, No. 1:28-31, March 2006.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kahn, Moshin S., and Jonathan D. Ostry, 1991, “Response of the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate to Real Disturbances in Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper WP/91/3 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kim, B-Y, and Likka Korhonen, 2005, “Equilibrium Exchange Rates in Transition Countries: Evidence from Dynamic Heterogeneous Panel Models,” Economic Systems, Vol. 29, 144-162.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lane, Philip and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2006, “The External Wealth of Nations Mark II: Revised and Extended Estimates of External Assets and Liabilities, 1970-2004,” IMF Working Paper, 06/69 (March).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levin, A., C. F. Lin, and C. Chu, 2002, “Unit Root Tests in Panel Data: Asymptotic and Finite-Sample Properties,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 108, 1-24.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Maddala, G. S., and S. Wu, 1999, “A Comparative Study of Unit Root Tests with Panel Data and A New Simple Test,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 61, pp. 631-52.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mark, Nelson C., and Donggyu Sul, 2003, “Cointegration Vector Estimation by Panel DOLS and Long-Run Money Demand,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 65, No. 5, pp. 655-80.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mongardini, Joannes, 1998, “Estimating Egypt’s Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate,” IMF Working Paper No. 98/05, (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), 1992, Technology and the Economy: The Key Relationships (Paris: OECD).

  • Ostry, Jonathan D., 1988, “The Balance of Trade, Terms of Trade, and Real Exchange Rate: An Intertemporal Optimizing Framework,” Staff Papers, Vol. 35, No. 4, pp. 541-73, International Monetary Fund.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., and Carmen M. Reinhart, 1992, “Private Savings and Terms of Trade Shocks: Evidence from Developing Countries,” Staff Papers, Vol. 39, No. 3 (September), pp. 495-517, International Monetary Fund.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pedroni, Peter, 2000, “Fully Modified OLS for Heterogeneous Cointegrated Panels,” Advances in Econometrics, Vol. 15, 93-130

  • Pesaran, M Hashem, and Yongcheol Shin, 1999, “An Autoregressive Distributed Lag Modeling Approach to Cointegration Analysis,” in, Econometrics and Economic Theory in the 20th Century: The Ragnar Frisch Centennial Symposium, edited by S. Strom (Cambridge, England: