Inequality, Poverty, and Growth: Cross-Country Evidence

Contributor Notes

Author(s) E-Mail Address: giradian@imf.org

This paper examines the empirical relationship between inequality and growth, and analyzes the impacts of growth, inequality, and government spending on poverty reduction. A new panel dataset has been assembled on inequality and poverty that reduces measurement error and ensures comparability across countries and over time. The empirical results in this paper challenge the belief that income inequality has a negative effect on growth and confirm the validity of the Kuznets curve. Credit market imperfections in low- and medium-income countries are identified as the likely reason for the positive link between inequality and growth over the short-to-medium term. In the long term, inequality may have an adverse impact on growth.

Abstract

This paper examines the empirical relationship between inequality and growth, and analyzes the impacts of growth, inequality, and government spending on poverty reduction. A new panel dataset has been assembled on inequality and poverty that reduces measurement error and ensures comparability across countries and over time. The empirical results in this paper challenge the belief that income inequality has a negative effect on growth and confirm the validity of the Kuznets curve. Credit market imperfections in low- and medium-income countries are identified as the likely reason for the positive link between inequality and growth over the short-to-medium term. In the long term, inequality may have an adverse impact on growth.

I. Introduction

Poverty alleviation and equity considerations are playing an increasingly important role in the work of the International Monetary Fund (IMF). This is because it is socially unacceptable to have poverty in the midst of prosperity and because equitable adjustment programs are more likely to be sustainable.2 In this regard, efforts are being made to increase the use of poverty and social-impact analysis techniques for the assessment of the impact of policy reforms on income distribution. These reforms are supported in the programs of the IMF, notably under the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF).

This paper analyzes the impact of income inequality on growth, in addition to testing the validity of the Kuznets curve, according to which income inequality rises with per capita income to a certain level and declines thereafter. It also examines the relationship among economic growth, income distribution, government spending, and poverty reduction. The paper attempts to respond to the following questions:

  • Is inequality harmful for growth?

  • Is inequality related to the level of per capita income (Kuznets curve)?

  • How responsive is poverty to economic growth and changes in inequality?

  • Would an increase in government expenditures reduce the incidence of poverty and improve the income distribution?

  • What is the minimum annual per capita real GDP growth needed for sub-Saharan African countries to reach their respective poverty targets, under the Millennium Development Goals, by 2015?

I use a new dataset on inequality and poverty. With that, I apply appropriate econometric techniques which address the potential biases induced by simultaneity, omitted variables, and unobserved country-specific effects—all of which have plagued previous empirical work on the links among growth, inequality, and poverty. A panel dataset for 82 countries for the period 1965–2003 has been assembled with the data averaged over periods of three to seven years, depending on the availability of inequality and poverty data. The minimum number of observations for each country is three and the maximum, seven. That is, only countries with observations for at least three consecutive periods are included. In the dataset, two household surveys for one country define what is called an interval of three to seven years in length. The entire sample includes 380 observations and 290 intervals.

Poverty in this paper is measured using the World Bank’s definition, that is, the percentage of the population living on less than $1 a day at 1993 prices, adjusted for purchasing power parity. For a few developing countries, the national household surveys’ definition of poverty is used. As to the measure of income distribution, I use the Gini coefficient, which is one of the most popular representations of income inequality. It is based on the Lorenz curve, which plots the share of population against the share of income received and has a minimum value of 0 (reflecting perfect equality) and a maximum value of 1 (reflecting total inequality).

The paper is structured as follows. Section II reviews analytical arguments and the related literature regarding the relationship among growth, inequality, poverty, and government spending. Section III presents data issues and suggests using more consistent data to reduce measurement error. Section IV analyzes and evaluates the panel regression results. Section V discusses the feasibility of the Millennium Development Goals of poverty reduction in light of the estimated growth elasticity of poverty. Section VI summarizes the empirical results. Appendix I describes the empirical methodology, and Appendix II reports the complete dataset used in this paper.

The empirical results in this paper challenge the belief that income inequality has a negative effect on growth and confirm the validity of the Kuznets curve. The paper identifies credit market imperfections in low- and medium-income countries as the likely reason for the positive link between inequality and growth over the short-to-medium term. The results also find evidence that higher government spending has a statistically significant impact on reducing inequality and poverty. Data quality, period length, and estimation technique may explain why the results in this paper are different from previous studies.

II. Theory and Evidence

Is income inequality harmful for growth? What are the factors which explain the differences in inequality across countries? Do higher government expenditures reduce inequality? To answer these questions, this section examines the related theory and the available cross-country evidence.

A. Impact of Inequality on Growth

There is as yet no consensus throughout the economics profession on the relationship between income inequality and growth. Early thinking on the effects of inequality on growth suggested that greater inequality might be good for growth, for example by redistributing income to the rich, who save, from the poor, who do not. This view implied a trade-off where more growth could be bought for the price of more inequality, with ambiguous effects on poor people. Figure 1 presents three different approaches of the channels through which income inequality affects growth:

  • ▪ The classical approach (Kaldor, 1957 and Bourguignon, 1981) suggests that the marginal propensity to save of the rich is higher than that of the poor, implying that a higher degree of initial inequality will yield higher aggregate savings, capital accumulation, and growth.

  • ▪ In contrast, the modern approaches emphasize the main four channels through which income inequality lowers growth: (a) the impact of inequality on encouraging rent-seeking activities that reduce the security of property rights; (b) unequal societies are more prone to difficulties in collective action—possibly reflected in political instability, a propensity for populist redistributive policies, or greater volatility in policies—all of which can lower growth; (c) the median voter in a more unequal society is relatively poorer and favors a higher (and thus more inefficient) tax burden; and (d) to the extent that inequality in income or assets coexists with imperfect credit markets, poorer people may be unable to invest in their human and physical capital, with adverse consequences for long-run growth.

  • Galor’s (2000) “unified model” provides an intertemporal reconciliation for the above two conflicting approaches (Box 1). He argues that the classical approach holds at low income levels but not at later stages of development. In the early stage of development, inequality would promote growth because physical capital is scarce at this stage and its accumulation requires saving. Inequality in income would then result in higher savings and rapid growth. In later stages of economic development, however, as the return to human capital increases owing to capital-skill complementarity, human capital becomes the main engine of growth. Credit constraints, however, become less binding as wages increase, and the adverse effect of income inequality on human capital accumulation subsides, and thus the effect of inequality on the growth process becomes insignificant.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Channels Through Which Inequality Can Affect Growth

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2005, 028; 10.5089/9781451860474.001.A001

The Unified Model

The unified approach complements the research of Galor and Weil (1999, 2000) who developed unified models that encompasses the transition between three distinct regimes that have characterized the process of economic development: the Malthusian Regime, the Post-Malthusian Regime, and the Modern Growth Regime, focusing on the historical evolution of the relationship between population growth, technological change, and economic growth.

Galor and Moav (1999) argue that inequality has a positive effect on capital accumulation but negative effect on human capital accumulation in the presence of credit constraints. In the early stages of development physical capital is scarce, the rate of return to human capital is lower than the return on physical capital and the process of further development is driven mainly by capital accumulation.

In the early stages of development, the positive effect of inequality on aggregate saving more than offsets the negative effect on investment in human capital and, since the marginal propensity to save is an increasing function of the individual’s wealth, inequality increases aggregate savings and capital accumulation, enhancing the process of development. In the later stages of development, however, the positive effect of inequality on saving is offset by the negative effect on investment in human capital.

There is empirical evidence that growth depends on human capital, economic policies—such as openness to international trade, sound monetary and fiscal policies (reflected in small budget deficits and the absence of high inflation)—and a well-developed financial system. Other factors, such as geography, initial incomes and level of corruption, matter as well. Strong evidence suggests that growth is higher in countries with lower initial per capita income and in countries that have experienced a sharp fall in output (such as the transition economies in the early 1990s).3

In the past few years, inequality has been added as an additional independent variable to such cross-country growth regressions. But the literature has found mixed results using different samples and different econometric techniques. On the one hand, Alesina and Rodrik (1994), Clarke (1995), Perotti (1996), and Panizza (2002) found support for a negative impact of inequality on growth using cross-country growth regressions. Meantime, Deininger and Squire (1998) questioned the robustness and the validity of the negative association between inequality and growth.

On the other hand, Forbes (2000) found positive effects of income inequality on growth. She argued that country-specific effects and omitted variables are the cause of a significant negative bias in the estimations of the effects of inequality on growth. She also concluded that fixed-effect estimations yield the consistent result of a positive short- and medium-term correlation between inequality and growth. Smith (2001), examined empirically two hypotheses—subsistence consumption and credit market imperfections—of specific channels for inequality to affect private saving rates. He found that there is econometric evidence that especially at low per capita income levels, income inequality may be associated with higher aggregate savings.

B. Kuznets’s Law

Kuznets (1955) argued that the income distribution within a country was likely to vary over time with its progress from a poor agricultural society to a rich industrial society. The average per capita income of the rural population is usually lower than that of the urban population, whereas income distribution within the urban population is more unequal. In the urban population, savings are concentrated in the upper-income groups and the cumulative effects of such savings would be the concentration of an increasing proportion of income yielding assets in the upper-income groups. Thus, as the weight of the urban sector in the economy increases with industrialization, the country’s overall income distribution will tend to deteriorate until such time as the urban sector dominates. Thereafter, the income distribution will tend to stabilize because of three factors: (i) the slower growth in the population of the wealthier classes; (ii) the exploitation of the opportunities for wealth-creation offered by technology undertaken by those whose assets are not in established industries; and (iii) the shift of workers away from lower-income to higher-income industries.

The literature in the 1960 and 1970s in general supported the hypothesis that income inequality is related to the level of per capita income (see especially Ahluwalia 1976). According to Kuznets’ law, the relationship between income inequality and per capita income may be described by a curve in the shape of an inverted U, with an upward phase in which income inequality increases with rising per capita income, and a downward phase in which inequality declines with increases in per capita income. Some of the recent literature, however, challenged this hypothesis and several empirical studies found no significant relationship between inequality and per capita income, see Anand and Kanbur (1992). Li, Squire, and Zou (1998) argue that the Kuznets curve works better for a cross section of countries at a point in time than for the evolution of inequality over the time within countries.

During the past three decades, diverse patterns have emerged with respect to income distribution. On balance, Table 1 shows that more countries have experienced some worsening in inequality (see Appendix II for the full data set). Most South and East Asian economies grew at high per capita rates since the early 1970s while maintaining moderate levels of inequality, although increasing over time, in particular in China. In contrast, Latin American countries grew by less than half of the average growth rate in South and East Asia while maintaining high inequality. The differences in inequality at a given rate of growth could reflect a different combination of policies and institutions across countries and that these differences in policies matter for income distribution.4

Table 1.

Inequality and Growth in Selected Countries

article image
Sources: Derived from World Bank, OECD, and IMF reports and databases.

I denotes household surveys based on per capita income, and E, household surveys based on consumption.

C. Growth, Inequality, Government Spending, and Poverty

The positive relationship between economic growth and poverty reduction is clear. However, there are significant differences across countries and over time in how much poverty reduction occurs at a given rate of economic growth. The extent of poverty reduction depends on how the distribution of income changes with growth and on initial inequalities in income and the sources or quality of growth. In theory at least, if income inequality increases, it is possible for a country to enjoy positive economic growth without significant benefit to its poorest segment of population—the rich get richer while the incomes of the poor stagnate. Therefore, establishing the relationship between economic growth and income distribution is critical for poverty reduction.

Fiscal policy is important both for reducing poverty and for improving social indicators through government expenditures programs. But increasing total government expenditures is not always the answer to improving the well-being of the poor. The composition of expenditures greatly influences the nature and outcome of government spending. Several developing countries were able to maintain social spending or even increase it as a share of GDP while total government expenditures were reduced. Chile, for example, managed to protect services to the poor during its fiscal adjustment in the 1980s and 1990s. Despite lower public spending on goods and services overall, basic health and child nutrition programs targeted to the poor expanded. This helped to sustain a continued improvement in social conditions in the 1980s and 1990s.5

Larger public spending on the social sectors (education, health, and housing) and on infrastructure is necessary to alleviate poverty and promote human development. The markets for education and health services are imperfect and governments in many countries have no other choice but to intervene on grounds of equity and efficiency. The link between social spending and income distribution is particularly strong, and public investment in human capital can be an efficient way to reduce income inequality over the long run. Investment in infrastructure could also be considered as poverty-reducing public expenditure. For example, building a road that eases access to a market for rural farmers enhances their income.

However, a larger government (as measured by the ratio of public expenditure to GDP) is also likely to harm growth prospects.6 This is particularly the case if the government maintains ineffective public programs and a bloated bureaucracy. In a retrenchment of the public sector, programs that benefit the poor might be cut. Also, if public employment plays a safety net role, then retrenchment may lead to increasing income inequality.

III. Data Issues

Data quality and measurement errors are major concerns in cross-country studies, particularly in the case of inequality and poverty data. In this paper, a concerted effort has been made to ensure that the statistics are comparable across countries and over time, using similar definitions of variables for each country and year. However, perfect comparability is not attainable, since the coverage of and questionnaires used in household surveys differ among countries and frequently also within countries over time. Whenever a trade-off arises, I decided to preserve comparability within a country over time rather than across countries.

While the quality of the World Bank data on poverty and inequality has recently improved, it is still far from being problem free. The data available at http://www.worldbank.org/research/povmonitor/ includes a data set on poverty and inequality for about 60 developing and transition countries. However, many of these countries had only one or two observations of three or more years apart. I have, therefore, expanded the existing data set by including comparable data on poverty and inequality from recent household surveys included in IMF staff reports and in Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers (PRSPs). I have also added to the sample data on inequality for the Organization for Economic Development (OECD) countries. All regions are well represented in the whole sample (16 countries from Latin America, 12 from sub-Saharan Africa, 12 from South and East Asia, 11 from the former Soviet Union, 6 from Central and Eastern Europe, 8 from the Middle East and North Africa, and 17 OECD countries)

The data set refers to an unbalanced panel of 82 countries observed from 1965 to 2003 (unequal country sizes or data are not available for all countries in the same period). The use of panel data allows us to control for time-specific effects, as well as country-specific effects. Also, the likely endogeneity of some explanatory variables can be accounted for using previous observations of the variables in the panel as instruments. The constraining factor is the scarcity of inequality and poverty data over time for many countries. Those included in the regressions have at least three observations. In the data set, two household surveys for one country define what is called an interval. In constructing the intervals the following criteria were used: intervals must be three or more years in length. They come from nationally representative surveys, and use either expenditures or income per person over time.

Data on poverty and inequality may not be comparable across countries as a result of differences in definitions and methodologies. There are some problems in comparing household surveys across countries. Different countries have different definitions of poverty, and consistent comparisons between countries based on the same definition can be difficult to obtain. The most widely used poverty indicator for developing and transition economies is the one used by the World Bank: the percent of the population living below $1 a day of consumption or income at 1993 prices, adjusted for purchasing power parity (PPP).

National household surveys are often the source for constructing consumption or income distributions and estimating poverty. But their design is not standardized across countries and over time, leading to significantly different estimates of average consumption or personal income. Some surveys only obtain information on income of households and others only on consumption. For developing and transition countries, slightly more than half of the observations are based on expenditures, and the remaining on income. Also, the Gini coefficient for some OECD countries is based on individual rather than households incomes. Household surveys based on expenditure data are usually regarded as more accurate than income data because they are likely to have fewer errors of underreporting. Also, data on expenditures yield a lower estimate of inequality than that based on income data, as a result of the higher saving rates of upper-income classes, the size of the informal economy, and private transfers.7 While there are significant methodological differences across surveys in different countries, these differences are likely to be less important in surveys conducted in a particular country across time. Although there is no perfect solution for this problem, using only one type of survey for each country and restricting cross-country comparisons to changes (as opposed to levels) of poverty and inequality, should go a long way toward addressing these problems.

IV. Econometric Results

A. Growth and Inequality

This section presents the panel regression results on the relationship between inequality and growth. Previous studies utilized Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) to estimate the cross-country growth regression. The resulting estimates of a negative coefficient on inequality suggested that countries with a more equal income distribution (that is a lower Gini index) tend to have higher levels of income. Due to the limited availability of comparable inequality statistics, sample selection is always a problem in estimates of the relationship between inequality and growth. This problem is magnified by using inappropriate econometric techniques of panel data. This paper specifically addresses these problems by using the fixed effect and the Generalized Method-of-Moments (GMM) econometric estimation techniques for panel data (for a brief description of these techniques see Appendix I).

Credit market imperfections could be a reason why inequality may increase growth. Galdor and Zeira (1993) have argued that when individuals cannot borrow against future income, the initial income inequality level affects physical and human capital accumulation and growth. Their models suggest that the poor are likely to be most affected by credit market imperfections.

One way to econometrically evaluate this hypothesis is to include the inequality variable and measures of credit market imperfections in a standard growth equation. Following King and Levine (1993), two variables from International Financial Statistics (IFS) were used to proxy financial market development and credit market imperfections. The first is the share of broad money (M2) in GDP, and the second is the share of credit to the economy in GDP. The specification estimated in Table 2 is as follows:

GRit=α1t+β1GINIit1+β2LogYit1+β3INVit+β4INFit t+β5GINIit1*HFI+β6HFI+μi+νt+εit(1)
Table 2.

Growth, Income Inequality, and Credit Market Imperfections

article image
Source: Authors’ own calculations.Notes: Dependent variable: average annual per capita growth rate between two survey years of 3 to 6 years apart. See Appendix II for full set of data and definitions of variables. T-statistics in parenthesis are heteroskedasticity corrected.

Short- to medium-term effect. Each observation is derived from household surveys of 3 to 7 years in length.

Each observation is derived from household surveys of 10-15 years in length.

Algeria, Argentina, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Brazil, Bulgaria, Cameroon, China, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Rep., Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Estonia, Ethiopia, Georgia, Ghana, Honduras, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Iran, Jamaica, Ivory Coast, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Rep., Latvia, Lesotho, Lithuania, Mali, Mauritania, Mexico, Morocco, Nepal, Nigeria, Pakistan, Paraguay, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Romania, Russia, Senegal, Sri Lanka, Tajikistan, Turkey, Uganda, Venezuela, Vietnam, and Zambia.

Austria, Belgium, Canada, Chile, China, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Jordan, South Korea, Malaysia, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Panama, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Thailand, Tunisia, the United Kingdom, Uruguay, and the United States.

HFI is a dummy variable to indicate countries with relatively high financial intermediation level. The shares of credit to the private sector and broad money in GDP are used as proxies to determine the level of financial intermediation.

where GR is the average growth rate of per capita GDP at 1993 prices and PPP adjusted; GINIit-1 is the Gini index in the previous period; LogYit-1 is the natural logarithm at the beginning of the period of per capita GDP in dollars at 1993 prices and PPP adjusted; INVit is the share of gross capital formation in GDP; INFit is the average CPI inflation rate; HFI is a dummy variable equal to one for countries with a high level of financial intermediation, that is, above the sample median (as measured by the share of M2 and credit to the private sector in GDP); i =1, 2, …, n cross-sectional units (in this case, countries); µi is a country-specific unobservable effect, νt is a time-specific factor; and εit is the disturbance term.

Table 2 shows the panel regression estimates for the determinants of per capita real GDP growth. As to the impact of other explanatory variables (excluding inequality and financial intermediation level) on growth the main findings of the panel regressions are as follows:

  • ▪ There is a negative and significant correlation between growth and initial income per capita expressed in U.S. dollars. A poor country, other things being equal, tends to grow faster than a rich country.

  • ▪ There is a strong association between investment shares and GDP growth.

  • ▪ Macroeconomic instability (as measured by inflation) is negatively correlated with growth. The links appear to operate through a dampening of both investment and productivity.

The positive relationship between inequality and growth challenges previous empirical results. The estimated coefficients on inequality (GINIit-1) are positive in columns (1) to (4) (which test the short to medium-term effect of inequality on growth). Columns (3) and (4) in Table 2 split the full sample by low and high financial intermediation levels. The effect of inequality on growth differs between low and high financial intermediation sub-samples.

It is expected that β1>0, β5<0, and β6> meaning that the positive effect of inequality on growth is weaker in countries with high financial intermediation levels (or developed financial markets). The interaction term, GINIit-1* HFI, is strongly negative in column (1). Despite the relatively low t-statistics, an F-test shows that GINIit-1* HFI and the dummy variable HFI are jointly highly significant. Also the coefficient for HFI (β6) is positive and highly significant as expected. The insignificance of the inequality coefficient in column (4) is consistent with the argument that inequality has no explanatory power in countries with developed financial markets.

The long-term relationship between inequality and growth, however, is different than the short to medium-term relationship as shown in columns (5) and (6). Here the data are constructed as 10–20 year averages, and the estimated inequality coefficients are negative and statistically significant at the 10 percent level of confidence.

In conclusion, credit market imperfections may be a source of the positive link between inequality and growth. The results show that inequality stimulates growth in the short- to medium-term in countries with low levels of financial market development and credit available to the private sector. Over the long-term, however, inequality may have an adverse impact on growth.

B. Determinants of Income Inequality

Subsequently, I consider the factors influencing the variation of income inequality between countries and over time. In this paper, an effort has been made to compile an improved set of inequality statistics not only to reduce measurement error, but also to utilize panel estimation to control for time-invariant omitted variables.

Figure 2 shows a scatter of the inequality values against values of the log of per capita real GDP. A Kuznets’ curve would appear as an inverted-U relationship between the Gini value and log of GDP per capita (a proxy measure of economic development). The framework does not include country fixed effects, which would eliminate the cross-sectional information in the data. While the results should reflect both cross-sectional differences among countries as well as variations over time within countries, the main information comes from the cross-sectional dimension due to the fact that few observations are used for each country.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Inequality Versus Per Capita Income

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2005, 028; 10.5089/9781451860474.001.A001

Table 3 shows the panel regression results of the following equation:

Log GINIit=β1LogYit+β2Log2Yit+β3Log EXPit+β4Log EDUC+β5POPGR+RegionalDummies+Dummy for Income based Inequality+μi+νt+εit,(2)
Table 3.

Determinants of Inequality

article image
Source: Authors’ own calculations.Notes: T-statistics in parenthesis. Estimation is by fixed effects.

The first dummy variable equals one if the country is in sub-Saharan Africa and zero otherwise.

The second dummy variable equals one if the country is in Latin America and zero otherwise.

The third dummy variable equals one for transition economies or socialist countries prior to 1994, that is, before significant progress was made to move to a market economy.

The fourth dummy equals one if the Gini index is based on income rather than consumption.

where Log GINIit is the natural logarithm of the Gini index8; LogYit is the natural logarithm of income per capita and Log2Yit is included in equation (2) to test the hypothesis of a nonlinear conditional convergence; Log (EXP) is the natural logarithm of government expenditures in GDP (proxy for government expenditures on social sectors); EDUC is the secondary school enrolment rate (in percent of the total secondary school-aged population); POPGR is the percent change in population; i =1, 2, …, n cross-sectional units (here countries); µi is a country specific unobservable effect, νt is a time specific factor; and εit is the disturbance term. The following dummies are used:

D1: a dummy variable equal to one if the country is in Sub-Saharan Africa;

D2: a dummy variable equal to one if the country is in Latin America;

D3: a dummy variable equal to one if the country is in East Europe or the former Soviet Union for the period prior to 1995; and

D4: a dummy variable equal to one for the income-based measure of the Gini index.

The panel regression results presented in Table 3 show clear evidence of a non-monotonic relationship between inequality and the level of development as measured by per capita income. The estimated coefficients of LogYit and Log2Yit reported are highly significant and of the expected sign, implying a quadratic relationship between income per capita and inequality (Kuznets’ curve). The estimated coefficient is about 1 on the linear term and -0.15 on the squared term. The estimated coefficients were also found to be stable over time. The Gini coefficient value rises with per capita GDP to a certain level (estimated at about 4,000 in PPP dollars of 1993 prices) and declines thereafter. However, per capita income explains only about 20 percent of the variations in inequality across countries or over time (first column of Table 3).

These results are consistent with the findings in section A on the relationship between inequality and growth. They may have important implications for policies relating to income distribution in poor developing countries. Thus, if during a given period income inequality shows a tendency to increase modestly, than according to Kuznets’ law (which is confirmed in this paper) income inequality would have to be treated as an inevitable consequence of an increase of per capita incomes in the early stages of growth. It could then be argued that it is only in subsequent stages of their growth that there would be a “trickle down” of the effects of growth and a reduction of income inequalities.

There are other factors that also explain differences in inequality across countries. These may include the following: (i) school enrollment ratio; (ii) share of agriculture in GDP; (iii) real growth rate in agriculture; (iv) population growth; (v) governance; and (vi) other social and structural factors particular to countries or regions. However, historical data on governance and growth in agriculture is not available for most developing countries. Columns two and three of Table 3 include secondary school enrollment ratio, government spending as percent of GDP, and population growth in addition to per capita income.

Governments may be inefficient (more government means less growth) but appear to be benevolent since more government spending may reduce inequality. The estimated coefficient for the government size or government expenditures in terms of GDP has the right sign and is highly significant. Higher targeted government spending can be expected to improve the income distribution to the extent that rent seeking by privileged groups is avoided and government bureaucracies concentrate on enhancing the possibilities of the poor. While cutting the size of the government is likely to lead to faster growth,9 it could increase inequality.

The coefficient on the secondary school enrollment ratio (a proxy for human capital) was found to be negative and highly significant. This implies that improvement in education could reduce inequality. In contrast, high population growth would increase inequality.

Subsequently, I re-estimated the model using regional dummies. The estimated coefficients of the dummy variables for Latin America10 and sub-Saharan Africa are each positive and statistically highly significant. The results show that Latin America and the sub-Saharan region are 14 and 8 points, respectively, more unequal than the average for all countries. The dummy variable for transition countries is also significant but of negative sign as expected. The dummy variable for inequality based on income (D4) is also highly significant with a negative sign as expected. The estimated coefficient for D4 implies that inequality based on income is on average about four percentage points higher than inequality based on expenditures for the whole sample.

C. Role of Growth, Equity, and Government Expenditures in Reducing Poverty

Poverty is a multidimensional phenomenon, encompassing both monetary and non-monetary aspects. A common component of all poverty measurement and analysis is the setting of a poverty threshold, or a poverty line. People with welfare levels below the line are defined to be poor, and those above are not poor. Despite the limitations of such an approach, poverty measures of these sorts are useful in that they: (i) serve a monitoring role on the evolution of living standards, and (ii) can be an important means of focusing policy attention and public debates on the deprived groups.

The choice of the definition of poverty depends on the purpose of the analysis or the policy objective. There is no universally accepted concept of poverty that can be applied to every conceivable situation in every country. The one dollar-per-day poverty line, which is adopted in this paper, is the most widely used benchmark for developing and transition economies with a low per capita income.11

Rapid and sustainable economic growth is generally viewed as the primary vehicle for poverty reduction. The basic proposition is that if the economies of low-income countries grow rapidly enough and their income distributions are not unusually skewed against the poor, poverty reduction should occur. The experience of several countries has shown that poverty can increase not only because of a fall in output, but also because of increased inequality in the distribution of income. One important reason why inequality hinders poverty reduction is that the higher the level of inequality, the smaller are the absolute gains of the poor as the economy grows.

There is a significant difference across countries and over time in how much poverty reduction occurs at a given rate of economic growth. A key magnitude in assessing the impact of growth on poverty is the elasticity of poverty with respect to per capita real GDP growth. The correlation between per capita income and poverty incidence suggests some general tendencies related to income and poverty levels. First, lower poverty levels are associated with higher per capita income. Second, the incidence of poverty varies widely among countries with similar annual per capita incomes. The variation in poverty among countries with similar economic growth rates reflects the degree of income inequality of the countries. Also, as discussed earlier, in a retrenchment of the public sector, programs that benefit the poor might be cut. Larger government spending on social sectors (education, health, housing) and on infrastructure is necessary to alleviate poverty and to promote human development.

To capture the impact of growth, change in inequality, and government expenditure on poverty, the following equation is estimated:

ΔPit=αi+β1GRit+β2ΔGINIit+β3ΔEXPit+β4GINIit1+μi+νt+εit(3)

where ΔPit is the headcount change in poverty of the total population (in percentage points) for country i between two household survey years; GRit is the per capita real GDP growth rate for country i between two survey years; ΔGINIit is the change in inequality (in percentage points) between two survey years; ΔEXPit is the change in government expenditures as percent of GDP for country i between two household survey years (a proxy for government expenditure on social sectors and infrastructure in the absence of such data for many developing and transition economies); and GINIMit-1 is the initial inequality level. Ideally, social spending should be used instead of total government expenditures. However, reliable and comparable breakdowns of government spending in many developing countries are not readily available. For this reason, equation (3) uses the change in total government expenditures as percent of GDP as a proxy for the change in social spending

The results of the panel regressions are reported in Table 4. The regression coefficients of growth in per capita GDP and change in inequality are statistically significant with the right signs. The estimated β1 coefficient shows how much poverty could be reduced in percentage points for a given growth in real GDP per capita. The coefficient for the change in the Gini index or income distribution (β2) is positive as expected and is also highly significant (robust). This finding suggests a positive and significant association between changes in inequality and the change in the level of poverty within a country. Growth will reduce poverty more if it is accompanied by a decrease in inequality, while poverty reduction will be tempered if growth is accompanied by an increase in inequality.

Table 4.

Poverty, Growth, Inequality, and Government Size 1/

article image
Sources: Authors’ own calculations.Notes: t-statistics in parenthesis. All estimated coefficients are significant at the 1% level.

Dependent variable is the poverty change in percentage points between two survey years.

2/ Developing and transition countries with per capita income of less than $3,000 calculated at PPP.

The regression results in Table 4 also show that the estimated coefficient for government expenditures (β3) is highly significant (robust) and has the expected negative sign. Controlling for the per capita GDP growth and income distribution level, an increase in government expenditures (particularly on social sectors and infrastructure) can be expected to reduce poverty. One percentage point reduction in government expenditures to GDP ratio would increase poverty by 0.7 percentage points.

It is likely that poverty increases if the adverse impact of an increase in inequality more than offsets the reduction in poverty associated with growth. The regression results show that the extent of poverty reduction also depends on the initial inequality level and not only on the change in inequality. That is, for the same growth in per capita income, poverty will be reduced more in countries with low initial equality than in countries with high initial inequality. Other things being equal, growth leads to less poverty reduction in unequal societies than in egalitarian ones.

Higher growth is associated with a lower poverty rate, but the response of poverty reduction to growth varies among regions. The estimated β1 coefficients by region could be used to calculate the elasticity for different regions, by dividing by their respective mean values of poverty rates. Such elasticity estimates generally measure the percentage change in the share of the population living below the poverty line following an increase of 1 percent in the average income or private consumption per capita of the population as a whole.

The calculated elasticity varies substantially, depending on the particular sample of countries chosen (Table 5). Transition countries, as a region, have the highest poverty elasticity of growth. A 10 percent decline in real per capita growth would lead to a 14 percent increase in poverty incidence. Such a sharp increase in the poverty rate in response to economic contraction suggests that the collapse of the centrally planned economic system in the early 1990s has affected the welfare of the population, not only through economic decline, but also through the deterioration of social conditions because of reductions in social expenditures by governments. For sub-Saharan Africa, the estimated elasticity of poverty reduction with respect to economic growth is -0.79 and the calculated inequality elasticity of poverty is 1.20. In general, if growth has a weak effect on poverty, it could be due to high inequality or a worsening income distribution, and thus poverty reduction policies should also focus on measures that could reduce inequality.

Table 5.

Estimated Growth and Inequality Elasticities of Poverty, by Region

article image
Source: Author’s own calculations.

As measured by the secondary school enrollement rate.

The World Bank studies (including Ravallion, 1997) show much higher growth elasticity of poverty (-1.68) and inequality elasticity of poverty (1.90).

Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Rep., Ecuador, El Salvador, Honduras, Jamaica, Mexico, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela.

Cameroon, Côte d’Ivoire, Ethiopia, Ghana, Lesotho, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritania, Nigeria, Senegal, Uganda, Zambia.

Algeria, Egypt, Pakistan, Iran, Jordan, Morocco, Tunisia, and Turkey. This group of countries have relatively low incidence of poverty (except for Pakistan) and income inequality as compared with other countries of similar per capita income due to the substantial remittances and the large size of the public sector in the economy. International migration to the Persian Gulf and Europe and the large public sector employment has helped boost the income of the poor in several Middle Eastern and North African countries (Adams and Page, 2003).

Bangladesh, China, India, Indonesia, Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Nepal, Pakistan, Philippines, Sri Lanka, Thailand, and Vietnam.

Armenia, Azerbaijan, Bulgaria, Georgia, Hungary, Kazakistan, Kyrgyz Republic, Romania, Tajikistan, Russia, and Ukraine.

V. The Millennium Development Goals of Poverty Reduction

The results in the previous section contribute to our knowledge of the relative importance of growth and equity in reducing poverty. The estimated growth and inequality elasticities of poverty could be used to determine the minimum economic growth required to achieve the Millennium Development goal of poverty reduction. The United Nations Millennium Declaration (General Assembly Resolution 55/2 of September 2000) endorsed the commitment to halve the proportion of people living in extreme poverty between 1990 and 2015. The poverty line in this case is based on one dollar per day in purchasing power parity.

Table 6 shows that poverty has declined significantly on a global level over the past two decades. However, most of this improvement was due to the sharp reduction in poverty in China and India, where the largest share of the world’s poor people live. The poverty rate in east Asia and the Pacific in 20 years dropped from about 58 percent of the population in 1981 to 15 percent in 2001, mainly because of the dramatic poverty reduction in China. In contrast, poverty rates in sub-Saharan Africa have increased, in the same period moving from 42 percent of the population in 1981 to 47 percent in 2001. The explanation for this is mainly the stagnant annual per capita growth in sub-Saharan Africa over the past two decades. The decline in poverty in recent years in several Asian economies was due to both improved income distribution and sustained rapid growth.

Table 6.

Poverty and Growth Across the Globe

article image
Source: Poverty figures extracted from http://www.worldbank.org/research/povmonitor/ on August 4, 2004, except for the Middle East and North Africa, which is derived from the data reported in Appendix II. Per capita annual growth figures are derived from the IMF WEO database. Note: PPP denotes purchasing power parity.

China, Indonesia, the Republic of Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam.

Bangladesh, India, Nepal, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka.

Benin, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Côte d’Ivoire, Ethiopia, the Gambia, Ghana, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritania, Niger, Nigeria, Senegal, Tanzania, Uganda, Zambia, and Zimbabwe.

Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela.

Algeria, Egypt, Iran, Jordan, Morocco, Tunisia, and Turkey.

A variation between countries has arisen to the extent to which poverty responds to growth. Initial inequality and per capita income are important factors. In this paper, the estimated growth elasticity of poverty is -1.08 and the inequality elasticity of poverty is 1.40 for the whole sample. The World Bank studies (including Ravallion, 1997) show much higher growth elasticity of poverty (-1.68) and inequality elasticity of poverty (1.90).

Based on the estimated growth elasticity of poverty in this paper, the per capita real GDP in sub-Saharan African countries needs to grow by at least 4.5 percent a year to reduce poverty from 47 percent in 2001 to 22 percent by 2015 (Table 7). Given an average population growth of at least 2 percent, this implies that the minimum needed economic growth should be about 6.5 percent a year. If we assume that inequality, as measured by the Gini index, improves by half a percentage point every year (that is average inequality in sub-Saharan Africa declines gradually from about 0.48 in 2001 to 0.40 in 2015) then real GDP needs to grow by 5.5 percent a year.

Table 7.

Projection of Poverty in Sub-Saharan Africa

(In percent of the population)

article image
Source: Authors’ own calculations using estimated growth and inequality elasticities of poverty.

VI. Conclusion

The empirical results in this paper challenge the current belief that income inequality has a negative effect on economic growth. The panel regression results suggest that in the short-to-medium term, an increase in a country’s level of income inequality may have a positive relationship with subsequent economic growth. Credit market imperfections may be a source of the positive link between inequality and growth. In the long term, however, inequality would have an adverse impact on growth.

The results in this paper also confirm the validity of the Kuznets curve, according to which income inequality first increases and later decreases during the process of economic development. Inequality rises with per capita income to a certain level, estimated at about 4,000 in PPP dollars and 1993 prices, and declines thereafter. However, per capita income explains only about 20 percent of the variations in inequality across countries or over time.

Higher growth in per capita income is associated with higher rates of poverty reduction. The variation in poverty with similar economic growth rates reflects the degree of income inequality of countries. Poverty would increase if the adverse impact of an increase in inequality more than offsets the reduction in poverty associated with growth. For the same growth in per capita income, poverty will be reduced more in countries with low initial equality than in countries with high initial inequality. Other things being equal, growth leads to less poverty reduction in unequal societies than in egalitarian ones.

Sub-Saharan African countries will need to grow by at least 6.5 percent a year to reduce poverty from 47 percent of the population in 2001 to 22 percent by 2015 (assuming that the level of inequality remains constant).

APPENDIXES

APPENDIX I

I. Panel Estimation Techniques

This section describes briefly three panel data estimation econometric techniques. The technique of Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) may be plagued by problems of reverse causality. Baltagi (2001) proposes several other econometric techniques to estimate panel data which could avoid the problem of reverse causality including Fixed Effects and the Generalized Method-of-Moments (GMM) dynamic panel estimators.12 The optimal estimation technique is evaluated on the basis of the following two criteria: (i) the presence of unobserved time- and country-specific effects; and (ii) the likely endogeneity of some of the regressors. This chosen technique is necessary to control for unobserved time- and country-specific effects because these may be correlated with the right-hand side variables, and produce biased coefficients if omitted. The unobserved time-specific effects could be controlled for by using time-period dummies; this entails the elimination of information related to those variables that vary across time periods but not across countries.

The class of models that can be estimated using panel data can be written as:

yit=αit+βiXit+uit(1)
uit=μi+νt+εi,t,(2)

where yit is the dependent variable, and αit and Xit are k-vectors on non-constant regressors and parameters for i =1, 2, …, n cross-sectional units (here countries); uit is a general disturbance, including a country specific unobservable effect, µi, a time specific factor νt, and an idiosyncratic disturbance εi,t. The fixed effects µi act as proxy for other determinants of a country’s steady state not included in Xit and the time specific factor νt controls for shocks common to all countries. Each country is observed for dated periods t =1, 2 … T.

Fixed-Effects Model

The fixed-effects estimator allows αi to differ across countries by estimating different constants for each country.13 The fixed effects model is equivalent to taking deviations from individual (country) means and then estimating an ordinary OLS regression using the transformed data:

(yit,y¯i.)=β(XitX¯i.)+(uitu¯i.),(3)
where y¯i= yit/n;X¯i= xit/n;u¯i= ui,t/n.

The deviation from the mean purges the data of the fixed effects by removing means of these variables across countries. The OLS estimates of β in the fixed effects model are inconsistent, although as T→∞, the inconsistency disappears. But for finite, typically small T, the inconsistency remains, as is the case in this paper, with N=90 countries and T=7 (maximum periods for each country.

The coefficient covariance matrix estimates are given by the usual OLS covariance formula applied to the mean differenced model:

Var(bFE)=σ2w(XX)1,(4)

where X represents the mean differenced x, and

σ2w=(eFEeFE)/(nTnk)={(yitxitbFE)2}/(nTnk),(5)

where uFE′uFE is the SRR from fixed effects model and (nT-n-k) is the correct number of degrees of freedom (nT being the number of observations, n the number of countries and k the number of parameters).

The fixed effects themselves are not estimated directly. They are computed from:

αi= (y¯i.X¯i.bFE)/N.(6)

The fact that the fixed effects estimator can be interpreted as a simple OLS regression of means-differenced variables explains why this estimator is often called a within group estimator. That is, it uses only the variation within a country’s set of observations.

Generalized Method-of-Moments (GMM)

Using the GMM estimator that was developed for dynamic models of panel data can be written as follows:

yi,tyi,t1=(ε1)yi,t1+βxi,t+μi+εi,t ,(7)

where y is the natural logarithm of real per capita GDP, x is the set of explanatory variables (other than lagged per capita GDP), µ is an unobserved country-specific effect, ε is the error term.

Following the procedure of Anderson and Hsiao (1981) to account for unobserved country-specific effects, all variables in equation (7) are first-differenced. This eliminates not only the unobserved country-specific effects but also all variables for which only cross-sectional information is available. After first-differencing and rearranging the terms of the dependent variable, equation (7) becomes:

yi,tyi,t1=ε(yi,t1yi,t2)+β(xi,txi,t1)+(εi,tεi,t1).(8)

First-differencing, however, introduces a correlation between the error term (εi,t - εi,t-1) and the differenced lagged-dependent variable (yi,t-1- yi,t-2). An OLS estimation in this case would produce biased results, even when the set of explanatory variables X is strictly exogenous. The other econometric problem to be addressed is the likely endogeneity of some of the regressors.

To deal with these two estimation problems, we need to use certain instruments. Under the assumption that in (8) the error terms εi,t are serially uncorrelated (i.e., is E(εi,t - εi,s) = 0 for t≠s, and the explanatory variables, X, are weakly exogenous that is E(Xi,t εi,s) = 0 for s > t, then values of y and x, respectively, which lagged two periods or more, are valid instruments in the equations in first differences. These two assumptions imply a set of moment restrictions that can be used in the context of the GMM to generate consistent and efficient estimates of the parameters of interest. This methodology follows work by Arellano and Bond (1991) on dynamic panel data estimation.

Consistency of the GMM estimator, however, depends on the validity of the instruments. To address this issue, I present two specification test suggested by Arellano and Bover (1995). The first is the Sargen test of over-identifying restrictions, which tests the overall validity of the instruments by analyzing the sample analog of the moment conditions used in the estimation process. The second test examines the hypothesis that the error term in the differenced regression (εi,t - εi,t-1) is not serially correlated. One potential limitation of the GMM approach is that not much heterogeneity is allowed across countries. Heterogeneity is restricted to the intercept but is not permitted in the slope coefficients. Yet, if the slope coefficients vary across units lagged, values of serially correlated regressors cannot be used as valid instruments

APPENDIX II

II. Data Definition, Sources, and Dataset

Data Definition and Sources

Dataset

article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
article image