Are Asset Price Guarantees Useful for Preventing Sudden Stops?A Quantitative Investigation of the Globalization Hazard-Moral Hazard Tradeoff1
Author:
Mr. Enrique G. Mendoza https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Mr. Enrique G. Mendoza in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
and
Ceyhun Bora Durdu https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Ceyhun Bora Durdu in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Contributor Notes

Author(s) E-Mail Address: emendoza@imf.org

An implication of the "globalization hazard" hypothesis is that sudden stops could be prevented by offering foreign investors price guarantees on emerging markets assets. These guarantees create a tradeoff, however, because they weaken globalization hazard by creating international moral hazard. We study this tradeoff using an equilibrium asset-pricing model. Without guarantees, margin calls and trading costs cause Sudden Stops driven by Fisher's debt-deflation process. Price guarantees prevent this deflation by propping up foreign asset demand, but their effectiveness and welfare implications depend critically on the price elasticity of foreign demand and on making the guarantees contingent on debt levels.

Abstract

An implication of the "globalization hazard" hypothesis is that sudden stops could be prevented by offering foreign investors price guarantees on emerging markets assets. These guarantees create a tradeoff, however, because they weaken globalization hazard by creating international moral hazard. We study this tradeoff using an equilibrium asset-pricing model. Without guarantees, margin calls and trading costs cause Sudden Stops driven by Fisher's debt-deflation process. Price guarantees prevent this deflation by propping up foreign asset demand, but their effectiveness and welfare implications depend critically on the price elasticity of foreign demand and on making the guarantees contingent on debt levels.

I. Introduction

The Sudden Stop phenomenon of emerging markets crises is characterized by three stylized facts: sudden reversals of capital inflows and current account deficits, collapses in output and private absorption, and large relative price corrections in domestic goods prices and asset prices. A large fraction of the literature on this subject is based on a hypothesis that Calvo (2002) labeled “globalization hazard.” According to this hypothesis, world capital markets are inherently imperfect, and hence prone to display contagion and overreaction in asset positions and prices relative to levels consistent with “fundamentals” (see Arellano and Mendoza, 2003, for a short survey of this literature). This argument suggests that an international financial organization (IFO) could help prevent Sudden Stops by offering global investors ex-ante price guarantees on the emerging-markets asset class. Calvo proposed an arrangement for implementing this policy and compared it with other arrangements that favor ex-post guarantees (including Lerrick and Meltzer’s, 2003, proposal).

Ex-ante price guarantees aim to create an environment in which asset prices can be credibly expected to remain above the crash levels that trigger Sudden Stops driven by globalization hazard. Calvo views this facility as akin to an open-markets operation facility: it would exchange a liquid, riskless asset (e.g., U.S. T-bills) for an index of emerging markets assets whenever the value of the index falls by a certain amount, and would repurchase the riskless asset when the index recovers. Market participants would consider in their expectations that these guarantees would be executed if a systemic fire sale makes asset prices crash, and hence the guarantees could rule out rational expectations equilibria in which Sudden Stops occur. If globalization hazard is the only cause of Sudden Stops, and if the support of the probability distribution of the shocks that causes them is known (i.e., if there are no truly “unexpected” shocks), the facility would rarely trade.

A potentially important drawback of ex-ante price guarantees is that they introduce moral hazard incentives for global investors. Everything else the same, the introduction of the guarantees increases the foreign investors’ demand for emerging markets assets, since the downside risk of holding these assets is transferred to the IFO providing the guarantees. This can be a serious drawback because a similar international moral hazard argument has been forcefully put forward as an alternative explanation of Sudden Stops (see the Meltzer Commission report and Lerrick and Meltzer, 2003).3 Proponents of this view argue that Sudden Stops are induced by excessive indebtedness of emerging economies driven by the expectation of global investors that IFOs will bail out countries in financial difficulties. Based on this premise, Lerrick and Meltzer proposed the use of ex-post price guarantees to be offered by an IFO to anchor the orderly resolution of a default once it has been announced and agreed to with the IFO. The IFO would determine the crash price of the asset in default and would require the country to commit to repurchase the asset at its crash price (making the arrangement credible by committing the IFO to buy the asset at a negligible discount below the crash price if the country were unable to buy it).

The tensions between the globalization hazard and moral hazard hypotheses, and their alternative proposals for using price guarantees, reflect an important tradeoff that ex-ante price guarantees create. On one hand, ex-ante price guarantees could endow IFOs with an effective tool to prevent and manage Sudden Stops driven by globalization hazard. On the other hand, ex-ante guarantees could end up making matters worse by strengthening international moral hazard (even if it were true that globalization hazard was the only cause of Sudden Stops in the past).

The goal of this paper is to study the globalization hazard-moral hazard tradeoff from the perspective of the quantitative predictions of a dynamic, stochastic general equilibrium model of asset pricing and current account dynamics. The model is based on the globalization hazard setup of Mendoza and Smith (2006). This paper adds to their framework an IFO that offers ex-ante guarantees to foreign investors on the asset prices of an emerging economy. We are interested in particular in studying how the guarantees affect asset positions, asset price volatility, business cycle dynamics, and the magnitude of Sudden Stops.

Asset price guarantees have not received much attention in quantitative equilibrium asset pricing theory, with the notable exception of the work by Ljungqvist (2000), and these guarantees have yet to be introduced into the research program dealing with quantitative models of Sudden Stops. The theoretical literature and several policy documents on Sudden Stops have examined various aspects of the globalization hazard and international moral hazard hypotheses separately. From this perspective, one contribution of this paper is that it studies the interaction between these two hypotheses in a unified dynamic equilibrium framework.

The two financial frictions that we borrow from Mendoza and Smith (2006) to construct a model in which globalization hazard causes Sudden Stops are: (a) a margin constraint on foreign borrowing faced by the agents of an emerging economy, and (b) asset trading costs incurred by foreign securities firms specialized in trading the equity of the emerging economy.4 These frictions are intended to represent the collateral constraints and informational frictions that have been widely studied in the Sudden Stops literature (see, for example, Calvo (1998), Izquierdo (2000), Calvo and Mendoza (2000a, 2000b), Caballero and Krishnamurty (2001), and Mendoza (2006)).

The model introduces asset price guarantees in the form of ex-ante guarantees offered to foreign investors on the liquidation price (or equivalently, on the return) of the emerging economy’s assets. Thus, these guarantees are akin to a “put option” with minimum return. An IFO offers these guarantees and finances them with a lump-sum tax on foreign investors’ profits. Hence, forward-looking equity prices reflect the effects of margin constraints, trading costs and ex-ante price guarantees. The setup of the price guarantees is similar to the one proposed in Ljungqvist’s (2000) closed-economy, representative-agent analysis, but framed in the context of what is effectively a two-agent equilibrium asset-pricing model with frictions.

Price guarantees have different implications depending on the level at which they are set. If they are set so low that they are never executed, globalization hazard dominates and the model yields the same Sudden Stop outcomes of the Mendoza-Smith model. If they are set so high that they are always executed, the model yields equilibria highly distorted by international moral hazard. Hence, the interesting range for studying the globalization hazard-moral hazard tradeoff lies between these two extremes. The quantitative analysis shows that guarantees set slightly above the model’s “fundamentals” price (by ½ to 1 percent) contain the Sudden Stop effects of globalization hazard and virtually eliminate the probability of margin calls in the stochastic steady state. If the guarantee is non-state-contingent, however, the guarantee is executed often (with a long-run probability of about 1/3) and the model predicts persistent overvaluation of asset prices above the prices obtained in a frictionless environment. A guaranteed price set at the same level but offered only at high levels of external debt is executed much less often (with a long run probability below 1/100) and it is equally effective at containing Sudden Stops without inducing persistent asset overvaluation.

Analysis of the normative implications of the model shows that, when the elasticity of foreign demand for domestic assets is high, the guarantees improve domestic welfare measured from initial conditions at a Sudden Stop state, with negligible changes in long-run welfare levels. At the same time, the value of foreign traders’ firms measured in a Sudden Stop state falls slightly, while their long-run average rises sharply. In this case the balance tilts in favor of using price guarantees to contain globalization hazard. On the other hand, when the elasticity of foreign demand for domestic assets is low, higher price guarantees are needed to prevent Sudden Stops, and as a result large moral hazard distortions reduce domestic welfare gains at Sudden Stop states and enlarge average welfare losses in the stochastic steady state. In this case, price guarantees can be a misleading policy instrument that yields a short-term improvement in macroeconomic indicators and welfare at the expense of a long-term welfare loss.

The paper is organized as follows. Section II presents the model and characterizes the competitive equilibrium in the presence of margin constraints, trading costs and ex-ante price guarantees. Section III studies key properties of this equilibrium that illustrate the nature of the globalization hazard-moral hazard tradeoff. Section IV represents the model’s competitive equilibrium in a recursive form suitable for quantitative analysis and examines a set of baseline results. Section V conducts normative and sensitivity analyses. Section VI concludes.

II. A Model of Globalization Hazard and Price Guarantees

Consider a small open economy (SOE) inhabited by a representative household that rents out labor and a time-invariant stock of capital to a representative firm. Households can trade the equity of this firm with a representative foreign securities firm specialized in trading the economy’s equity, and can also access a global credit market of one-period bonds. In addition, an IFO operates a facility that guarantees a minimum sale price to foreign traders on their sales of the emerging economy’s equity. Dividend payments on the emerging economy’s equity are stochastic and vary in response to exogenous productivity shocks. Markets of contingent claims are incomplete because trading equity and bonds does not allow domestic households to fully hedge domestic income uncertainty, and the credit market is imperfect because of margin constraints and trading costs.

A. The Emerging Economy

The representative firm inside the SOE produces a tradable commodity by combining labor (n) and a time-invariant stock of physical capital (k) using a Cobb-Douglas technology: exp(εt)F(k, n), where ε is a Markov productivity shock. This firm participates in competitive factor and goods markets taking the real wage (w) as given. Thus, the choice of labor input consistent with profit maximization yields standard marginal productivity conditions for labor demand and the rate of dividend payments (d):

w t = exp ( ε t ) F n ( k , n t ) ( 1 )
d t = exp ( ε t ) F k ( k , n t ) ( 2 )

Households choose stochastic sequences of consumption (c), labor supply (n), equity holdings (α), and foreign bond holdings (b) so as to maximize the following utility function:

U ( c , n ) = E 0 [ t = 0 exp { τ = 0 t 1 υ ( c τ h ( n τ ) ) } u ( c t h ( n t ) ) ] ( 3 )

This utility function is a time-recursive, intertemporal utility index with an endogenous rate of time preference that introduces an “impatience effect” on the marginal utility of consumption (i.e., changes in ct alter the subjective discount rate applied to future utility flows). Utility functions with this feature are commonly used in small open economy models to obtain well-defined long-run equilibria for holdings of foreign assets.5 As Section III shows, in models with credit constraints these preferences are also critical for supporting long-run equilibria in which credit constraints can bind.

The period utility function u() is a standard, concave, twice-continuously differentiable utility function. The function v() is the time preference function, which is also concave and twice-continuously differentiable. The argument of both functions is a composite good defined by consumption minus the disutility of labor c-h(n), where h() is an increasing, convex, continuously-differentiable function. Greenwood, Hercowitz and Huffman (1988), GHH, introduced this composite good as a way to eliminate the wealth effect on labor supply. As in Mendoza and Smith (2006), this property of preferences, together with conditions (1) and (2), separates the determination of equilibrium wages, dividends, labor and output from the equilibrium allocations of consumption, saving and portfolio choice.

The household maximizes lifetime utility subject to the following budget constraint:

c t = α t kd t + w t n t + q t ( α t α t + 1 ) k b t + 1 + b t R ( 4 )

where αt and αt+1 are beginning-and end-of-period shares of capital owned by households, qt is the price of equity, and R is the world real interest rate, which is kept constant for simplicity.

Foreign debt contracts feature a collateral constraint in the form of a margin clause that limits the debt not to exceed the fraction κ of the market value of the SOE’s equity holdings:

b t + 1 κ q t α t + 1 K , 0 κ 1 ( 5 )

Margin clauses of this form are widely used in international capital markets. In some instances they are imposed by regulators with the aim of limiting the exposure of financial intermediaries to idiosyncratic risk in lending portfolios, but they are also widely used by investment banks and other lenders to manage default risk (either in the form of explicit margin clauses attached to specific securities offered as collateral, or as implicit margin requirements linked to the volatility of returns of an asset class like those implied by value-at-risk collateralization). Margin clauses are a particularly effective collateral constraint (compared to the classic constraint of Kiyotaki and Moore, 1997, that limits debt to the discounted liquidation value of assets one period ahead) because: (a) custody of the securities offered as collateral is surrendered at the time the credit contract is entered and (b) margin calls to make up for shortfalls in the market value of the collateral are automatic once the value of the securities falls below the contracted value.

Households in the small open economy also face a short-selling constraint in the equity market: αt+1 χ with -∞<χ<1 for all t. This constraint is necessary in order to make the margin constraint non-trivial. Otherwise, any borrowing limit in the bond market implied by a binding margin constraint could always be undone by taking a sufficiently short equity position.

B. The Foreign Securities Firm, IFO & the Price Guarantees

The representative foreign securities firm obtains funds from international investors and specializes in investing them in the SOE’s equity. This firm maximizes its net present value discounted at the discount factor of its international clients (i.e., the world interest rate). Thus, the foreign traders’ problem is to choose αt+1*, for t = 1,…, , so as to maximize:

D = E 0 [ t = 0 R t π t ] ,     π t κ [ α t * d t ( q t α t + 1 * max ( q t , q ˜ t ) α t * ) q t ( a 2 ) ( α t + 1 * α t * + θ ) 2 T t * ]   . ( 6 )

The total net return of the foreign securities firm (πt) is the sum of: (a) dividend earnings on current equity holdings (kαt*dt), minus (b) the value of equity trades, which is the difference between equity purchases qt k α t+1* and equity sales max(qt,q˜t)kαt* executed at either the market price qt or the guaranteed price q˜t, whichever is greater, minus (c) trading costs, which include a term that depends on the size of trades (αt+1*αt*) and a recurrent trading cost (θ), minus (d) lump sum taxes paid to the IFO (kTt*). Trading costs are specified in quadratic form, so a is a standard adjustment-cost coefficient.

The IFO buys equity from the foreign traders at the guaranteed price and sells it at the equilibrium price. Thus, the IFO’s budget constraint is:

T t * = max ( 0 , ( q ˜ t q t ) α t * ) ( 7 )

If the guarantee is not executed, the tax is zero. If the guarantee is executed, the IFO sets the lump-sum tax to match the value of the executed guarantee (i.e., the extra income that foreign traders earn by selling equity to the IFO instead of selling it in the equity market). Since the return on equity is Rtq[dt+qt]/qt1, the IFO’s offer to guarantee the date-t price implies a guaranteed return on the emerging economy’s equity R˜tq=[q˜t+dt]/qt1.

C. Equilibrium

A competitive equilibrium is given by stochastic sequences of prices [wt,dt,qt]t=0 and allocations [ct,nt,bt+1,αt+1,αt+1*,Tt*]t=0 such that: (a) households maximize the utility function (3) subject to the constraints (4) and (5) and the short-selling constraint, taking prices, wages and dividends as given, (b) domestic firms maximize profits so that equations (1) and (2) hold, taking wages and dividends as given, (c) foreign traders maximize (6) taking the price of equity, the price guarantees and lump-sum taxes as given, (d) the budget constraint of the IFO in equation (7), holds and (e) the equity market clears (i.e., αt + αt* = 1 for all t).

III. Characterizing the Globalization Hazard-Moral Hazard Tradeoff

The tradeoff between the globalization hazard introduced by the distortions that margin constraints and trading costs create, and the moral hazard introduced by distortions due to price guarantees, can be illustrated with the optimality conditions of the competitive equilibrium. Consider the first-order conditions of the domestic household’s maximization problem:

U C t ( c , n ) = λ t ( 8 )
h ( n t ) = w t ( 9 )
q t ( λ t η t κ ) = E t [ λ t + 1 ( d t + 1 + q t + 1 ) ] + υ t ( 10 )
λ t η t = E t [ λ t + 1 R ] ( 11 )

Uct(c, n) is the derivative of the SCU function with respect to ct (which includes the impatience effect), and λt, ηt and υt are the Lagrange multipliers on the budget constraint, the margin constraint, and the short-selling constraint respectively.

Condition (8) has the standard interpretation: at equilibrium, the marginal utility of wealth equals the lifetime marginal utility of consumption. Condition (9) equates the marginal disutility of labor with the real wage. This is the case because the GHH composite good implies that the marginal rate of substitution between ct and nt is equal to the marginal disutility of labor h′(nt), and thus is independent of ct. It follows from this result that condition (9) together with (1) and (2) determine the equilibrium values of nt, wt and dt as well as the equilibrium level of output. These “supply-side” solutions are independent of the dynamics of consumption, saving, portfolio choices and equity prices, and are therefore also independent of the distortions induced by financial frictions and price guarantees. This result simplifies significantly the numerical solution of the model. Mendoza (2006) studies the implications of margin constraints in a small-open-economy model with endogenous investment in which financial frictions affect dividends, investment and the Tobin Q, but abstracting from international equity trading.

Conditions (10) and (11) are Euler equations for the accumulation of equity and bonds respectively. As in Mendoza and Smith (2006), these conditions can be combined to derive expressions for the forward solution of equity prices and the excess return on equity from the perspective of the emerging economy. The forward solution for equity prices is:

q t = E t ( i = 0 [ j = 0 i ( 1 η t + j λ t + j κ ) 1 ] M t + 1 + i d t + 1 + i ) ( 12 )

where Mt+1+iλt+1+i/λt, for i=0,…, , is the marginal rate of substitution between ct+1+i and ct. The excess return on domestic equity is:

E t [ R t + 1 q ] R = η t ( 1 κ ) υ t q t COV t ( λ t + 1 , R t + 1 q ) E t [ λ t + 1 ] ( 13 )

Given these results, the forward solution for equity prices can also be expressed as:

q t = E t ( i = 0 [ j = 0 i ( E t [ R t + 1 + j q ] ) 1 ] d t + 1 + i ) ( 14 )

Expressions (12)-(14) show the direct and indirect effects of margin calls on domestic demand for equity and excess returns. The direct effect of a date-t margin call is represented by the term ηt (1-к) in (13), or the term ηtк in (12): When a margin call occurs, domestic agents “fire sale” equity in order to meet the call and satisfy the borrowing constraint. Everything else the same, this effect lowers the date-t equity price and increases the expected excess return for t+1. The indirect effect of the margin call is reflected in the fact that a binding borrowing limit makes “more negative” the covariance between the marginal utility of consumption and the rate of return on equity (since a binding borrowing limit hampers the households’ ability to smooth consumption). These direct and indirect effects increase the rate at which future dividends are discounted in the domestic agents’ valuation of asset prices, and thus reduce their demand for equity. Interestingly, the date-t equity price along the domestic agents’ demand curve is reduced by a margin constraint that is binding at date t or by any expected binding margin constraint in the future. As a result, equity prices and the domestic demand for equity can be distorted by the margin requirements even in periods in which the constraint does not bind.

In a world with frictionless asset markets, domestic agents facing margin calls could sell assets in a perfectly competitive market in which the world demand for the emerging economy’s assets is infinitely elastic at the level of the fundamentals price. Margin calls would trigger portfolio reallocation effects without any price movements. However, in the presence of frictions that make the world demand for the emerging economy’s assets less than infinitely elastic, the equilibrium asset price falls. Since households were already facing margin calls at the initial price, this price decline tightens further the margin constraint triggering a new round of margin calls. This downward spiral in equity prices is a variant of Fisher’s (1933) debt-deflation mechanism, which magnifies the direct and indirect effects of the margin constraint.

The foreign demand for the emerging economy’s assets is less than infinitely elastic because of the trading costs that foreign traders pay. Define the fundamentals price as the conditional expected value of dividends discounted at the world interest rate qtfEt(i=0R(t+1+i)dt+1+i).

The first-order condition for the optimization problem of foreign traders implies then:

( α t + 1 * α t * ) = 1 a ( q t f q t 1 + E t [ i = 1 R ( t + i ) ( max ( q t + i , q ˜ t + i ) q t + i ) ] q t ) θ ( 15 )

The foreign traders’ demand for the emerging economy’s assets is an increasing function of: (a) the percent deviation of qtf relative to qt (with an elasticity equal to 1/a) and (b) the expected present discounted value of the “excess prices” induced by the price guarantees in percent of today’s equity price. The first effect reflects the influence of the per-trade trading costs. If a =0 and there are no price guarantees, the foreign traders’ demand function is infinitely elastic at qf. The second effect is the international moral hazard effect of the guarantees, which acts as a demand shifter on the foreign traders’ demand function. Foreign traders that expect price guarantees to be executed at any time in the future have a higher demand for domestic assets at date t than they would in a market without guarantees. The recurrent trading costs are also a demand shifter (the foreign traders’ demand function is lower the higher is θ).

In light of the previous results, the tradeoff between globalization hazard and international moral hazard can be summarized as follows. Suppose the date-t asset price in a market without margin constraints and without price guarantees is determined at the intersection of the domestic agents’ and foreign traders’ demand curves (HH and FF respectively) at point A in Figure 1.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Equilibrium in the Asset Market

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2006, 073; 10.5089/9781451863338.001.A001

The demand function of foreign traders is simply equation (15), shown in Figure 1 as a linear function for simplicity and as an upward sloping curve because the horizontal axis measures α, which is the complement of α*. This FF curve is relatively flat to approximate a situation with low per-trade costs. There is no closed-form solution for HH, so the curve depicted is intended only to facilitate intuition. HH is shown as a downward-slopping curve but, since domestic agents respond to wealth, intertemporal-substitution and portfolio-composition effects in choosing their equity holdings, HH can be downward or upward slopping depending on which effect dominates.

Suppose that a margin call hits domestic agents because an adverse shock hits the economy when their debt is sufficiently high relative to the value of their assets. As a result, HH shifts to HH ′. In Figure 1, HH ′ represents the “final” demand function, including the magnification effect of the Fisherian debt-deflation mechanism. Without price guarantees, the date-t equilibrium price would fall to point B. This is the “Sudden Stop scenario,” in which margin calls result in lower asset prices and reversals in consumption and the current account. Enter now an IFO that sets a price guarantee higher than the market price at B. The international moral hazard effect shifts the foreign traders’ demand curve to FF′ and the new date-t market price is determined at point C, which yields the fundamentals price. The scenario depicted here is an ideal one in which the IFO is assumed to know exactly at what level to set the guaranteed price so as to stabilize the market price at the fundamentals level.

In contrast, if the guarantee is set below the price at B, it would have no effect on the Sudden Stop equilibrium price, and thus price guarantees would be irrelevant. If the guarantee is set too high, it can lead to a price higher than the fundamentals price (with the overpricing even larger than the underpricing that occurs at B). Hence, ex-ante price guarantees do not necessarily reduce the volatility of asset prices (as Ljungqvist’s (2000) findings showed).

From the perspective of the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model, Figure 1 is a partial equilibrium snapshot of the date-t asset market. The forward-looking behavior of domestic households and foreign traders implies that changes that affect the date-t asset market spillover into the market outcomes at other dates and vice versa. For example, the price guarantee may not be in force at t but the expectation of executing future price guarantees will shift upward the FF curve at t. Similarly, the margin constraint may not bind at t, but the expectation of future margin calls is enough to shift the date-t HH curve. Given the lack of closed-form solutions for equilibrium allocations and prices, the only way to study the effects of price guarantees on the dynamics of consumption, the current account, asset holdings, and asset prices is by exploring the model’s quantitative implications via numerical simulation.

IV. Quantitative Analysis

A. Recursive Equilibrium and Solution Method

In the recursive representation of the equilibrium, the state variables are the current holdings of assets and bonds in the emerging economy, α and b, and the realization of the productivity shock ε. The state space of asset positions spans the discrete grid of NA nodes A={α12<…<αNA} with α1=χ, and the state space of bonds spans the discrete grid of NB nodes B={b1<b2<…<bNB}. The endogenous state space is defined by the discrete set Z = A × B of NA ×NB elements. Productivity shocks follow a stationary, two-point Markov chain with realizations E={εL < εH}. Equilibrium wages, dividends, labor and output are determined by solving the supply-side system given by equations (1), (2), (9) and the production function. The solutions are given by functions that depend only on ε: w(ε), d(ε), n(ε) and F(ε).

The numerical solution of the recursive equilibrium is obtained using a modified version of Mendoza and Smith’s (2006) quasi-planning problem algorithm. The algorithm starts with a conjecture for the function Ĝ(α, b, ε): E × Z → R+, which returns the expected present discounted value of “excess prices” for any triple (α, b, ε) in the state space. Given this conjecture, the optimal decision rules for equity and bond holdings of domestic agents, α′ (α, b, ε),b′ (α, b, ε): E × Z → R, are obtained by solving the following dynamic programming problem:

V ( α , b , ε ) = max α , b A × B { u ( c h ( n ( ε ) ) ) + exp ( υ ( c h ( n ( ε ) ) ) ) E [ V ( α , b , ε ) ] } ( 16 )

subject to:

c = α kd ( ε ) + w ( ε ) n ( ε ) + q f ( ε ) + G ^ ( α , b , ε ) 1 + a θ + a ( α α ) k ( α α ) b + bR ( 17 )
b κ q f ( ε ) + G ^ ( α , b , ε ) 1 + a θ + a ( α α ) α k ( 18 )

Note that equity prices in (17) and (18) were replaced with the prices along the demand curve of foreign traders by imposing equity market clearing and solving for equity prices using (15).

The decision rule for equity holdings is plugged into equation 15) to derive an “actual” asset pricing function (for the given conjecture Ĝ(α, b, ε)). The decision rules for bonds and equity, the guaranteed prices, and this “actual” pricing function are then used to solve for the “actual” G(α, b, ε) function. The conjectured and actual G functions are then combined to create a new conjecture using a Gauss-Siedel rule, and the procedure starts again with the Bellman equation (18). The process is repeated until Ĝ(•) and G(•) converge, so that the function Ĝ(α, b, ε) that is taken as given in the dynamic programming problem is consistent with the function G(α, b, ε) implied by the asset pricing function and decision rules that are endogenous outcomes of that problem.

The drawback of this method is that it assumes that the emerging economy internalizes the demand function of foreign traders. As a result, the equilibrium of problem (18) is equivalent to a competitive equilibrium for a variant of the model with a proportional tax or subsidy on asset returns, with tax revenues rebated as a lump-sum transfer. In the simulations we discuss below, however, the implied taxes are negligible: The maximum taxes in absolute values range between 0.08 (0.4) and 0.2 (0.8) percent when a =0.2 (2). The average tax in absolute value is 0.03 (0.3) percent in the simulations with a =0.2 (2).

B. Deterministic Steady State and Calibration

The functional forms that represent preferences and technology are the following:

F ( k , n t ) = k 1 γ n t γ , 0 γ 1 ( 19 )
u ( c t h ( n t ) ) = [ c t h ( n t ) ] 1 σ 1 1 σ ,         σ > 1 ( 20 )
υ ( c t h ( n t ) ) = β [ Ln ( 1 + c t h ( n t ) ) ] , 0 < β σ ( 21 )
h ( n t ) = n t δ δ , δ > 1 ( 22 )

γ is the labor income share, σ is the coefficient of relative risk aversion, β is the elasticity of the rate of time preference with respect to 1+ct - h(nt), and δ sets the wage elasticity of labor supply (which is equal to 1/(δ-1)). The condition 0<β≤σ is required to limit impatience effects and obtain a well-defined limiting distribution of foreign bonds (see Arellano and Mendoza (2003) for details).

The calibration strategy differs markedly from the one in Mendoza and Smith (2006). They normalize the capital stock to k=1 and let the steady-state equity price adjust to the value implied by the asset pricing condition, given a set of parameter values taken directly from the data or set to enable the model to match ratios of national accounts statistics. Here, we normalize instead the steady-state equity price so that the capital stock matches the deterministic, steady-state capital stock of a typical RBC-SOE model calibrated to Mexican data (see Mendoza (2006)). The steady state of this RBC-SOE model is a frictionless, neoclassical stationary equilibrium. Calibrating to this frictionless equilibrium helps focus the analysis on the use of price guarantees to prevent Sudden Stops triggered by margin calls that hit the economy only when it is highly leveraged (and hence off the long-run equilibrium).

The risk aversion parameter is set at σ =2 in line with values often used in RBC-SOE studies. The parameter values that enter into the supply-side system are determined as follows. The labor share is set at γ =0.65, in line with international evidence on labor income shares. The Mexican average share of labor income in value added in an annual sample for 1988–2001 is 0.34, but values around 0.65 are the norm in several countries and there is concern that the Mexican data may measure inaccurately proprietors income and other forms of labor income (see Mendoza (2006) for details). The real interest rate is set at 6.5 percent, which is also a value widely used in the RBC literature. Since the model is set to a quarterly frequency, this implies R=1.0651/4. The labor disutility coefficient is set to the same value as in Mendoza and Smith (2006), δ =2, which implies a unitary wage elasticity of labor supply.

As in a typical RBC calibration exercise, the calibration is designed to yield a set of parameter values such that the model’s deterministic steady state matches actual averages of the GDP shares of consumption (sc), investment (si), government purchases (sg) and net exports (snx). In the Mexican data, these shares are sc=0.684, si=0.19, sg=0.092, and snx=0.034. Since the model does not have investment or government purchases, their combined share (0.282) is treated as exogenous absorption of output equivalent to 28.2 percent of steady-state GDP. In the stochastic simulations we keep the corresponding level of these expenditures constant at 28.2 percent of the value obtained for steady-state output in the calibration.

The typical RBC-SOE model features a standard steady-state optimality condition that equates the marginal product of capital net of depreciation with the world interest rate, and a standard law of motion of the capital stock that relates the steady-state investment rate to the steady-state capital-output ratio. Given the values of si, γ, δ and R, these two steady-state conditions yield values of the depreciation rate (dep) and the capital-output ratio (sk). On an annual basis, the resulting depreciation rate is 7.75 percent and sk is about 2.5.

In a deterministic steady state of the model of Section II in which the credit constraint does not bind and there are no price guarantees, the equity price is q = q f = d/(R-1). Given the RBC-SOE calibration criterion that the steady-state marginal product of capital net of depreciation equals the net world interest rate, qf can be re-written as Fk (k, n)/(Fk (k, n)-dep). With the Cobb-Douglas production function this reduces to q f = (1-γ)/(1-γ -si). Thus, the requirement that the model’s dividend rate must match a typical RBC-SOE calibration implies that the steady-state equity price is determined by si and γ. With the parameter values set above we obtain q f=2.19.

Given the values of γ, δ, R, and qf the steady-state solutions for n, w, k, and F(k, n) follow from solving the supply-side system conformed by (1), (2), (9) and (21). The resulting steady-state capital stock is k =79. By construction, this capital stock is also consistent with the estimated capital-output ratio of 2.5 and the observed Mexican investment rate of 0.19.

The parameters that remain to be calibrated are the time-preference elasticity coefficient β and the financial frictions parameters a, θ and к. The value of β is derived from the consumption Euler equation as follows. In the deterministic stationary state of the model there are no credit constraints and hence the endogenous rate of time preference equals the real interest rate:

( 1 + scF ( k , n ) n δ δ ) β = R ( 23 )

Given the values of R, δ, n, F(k, n) and sc, this condition can be solved for the required value of β. The solution yields β =0.0118. The total stock of domestic savings at steady state follows then from the resource constraint as s = [c-F(k, n)(si+sg)-wn]/(R-1)= αq fk + b.

Up to this point the calibration followed the typical RBC-SOE deterministic calibration exercise. A problem emerges, however, when we try to determine the composition of the savings portfolio because the allocation of savings across bonds and equity is undetermined. Any portfolio (α, b)∈A×B is consistent with the RBC-SOE deterministic steady state as long as it supports the unique steady-state level of savings (i.e., αq fk + b = s) and the margin and short-selling constraints do not bind (b> -кαq fk and α > χ). Moreover, given the values of s, qf and k implied by the calibration, it follows from the definition of savings that there is only a small subset of portfolios in which the economy borrows in the bond market (i.e., portfolios with b<0) in the set of multiple steady-state portfolios. Debt portfolios require α > 0.9. If domestic agents own less than 90 percent of k, their steady-state bond position is positive and grows larger the smaller is α. This also implies that it will take low values of к to make the margin constraint bind. In particular, setting the upper bound of α at 100 percent, it takes к0.10 for the margin constraint to bind for at least some of the multiple steady-state pairs of (α, b). These low values of к can be justified by considering that the margin constraint represents the fraction of domestic capital that is useful collateral for external debt. Several studies in the Sudden Stops literature provide arguments to suggest that this fraction is small (see, for example, Caballero and Krishnamurty (2001)).

The stochastic RBC-SOE without credit constraints has the additional unappealing feature that it can lead to degenerate long-run distributions of equity and bonds in which domestic agents hold the smallest equity position (χ) and use bonds to engage in consumption smoothing and precautionary saving. The reason is that, without credit constraints and zero recurrent trading costs, risk-averse domestic agents demand a risk premium to hold equity while risk-neutral foreign traders do not.6 Hence, domestic agents end up selling all the equity they can to foreign traders, although the process takes time because of the trading costs that foreign traders pay.

To circumvent the problems of portfolio determination in the deterministic and stochastic RBC-SOE steady states, we calibrate the values of the financial frictions parameters (a, θ and к) so that the allocations and prices obtained with the deterministic RBC-SOE steady state can be closely approximated as the deterministic steady state of an economy with negligible (but positive) recurrent trading costs and a margin constraint that is just slightly binding. This calibration scenario is labeled the “nearly frictionless economy”(NFE).

The deterministic steady state of the NFE has well-defined, unique solutions for bond and equity positions. In particular, foreign traders hold a stationary equity position at the price q = qf/(1+aθ). Since this price is less than qf, which is the price at which the return on domestic equity equals R, it follows that at this lower price Rq > R. Thus, foreign traders now require an equity premium to hold a stationary equity position. The ratio of the Lagrange multipliers of the domestic agent’s margin constraint and budget constraint can then be found to be η/λ = (Rq-R)/(Rq -Rк). In addition, since the margin constraint binds, bond holdings must satisfy b = -кα q k, and hence a unique stationary domestic equity position can be obtained from the steady-state consumption Euler equation. This is the value of α that solves the following expression:

( 1 + α kd + wn κ q α k ( R 1 ) n δ δ ) β       = R 1 ( η / λ ) ( 24 )

Equation (24) illustrates the key role of the endogenous rate of time preference in supporting deterministic stationary equilibria with binding credit limits: it allows the rate of time preference to adjust so as to make the higher long-run consumption level, implied by the fact that the credit constraint prevents domestic agents from borrowing as they desire in the transition to steady state, to be consistent with the higher effective long-run real interest rate also implied by the credit constraint. The recurrent trading cost is also critical. With θ=0, a stationary equity position for foreign traders requires a price equal to qf and a return on equity equal to R, but the latter implies that η/λ=0, so the borrowing constraint could not bind.

In the NFE steady state, the values of a, θ and к are set to support a deterministic steady state with a binding borrowing constraint that satisfies the following conditions: (1) the debt-GDP ratio is in line with Mexican data, (2) the allocations, factor payment rates and the equity price are nearly identical to those obtained for the frictionless RBC-SOE deterministic steady state, and (3) the elasticity of the foreign trader’s demand curve is relatively high. The values of the financial frictions parameters are: a = 0.2, θ = 0.001 and к = 0.03. With these parameter values, and the values set earlier for γ, δ, β, and R, the NFE steady state yields values of c, s, n, w, d, q, and Rq nearly identical to those of the RBC-SOE deterministic steady state, but the NFE also has unique portfolio allocations of α = 0.931 and b = -4.825 (which implies a debt-GDP ratio of about 0.62).

C. Stochastic Simulation Framework

The stochastic simulations are solved over a discrete state space with 78 evenly-spaced nodes in the equity grid and 120 evenly-spaced nodes in the bonds grid. The lower bound for equity is set at χ=0.84, so the equity grid spans the interval [0.84,1]. These equity bounds, together with the maximum equity price supported by (15) and the margin constraint, set the lower bound for bonds as -к qmaxk = -5.2. This is the largest debt that the SOE could leverage by holding the largest possible equity position at the highest possible price. The upper bound of bonds is found by solving the model repeatedly starting with an upper bound that supports steady state savings with the equity position at its lowest, and then increasing the upper bound until the grid captures the support of the ergodic distribution of bonds. The resulting grid spans the interval [-5.2,25.7]. The segment of debt positions inside this interval is relatively small, reflecting the fact that, despite the frictions induced by asset trading costs, domestic agents still have a preference for riskless bonds as a vehicle to smooth consumption and build a buffer stock of savings.

A lower bound on domestic equity holdings of 84 percent seems much higher than the conventional short-selling limit set at 0 but it is consistent with the national aggregates targeted in the calibration. In Mexico, the 1988–2000 average ratio of stock market capitalization to GDP was 27.6 percent. Since the calibration produced an estimate of the capital-output ratio of about 2.5, the shares of publicly traded firms constitute just 11 percent of the capital stock. A large fraction of Mexico’s capital is owned by non-publicly-traded firms and by owners of residential property, and thus does not have a liquid market in which shares are traded with foreign residents. In general, it is hard to argue that a large fraction of the physical capital of most emerging economies has a liquid international market. Moreover, the result from the calibration showing that bond positions become positive and unrealistically large for α<0.9 also argues for a high value of χ.

Productivity shocks are modeled as a two-point, symmetric Markov process that follows the “simple persistence” rule. The two points of the Markov chain and the transition probability matrix are set so that the model mimics the standard deviation and first-order autocorrelation of the quarterly cyclical components of Mexico’s GDP reported in Mendoza (2006)—2.64 percent and 0.683 respectively. This requires a Markov process of productivity shocks with a standard deviation (σε) of 1.79 percent and a first-order autocorrelation coefficient (ρε) of 0.683. The simple persistence rule implies then that the two points of the Markov chain are -εL = εH = 0.0179 and these two states have a long-run probability of ½. The transition probability of remaining in either state is given by ½(1-(ρε)+ρε = 0.8415 and the transition probability of shifting across states is ½(1-ρε) = 0.1585.

D. Baseline Results: Globalization Hazard and Sudden Stops Without Price Guarantees

The baseline results include four simulations: (1) the NFE case, (2) the economy with binding margin requirements (BMR), which uses a margin coefficient set at к =0.005, (3) a simple price-guarantees policy that sets a single, non-state-contingent guaranteed price (NSCG) for all dates and states, and (4) an economy with the same guaranteed price but as a state-contingent guarantee (SCG) that applies only in a subset of the state space.

The key result that emerges from comparing the NFE and BMR economies is that the financial frictions representing globalization hazard in the model do cause Sudden Stops when the ratio of debt to the market value of equity is high and the equity market has enough liquidity (i.e., domestic agents are not at their short-selling limit). Since this result echoes findings from Mendoza and Smith (2006), we keep the presentation short and refer the reader to their article for details.

Figures 2 shows the long run distributions of equity and bonds for the four simulations. Comparing the bond distributions of the NFE and BMR simulations, the effect of the margin constraint is evident. The distribution is biased to the left in the two economies but it shifts markedly to the right in the BMR case. The opposite occurs with the distribution of equity. The bias to the left in the distribution of equity reflects the incentive that risk-averse domestic agents have to sell equity to risk-neutral foreign traders. Binding margin constraints shift the equity distribution further to the left because of the equity fire sales triggered by margin calls. These shifts in the distributions of equity and bonds also reflect the outcome of precautionary saving. Domestic agents, aware of the imperfections of financial markets, have an incentive to build up a buffer stock of savings so as to minimize the risk of large declines in consumption, and in doing so they also lower the risk of facing states in which margin constraints bind in the long run (Figure 2 shows that the long run distribution of bonds of the BMR economy rules out states with very large debt positions). Still, Table 1 shows that the long-run probability of binding margin constraints is about 4 percent. Sudden Stops are therefore rare but non-zero probability events in the stochastic steady state (although many of the states in which margin constraints bind in the long run do not trigger Sudden Stops, as explained below). Note also that margin constraints cause a portfolio reallocation of savings from equity into bonds. Table 1 shows that the long-run average of the bonds-output ratio increases from 18 percent in the NFE to 50 percent in the BMR economy.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Ergodic Distributions of Domestic Equity and Bond Holdings

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2006, 073; 10.5089/9781451863338.001.A001

Note: NFE is nearly frictionless economy, BMR is economy with binding margin requirements, NSCG is economy with be margin requirements and non-state-contingent guarantees, and SCG is economy with binding margin requirements and stag contingent guarantees.
Table 1.

Long Run Business Cycle Moments

article image
Note: NFE is nearly frictionless economy, BMR is economy with binding margin requirements, NSCG is economy with binding margin requirements and non-state-contingent guarantees, and SCG is economy with binding margin requirements and state-contingent guarantees.

Financial frictions have negligible effects on business cycle moments (see Table 1). Hence, as in Mendoza and Smith (2006), we study Sudden Stops by examining the model’s dynamics in the high-debt region of the state space in which the margin constraint binds (i.e., the “Sudden Stop region”). Figure 3 shows the date-0 responses (or impact effects) of consumption and the current account-GDP ratio (ca/y) to a negative, one-standard-deviation productivity shock for (α, b) pairs in the Sudden Stop region, measured in percent of the long-run mean of each variable. The Sudden Stop region includes the first 25 nodes of the B grid and all 72 nodes of the A grid.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Consumption & Current Account-GDP Ratio Impact Effects of a Negative Productivity Shock in the Sudden Stop Region of Equity & Bonds

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2006, 073; 10.5089/9781451863338.001.A001

Note: The values are in percent deviations from long run average for consumption impact effects, and percentage point difference for current account-GDP ratio impact effects.

Figure 3 suggests that there are two key factors driving impact effects in the Sudden Stop region: (1) The leverage ratio, defined as the ratio of debt to the market value of equity, and (2) The liquidity of the equity market, defined as the difference between α and χ. Sudden Stops with large reversals in c and ca/y occur when the leverage ratio is high, but given high leverage the impact on asset prices is different depending on asset market liquidity. If the asset market is illiquid, the Sudden Stop can feature negligible asset price declines because domestic agents are close to χ and hence have little equity to sell (see Figure 5a), but if there is some liquidity in the asset market, the Sudden Stop in c and ca/y is accompanied by a fall in q. In contrast, when the leverage ratio is sufficiently low and the asset market is sufficiently liquid, the drop in consumption and the current account reversal are small (nearly as small as in the NFE case) but the drop in asset prices is larger. In this case, domestic agents liquidate more equity and trigger larger asset price collapses, but they do so in order to swap their limited borrowing ability via bonds for equity sales so as to minimize the drop in consumption. This pattern of larger current account corrections coinciding with smaller asset price collapses fits the observations of some emerging markets crises. The current account reversal in the first quarter of 1995 in Mexico was 5.2 percent of GDP but the drop in real equity prices was nearly 29 percent. In contrast, in Korea the current account reversal in the first quarter of 1998 was twice as large but the asset price drop was just 10 percent.

Figure 4 illustrates Sudden Stop dynamics using the conditional forecasting functions of c, q and ca/y. The first two are shown as percentages of their long-run averages in the NFE and the last is shown as the percentage points difference relative to the long-run average in the NFE. These forecasting functions represent non-linear impulse response functions to a negative, one-standard-deviation productivity shock conditional on initial positions of equity and bonds inside the Sudden Stop region. The Figures plot two sets of forecasting functions, one for a high leverage initial state, at which α = 0.938 and b = -4.68 (with debt ratio of 60 percent of GDP and a leverage ratio of 3 percent of GDP), and one for a low leverage state with the same α but b = -3.38 (with a debt ratio of 43 percent of GDP and a leverage ratio of 2 percent of GDP). Since these initial states are distant from the corresponding long-run averages, the data in the Figures were adjusted to remove low-frequency transitional dynamics driven by the convergence of bonds and equity to their long-run means. Given that c, q and ca/y have nearly identical long-run averages in the four baseline experiments (except for the mean of q in the NSCG economy, which is higher), the forecasting functions were detrended by taking differences relative to the NFE forecasting functions.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Conditional Responses to a Negative, One-Standard-Deviation Productivity Shock

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2006, 073; 10.5089/9781451863338.001.A001

1/ Forecasting functions of each variable’s equilibrium Markov process conditional on initial states α=0.938 and b=-4.68, which imply a leverage ratio of 0.029 and a debt/GDP ratio of 0.597.2/ Forecasting functions of each variable’s equilibrium Markov process conditional on initial states α=0.938 and b=-3.38, which imply a leverage ratio of 0.021 and a debt/GDP ratio of 0.434.
Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Equity Pricing Function in the Low Productivity State

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2006, 073; 10.5089/9781451863338.001.A001

The impact effects in the initial date of the forecasting functions of the BMR economy differ sharply across the high and low leverage states, and those of the high leverage state deviate significantly from those of the NFE (or from zero in terms of Figure 4, since the data are plotted as differences relative to the NFE). In the high leverage state of the BMR economy, the negative shock triggers a Sudden Stop driven by the mechanisms described in Section 3: Domestic agents sell equity to meet margin calls and trigger a Fisherian deflation that reduces further their ability to borrow. The net result is that, on impact, a one-standard-deviation shock to productivity causes c and q to drop by 1.5 and 0.4 percent more than in the NFE respectively and ca/y to rise by about 1 percentage point of GDP. In the low leverage state, domestic agents are better positioned to smooth consumption by substituting debt for equity to finance a current account deficit. As a result, the responses of c and ca/y in the BMR economy are nearly identical to those in the NFE, so their detrended forecasting functions hover around zero. This occurs even though the sales of equity still make q fall by about the same amount as in the high leverage scenario. Notice also that the drop in asset prices is small relative to observed Sudden Stops, but very large relative to the standard deviation of asset prices in the NFE.

One caveat about the plots in Figure 4: The initial bond and equity positions used to generate them yield outcomes consistent with Sudden Stops, but the set of impact effects that the model predicts for all initial conditions inside the Sudden Stop region are shown in Figures 3. As these Figures show, the Sudden Stop region includes scenarios with much larger consumption and current-account reversals than those shown in Figure 4, as well as scenarios in which there is little difference between the BMR and NFE because the asset market is sufficiently liquid to maintain a similar current account deficit by selling equity when the margin constraint binds. Precautionary saving implies, however, that all the scenarios with very large reversals in consumption have zero probability in the long run. Notice also that, since the Sudden Stop region includes instances in which the margin constraint binds but fire sales of assets prevent a sharp current account reversal, the probability of binding margin constraints is not identical to the probability of Sudden Stops.

Figure 4 suggests that Sudden Stops in the model are short-lived. The responses of the BMR economy converge to those of the NFE in about 4 quarters. Mendoza and Smith (2006) obtained Sudden Stops with more persistence using higher per-trade costs, which hamper the foreign traders’ ability to adjust equity holdings.

E. Baseline Results: State-Contingent and Non-State-Contingent Price Guarantees

The price guarantees are set above the fundamentals price in the low productivity state.7 This is motivated by a theoretical result that holds for stationary decision rules (i.e., αt+1=αt, bt+1=bt) and equilibrium equity prices in the high productivity state that exceed a time-and state-invariant guaranteed price. Under these assumptions, we can show that G(α,b,εL)=z(q˜qf(εL)1+aθ), where z is a positive fraction that depends on R, a, θ and the transition probabilities of the shocks. Hence, q˜>qf(εL)1+aθ is a necessary condition for the guarantees to be executed at least in some states.

The non-state-contingent price guarantee is set ½ of a percentage point above the fundamentals price in the low productivity state (2.185). Hence, the guaranteed price is 2.196. This guarantee is offered in all states (α,b, ε) in the NSCG economy. In contrast, the SCG economy provides the same guaranteed price only for (α,b) pairs inside the Sudden Stop region.

Figure 2 shows that, relative to the BMR case, the non-state-contingent guarantee shifts the distribution of equity (bonds) markedly to the left (right). The long-run average of the expected present value of excess prices (i.e., the long-run average of G) is 0.01, which is about ½ of a percent above the mean equity price in the stochastic stationary state. Comparing long-run moments across Panels I, II and III of Table 1, the main change in the NSCG simulation is the reduction in the probability of binding margin constraints. The probability is almost zero with price guarantees, compared with 4 percent in the BMR economy. The long-run moments of the model’s endogenous variables vary slightly with the non-state-contingent guarantee. Asset-price fluctuations display less variability, persistence and comovement with output in the NSCG economy relative to the NFE and BMR cases. The mean equity price increases by 0.053 percent, slightly more than the percent difference between the guaranteed price and the fundamentals price of the low productivity state. The coefficient of variation of consumption falls by about 1/5 of a percentage point and the variability of the current account and the trade balance increase slightly. Consumption also becomes less correlated with GDP.

The effects of the price guarantee on Sudden Stop dynamics are shown in Figure 4. Price guarantees are an effective policy for containing Sudden Stops. Comparing the NSCG and BMR economies in the high leverage state, the initial consumption and current account reversals are smaller in the NSCG economy, and the drop in equity prices turns into an increase of about ¼ of a percentage point. In the low leverage state, the increase in equity prices in the NSCG economy is slightly larger than in the high leverage state, and we now obtain an increase in consumption and a widening of the current account deficit at date 0. The price guarantee results in a price of equity at date 0 that is 2/3 of a percentage point higher in the NSCG than in the BMR economy in both the high and low leverage states. The price guarantee is executed in both states of the NSCG economy.

Figure 5 plots the levels of equity prices in the low productivity state of the NFE, BMR and NSCG economies for all equity and bond positions. The plots show that the non-state-contingent guarantee not only results in higher prices in the Sudden Stop region, but it actually increases prices in all states. In fact, the guarantee produces significantly higher asset prices in the NSCG economy than in either the NFE or BMR economies in states well outside the Sudden Stop region. This is a potentially important drawback of non-state-contingent price guarantees: they distort asset prices even when the economy is in states where it is far from vulnerable to Sudden Stops.

One alternative to remedy the drawbacks of non-state-contingent price guarantees is to consider state-contingent guarantees. Figure 2 shows that the SCG economy yields a long-run distribution of equity (bonds) that is less skewed to the left (right) than in the NSCG economy. Table 1 shows that the changes in the long-run business cycle moments of the SCG economy relative to the NFE and BMR cases are qualitatively similar to those noted for the NSCG economy but the magnitude of the changes is smaller. The SCG economy still features near-zero percent probability of observing states of nature in which the margin constraint binds. Hence, the state-contingent guarantee is as effective as the non-state-contingent guarantee at eliminating the possibility of hitting states with binding margin requirements in the long run.

Figure 4 shows that, in both the high and low leverage states, the SCG economy features nearly identical date-0 responses in consumption and the current account as the NSCG economy and a slightly smaller recovery in asset prices. After date 0, the SCG economy converges faster to the dynamic paths of the NFE economy. Finally, a comparison of the middle and bottom plots of Figure 5 shows that the SCG economy yields higher asset prices mainly in the Sudden Stop region of the state space. Thus, state contingent guarantees induce smaller distortions on asset demand and asset prices than the non-state-contingent guarantees, particularly outside the Sudden Stop region, yet they have similar effects in terms of their ability to prevent Sudden Stops.

V. Normative Implications and Sensitivity Analysis

A. Normative Implications of the Baseline Simulations

We study next the normative implications of the baseline simulations by examining how domestic welfare and the value of foreign securities firms varies across the NFE, BMR, NSCG and SCG simulations. Welfare costs, W(α, b, ε), are measured by computing compensating variations in date-0 consumption that equate expected lifetime utility in the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies with that of the NFE for any triple (α, b, ε) in the state space. Welfare effects are typically computed as compensating variations that apply to consumption at all dates, but in principle both measures are useful for converting ordinal units of utility into the cardinal units needed for quantitative welfare comparisons. The two measures yield identical welfare rankings for the four experiments, but the measure based on date-0 consumption highlights better the welfare costs of Sudden Stops and the potential benefits of price guarantees because large deviations from the consumption dynamics of the NFE occur only in Sudden Stop states (in which bond and equity positions are distant from their long-run averages).

The model belongs to the class of models in which capital markets are used to smooth consumption over the business cycle. Hence, since it is well-known that the welfare cost of “typical” consumption fluctuations is small in these models, the mean welfare costs of deviating from the NFE (E[W(α, b, ε)] computed with the ergodic distribution) should be small. As Table 2 shows, welfare comparisons based on date-0 consumption preserve this result. Agents in the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies incur average welfare losses relative to the NFE equivalent to cuts of less than 0.07 percent in c0. This is also in line with Mendoza’s (1991) results showing trivial welfare costs for giving up access to world capital markets in an RBC-SOE model.

Table 2.

Payoffs of Domestic Agents and Foreign Traders in Baseline Simulations

article image

Compensating variation in date-0 consumption that equates expected lifetime utility obtained in the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies with that of the NFE.

Compensating variation in date-0 consumption that equates date-0 period utility obtained in the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies with that of the NFE.

Difference of total welfare cost minus short-run cost.

The situation is very different when comparing welfare conditional on Sudden Stop states. Since the Bellman equation implies that lifetime utility as of date 0 can be expressed as V(t) = u(t) + exp(-v(t))Et[V(t+1)], Table 2 decomposes the total welfare cost into a short-run cost (i.e., the percent change in c0 that equates u(0) in the distorted economies with that of the NFE) and a long-run cost (i.e., the percent change in c0 that equates exp(-v(0))E0[V(1)] in the distorted economies with that of the NFE). The Table also lists the rate of time preference, exp(-v(0)), to show that changes in the endogenous subjective discount are irrelevant for the welfare analysis.

In the high leverage Sudden Stop state, which is the one that in the BMR economy produces dynamics closer to those of observed Sudden Stops, the short-run welfare costs show that domestic agents are worse off in the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies than in the NFE. The welfare cost is 1.4 percent for the BMR economy and 0.9 and 1 percent for the NSCG and SCG economies respectively. This ranking reflects the fact that declines in date-0 consumption, and hence u(0), are smallest in the NFE because it provides the best environment for consumption smoothing, followed by the economies in which price guarantees help contain Sudden Stops.

The long-run costs are negative (i.e., domestic agents make welfare gains) because consumption after date 0 increases at least temporarily in the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies. In the high leverage case of the BMR economy, the binding credit constraint tilts the consumption profile by reducing consumption at date 0 and increasing it later, resulting in a long-run welfare gain of about 1 percent. Consumption tilting is also at work in the NSCG and SCG economies, but in addition the higher (distorted) asset prices lead to higher consumption relative to both the BMR and the NFE for three quarters beyond the initial date (see Figure 4). This expansion of consumption in the economies with price guarantees is driven in turn by larger current account deficits, which are financed by equity sales at higher prices.

After date 0, domestic agents set to rebalance their portfolios from equity into bonds gradually, but in economies with price guarantees the capital inflows from equity sales exceed the outflows from bond purchases in the early periods of transition thus producing larger external deficits. This leads to long-run welfare gains in the high leverage NSCG and SCG economies (1.9 and 1.3 percent respectively) that are large enough to offset the short-run costs, so that domestic agents obtain total welfare gains of 1 percent in the NSCG and 0.3 percent in the SCG.

These results show that the asset price changes induced by price guarantees represent nontrivial distortions relative to the NFE. Moreover, as we show below, the same distortions that increase domestic welfare in the high leverage Sudden Stop states of the NSCG and SCG economies reduce the value of foreign traders’ firms in those states.

At equilibrium, the foreign traders’ net returns can be written as:

π ^ ( α , b , ε ) k { [ ( 1 α ) d ( ε ) ] [ q ( α , b , ε ) ( α α ^ ( α , b , ε ) ) ] [ q ( α , b , ε ) ( a 2 ) ( α α ^ ( α , b , ε ) + θ ) 2 ] } ( 25 )

The three terms in square brackets in the right-hand-side of this expression represent the foreign traders’ dividend earnings, the net value of their trades, and the trading costs they incur. Notice that, since the budget constraint of the IFO holds, the lump sum taxes paid by foreign traders cancel with the value of the executed guarantees. Thus, price guarantees distort the traders’ optimality condition with the moral hazard effect identified in (15) without direct income effects.

The payoff of foreign traders D is the expected present discounted value of the stream of net returns. In the recursive representation of the equilibrium, this present value of returns is a function D(α, b, ε), and hence we can compute long-run averages of net returns, E[D(α, b, ε)], and values of D(α, b, ε) conditional on Sudden Stop states. Since the model has a well-defined stochastic steady state, the long-run mean of net returns is given by E[D]=kE[π^]R(R1)1.

Table 2 shows that, relative to the NFE, E[D] and E[π^] are 14.5 percent higher in the BMR economy and 52.6 and 42.5 percent higher in the NSCG and SCG economies respectively. Thus, from the perspective of the long-run average of the value of their firms, foreign traders are better off in the BMR economy and significantly better off in the economies with price guarantees than in the NFE. Table 2 also shows that this is the case mainly because of the increased average equity holdings of foreign traders in the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies, and the corresponding increase in their average dividend earnings. The contribution of changes in the value of trades to changes in E[D] and E[π^] is zero by definition (since the unconditional means of αt and αt+1 are identical) and the contribution of changes in trading costs is negligible. Foreign traders build up a larger equity position in the BMR economy as a result of the rebalancing of the portfolio of domestic agents from equity into bonds shown in Figure 2, and also because in some states foreign traders buy assets at crash prices (i.e., when domestic agents fire sale assets to meet margin calls). Foreign traders are much better off when price guarantees are in place because the price guarantees are equivalent to a guaranteed minimum return, which reduces sharply the downside risk of holding equity and results in even larger domestic portfolio reallocations from equity into bonds.

The result that the payoff of foreign traders is significantly higher on average in the long run with price guarantees hides the fact that, when evaluated conditional on a Sudden Stop state, the payoff of foreign traders is lower in economies with price guarantees. Table 2 shows that the ranking of foreign traders’ payoffs obtained by comparing D(α, b, ε) across Sudden Stop states with low or high leverage is the opposite from the one obtained by comparing E[D]. Relative to the NFE, the present value of profits is nearly unchanged in the BMR economy and it falls in the high and low leverage states of the economies with price guarantees (by about 0.7 and 0.3 percent in the NSCG and SCG economies respectively). The latter occurs because in the NSCG and SCG economies the increase in the long-run average of net returns (E[π^]) is not sufficient to offset the short-run decline in returns (π^(α,b,ε)) that occurs at date 0 when a Sudden Stop hits (see Table 2). In turn, this decline in net returns at date 0 is almost entirely driven by changes in the value of trades. The value of trades in the high (low) leverage state rises from 0.36 in the NFE to 3.93 (3.22) in the BMR economy and to about 3.95 (3.24) in the NSCG and SCG economies. In the BMR economy, the increase reflects the domestic agents’ fire sales of equity to meet margin calls. The equity price falls, and when it falls foreign traders demand more equity and the value of their trades increases. In the economies with price guarantees, the moral hazard distortion exacerbates this effect by increasing the foreign traders’ equity demand and producing equilibrium prices higher than in the BMR economy.

In line with the increase in trading values, trading costs rise sharply from the NFE economy to the other economies, but their absolute amounts remain small. Dividend earnings do not change because date-0 equity holdings are the same in all four economies and the dividends of domestic firms are independent of financial frictions and price guarantees.

In principle, the present value of foreign traders’ net returns conditional on a Sudden Stop state could be higher or lower with price guarantees than without depending on whether the short-run effect lowering date-0 net returns is weaker or stronger than the long-run effect increasing average net returns. The strength of these effects depends in turn on how much and how fast equilibrium equity positions and equity prices move, which depends on the parameters driving the demand for equity of domestic agents and foreign traders. According to Table 2, however, the substantial increases in the average payoff of foreign traders (E[D]) in the NSCG and SCG economies exceed by large margins the small reductions in D(α, b, ε) to which foreign traders are exposed with very low probability in the long run.

To analyze the distributional implications of price guarantees, consider the “resource constraint” implied by the households’ budget constraint and the traders’ net returns:

c = ε F ( k , n ) [ k α * d b ( R 1 ) ] + [ qk ( α * α * ) ( b b ) ] ( 26 )

As noted earlier, the long-run averages of consumption in the NFE, BMR, NSCG and SCG economies are nearly identical (see Table 1). On the other hand, Table 2 shows that the long-run average of the foreign traders’ dividend earnings is higher in the latter three than in the NFE. Taking the long-run average of equation (26), it follows from these two observations that domestic agents can sustain similar long-run average consumption levels because their average savings remain nearly unchanged: The drop in dividend earnings on equity is nearly offset by increased interest income from bonds. Thus, the baseline results suggest that globalization hazard and price guarantees, as modeled in this paper, do not alter the long-run average shares of global income and wealth across the small open economy and the rest of the world. Foreign traders receive a larger share of domestic GDP but GNP is unaffected because domestic agents increase bond holdings and thus collect more interest income from abroad. The independence of GDP from financial frictions and price guarantees is a strong assumption that plays a key role in this result. The SOE assumption also plays a role because it allows the domestic portfolio swap of equity for bonds to occur without increasing the price of these bonds, which would lower the world interest rate.

Short-run distributional effects at a Sudden Stop state are different. GNP and GDP are unchanged across the four simulations, but there is a redistribution of world income via the current account. Relative to the NFE, foreign traders transfer income to domestic households in the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies, as the value of trades in the third term of the right-hand-side of (26) increases because domestic agents fire-sale equity to meet margin calls. But whether the domestic economy receives more or less income from the rest of the world as a whole depends on whether the fire sale of assets can prevent the current account reversal, which in turn depends on the leverage ratio and the liquidity of the asset market. Table 2 shows that π^(α,b,ε) falls at date 0 in the high and low leverage states, but Figure 4 shows that the reversal in ca/y is larger in the former. Thus, the high leverage state features a redistribution of income from foreign traders to domestic agents via the equity market, but the larger current account reversal indicates that this redistribution is more than offset by the loss of access to the credit market, so that the domestic economy reduces the share of world output that it absorbs. In contrast, in the low leverage state the current account deficit remains close to the level of the NFE and hence the domestic economy maintains its share of world output. These results hold across the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies compared to the NFE but the effects are stronger in the economies with price guarantees.

The above results show that, comparing long-run averages of the payoffs of domestic agents and foreign traders, foreign traders are significantly better off in the economies with price guarantees than in the NFE or BMR economies, while domestic agents are nearly indifferent. This suggests that price guarantees could be close to a win-win situation, but this result has some caveats. In particular, domestic agents are nearly indifferent between the long-run outcomes of the four economies because of the trivial cost of consumption fluctuations in models of the class examined here, and foreign traders make large gains in the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies because their dividend earnings are unaffected by financial frictions. Interestingly, in the short run and starting at a Sudden Stop state, the moral hazard distortion of economies with price guarantees yields persistently higher asset prices that redistribute income from foreign traders to domestic agents by more than is needed if the aim were just to recover the outcome of the NFE (hence making domestic agents better off and foreign traders worse off). Still, foreign traders are much better off in the long run because the large increase in E[D] in the NSCG and SCG economies dwarfs the small, near-zero-probability reduction in D(α, b, ε) for Sudden Stop states.

B. Sensitivity Analysis

Table 3 reports the results of a sensitivity analysis that evaluates the robustness of the baseline results to the following parameter changes: Columns (II) and (III), larger and more persistent productivity shocks (σε=0.024 and ρε=0.8), Column (IV), higher price guarantees (1 percent above q fL)), Column (V), higher recurrent trading costs (θ=0.01), and Column (VI), higher per-trade costs (a =2). Column (I) reproduces the baseline results. The Table shows panels with results for the BMR, NSCG and SCG economies for all six scenarios. In each case, three sets of results are listed: (a) Sudden Stop effects as measured by the detrended, date-0 forecasting functions conditional on the high leverage state, (b) key moments of the ergodic distribution, and (c) changes in the payoffs of domestic agents and foreign traders, relative to the corresponding NFE simulation, for the high leverage Sudden Stop state and in the long-run averages.

Table 3.

Sensitivity Analysis

article image
article image
Note: The guaranteed price is 0.5 percent (1 percent for column (IV)) above the fundamentals price in the low productivity state of the baseline simulation. Welfare costs are compensating variations in initial consumption that equalize lifetime utility in each simulation with that of the corresponding NFE. Initial responses are in percent of the corresponding NFE and detrended as described in the text (except the response for traders’ returns which is in percent of the capital stock and the response for the current account-output ratio which is the difference in percentage points relative to the corresponding NFE).

Percentage change relative to NFE

Consider first the BMR panel. Columns (I)-(VI) show that the results of the comparison of the baseline NFE and BMR economies are robust to the parameter changes considered. Increases in σε and ρε result in small changes in Columns (II) and (III) relative to Column (I). The exceptions are the probability of binding margin constraints, which rises (falls) to 4.2 (2.3) percent when ρε (σε) increases, and the long-run average of the value of the foreign traders’ firms, which falls to 12.2 and 4.4 percent in Columns (II) and (III) respectively. The changes in the probability of margin calls result from portfolio rebalancing effects. More persistent (variable) shocks increase (reduce) slightly the long-run average of domestic equity holdings, and have the opposite effects on bond holdings. As a result, the economy with more persistent (variable) shocks is more (less) likely to hit low bond positions (i.e., high debt positions) in which the margin constraint binds.

In line with the findings of Mendoza and Smith (2006), Columns (V) and (VI) show that BMR economies with higher θ or higher a display larger Sudden Stops, with the latter showing stronger effects. The long-run probability of margin calls is also sharply higher in these economies, reaching 16.7 percent with θ =0.01 and 19.4 percent with a =2. The BMR economy with a =2 is the only scenario in Table 3 that can account for large consumption and current account reversals and large drops in asset prices, as in actual Sudden Stops. This scenario also results in increased long-run variability in consumption and asset prices, and sharply higher domestic welfare costs.

Comparing now Columns (I)-(VI) across the BMR, NSCG and SCG panels, we find that price guarantees always work to virtually eliminate the long-run probability of binding margin constraints. On the other hand, the long-run probability of executing the guarantees is high in the NSCG economy, ranging between 29 and 34 percent in all scenarios except the one with higher σε, in which it falls to 15 percent. In contrast, the probability of executing the guarantees in the SCG economy is below 1 percent in all the scenarios except those with θ =0.01 and a =2, in which it reaches 6 and 3.2 percent respectively. Thus, state-contingent guarantees are as effective as non-state-contingent guarantees at reducing the long-run probability of margin calls, with the advantage that in the SCG economy the IFO would be trading much less frequently.

A comparison of Columns (I) and (IV) shows that rising the guaranteed price 1 percent above q fL), twice as large than in the baseline, the NSCG and SCG economies dampen the Sudden Stops of the BMR economy even more than in the baseline. With the higher price guarantee in Column (IV), the fall in c is just 0.5 (0.6) percent in the NSCG (SCG), compared to 0.8 (0.9) percent in the corresponding baseline simulations. Similarly, the reversal in ca/y in the NSCG (SCG) is just 0.3 (0.4) percentage points of GDP in Column (IV), compared to 0.6 (0.7) in Column (I). On the other hand, the economies with higher guarantees prop up asset prices in the Sudden Stop state even more than in Column (I), with price increases of 0.7 (0.6) percent in the NSCG (SCG) economy. The domestic welfare gain in the high leverage Sudden Stop state increases to 2.4 (0.9) percent in Column (IV) of the NSCG (SCG) economy, compared to 1 (0.3) percent in the corresponding baseline simulations, while the long-run welfare losses remain nearly unchanged across Columns (I) and (IV). At the same time as the domestic welfare gains in the Sudden Stop state grow, the decline in the payoff of the foreign traders in the same state grows from 0.7 (0.3) percent in the NSCG (SCG) baseline to 1.4 (0.9) percent in the NSCG (SCG) with higher guarantees. In contrast, the long-run average of the traders’ payoff increases with the higher guarantees. Thus, the results regarding the effects of price guarantees obtained with the baseline simulations are qualitatively similar to those obtained with higher guarantees, but quantitatively the higher guarantees induce larger moral hazard distortions, which result in weaker Sudden Stops but larger redistribution effects across foreign traders and domestic agents.

Column (VI) shows that, if the baseline level of price guarantees is applied to an economy with higher per-trade asset trading costs, the price guarantees still work to weaken the real effects of Sudden Stops relative to those in the BMR economy. With a =2, however, the guarantee set 0.5 percent above q fL) is insufficient to prevent marked reversals in c and ca/y and a sharp drop in q. Consequently, domestic agents suffer a substantial welfare loss of 1.5 (2.6) percent in the high leverage Sudden Stop state of the NSCG (SCG) economy, instead of the small gains obtained in the corresponding baseline simulations with a=0.2.

Moreover, the long-run average of welfare costs increases about 5 (2) times in the NSCG (SCG) economy with a=2 relative to the same simulations with a=0.2. Interestingly, the payoff of the foreign traders in the high leverage Sudden Stop state is larger in the NSCG and SCG economies with a=2 than in their baseline counterparts with a=0.2. In fact, in the SCG economy with a=2 the value of the foreign traders’ firm in the high leverage state is even higher than that in the corresponding NFE economy.

The above results show that, for a given guaranteed price, there can be a sufficiently high value of a such that the mix of globalization hazard and international moral hazard yields outcomes in which domestic agents suffer large welfare losses at Sudden Stops, but still these losses are smaller than in the BMR economy without guarantees. Moreover, for given a, higher guarantees dampen Sudden Stops more and produce welfare gains at Sudden Stop states. These findings suggest that price guarantees should be higher the higher are trading costs. The results also show, however, that economies with higher a face higher long-run averages of welfare costs with price guarantees than without them (the cost is 1/3 of a percent in the NSCG panel of Column (VI), compared to 1/10 of a percent in the corresponding BMR). In addition, economies with higher guarantees and the baseline value of a yield larger long-run welfare losses (see Column IV). Thus, if per-trade trading costs are high, increasing price guarantees makes domestic agents better off at Sudden Stop states by weakening more the effects of globalization hazard, but the stronger effects of international moral hazard makes them worse off on average in the long run.

The findings of the sensitivity analysis suggest that the size of per-trade costs is crucial for the effectiveness of price guarantees and the globalization hazard-moral hazard tradeoff. Mendoza and Smith (2006) showed that this parameter is also crucial for the model’s ability to account for asset price collapses of the magnitude observed in Sudden Stops, and documented empirical evidence of trading costs roughly in line with the model’s predictions. Nevertheless, the crucial feature is not the magnitude of a per se but the elasticity of world demand for the SOE’s equity, which can be influenced by factors other than trading costs. The findings of this paper suggest that, if this elasticity is high, it is possible to set up state-contingent price guarantees that reduce the probability of margin calls, undo the Sudden Stop effects of globalization hazard, and make domestic agents better off at Sudden Stop states with negligible effects on foreign traders’ returns in those states, and with trivial implications for the long-run welfare of domestic agents. On the other hand, as the elasticity falls, price guarantees still weaken Sudden Stops but the globalization hazard-moral hazard tradeoff can have negative consequences for domestic welfare.

VI. Conclusions

This paper shows that, in the presence of globalization hazard caused by world capital market frictions, providing ex-ante price guarantees on emerging markets assets can be an effective means to contain Sudden Stops. The same theory predicts, however, that these guarantees create a form of international moral hazard that props up the foreign investors’ demand for emerging markets assets. Hence, ex-ante price guarantees create a tradeoff between the benefits of undoing globalization hazard and the costs of international moral hazard.

The paper borrows from Mendoza and Smith (2006) a dynamic, stochastic equilibrium model of asset prices in which the sources of globalization hazard are collateral constraints and asset trading costs. Collateral constraints are modeled as margin constraints that limit the ability of domestic agents to leverage foreign debt on equity holdings. Asset trading costs are incurred by foreign traders and take the form of per-trade costs and recurrent costs. In this environment, typical realizations of productivity shocks trigger margin calls when the economy’s debt is sufficiently large relative to the value of its equity. Margin calls lead to fire sales of equity and a Fisherian deflation of asset prices. If domestic asset markets are relatively illiquid, the result is a Sudden Stop with reversals in consumption and the current account and a fall in asset prices.

This paper introduced into the Mendoza-Smith model an IFO that offers foreign traders ex-ante guarantees to buy the emerging economy’s assets at preannounced minimum prices. The resulting international moral hazard distortion increases the foreign traders’ demand for the emerging economy’s assets by an amount that depends on the traders’ conditional expected present value of the excess of guaranteed prices over market prices.

The paper’s quantitative analysis, based on a calibration to Mexican data, showed that guaranteed prices set ½ to 1 percent above the fundamentals price in a low productivity state reduce significantly the Sudden Stop effects of globalization hazard, and eliminate the long-run probability of margin calls. If the guarantee is non-state-contingent, however, the IFO trades often (with a long-run probability of executing the guarantee of about 1/3), and there is persistent asset overvaluation above the prices obtained without globalization hazard. The IFO trades much less often, with a long run probability below 1/100, if the same guaranteed price is offered as a state-contingent guarantee that applies only at high debt levels. These state-contingent guarantees are just as effective at containing Sudden Stops and they do not cause persistent asset overvaluation.

The effectiveness of price guarantees to prevent Sudden Stops and increase social welfare hinges on the relative magnitudes of globalization hazard and international moral hazard. The price elasticity of world demand for domestic assets, which in the model depends on the size of per-trade costs, is the key determinant of both. The Fisherian deflation that governs globalization hazard depends on how much prices have to fall for foreign traders’ to accommodate the fire sales of domestic assets. The moral hazard distortion increases foreign demand for domestic assets by an amount proportional to the price elasticity of this demand. With per-trade costs that yield an elasticity of 5, guaranteed prices set ½ to 1 percent above the low-productivity fundamentals price result in domestic welfare gains when the economy hits a Sudden Stop, with negligible changes in long-run welfare. The value of foreign traders’ firms in a Sudden Stop state falls slightly but its long-run average rises sharply. Hence, in this case the benefits of price guarantees to contain globalization hazard outweigh the costs of international moral hazard.

These results are reversed when per-trade costs yield an elasticity of world demand for domestic equity of ½. In this case, globalization hazard causes larger Sudden Stops and higher price guarantees are needed to contain them. However, even with guarantees set at ½ to 1 percent above the low-productivity fundamentals price, which cannot prevent reversals in consumption and the current account, the moral hazard distortion is magnified significantly. Welfare gains for the emerging economy at Sudden Stop states are smaller, and the economy suffers nontrivial welfare losses in the stochastic steady state. In this case, price guarantees yield a short-term improvement in macroeconomic indicators and welfare because they weaken globalization hazard, but international moral hazard outweighs this benefit and causes a long-run welfare loss. This outcome can be altered by increasing guaranteed prices (to fully offset Sudden Stop effects) and by adjusting their state-contingent structure (to weaken the moral hazard distortion) at the same time.

The challenge to the IFO is to design ex-ante price guarantees that can yield better outcomes than those obtained without an instrument to contain Sudden Stops. The findings of our quantitative analysis illustrate the complexity of this task. An effective system of price guarantees requires a “useful” quantitative model of asset prices that can explain the observed features of Sudden Stops, and provide assessments of the effects of the guarantees taking into account how they affect the optimal plans of forward-looking agents. This challenge also applies to ex-post price guarantees. The Lerrick-Meltzer proposal assumes that a “useful” model sets sustainable levels of external debt and the “normal” and crash prices of an emerging economy’s assets. This paper makes some progress towards developing models that can be used for these purposes, but clearly there is a lot left for further research.

References

  • Arellano, C., and E.G. Mendoza, 2003, “Credit Frictions and ‘Sudden Stops’ in Small Open Economies: An Equilibrium Business Cycle Framework for Emerging Markets Crises,” in Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis, ed. by S. Altug, J. Chadha and C. Nolan (Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aiyagari, R.S., and M. Gertler, 1999, “Overreaction of Asset Prices in General Equilibrium,” Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 2, pp. 335.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caballero, R.J., and A. Krishnamurthy, 2001, “International and Domestic Collateral Constraints in a Model of Emerging Market Crises,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 48, pp. 51348.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, G.A., 1998, “Capital Flows and Capital-Market Crises: The Simple Economics of Sudden Stops,” Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. 1, pp. 3554.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, G.A., 2002, “Globalization Hazard and Delayed Reform in Emerging Markets,” Economia, Vol. 2 (Spring), pp. 129.

  • Calvo, G.A., and E.G. Mendoza, 2000a, “Capital-Market Crises and Economics Collapse in Emerging Markets: An Informational-Frictions Approach,” American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, Vol. 90 (May), pp. 5964.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, G.A., and E.G. Mendoza, 2000b, “Rational Contagion and the Globalization of Securities Markets,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 51, pp. 79113.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fisher, I., 1933, “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions,” Econometrica, Vol. 1, pp. 33757.

  • Greenwood, J., Z. Hercowitz, and G.W. Huffman, 1988, “Investment, Capacity Utilization and the Real Business Cycle,” American Economic Review, Vol. 78 (June), pp. 40217.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Izquierdo, A., 2000, “Credit Constraints, and the Asymmetric Behavior of Asset Prices and Output under External Shocks” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kiyotaki, N., and J. Moore, 1997, “Credit Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 105, pp. 21148.

  • Krugman, P., 2000, “Fire-Sale FDI,” in Capital Flows and the Emerging Economies, ed. by Sebastian Edwards (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lerrick, A., and A.H. Meltzer, 2003, “Blueprint for an International Lender of Last Resort,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50, pp. 289303.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ljungqvist, L., 2000Government Guarantees on Assets and Volatility” (unpublished; Stockholm: School of Economics).

  • Mendoza, E.G., 1991, “Capital Controls and the Dynamic Gains from Trade in a Business Cycle Model of a Small Open Economy,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 38 (September), pp. 480505.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, E.G., 2006 “‘Sudden Stops’ in an Equilibrium Business Cycle Model with Credit Constraints: A Fisherian Deflation of Tobin’s Q,” (unpublished; College Park: Department of Economics, University of Maryland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, E.G., and K.A. Smith, 2006, “Quantitative Implications of a Debt-Deflation Theory of Sudden Stops and Asset Prices,” Journal of International Economics, forthcoming.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

Comments and suggestions by Guillermo Calvo, Reuven Glick, Olivier Jeanne, Urban Jermann, Alejandro Izquierdo, Katherine Smith, Linda Tesar, and Diego Valderrama are gratefully acknowledged.

2

Ceyhun Bora Durdu is a doctoral candidate in the Economics Department at the University of Maryland.

3

Part of the literature on Sudden Stops focuses on domestic moral hazard problems caused by government guarantees offered to domestic agents (see, for example, Krugman, 2000). This paper focuses instead on Sudden Stops triggered by globalization hazard, and on the tradeoff between this hazard and the international moral hazard created by offering price guarantees to global investors.

4

These two frictions are modeled following the closed-economy analysis of Aiyagari and Gertler (1999).

5

See Arellano and Mendoza (2003) for further details on this issue.

6

With θ=0 and no price guarantees, equation (15) implies that foreign traders attain a stationary equity position when the equity price equals the fundamentals price, and the latter implies a stationary asset return equal to R. Thus, at this steady state foreign traders hold equity at zero equity premium.

7

Note that incomplete asset markets and the risk-averse nature of domestic agents imply that equilibrium prices in the NFE differ from the fundamentals price that discounts dividends at the risk-free rate.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Are Asset Price Guarantees Useful for Preventing Sudden Stops?A Quantitative Investigation of the Globalization Hazard-Moral Hazard Tradeoff
Author:
Mr. Enrique G. Mendoza
and
Ceyhun Bora Durdu
  • Figure 1.

    Equilibrium in the Asset Market

  • Figure 2.

    Ergodic Distributions of Domestic Equity and Bond Holdings

  • Figure 3.

    Consumption & Current Account-GDP Ratio Impact Effects of a Negative Productivity Shock in the Sudden Stop Region of Equity & Bonds

  • Figure 4.

    Conditional Responses to a Negative, One-Standard-Deviation Productivity Shock

  • Figure 5.

    Equity Pricing Function in the Low Productivity State