Abstract
An independent central bank can manage its balance sheet and its capital so as to commit itself to a depreciation of its currency and an exchange rate peg. This way, the central bank can implement the optimal escape from a liquidity trap, which involves a commitment to higher future inflation. This commitment mechanism works even though, realistically, the central bank cannot commit itself to a particular future money supply. It supports the feasibility of Svensson's Foolproof Way to escape from a liquidity trap.
I. Introduction
In a liquidity trap, the nominal interest rate is zero, but the real interest rate is higher than optimal, due to private-sector expectations of low inflation or even deflation. It is well known since Krugman (1998) that the optimal way to escape from a liquidity trap is to generate expectations of a higher future price level and thereby expectations of higher future inflation. This will lower the real interest rate and stimulate the economy out of the liquidity trap, even though the nominal interest rate is zero. The problem, also emphasized by Krugman (1998) is how to make the higher future price level credible. A promise of a higher future price level may not be credible, since the central bank may renege on its promise in the future and achieve a lower price level than promised, so as to maintain low and stable inflation.
This paper shows that a central bank’s realistic concerns about its balance sheet and capital creates a commitment mechanism, which allows the bank to commit to a higher future price level through a current currency depreciation and a commitment to maintaining a weaker currency in the future. This commitment mechanism provides support for the Foolproof Way to escape from a liquidity trap that has been suggested by Svensson (2001) and (2003b).2 The bank wishes to maintain its independence from the government. A negative capital would require a capital injection from the government and put the bank at the government’s mercy. In order to avoid this, the bank never voluntarily allows its capital to fall below a certain minimum level. Because undoing the current currency depreciation by a future currency appreciation would imply a future capital loss on the bank’s foreign-exchange reserves, a minimum capital level provides a lower bound on the future exchange rate (an upper bound on the future currency appreciation). By managing its capital such that the minimum capital level is reached for the exchange-rate level consistent with the desired higher future price level, the bank can commit itself to that higher future price level. Although we believe that foreign-exchange reserves provide the most relevant and realistic case, this commitment mechanism could potentially also arise for other assets on central-bank balance sheets, such as equity, property and indexed bonds—but not, as we shall see, for fixed-income securities nominated in the home currency.
Although several recent papers on liquidity traps and the experience of Japan have emphasized the credibility problem of committing to future inflation for a central bank with an established low-inflation reputation (for instance, Krugman (1998), Svensson (2001) and (2003a,b), and Eggertsson (2003)), this literature has not explicitly incorporated the specific balance-sheet concerns of independent central banks.
Eggertsson (2003) models the role of the nominal liabilities of a combined government and central bank in providing incentives to future inflation that will reduce the real value of the public debt and, thereby, distortionary taxation. In a liquidity trap, accumulation of more nominal debt strengthens incentives to inflation in the future and increases current private-sector inflation expectations. One way to increase the nominal debt is by borrowing in order to accumulate foreign exchange. In Eggertsson’s setup, and counter to the situation in many countries, including Japan, the central bank is not independent but controlled by the government.
Our setup differs from Eggertsson’s in several respects. More realistically, the central bank is not subordinated to the fiscal authority, and monetary policy is not used to reduce the public debt and lower future taxation. Instead the central bank is independent and concerned about its capital solely in order to maintain its independence. It is not concerned about the balance sheet of the consolidated public sector but about capital losses on its foreign-exchange reserves. Furthermore, it is indifferent to such capital losses as long as they do not lead to capital falling below the minimum level.
For both Krugman (1998) and Eggertsson (2003), central-bank independence and a lack of coordination of monetary and fiscal policy imply a problem and a barrier to the escape from a liquidity trap. In our paper, central-bank independence, together with balance-sheet concerns, provide the solution to this problem.
The balance-sheet concerns of central bankers is an area of research that has been left largely unexplored in the literature on monetary policy. However, as we show in section IV, there is a great deal of evidence that central bankers pay attention to the capital of the central bank because its level matters for the financial autonomy and the independence of the central bank. As more and more central banks become independent, it would seem important to understand better the channels by which the balance-sheet concerns of central bankers and monetary policy influence each other. As this paper illustrates, the balance-sheet concerns of central banks may have implications for the conduct of monetary policy that are non-trivial from an analytical point of view and relevant for real-world policy problems.
In the context of a liquidity trap, the balance-sheet concerns of central banks have been the subject of some informal discussion. Many commentators, for instance, Bernanke (2003), have suggested that balance-sheet concerns of the Bank of Japan have been a barrier to more aggressive policies and that monetary and fiscal cooperation, including compensation for central-bank losses from risky open-market purchases, would contribute to Japan’s escape from the liquidity trap.
In other contexts than a liquidity trap, more formal models of the balance-sheet concerns of central banks have been presented. Isard (1994) presents a model of currency crises in which the central bank cares about the value of its foreign-exchange reserves. Sims (2001) shows that a low level of capital may prevent a central bank from avoiding self-fulfilling hyperinflationary equilibria. In Sims’s model, balance-sheet concerns are an impediment: they prevent the central banker from taking the right policy actions in a situation of economic distress. Sims argues that such situations will require a closer monetary and fiscal cooperation (a stronger fiscal backing of monetary policy), which the independence of the central bank is likely to make more difficult.3
Thus, according to the previous literature, balance-sheet concerns and central-bank independence may cause problems. In contrast, in this paper, we show that, in the context of a liquidity trap, balance-sheet concerns and central-bank independence may provide a solution, a commitment mechanism for optimal escape from a liquidity trap.
Section II lays out the model of the paper, shows how a liquidity trap can arise, and specifies the suboptimal policy under discretion and the optimal policy under commitment. Section III presents some evidence on the balance-sheet concerns of central banks. Section IV shows how an independent central bank can commit itself to the optimal policy. Section V discusses some generalizations of our results. Section VI provides some conclusions. An appendix includes some technical details.
II. A SIMPLE OPEN ECONOMY MODEL OF THE LIQUIDITY TRAP
We consider a small open economy, a simplified version of many current open-economy models, for instance, that in Svensson (2003b). Households consume a traded good and a nontraded good. The nontraded good is produced with nontraded intermediate inputs whose nominal prices are set one period ahead by monopolistic producers. The central bank conducts flexible inflation targeting by minimizing a standard quadratic loss function of inflation and the output gap. We show that the economy may fall into a liquidity trap with excessively low output and inflation as a result of an unanticipated fall in expected productivity growth and a related fall in the natural interest rate.4
A. The Structure of the Economy
Time is separated into discrete periods, t =…,− 1, 0, 1,… There is one traded good, the foreign good. The foreign-currency price of the good is unity in all periods. Let St denote the exchange rate in period t, measured in home-currency units per foreign currency. The Law of One Price holds, so the home-currency price of the foreign good is simply equal to the exchange rate. A foreign-currency bond, with a constant continuously compounded interest rate, r* >0, is the only traded asset.
The home country has a private sector, consisting of a household and firms, and a public sector, consisting of a central bank and a government. The household consumes the traded foreign good and the nontraded home good and supplies labor. The utility function of the household in period t is
where Et denotes expectations conditional on information available in period t, δ ≡ e−r* is the discount factor, Cht denotes consumption of the home good in period t, Cft denotes consumption of the foreign good, α ∈ (0, 1) denotes the consumption share of the foreign good, Mt denotes the household’s holding of home currency, Pht denotes the home-currency price of home goods, and Nt denotes the supply of labor. The function U(Mt/Pht) represents the liquidity services of real money, which consist of time saved in the transactions of the home good. Real money is consequently measured in terms of the home good.
The liquidity-services function is continuous and continuously differentiable for Mt/Pht > 0 and has the additional properties
where eμ > 0 is the satiation level of real money. That is, U(Mt/Pht) is increasing at a decreasing rate for Mt/Pht < eμ and has a maximum equal to U0 for Mt/Pht ≥ eμ. There is a positive demand for real balances regardless of how high the home-currency interest rate is. The liquidity-services function is illustrated in Figure 1.
The Liquidity–Services Function
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2004, 162; 10.5089/9781451857900.001.A001
The consumer price index (CPI), Pt, will be given by
where we use the fact that the home-currency price of the foreign good is equal to the nominal exchange rate.
The nontraded home good is produced in two stages. In the final stage, final-good firms produce the output Yt of the home good with inputs of a continuum of nontraded intermediate goods, Yt(l), l ∈[0, 1], according to the production function,
where ξ > 1 denotes the elasticity of substitution between the intermediate inputs. The final-good firms operate under perfect competition and take the prices of the home good and intermediate inputs as given. The corresponding price index fulfills
where Pht(l) denotes the home-currency price of intermediate good l. It follows that demand for intermediate good l is given by
In the initial stage, each intermediate good l is produced by a single firm l with a technology that is linear in labor input with a country-wide exogenous stochastic productivity, At,
where Nt(l) denotes labor input in the production of intermediate good l. There is hence a continuum of firms producing intermediate goods. Firm l maximizes profits, subject to perfect competition in the labor market and monopolistic competition in the intermediate goods market (with the gross markup ξ/(ξ–1) over marginal cost), and distributes the profits to the home household. Firm l sets its price for period t one period in advance, that is, in period t −1, so as to maximize the expected utility value of profits. Aggregate labor supply and demand will be given by
The budget constraint in period t for the home household is
where Bt denotes the number of home-currency one-period bonds held between periods t and t+1, it is the continuously compounded interest rate paid in period t +1 on those bonds,
The budget constraint for the central bank is
where Zt is the home-currency value of the central bank’s dividend paid to the government, Rt ≥ 0 denotes the number of foreign-currency bonds held as foreign-exchange reserves between period t and t + 1, and Mt−Mt–1 is the change in the central bank’s supply of home currency. In this simple model, the supply of home currency, the monetary base, and the stock of money are identical. For simplicity, we also assume that the only asset on the central bank’s balance sheet is foreign-exchange reserves. As shown in appendix, introducing domestic credit on the asset side of the central bank’s balance sheet does not change our results.
There is no government consumption. The government collects the dividend from the central bank and passes it on as a lumpsum transfer to the household. We assume that no home-currency bonds are held in the foreign country, and that the net supply of home-currency bonds is zero,
B. Equilibrium Relationships
In equilibrium, consumption and production of the home good are equal,
Adding (5) and (6) and using (7) and (8), we can write the consolidated budget constraint for the home country in terms of the foreign good,
where
denotes the home-country’s net foreign assets.
The first-order condition for optimal intertemporal consumption of the foreign good will be
(see Appendix for a derivation of the first-order conditions). Since δ = e−r*, we realize from (9) and (10) that Cft and Ft will be constant over time and fulfill
The current account is hence constant and unaffected by monetary policy. This property—which considerably simplifies the analysis—stems from the assumptions that utility is separable in consumption of home and foreign goods.
As shown in Appendix II, firm l’s optimal price is given by the first-order condition
where Wt is the nominal wage in period t. The price is simply set equal to the gross markup times the expected home-currency marginal cost.
The first-order condition for the household’s labor supply implies that the wage in home goods, Wt/Pht, is equal to the marginal rate of substitution of home goods for labor,
where we use (8). It follows from the two previous equations that
where
is the flexprice level of output, the level that would prevail under flexible prices and constant money supply.5 Potential output is proportional to productivity.
Equation (14) shows how the decision of an individual price-setter l depends on the prices set by the competitors as well as the expected ratio of actual to potential output. It says that an intermediate-good firm sets its price above (below) its competitors’ if and only if it expects the ratio of actual output to potential output to be above (below) one. Since in equilibrium all intermediate-good producers set their prices at the same level, the expected ratio of actual to potential output must be equal to one
Actual output can deviate from potential output in the short run because of nominal stickiness. Given that the consumption of the traded good is constant, a change in the production (and consumption) of the nontraded good must be associated with a change in the real exchange rate. The real exchange rate, defined as the price of the traded foreign good in terms of the nontraded home good,
will equal the marginal rate of substitution of the home good for the foreign good,
where we have used (8) and (11). The real exchange rate is proportional to output. We define the natural real exchange rate as the flexprice level, the level that would prevail under flexible prices (and constant money supply),
We conclude this section with the equilibrium relationships for interest rates and money. The first-order condition for optimal intertemporal consumption of the home good is
where we use (8) and that the marginal utility of nominal income is proportional to 1/(PhtYt). The real (CPI) interest rate, rt, will fulfill
where we have used (1), (17), and (18). The natural (CPI) interest rate,
The home-currency interest rate fulfills the zero lower bound,
Given the assumptions about the liquidity-services function, money demand can be written
(see Appendix I). Note that the satiation level, eμ, is independent of home output. The function G(Yt, it) has the properties
C. Productivity
The dynamics of the economy is driven by the exogenous stochastic process for productivity. We specify this process in such a way that the economy may fall in a liquidity trap in period 1 and in that period only. This simplifies the analysis without substantial restriction of generality, since the policies that succeed in extracting the economy from a liquidity trap in period 1 can be implemented in other periods, too.
We assume that productivity is equal to a constant level A up to period 1, and falls to a constant lower level e−b A from period 2 onwards (b ≥ 0). Denoting the log of variables by lower case, this assumption can be written
The value of parameter b is announced in period 1, one period before the productivity fall takes place. It could be equal to zero, in which case productivity remains unchanged. As we shall see, the economy falls in a liquidity trap when the value of b is large enough. The realization of b is governed by a probability distribution function that is known by all agents, and expectations are rational.
It then follows from (15) and (18) that the log of potential output and the log of the natural real exchange rate also fall by b in period 2
with
Taking the log of (22)—and using that potential output is known one period in advance—we get
Thus, the natural interest rate is directly related to the rate of time preference, -ln δ = r*, and to expected productivity growth, at +1 − at. Expected productivity growth is constant and equal to zero in all periods, except in period 1 when it is falls to − b. Consequently, the natural interest rate is equal to r* in all periods, except in period 1 when it falls to
Furthermore, the logs of money, prices, and output will be related by
where g(yt, it) ≡ In G(eYt, it).
As shown in Appendix III, the model can be solved under rational expectations for an arbitrary distribution of b. For expositional simplicity, however, we assume in the main text that economic agents view the lower expected productivity growth in period 1 as very unlikely ex ante. Hence, until period 0 they behave as if b were going to be equal to zero, and the lower expected productivity growth comes to them as an unexpected surprise in period 1. Examining this simple case makes the algebra easier and, as shown in the appendix, it does not affect the essence of our results on the optimal policy to escape a liquidity trap.
D. Monetary Policy
Assume that the central bank has an objective function corresponding to flexible (CPI) inflation targeting, with an intertemporal loss function
with the period loss function
where πt = log (Pt/Pt−1) is the inflation rate, π ≥ 0 is a given inflation target,
Let us derive the equilibrium inflation rate. Taking the log of (1) and (17), inflation can be written
Taking the log difference of (18) and (19), we find that the log deviations of output and of the real exchange rate from their natural levels are equal,
Using this equation to substitute for qt in (31) gives the following Phillips curve,
The first term on the right side involves variables that are either exogenous
The central bank will be able to control it by setting mt. For given inflation expectations, this will determine rt and yt. Via (33), πt is then determined. For simplicity, we can think of the central bank as choosing yt directly, and then inferring the corresponding level of mt from (28).
We will see below that a liquidity trap can only arise in period 1, when expected productivity growth and the natural interest rate are low. In all other periods, there is no liquidity trap. Then (33) is the only relevant constraint. In those periods, the central bank’s optimization problem under discretion is to minimize the period loss function (30) subject to the Phillips curve (33). This implies the targeting rule (first-order condition)
The only period in which new information is revealed is period 1. In all other periods t ≠1, there is no new information, and yt is known in the previous period, t−1. Equation (16) then implies that output equals potential output,
Under discretion, for t ≤ 0 and t ≥ 2,
E. A Liquidity Trap in Period 1
Having characterized the equilibrium in periods other than 1, we now focus on period 1. We can summarize the model in period 1 as
Equation (35) is obtained by taking the log of (21) and (22) for t = 1 and observing that perfect foresight applies from period 1 onwards. The inequality follows from the zero lower bound on the home nominal interest rate and the relation between the nominal and real interest rate in period 1,
Equation (36) follows from (33),
The economy is in a liquidity trap in period 1, if the constraint (37) prevents the central bank from setting output at its potential level, that is, if
In a discretion equilibrium with a liquidity trap in period 1, the best the central bank can do is to set m1 ≥ ph1+μ, so the nominal interest rate will equal zero, i1 = 0. We let denote the values of variables in the discretion equilibrium, so
The output gap and the inflation gap are negative, and the real interest-rate gap is positive.
F. The Optimal Policy Under Commitment
The above equilibrium is suboptimal, with a negative output gap that is unnecessary large, because private-sector inflation expectations are equal to the inflation target. If possible, it would be better for the central bank to credibly commit to exceeding the inflation target next period, period 2, and this way create private-sector expectations in period 1 of a higher period- 2 inflation. This would lower the real interest rate and reduce the magnitude of the output gap in period 1. In order to specify this optimal policy—the optimal escape from a liquidity trap—we consider the optimal policy in a liquidity trap under commitment.
The relevant loss function in period1 is then
In period 2, we have
The central bank minimizes (40) subject to (35) and (36). We now consider π2 as a control variable, in addition to y1. The Lagrangian is
where φ1 ≥ 0 is the Lagrange multiplier for the constraint (35) and we will use (36) to substitute for π1−π. The first-order conditions with respect to y1 and π2 and the complementary-slackness condition are then, respectively,
In a liquidity trap,φ1 > 0. Eliminating φ1 from (41)–(43) results in the targeting rule under commitment in a liquidity trap:7 Set m1 ≥ ph1+μ and thereby i1 = 0, and choose π2 > π, and thereby
so as to fulfill the target criterion
The commitment equilibrium in the liquidity trap is then determined by (36), (44), and (45). We let ∼ denote the values of variables in the commitment equilibrium. Combining (36), (44), and (45), we get
where the last equation follows from (35) and (46).
Comparing the output gap in the commitment equilibrium, (46), with that in the discretion equilibrium, (38), we see that
The magnitude of the negative output gap is less than under discretion. By (36), it follows that the magnitude of the negative inflation gap in period 1,
G. Implementing the Commitment Equilibrium
The commitment equilibrium will imply a period-2 money supply,
where
Indeed, since the spring of 2001, the Bank of Japan has expanded the monetary base by more than 60 percent. If this expansion had been perceived as permanent, it would have resulted in dramatically increased expectations of future inflation in Japan, which would have shown up in either a large depreciation of the yen or a large rise in long interest rates. Obviously, none of this has happened, and the obvious explanation is that the Bank of Japan is expected to contract the monetary base in the future.
We will show below that we can find a different commitment mechanism through which the central bank can commit to a higher future price level, namely through a credible commitment to a weaker currency. For this purpose, we will specify the exchange rates consistent with the commitment and discretion equilibria. Using (17) and (32), the period-1 log exchange rate in the commitment equilibrium is
with
which, since the nominal interest rate is equal to zero in the liquidity trap, implies
The central bank can implement the commitment equilibrium, if it can credibly commit itself to pegging the exchange rate at the optimal levels
In order to see this, suppose that the central bank has credibly implemented the optimal policy in period 1, resulting in the output gap
where ex post inflation π2 and output y2 could differ from the levels expected in period 1,
Combining (52) and (53) results in
That is, ex post, the central bank would renege on its commitment to implement the optimal inflation rate
The above reneging cannot arise in the formulation of the Foolproof Way in Svensson (2003b). There, monetary policy is concerned about domestic inflation, inflation in the home-currency price of home goods, with the period loss function (in the notation of the present paper)
where domestic inflation, pht − ph,t−1, enters rather than CPI inflation, pt − pt−1 Since the period-t domestic price level and domestic inflation is predetermined by pricing decisions in period t−1, the central bank cannot renege. Indeed, the discussion of the price level in the context of the Foolproof Way in Svensson (2001)–(2003b) has consistently referred to the domestic price level rather than the CPI price level. In the present set up, with monetary policy concerned about CPI inflation and instantaneous pass-through of exchange-rate movements to home-currency prices of the foreign good, the period-t CPI price level and CPI inflation are directly affected by the period-t exchange rate, pt = (1−α)pht + αst, and reneging is possible.
Conditional on the assumption of reoptimization under discretion in period 2, the only equilibrium in the present setup in period 1 is the discretion equilibrium, the equilibrium we have characterized in section. The corresponding log exchange rates in the discretion equilibrium are given by
The exchange rates in the two periods are lower by the same amount—the currency is stronger—in the discretion equilibrium than in the commitment equilibrium.
In the rest of the paper, we argue that a commitment mechanism for a commitment to the optimal exchange rates,
III. The balance-sheet concerns of central banks
In the following sections, we extend our model by assuming that the central bank does not let its capital fall below some threshold, and that this concern may override the macroeconomic objectives for output and inflation. This section presents some evidence supporting the realism of this assumption.
At the outset, it should be noted that the central bank’s concern for its level of capital is not obvious. Central banks do not need a positive level of capital for the same reasons as commercial banks. A negative level of capital does not subject them to the risk of a run and a bankruptcy, since they can always face their debt obligations by printing currency. So, strictly speaking, central banks do not need capital (Stella, 1997). If the central bank were consolidated with the central government, there would be no reason to consider the central bank’s capital separately from the intertemporal budget constraint of the government.
However, central banks have balance sheets that are constructed according to the same broad principles as private banks.8 Central banks, furthermore, seem to be concerned by their capital as their private counterparts. This is illustrated by several facts.
First, central-bank capital, although it can be quite low, is generally positive. In 2003, the median level of central-bank capital (including reserves and provisions) represented 8.8 percent of its total assets in emerging economies and 15.3 percent in advanced countries (Hawkins, 2003). In some countries, the central banks have had negative capital for prolonged periods of time, but these are mostly Latin American countries with a history of monetary instability (Stella, 2002).
Second, the level of capital seems closely related to the proportion of central-bank assets held as foreign-exchange reserves and thereby the amount of foreign-exchange risk they bear.9 Figure 2 plots the ratio of central-bank capital to total liabilities against the ratio of foreign-exchange reserves to total assets, for a sample of OECD countries.10 The figure illustrates the distinction made by Sims (2001) between two types of central banks. Some central banks (Sims’s type F) have a low proportion of their assets as foreign-exchange reserves and have low capital ratios. One example is the U.S. Federal Reserve System: it holds very little foreign-exchange reserves, and so does not need a large amount of capital to buffer the exchange risk. This category also includes countries that have large total foreign-exchange reserves but in which most of these reserves are held by the Treasury (Canada and Japan). The other type of central banks (Sims’s type E) have a higher proportion of assets as foreign-exchange reserves, and accordingly maintain a higher capital ratio. This category includes most European central banks.11
Central Banks’ Capital and Reserves, 1999–2003
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2004, 162; 10.5089/9781451857900.001.A001
Third, an increasing number of central banks explicitly define an objective in terms of a capital-adequacy ratio. Since 1998, the Bank of Japan targets a capital-adequacy ratio, consisting of the capital divided by a period average of outstanding bank notes, of around 8–12 percent (Cargill, 2004), (Stella, 2002). Recent legislation in Indonesia prevents the transfer of profits to the government until the central bank builds its capital up to 10 percent of its monetary liabilities. The Reserve Bank of India aims at capital and reserves of 8 percent of assets (Hawkins, 2003).
The central banks’ revealed preferences suggest a strong aversion to negative or low capital. But why is it so? The reasons given by central banks suggest that this has to do mainly with the autonomy of their institutions relative to the government. As the governor of the Bank of Japan put it in a recent speech (Fukui, 2003),
“[C]entral banks’ concern with the soundness of their capital base might not be grounded purely in economic theory but may be motivated rather by the political economy instincts of central bankers. In other words, once the restriction that the central bank should only take risks consistent with the level of its self-imposed capital base is violated, the boundary between the functions of the central bank and those of the government may become difficult to discern.”
The relationship between central-bank independence and central-bank losses goes both ways. First, a central bank that is not independent is more likely to make losses. These losses are typically the result of accounting rules or of the transfer to the central bank of quasi-fiscal activities (subsidized lending, bank bailouts) that make it possible for the government to artificially reduce the headline fiscal deficit (Leone, 1994).
Conversely, an independent central bank that makes large losses will see its independence eroded over time. A loss-making central bank is likely to become the object of increased oversight from the government−as any loss-making public entity should be. But the government might take advantage of increased oversight to influence monetary policy (Vaez-Zadeh, 1991; Ernhagen, Vesterlund and Viotti, 2002). As noted by Pringle (2003):
“What would happen if the BoJ had to report huge paper losses? Public reaction would be all important.… Also, the government might say that it would inject capital on certain conditions—e.g., that the central bank changed its monetary policy.”
IV. How an independent central bank can commit to a future price level
Consider a central bank that finds itself in a liquidity trap in period 1. The central bank cannot commit to a particular money supply in the future. We will show that it can, nevertheless, move to and implement the commitment equilibrium in period 1 by managing its balance sheet in the right way. Thereby it can commit itself to an exchange-rate in period 2 that corresponds to the desired higher next-period inflation,
Define the central bank’s capital at the end of period t, Vt, as
We note that, by (6) and (54),
so the only non-predetermined variables in period t that the capital Vt depends on are the exchange rate, St, and the dividend paid to the government during period t, Zt.
Importantly, let us assume that the central bank never allows its capital to fall below a given nonnegative lower bound,
The rationale for this, as explained in Section III, is that too low a capital indicates mismanagement, causes embarrassment, might require the resignation of the bank management, and, more importantly, may force the central bank to ask for an injection of capital from the government, a negative dividend, for which it may have to give up some of its independence. In line with this, we also assume that the central bank has control over the dividend it pays and that this dividend is always nonnegative,
Thus, we find (56) and (57) to be realistic assumptions. Assume, furthermore, that the private sector believes that (56) and (57) always hold, that is, that the central bank will never voluntarily allow its capital to fall below the minimum level or the dividend to be negative.
The central bank enters period1 with given M0 and R0. Suppose that the economy initially is in the discretion equilibrium in period1, with the period-1 exchange rate equal to
where we have used (6) and (55) and we recall that eµ > 0 is the satiation level of real money.
We want to show that the central bank can implement the commitment equilibrium by depreciating the currency in period 1 to the exchange rate
To see why this is true, we note that, in period 2, for given R1 and M1, (55), (56), and (57) imply a lower bound for the period- 2 exchange rate,
This inequality comes from the currency mismatch in the balance sheet of the central bank. The central bank finances foreign-currency assets by issuing home-currency liabilities. The central bank’s capital remains above the threshold
We then realize that the central bank should set and announce new levels of the money supply and the foreign-exchange reserves in period 1, denoted
This implies that the lower bound for the period- 2 exchange rate, the right side of (60) for period 2, is exactly equal to
Using equations (54), (55), and the interest parity condition,ei1 = er* S2/S1, the central bank’s capital in period 1 and period 2 are related as
The central bank’s capital increases by the revenues from seigniorage minus the dividend paid to the government. If the economy is in a liquidity trap (i1 = 0), the revenues from seigniorage are equal to zero. If the capital constraint is binding, furthermore, the central bank pays no dividend in period 2, and we have
Hence, in order to set the value of its capital to the minimum level
Thus, in order to implement the commitment equilibrium, in period 1 the central bank should pay the dividend
It only remains to demonstrate that it is feasible for the central bank to choose a nonnegative dividend
If, counter to the above logic and announcements, the private sector, irrationally, would believe that the currency might appreciate back to
V. Generalizations
We have shown how the central bank can commit to higher future inflation by pegging the exchange rate in a very simple model. The simplicity of the model is an advantage when explaining the logic of the argument, but raises the question of the robustness of our results to realistic changes in the assumptions.
A. A Multiperiod Liquidity Trap
Would the balance-sheet channel still work if the liquidity trap lasted for several periods? A multiperiod liquidity trap could arise in the model if nominal prices were sticky for more than one period (Eggertsson and Woodford, 2003). Let us simply assume, for the sake of this discussion, that the liquidity trap would end in period
The home currency must, by uncovered interest parity, appreciate at the foreign-currency interest rate, r*, in each period, when the home-currency interest rate is zero.
As in the case of a one-period liquidity trap, the central bank can implement the commitment equilibrium, if it can commit itself to the exchange-rate path
The central bank can achieve this by setting its capital, evaluated at the exchange rate
Since the home nominal interest rate is zero in each period t = 1, …,
By
As in the one-period liquidity trap, this constraint will bind in equilibrium. The central bank will minimizes its period loss by setting
B. Generalizing the Capital Constraint
Constraint (56), with a constant minimum capital level, is a simple but particular way of modeling the central bank’s balance-sheet concerns. First, it would be natural to assume that the minimum level of capital
for t ≥ 0 (since π ≥ 0).
Assume that the minimum capital is strictly increasing over time. For the one-period liquidity trap, it is easy to show that Proposition still holds, except that the central bank now sets its period-1 capital to the period-2 minimum level,
so the capital will exceed the minimum level in period 1.
Similarly, for a multi-period liquidity trap with optimal exit in period
For zero dividend payments, this will keep the capital constant and equal to that minimum level for all periods 2, …,
The central bank might be tempted to increase its capital before period
Second, some capital-adequacy rules may be problematic in a liquidity trap. For example, assume that the capital adequacy ratio is defined as a fraction of the supply of home currency,
with κ > 0 given (as in Japan). In a liquidity trap, the level of Mt is undetermined, as long as it exceeds the satiation level of demand for home currency. Typically, the monetary base during the liquidity trap may be much higher than the equilibrium monetary base when the liquidity trap is over (cf. the above comments on the large expansion of the monetary base in Japan, which the private sector apparently expects to a large extent to be undone when Japan exits from the liquidity trap). But this means, under (63) that the minimum capital level will be much higher during the liquidity trap. This will prevent the central bank from reducing its capital to the minimum capital level in the period of exit from the liquidity trap. From the point of view of escaping a liquidity trap, it is preferable to define the minimum capital level as a given exogenous level rather than as a fraction of an endogenous monetary aggregate.
Finally, it might be realistic to assume more flexibility in the balance-sheet concerns of the central bank. The capital-adequacy objective could, for instance, be defined as an average over a number of periods. There could also be more symmetry between the balance-sheet objectives and the monetary-policy objectives of the central bank. For example, the central bank’s balance-sheet concerns could be modeled as an additional term in its objective function instead of a constraint on its optimization problem. The period loss function (30) could be augmented with a term depending on the central bank’s capital
where µ > 0 is the weight on the balance-sheet concerns, vt is the log of Vt and
C. Pegging the Price of Other Assets than Foreign Exchange
As noted in Section III, in some countries (including Japan), the central bank holds only a small amount of foreign-exchange reserves. Most of the foreign-exchange reserves are held, and the associated risk is borne, by the Treasury. This does not necessarily prevent these central banks to optimally escape a liquidity trap with an exchange rate peg since—as shown in appendix—the results of Section II remain true even if the central holds small foreign-exchange reserves, as long as they are positive. This is because when the capital constraint is binding, the minimum level that it implies for the exchange rate does not depend on the amount of foreign-exchange reserves. In principle, therefore, the commitment mechanism presented in this paper could work with a very small amount of foreign-exchange reserves.
The amount of foreign-exchange reserves is irrelevant because the balance-sheet concerns of the central banker are modeled as the constraint (56). If instead these concerns were modeled with the loss function (64), then the amount of foreign-exchange reserves would matter, since it would determine the sensitivity of the central bank’s capital to the exchange rate. In this case, the central bank might have to increase its foreign-exchange reserves drastically in order to tie its hands using the foolproof way. Alternatively, the desired commitment might be achieved by pegging the price of assets other than foreign-exchange reserves. What other assets could be used for this purpose?
We show in this section that the balance-sheet management can be generalized to some, but not all assets. The important distinction in this regard is between the assets whose returns are predetermined in home currency (nominal assets, such as home-currency bonds of all maturities) and assets whose returns are not predetermined (real assets, such as stocks, real estate or indexed bonds). The latter, and the not the former, provide the appropriate tool for the sort of commitment strategies we have analyzed so far.
Consider the case of an inflation-indexed consol that yields a positive nominal coupon payment of ρPt in each period t, where ρ > 0 (the result can be generalized to other assets such as stocks, but it is easiest to show it with an indexed consol). Let
From the fact that, from period t = 2 onwards, Pt and
From (65), (66), and ei1 = 1, it follows that the price of the consol in period 1 is
The commitment solution can then be implemented by pegging the price of the consol to the levels in period 1 and 2,
where
Assume that consoles are the only assets on the central bank’s balance sheet, and let Xt denote the number of consols held by the central bank between period t and period t + 1. Then the central bank’s budget constraint is
and its capital is given by
In particular, the period-2 level of capital is given by
where we have used (66) for t = 2 to replace
in analogy with (60). This sets a lower bound on the price of consols in period 2—and, because of (66), also on the period-2 CPI. In period 1, the central bank should then choose M1 and X1 at levels
By (67) and (69), this implies
This is the same condition as in Proposition 3. It is easy to check, that this level
Interestingly, it is crucial for the argument that the bond’s coupon payment is fixed in real terms. Assume instead that ρ denotes a fixed coupon payment in home currency. Then equation (66) is replaced by
It follows that the home-currency price of the bond in period 2 is unaffected by monetary policy. Thus, it is impossible for the central bank to peg the nominal price of the bond in period 2 to a level different from the right side of (71). The commitment solution can no longer be implemented by pegging
It is straightforward to see that this result would hold for any asset with returns predetermined in home currency. The price of the asset is equal to the future nominal cash flows discounted by the nominal interest rate i = r + π*. Balance-sheet management works with foreign-exchange reserves or indexed bonds because, since the future equilibrium is homogenous of degree one in home-currency units, pegging the home-currency price of these assets is equivalent to pegging the home-currency price level, the home-currency value of the CPI. This does not work with fixed-income securities denominated in home currency.
VI. Conclusions
As we have emphasized above, in a liquidity trap, the nominal interest rate is zero, but the real interest rate is higher than optimal. This causes a recession that is deeper than optimal. The higher-than-optimal real interest rate is due to private-sector expectations of low inflation or even deflation. The optimal policy in this situation must generate expectations of a higher future price level and thereby expectations of higher future inflation. This will lower the real interest rate and stimulate the economy out of the liquidity trap even though the nominal interest rate is zero. This benefit is worth overshooting the future inflation or price-level target. The problem is how to make the higher future price level credible. A promise of a higher future price level may not be credible, since the central bank may renege on its promise in the future and achieve a lower price level than promised, so as to maintain low and stable inflation.
This paper shows that a central bank’s realistic concerns about its balance sheet and capital allows it to commit to a higher future price level through a currency depreciation and a crawling peg, in line with Svensson’s (2003a) and (2003b) Foolproof Way to escape from a liquidity trap. The bank wishes to maintain its independence from the government. A negative capital position would require a capital injection and put the bank at the government’s mercy. In order to avoid this, the bank never voluntarily allows its capital to fall below a certain minimum level. Because undoing the current currency depreciation by a future currency appreciation would imply a future capital loss on the bank’s foreign-exchange reserves, a minimum capital level provides a lower bound on the future exchange rate (an upper bound on the future currency appreciation). By managing its capital such that the minimum capital level is reached for the exchange-rate level consistent with the desired higher future price level, the bank can commit itself to the appropriate exchange-rate path and thereby to the appropriate higher future price level. This kind of commitment mechanism is also possible, if the central bank holds other assets than foreign-exchange reserves, but not if it holds only fixed-income securities denominated in home currency.
To conclude on a more general note, this paper might contribute to drawing the attention of scholars to the balance sheet concerns of central bankers and their implications for monetary policy. These concerns have not been analyzed in the academic literature, although central bankers do seem to care about their balance sheets in the real world. This omission may not be a serious one when central bankers’ balance sheet concerns do not significantly influence monetary policy and can be safely ignored to a first approximation. However, there are situations—and a liquidity trap is an important example—where central bankers’ balance sheet concerns might matter in a nontrivial way for monetary policy-making. This observation would seem to warrant more theoretical and empirical research on the foundations of central bankers’ balance sheet concerns and on their implication for monetary policy.
I. First-Order Conditions
The Lagrangian for the household’s optimization problem is
where
for money,
for labor,
for foreign-currency bonds,
implying (10); and for home-currency bonds,
implying (using the first-order condition for foreign-currency bonds and δer* = 1)
the interest-parity condition.
From the first-order condition for money, home-good consumption and home-currency bonds, we get
which by the assumptions on the liquidity-services function and (8) can be written in reduced form as (24).
II. Derivation of Equation (12)
The expected utility value of firm l’s profits is given by
where we have used (4). The first-order condition with respect to Ph, t+1 (ι) is
This, together with Ph, t+1(l) =Ph, t+1 gives
We realize that all firms l∈ [0, 1] will set the same price Ph,t+1 (ι) and produce the same quantity Yt+1 (ι), so by (2) and (3) we have Ph,t+1 (ι) = Ph,t+1 and Yt+1 (ι) = Yt+1 for all l ∈[0, 1]. Using this, (8) and the fact that Ph,t+1 will be predetermined and known in period t, the price-setting equation can be written as (12).
III. Households and Firms Perceiving a Positive Probability of a Liquidity Trap
Assume that private agents correctly perceive that the fall in log productivity, b, or equivalently the period 1 natural real interest rate
Until period 0 and from period 2 onwards, the economy is in the steady states that we have already analyzed in the text. In period 1, the Phillips curve (36) can be written
where Δph1 ≡ ph1 − ph0 and we use that p0 = αq0 + ph0. Since
For period 0, we can no longer assume that intermediate-good producers preset prices for period∼1 such that Δph1 = π. These producers realize that the economy might with some probability be in a liquidity trap in period 1, in which case the realized inflation rate will be lower than π. As a consequence, Δph1 will not equal π but be lower than π. It will be the solution to a fixed-point problem that we specify below.
Price setters do not know for sure, in period 0, whether the economy will be in a liquidity trap in period 1. The economy will be in a liquidity trap in period 1 if the fall in expected productivity growth, b, is above a threshold, or, equivalently, if the natural interest rates,
If the economy is not in a liquidity trap, the output gap can be computed by eliminating π1 from (C.1) and (34). This gives
The equilibrium output gap is the minimum of these two expressions
Equation (16) for t = 1 can be written in logs as
that is,
The equilibrium level of Δph1 is the solution to this equation. In equilibrium, the economy falls into the liquidity trap if and only if the natural rate of interest rate falls below the level, denoted r, for which the two terms under the minimum are equal. This level is given by
Note that r > − π for Δph1 < π, so the fact that the liquidity trap is expected with some probability makes the liquidity trap happen more often. The threshold r for the natural interest rate corresponds to a threshold for b.
Note that equation (C.3) does not necessarily have a solution. In particular, a solution exists only if the probability of a liquidity trap is not too large.
To see this, assume that private agents know with certainty that the natural real interest rate will fall to a level
Conditional on these changes, the analysis presented in the main text remains essentially the same. The period-1 relationships remain (35) and (36), with π in (36) replaced by the level of Δph1 that satisfies (C.3). This complicates the algebra somewhat, but the discretion and commitment equilibria, as well as the impact of the central banker’s balance-sheet concerns, can be derived following the same steps as in Sections II E, II D, and IV.
IV. Central-Bank Assets Including Domestic Credit
With domestic credit, Dt ≥ 0, on the central bank’s balance sheet, we have to modify the domestic bond market equilibrium, (7), to be
(in which case the central bank holds privately issued bonds), or modify the government’s budget constraint to include bonds issued, interest on outstanding bounds, net transfers to the private sector, and the dividend received from the central bank. The central bank’s balance sheet, (6), is modified to
and the central bank’s capital is given by
which, using the first equation, can be rewritten:
It follows that, if the central bank does not distribute any dividend in period 2 and the economy was in a liquidity trap in period 1 (i1 = 0), the period-2 exchange rate satisfies
which generalizes (60). The lower bound on the right-hand-side must be equal to
which, together with i1 = 0 and Z2 = 0, implies that V1 must be equal to
References
Aghion, Philippe, Philippe Bacchetta and Abhijit Banerjee (2001), “Currency Crises and Monetary Policy in an Economy with Credit Constraints,” European Economic Review Vol. 45, pp. 1121–50.
Auerbach, Alan J., and Maurice Obstfeld (2003), “The Case for Open-Market Purchases in a Liquidity Trap,” NBER Working Paper No. 9814 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).
Bernanke, Ben S. (2003), Some Thoughts on Monetary Policy in Japan, speech on May 31, 2003, www.frb.gov.
Cargill, Thomas F. (2004), Price Stability, Capital Structure, and Bank of Japan Policy, working paper, University of Nevada.
Eggertsson, Gauti (2003), “How to Fight Deflation in a Liquidity Trap: Committing to Being Irresponsible,” IMF Working Paper WP/03/64 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Eggertsson, Gauti, and Michael Woodford (2003), “The Zero Bound on Interest Rates and Optimal Policy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 2003, pp. 139–233.
Ernhagen, Tomas, Magnus Vesterlund, and Staffan Viotti (2002), “How Much Equity Does a Central Bank Need?” Sveriges Riksbank Economic Review 2002: 2, 5–18.
Fukui, Toshihiko (2003), Challenges for Monetary Policy in Japan, speech on June 1, 2003, www.boj.or.jp/en/press/03/ko0306a.htm.
Grilli, Vittorio (1986), “Buying and Selling Attacks on Fixed Exchange Rate Systems,” Journal of International Economics 20, pp. 143–56.
Hawkins, John (2003), Central Bank Balance Sheets and Fiscal Operations, in Fiscal Issues and Central Banking in Emerging Economies, BIS Papers No. 20, Bank for International Settlements, Basel.
Isard, Peter (1994), “Realignment Expectations, Forward Rate Bias, and Sterilized Intervention in an Optimizing Model of Exchange Rate Adjustment,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 41, pp. 435–59.
Krugman, Paul (1998), “It’s Baaack! Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 1998, 137–87.
Leone, Alfredo M. (1994), Institutional and Operational Aspects of Central Bank Losses, in Balino, Tomas J.T., and Carlo Cottarelli, eds., Frameworks for Monetary Stability: Policy Issues and Country Experience, IMF, Washington, D.C., 738–755.
Pringle, Robert (2003), “Why Central Banks Need Capital,” Central Banking 14: 1, pp. 76–80.
Vaez-Zadeh, Reza (1991), Implications and Remedies of Central Bank Losses, in Downes, Patrick, and Reza Vaez-Zadeh, eds., The Evolving Role of Central Banks, IMF, Washington, D.C., 69–92.
Sims, Christopher (2001), Fiscal Aspects of Central Bank Independence, working paper, www.princeton.edu/~sims.
Stella, Peter (1997), “Do Central Banks Need Capital?” IMF Working Paper 97/83 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Stella, Peter (2002), “Central Bank Financial Strength, Transparency, and Policy Credibility,” IMF Working Paper 02/137 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Svensson, Lars E.O. (2001), “The Zero Bound in an Open-Economy: A Foolproof Way of Escaping from a Liquidity Trap,” Monetary and Economic Studies 19(S-1), Bank of Japan, 277–312.
Svensson, Lars E.O. (2003a), “Escaping from a Liquidity Trap and Deflation: The Foolproof Way and Others,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 174, pp. 145–66.
Svensson, Lars E.O. (2003b), “The Magic of the Exchange Rate: Optimal Escape from a Liquidity Trap in Small and Large Open Economies,” Working Paper www.princeton.edu/~svensson.
Zhu, Feng (2004), “Central Bank Balance Sheet Concerns, Monetary and Fiscal Rules, and Macroeconomic Stability,” Working Paper, pantheon.yale.edu/~fz9.
Olivier Jeanne is an Economist in the Research Department at the IMF. Lars Svensson is a Professor of Economics at Princeton University.
The Foolproof Way consists of announcing and implementing (1) a target path for the domestic price-level, starting above the current price level by the price gap that the central bank wishes to undo, (2) a currency depreciation and a crawling peg to achieve the price-level target path, and (3) an exit strategy in the form of abandoning the peg and shifting to flexible inflation or price-level targeting once the price-level target path has been reached.
Zhu (2004) presents a model with central-bank balance-sheet concerns in the context of a liquidity trap. The balance-sheet concerns, in the form of an instrument rule with the instrument rate responding to both inflation and the central-bank’s real capital, lead to indeterminacy of equilibrium and increase the risk of falling into a liquidity trap. He suggests automatic fiscal backing of monetary policy in order to avoid the indeterminacy.
For simplicity, the liquidity trap is assumed to last one period, the same as the horizon of the nominal stickiness. So although the model is in infinite time, the analysis of the liquidity trap will involve two periods.
One can show that the assumption of constant money supply is sufficient to ensure that no liquidity trap arises under flexible prices. An endogenous future money supply adjusted to maintaining low inflation may prevent an equilibrium and equality between output and potential output also under flexible prices; see footnote 15.
Since the central bank’s target level for output equals potential output, there will not be any average inflation bias in a discretion equilibrium.
Outside a liquidity trap, under commitment, the central bank would just set m1 and i1 such that
Each year, the central bank’s capital is increased or decreased by the amount of retained earnings or losses. Retained earnings are equal to the profit minus the dividend paid to the government and/or other shareholders. Although the accounting rules differ across central banks, the profit may include valuation changes on most assets, in particular, foreign-exchange reserves. When it does not, these valuation changes are included in a separate valuation account on the liability side of the balance sheet, which can be viewed as a component of the bank’s capital broadly defined.
The other risky asset held by central banks is gold. However, gold is generally not risky from an accounting point of view because of accounting rules that insulate the balance sheet from variations in its market price. Many countries ignore changes in the market price of gold by utilizing a historical price set in foreign currency (frequently the U.S. dollar or SDR). By contrast, foreign exchange reserves are generally valued at the market exchange rates.
The figure reports averages over 1999–2002, based on the annual reports of the central banks. Our measure of capital includes reserves and revaluation accounts. Details are available from the authors upon request.
Central banks in the Eurosystem have a valuation account on the liabilities side of their balance sheets as a reserve against valuation losses arising from changes in the exchange rate. This account reflects net gains from valuation changes that are not distributed but set aside as reserve against future losses from exchange rate changes. When a valuation loss due to a change in the exchange rate occurs, the amount of the loss is deducted from the balance of the valuation account. In case the balance of this account is insufficient to cover the loss, it is included in the profit-and-loss account.
Note the contrast with the currency mismatches that are the focus of the recent literature on international financial crises (Aghion, Bacchetta and Banerjee, 2001). There, domestic firms are indebted in foreign currency so that a depreciation reduces their net value.
The dividend payment,
This argument requires that the central bank stands ready to buy unlimited amounts of reserves. There is no cost for the bank of doing so, since money is neutral in the liquidity trap. If instead the central bank allowed the currency to appreciate when the level of reserves exceeds a certain level, there could be a speculative attack leading to an appreciation of the domestic currency (Grilli, 1986).
The nonexistence of equilibrium with a sufficiently high probability of a liquidity trap is related to the observation that monetary policy that keeps inflation expectations low may prevent an equilibrium also under flexible prices. As noted in footnote, the assumption of constant money supply is sufficient to ensure that no liquidity trap arises under flexible prices. With a constant future money supply, the future price level is exogenous. With flexible prices, a present negative output gap and hence a positive real interest-rate gap cause the present price level to fall. This increases expected inflation, reduces the interest-rate gap and increases the output gap. The present price level falls until the output and interest-rate gaps are zero. It follows that monetary policy that prevents inflation expectations from rising may prevent a flex-price equilibrium with a low natural interest rate.