Economic Integration, Sectoral Diversification, and Exchange Rate Policy in a Developing Economy
Author: Gabriel Srour1
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: gsrour@imf.org

The paper develops a simple three-sector model of a developing country with nominal wage rigidity, in which one sector is thought of as the primary sector and the other two are sectors in which the country can diversify. The paper then analyzes the relationship between the market structure of the nonprimary sectors and equilibrium adjustments to shocks in the primary sector. In particular, the paper examines under what conditions the country should promote one nonprimary sector over another. Among other things, it argues that developing countries should promote those sectors that are more integrated with the outside world

Abstract

The paper develops a simple three-sector model of a developing country with nominal wage rigidity, in which one sector is thought of as the primary sector and the other two are sectors in which the country can diversify. The paper then analyzes the relationship between the market structure of the nonprimary sectors and equilibrium adjustments to shocks in the primary sector. In particular, the paper examines under what conditions the country should promote one nonprimary sector over another. Among other things, it argues that developing countries should promote those sectors that are more integrated with the outside world

I. Introduction

The last twenty years have seen a strong movement towards globalization in the world. Driven by the advent of new information and communication technologies, and by failed experiments in the past, many countries, large and small, are moving away from an earlier protectionist stance towards greater liberalization. Others are seeking yet freer trade through economic and political agreements. In this new environment, questions about exchange rate, trade, and industrial policy have taken new urgency. This paper examines certain effects of economic integration on sectoral diversification and exchange rate policy in developing economies. In contrast, however, to the large body of recent literature, which, in light of the currency crises in the 1990s, examines the role of capital market liberalization,2 we focus on the effects of integration in the goods markets. This question deserves more attention as an increasing number of countries are taking steps to open their goods markets to trade.

Developing countries have traditionally relied on primary exports, such as agriculture or mining, to generate foreign currency. To name but a few, Colombia has relied on coffee and, more recently, oil. The share of coffee was almost 60 percent of total exports in 1970, and that of oil was about 10 percent. In 1999, the share of coffee dropped to about 10 percent, while that of oil increased to more than 30 percent. In Zambia, metals made up more than 90 percent of exports in 1990, although that share dropped to 60 percent in 2000. The oil and gas sector in Indonesia contributed more than 70 percent of exports at the end of the 1970s. That share subsequently dropped to less than 30 percent in the 1990s. It is therefore not surprising to find that developing countries are highly vulnerable to shocks to their primary sectors.

Indeed, primary exports have been subject, historically, to frequent and important exogenous shocks. The loss of income, and the ensuing balance of payments deficits, due to these shocks were especially destabilizing for developing countries, both in the short and long run.3 A natural and often-cited policy to enhance a country’s ability to adjust to such shocks is industrial diversification. But while countries like Indonesia have in the past two decades successfully diversified their industry into nontraditional sectors, others have barely reduced their reliance on primary exports. For these countries, diversification remains a difficult challenge, and the question which new industries to promote and invest in is particularly relevant.

Accordingly, we develop a three-sector model with nominal wage rigidity, of the type made popular in the recent New Keynesian open-economy literature. One sector is singled out and is thought of as the primary sector of the developing country. We evaluate policies primarily in terms of their ability to offset the effects of shocks to this sector. We allow for two nonprimary sectors in the model, rather than one, to examine under what conditions the developing country should promote one sector over another. The level of economic integration of a particular sector with the rest of the world is measured by the degree of elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign goods in that sector, and the volume of trade.

First, we show that the efficient exchange rate policy in the context of this model conforms to conventional wisdom. Specifically, following a negative shock to primary goods prices, the local currency must depreciate and, hence, domestic prices must rise, to offset the rigidity in wages. Then, we show that higher economic integration in the form of higher elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign goods helps to offset the effects of shocks to the primary sector and, therefore, enhances macroeconomic stability and induces less exchange rate volatility. In accordance with this result, we show also that a shift of resources from the less-integrated to the more-integrated nonprimary sector enhances stability in the same fashion.4

The implications of higher economic integration in the form of higher volume of trade are, however, less clear-cut, and depend on the source of higher trade. We show that a higher volume of trade in one nonprimary sector that stems from higher investment in that sector lessens the effects of shocks to the primary sector. A priori, the effects of a shift of resources from one nonprimary sector to the other are unclear, since this raises the volume of trade in one and lowers it in the other. We show, however, that a shift of resources to the sector with higher volume of trade enhances macroeconomic stability.

In contrast, a higher volume of trade that stems from a lower consumption of domestic goods, due, for instance, to access to a greater variety of foreign goods, 5 has ambiguous effects on economic stability. But, here too, we show that a shift of resources to the nonprimary sector with larger volume of trade enhances stability.

To sum up, under the three forms of economic integration mentioned above, a shift of resources from the less integrated to the more integrated sector enhances macroeconomic stability. Thus, if the shocks to the primary sectors are substantial, then the home country would be better off investing in a single nonprimary sector. Naturally, if the shocks to the nonprimary sectors are nonnegligible, then further diversification may be called for.

Spurred by the work of Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995, 1996), the past decade has seen widespread application of New Keynesian open-economy models to the study of monetary and exchange rate policy.6 These models have been extended to examine the implications of alternative specifications regarding, for instance, the type of rigidities, the price-setting mechanism, and the size of the economy.7 But the question of sectoral diversification, and its relation with economic integration and exchange rate policy, has not been considered. Indeed, the models employed so far have usually involved symmetric, one-sector (albeit monopolistic-competitive) economies, which are not suited to analyze this question. The studies that come closest to our work are two papers by Tille. Using essentially one-sector representations of the home and foreign countries, Tille (1999) examines the effects of country-wide changes in the elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign goods on the exchange rate policy. Tille (2002) considers a two-sector model, but his focus is on the relation between industry specialization and exchange rate policy, and the model does not allow for differences in the elasticities of substitution or the volumes of trade between the two sectors.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. We describe the model in Section II and derive the equilibrium in Section III. In Section IV, we discuss the case where prices of all goods are exogenously given in the world market, and in Section V, we discuss the case where the prices of domestic nonprimary goods are endogenous. We conclude in Section VI.

II. The Baseline Model

The model is intended to describe the economic setting in many developing countries, if not many small open economies in general. In the model, a developing country, labeled 0, is represented as trading with the rest of the world, labeled 1. The home economy consists of three sectors, X, A, and B. The sector X is singled out, and is referred to as the primary sector. It stands, for example, for an oil or other primary commodities sector, agriculture, textile, or even a tourism sector, whose products are generally low in the production chain and very similar to foreign-made goods. Typically, such a sector makes up a large share of the developing country’s exports, and is subject to frequent and important shocks. Accordingly, in this paper, we will be mostly concerned with the effects of shocks to prices in this sector. We allow for two nonprimary sectors, A and B, in the model, rather than one, to examine under what conditions the developing country should promote one sector over another.

All goods can be traded.8 Home-produced and foreign-produced primary goods are assumed to be perfect substitutes for each other, whereas nonprimary goods are differentiated according to the country of origin. The model is static in that it admits only one period.

A. Households

Households in the home economy are identical and their total number is assumed constant and normalized to 1. The periodic utility of a household is

11σC1σ11ϕN1+ϕ+χLn(MP)(1)

where N is the number of hours worked, MP are real money balances held, and C is consumption of a composite of goods from the various sectors and countries:

C=(CXγX)γX(CAγA)γA(CBγB)γB,γX+γA+γB=1,(2)
CA=[γ0A1ηC0Aη1η+γ1A1ηC1Aη1η]ηη1,γ0A+γ1A=1,(3)
CB=[γ0B1vC0Bν1v+γ1B1νC1Bν1v]νν1,γ0B+γ1B=1,(4)

CX denotes consumption of primary goods, and Cli, (l = 0,1, i = A, B), denotes consumption of goods produced in country l of type i. The elasticity of substitution, η(ν), between home-produced and foreign-produced A-goods (B-goods) is assumed to be greater than or equal to the elasticity of substitution between goods across different sectors, which, given the Cobb-Douglas specification, equals 1.9

Households choose consumption goods and money balances after shocks are realized, subject to the budget constraint

PXCX+liPliCli+M=R+Π+T+M1,(5)

where Π denotes dividends, M−1 is the initial stock of money balances held, T is lump-sum transfers (equal to the increase in money balances MM−1), PX is the price of primary goods, Pli (l = 0,1, i = A, B), is the price of goods produced in country l of type i, and R is the household’s income from labor, all measures denominated in local currency.

The price index of i-goods, Pi, and the aggregate price index, P, are defined as follows10

PA=[γ0APHA1η+γ1AP1A1η]11η,(6)
PB=[γ0BPHB1ν+γ1BP1B1ν]11ν,(7)

and

P=PXγXPAγAPBγB.(8)

Standard optimization implies that a household’s holding of money balances and expenditures on the various types of goods are:

PiCi=γiPC,(i=X,A,B),(9)
PlAClA=γlA(PlAPA)1ηPACA,(l=0,1)(10)
PlBClB=γlB(PlBPB)1νPBCB,(l=0,1)(11)

and

MP=χCσ.(12)

B. Production

All domestic firms are identical and have decreasing returns-to-scale technologies. Production requires a continuum of differentiated types of labor, j, uniformly distributed over the unit interval (j[0,1]). Each household is associated with one type of labor, and the number of households of each type is constant and equal to 1.

Specifically,

Yi=11αAiLi1α,0α<1,(13)
Li=(01li(j)λ1λdj)λλ1,λ1,(14)

where Yi denotes output by a firm in sector i, li (j) is labor input of type j, and Ai is a sector-wide technological shock equal to 1 in steady state.

Firms take prices and wages as given and choose their volume of output after shocks are realized. Profit maximization therefore implies that demand by a firm in sector i for labor is

LX=[AXPXWX]1α,Li=[AiP0iWi]1α(i=A,B) and li(j)=[WiWi(j)]λLi,(15)

where Wi (j) is the wage for labor of type j in sector i, and Wi is the wage-index for labor employed in sector i,11

Wi=(01Wi(j)1λdj)11λ.(16)

Naturally, the higher the effective markup over wages, the larger the output and the larger the demand for labor.

C. Price and Wage Setting

We assume throughout that the law of one price holds for all goods. Furthermore, on the basis that the domestic market is small, the prices of primary goods and all foreign goods are assumed to be determined in the world market and exogenously given. We will consider, however, both the case where the price of home-produced nonprimary goods is exogenously given and the case where it is endogenously determined.

Labor is assumed to be perfectly mobile across firms and sectors. Households of the same type share equally all their resources and jointly fix their wages at the beginning of the period, before shocks are realized, and without discrimination as to the firm or sector of employment. Accordingly, households of the same type earn the same wage and share labor equally.

Maximization of expected utility implies

W(j)=λλ1E[l(j)1+ϕ]E[l(j)PC(j)σ],(17)

where E is the expectation operator, l(j) denotes the total demand for labor per household of type j, and C(j) is consumption per household of type j.

Under the model specification, wages are rigid in the sense that they cannot readjust after shocks are realized. We view, however, the outcome under flexible wages (that is, the outcome that obtain if wages could adjust after shocks are realized) as the benchmark that policymakers seek to approximate.

Optimization under flexible wages leads to an identical formula for wages as the one above without the expectation operator, e.g.,

W(j)P=λλ1C(j)σl(j)ϕ.(18)

D. Long-Run Shares of Trade

Consistent with the fact that wages are equal across sectors, and firms have identical technologies and take prices and wages as given, prices of all goods are assumed to be equal in steady state. It follows that all domestic firms produce the same output, Y¯, in steady state, and

C¯li=γliC¯i,(l=0,1),(i=A,B),(19)
C¯i=γiC¯,(i=X,A,B),(20)
C¯=nY¯,(21)

where bar superscripts denote steady-state values, ni is the number of firms in sector i, and n = nX + nA + nB is the total number of firms in the home country.

The (long-run) share of net exports of primary goods in total output is therefore

αXnXY¯XC¯XnY¯=nXnγX;(22)

the share of exports of nonprimary goods is

α0iniY¯iC¯0inY¯=ninγ0iγi,(i=A,B),(23)

while the share of imports of nonprimary goods is

α1i=C¯1inY¯=γ1iγi,(i=A,B).(24)

Since there is only one period, the share of total imports of nonprimary goods, αM, must balance the share of total exports

α1A+α1B+α2A+α2B=αX+α0A+α0B.(25)

III. Equilibrium

We focus on symmetric equilibriums, whereby all households and all firms within a sector have identical outcomes. Under these circumstances, households of all types earn the same wage, W, supply the same amount of labor, L, and consume the same baskets of goods, C. In equilibrium, total supply of labor must equal total demand, and total expenditures must equal total income. In other words,

L=nXLX+nALA+nBLB,(26)

and

PC=nXPXYX+nAP0AYA+nBP0BYB.(27)

Substituting the expressions for labor demand, Li, and output, Yi, by a firm in sector i, it follows,

L=Ω[PW]1α,(28)
C=11αΩ[PW]1αα,(29)

and

MP=χ(1α)σΩσ[PW]σ(1α)α,(30)

where

Ω=nX[AXPXP]1α+nA[AAP0AP]1α+nB[ABP0BP]1α.(31)

The system of equations above is “closed” by adding the equation for wages and specifying a rule for the money supply.

A. Flexible Wages

Under flexible wages, WP=λλ1CσLϕ. Substituting the expressions for C and L found above, it follows

(WP)Θ=(11α)ασ(λλ1)αΩα(ϕ+σ),(32)
CΘ=(11α)α+ϕ(λ1λ)1αΩα(1+ϕ),(33)
LΘ=(1α)σ(λ1λ)Ωα(1σ),(34)

where,

Θ=α+ϕ+σ(1α).(35)

Of course, under flexible wages, money is neutral and has no real effect on the economy.

B. Predetermined Wages

Under predetermined wages,

W=λλ1E[L1+ϕ]E[LPCσ].(36)

Now, monetary policy can be used to reproduce the level of real wages that obtains under flexible wages. For this it suffices that the money supply be set so that

PΘ=(11α)ασ(λλ1)αΩα(ϕ+σ)WΘ,(37)

hence

MΘ=χΘ(11α)σϕ(λ1λ)α+σ(1α)Ωαϕ(σ1)WΘ.(38)

To the extent that, under both flexible and predetermined wages, the rest of the aggregate variables depend in the same fashion on real wages, this monetary policy rule would achieve with predetermined wages the same equilibrium outcome that obtains under flexible wages, and is therefore considered efficient. Unless stated otherwise, this monetary policy is assumed to be implemented from now on.

Accordingly, under both flexible and predetermined wages, the behavior of the macro variables is governed by the behavior of Ω alone. To a first-order approximation, in terms of log-deviations from steady state, we have

αΩ^=nXn(p^Xfp^f)+nAn(p^0Afp^f)+nBn(p^0Bfp^f)+nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn=αXp^Xf+(α0Ap^0Afα1Ap^1Af)+(α0Bp^0Bfα1Bp^1Bf)+nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn(39)

where f superscripts denote prices denominated in foreign currency, and hat superscripts denote log-deviations from steady state. Abstracting from technological shocks, αΩ^ amounts to the effect of price changes on income from foreign trade. Thus, not surprisingly, the composition of trade has a bearing on the desired monetary policy and efficient equilibrium adjustments to shocks only through the effects on income from foreign trade.

The desired monetary policy rule described above can be expressed equivalently as an exchange rate policy rule:

s^=p^fp^=(γX+(ϕ+σ)ΘαX)p^Xf+(γAγ0A+(ϕ+σ)Θα0A)p^0Af+(γBγ0B+(ϕ+σ)Θα0B)p^0Bf+(γAγ1A(ϕ+σ)Θα1A)p^1Af+(γBγ1B(ϕ+σ)Θα1B)p^1Bf+(ϕ+σ)ΘnXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn(40)

where s is the nominal exchange rate (expressed as the price of a unit of domestic currency in foreign currency).

To complete the derivation of the equilibrium, we need to determine the relative prices of goods. We consider first the case where prices of all goods (denominated in foreign currency) are determined exogenously in the world market.

IV. All Prices Exogenously Given

Note first that if all prices are exogenously given, then the effect of a domestic technological innovation on Ω, and, hence, on the monetary policy response and economic equilibrium, is independent from the composition of trade in the home country. A positive technological shock12 leads to an increase in income, consumption, real wages, and real balances. To achieve the higher real wages, local prices must fall, which is achieved by not allowing the money stock to rise proportionately to output. Employment may increase if the substitution effect of the shock exceeds the income effect, i.e., if σ < 1.

Consider now shocks to world prices. Assuming that such shocks are sector-wide and prices within each sector move in tandem,13 Ω, and hence, all macro variables, are least volatile when there is balanced trade within each sector, i.e., αX = 0 and α0i = α1i (i = A, B). Under these circumstances, any change in income from exports is exactly offset by an equal change in the cost of imports.

Such a state of affairs is, however, unrealistic because of inherited endowments in capital and resources.14 Accordingly, we assume from now on that the home country is a net exporter of primary goods, i.e., αX ≥ 0, and we examine the effects of a change in the world price of primary goods, other (foreign-currency-denominated) prices kept constant.

Then, αΩ^=αXp^Xf.15 A drop in the foreign price of primary goods, p^Xf, entails a drop in income from exports of primary goods, and hence, a drop in real wages and aggregate consumption. The lower cost of labor induces output and employment in the nonprimary sectors to increase, and thus to partly offset the lower income from exports of primary goods.

The effect on employment and output in the primary sector, however, depends on the model’s parameters: the larger the effect of the shock on income (i.e., the larger the share of exports of primary goods, αX), the smaller the capacity in the nonprimary sectors to absorb new labor (i.e., the steeper the decrease in returns to scale, α), the larger the income effect relative to the substitution effect as incorporated in the household’s utility function (i.e., the smaller the parameter ϕ and the larger the parameter σ), then, the smaller the drop (if any) in employment and output in the primary sector. If σ ≤ 1, then the substitution effect of a drop in wages on the household’s utility dominates the income effect, and output and employment in the primary sector unambiguously decrease as wages decline less than the relative price of primary goods. If σ > 1, then output and employment in the primary sector can actually increase (see appendix for a formal proof). In any case, as can be seen from the expression of L in terms of Ω, aggregate labor always decreases if σ < 1 following a drop in primary goods prices, and increases if σ > 1.16

With regard to the exchange rate, we have

s^=(γX+(ϕ+σ)ΘαX)p^Xf(41)

Not surprisingly, this policy (which achieves with predetermined wages the same equilibrium outcome that obtains under flexible wages) calls for a depreciation of the local currency following a drop in the relative price of primary goods. This is intended to raise the price level above its steady state and achieve the downward adjustment in real wages that would obtain if wages were flexible.

The higher the volatility of prices in the primary sector, the larger the relative size of the primary sector (and, hence the larger the share of exports, αX, the share of domestic consumption, γX, being kept equal), the smaller the capacity in the nonprimary sectors to absorb new labor, i.e., the steeper the decrease in returns to scale, α, the greater the effect of a price change on income, and the larger the ensuing change in real wages if wages were flexible. Hence, the greater the required adjustment in the exchange rate, and the greater the need for a flexible exchange rate.

However, a higher share of exports that stems from lower consumption of local primary goods,17 would call for a more flexible exchange rate policy if, and only if, ϕ+σΘ>1, i.e., if σ > 1.18 In that case, as shown earlier, households are willing to accept low enough real wages to actually increase labor following the negative shock to income.

Note that the composition and volume of trade within the nonprimary sectors do not affect the conclusions above. Thus, to the extent that shocks to the nonprimary sectors can be neglected (and prices are exogenous), the market structure of the nonprimary sectors has no bearing on economic stability or monetary policy.

V. Prices of Home-Produced Nonprimary Goods Endogenous

Assume now that prices of primary goods and foreign–produced goods are still determined in the world market and exogenously given, but prices of home-produced nonprimary goods adjust to equate supply and demand. The rationale is that whereas it is too small to influence prices of primary goods and foreign-produced goods, the developing country may account for a significant share of the market (demand or supply) for home-produced goods, and can, therefore, influence their prices. As a consequence, prices of domestic nonprimary goods will also reflect the costs of domestic inputs, i.e., wages.

Specifically, in analogy with domestic demand, we suppose that foreign demand for home-produced nonprimary goods is as follows,

C0Af=α0AnY¯(PflevelPAf)μA(P0APA)η,(42)

and

C0Bf=α0BnY¯(PflevelPBf)μB(P0BPB)ν,(43)

where C0if, (i = A, B), denotes foreign consumption of home-produced i-goods, α0i and α0inY¯ are, respectively, the share and volume of exports of i-goods in steady state, Pflevel is the foreign aggregate price-level (not to confuse with the domestic aggregate price-level denominated in foreign currency, Pf), and μi is the elasticity of substitution between i-goods and other goods in the foreign country. Whereas the elasticity of substitution between i-goods and other goods equals 1 in the domestic country, μi can be greater than 1 to reflect, for instance, that the foreign country may have access to other goods not available in the home country. The elasticity of substitution between home-produced and foreign-produced i-goods is, however, the same, e.g., η or ν. Pflevel is assumed to be exogenously given, and unaffected by changes in the price of primary goods.19 This, combined with the fact that μi can be greater than 1, entails that the price elasticity of foreign demand for home-produced nonprimary goods is larger than that of domestic demand. Again, all prices are assumed equal in steady state.

In equilibrium, prices of home-produced nonprimary goods adjust to equate demand with supply:

C0i+C0if=niYi,(i=A,B),(44)

hence

γ0A(P0APA)ηCA+α0AnY¯(PflevelPAf)μA(P0APA)η=nAYA,(45)

which, after substituting the expressions for CA and YA, becomes

γ0AγAPPAC+α0AnY¯(PflevelPAf)μA=nA11αAA1α(P0APA)η[P0AW]1αα.(46)

Similarly, for B-goods, we get

γ0BγBPPBC+α0BnY¯(PflevelPBf)μB=nB11αAB1α(P0BPB)ν[P0BW]1αα.(47)

Keeping prices of foreign-produced goods constant, the system of equations above can be solved for p^0Af and p^0Bf and, hence, for Ω^ and s^. Specifically, one finds20

Λp^0Af=Πp^Xf(48)
Λp^0Bf=Γp^Xf(49)
αΩ^=Kp^Xf(50)

and

s^=Hp^Xf(51)

where Λ, Γ, Π, H, and K are coefficients that depend on the model’s parameters, and the behavior of which can be examined numerically.21

The equilibrium adjustment to a negative shock to primary goods prices (and the role of the parameters α, ϕ, and σ) are similar to those when all prices are exogenously given. In particular, the domestic currency must depreciate to allow real wages to fall and thus ease the shock to output and employment. The extra spin in this case is that the larger domestic output in the nonprimary goods sector induced by the depreciation can be liquidated only if the relative price of home-produced to foreign-produced nonprimary goods, P0iPi, falls. This particular effect entails that the market structure in the nonprimary sector has a bearing on economic adjustments to shocks and stability.

Leaving the primary sector, that is, nX, γX, and αX, unchanged, one can show:

1. The higher the elasticities of substitutions η, ν, μA, and μB, the lower the coefficients K and H. The reason is that the higher elasticities of substitution entail a smaller drop in the relative price of domestic nonprimary goods and, hence, a smaller loss of income from exports, following a negative shock to the price of primary goods. Thus, higher economic integration, in the form of higher elasticities of substitution, η, ν, μA, and μB, enhances stability of the aggregate variables as well as that of the exchange rate.

2. All else being equal between the two nonprimary sectors (except the elasticities of substitution, η, ν, μA, and μB), a reallocation of resources from the nonprimary sector with smaller elasticities to the one with larger elasticities enhances the stability of the aggregate variables. Numerically, one shows that at the point where the two sectors are symmetric in all but the elasticities of substitution, η, ν (resp. μA, and μB), KnA (keeping the total number of firms n fixed) has the opposite sign of (ην) (resp. μAμB).

This proposition takes a stronger form in the extreme case where there is no local demand for domestic nonprimary goods (i.e., γ0A = γ0B = 0). Then, K decreases continuously as more resources are reallocated from the nonprimary sector with smaller elasticity of substitution to the one with larger elasticity of substitution. In general, however, K traces a bell shape as nA increases from 0 to n. The reason is provided in the following result.

3. All else being equal between the two nonprimary sectors (except their sizes and shares of exports), the aggregate variables are more stable when resources are concentrated in one sector. Put differently, higher investment in the sector with higher volume of trade enhances macroeconomic stability. The reason is that, in both cases, demand for domestic products is relatively more price elastic. Hence, income is less affected by negative shocks. Numerically, K is largest when nA = nB, and K decreases as one or the other nonprimary sector grows larger relative to the other.

The reason is that the nonprimary sector with more capital (i.e., more firms) devotes a larger share of its output to exports. Because exports are more price elastic than local consumption, prices change relatively less in that sector and, hence, cause a relatively smaller change in income from trade following a shock. (In the extreme case where there is no local demand for home-produced nonprimary goods, i.e., γ0A = γ0B = 0, stability is unaffected by the relative size of the sectors.)

Whether greater concentration of resources in one sector calls for a more or less flexible exchange rate depends on the model’s parameters. Typically,22 a higher concentration of resources in one sector calls for a more flexible exchange rate policy if (ϕ+σ)Θ>1, i.e., if σ > 1.

4. All else being equal, a higher volume of trade in a nonprimary sector that stems from a lower share of domestic consumption of home- relative to foreign-produced goods in that sector23 requires smaller adjustments in the exchange rate following shocks. The effect on aggregate variables is, however, ambiguous (K traces a bell curve as the volume of trade increases).

The reason is that, since foreign demand for domestic goods is more elastic than local demand, the larger the share of exports relative to local consumption, the smaller the decrease in the relative price of domestic nonprimary goods, and, hence, the smaller the drop in real wages. The effect on income from trade is, however, ambiguous, since the volume of exports if higher.

Nonetheless, a shift of resources from the sector with smaller volume of trade, say B, to the one with larger volume of trade, say A, lowers volatility. (Numerically, one shows that at the point where the two sectors are symmetric in all but the volume of trade, KnA<0 if sector A has larger volume of trade.) The reason is that the shift of resources to sector A causes domestic prices in that sector to drop less following a negative shock to primary goods. This will have a first-order benefit, because sector A already devotes a larger volume of its output to exports than sector B.

VI. Conclusion

The paper examines certain effects of economic integration on sectoral diversification and exchange rate policy in developing economies. It develops a three-sector model with nominal wage rigidity, whereby one sector is thought of as the primary sector of the developing country, and the other two are sectors in which the country can diversify. The paper then examines the relationship between the market structure of the nonprimary sectors and macroeconomic adjustments to shocks in the primary sector. In particular, it examines under what conditions the developing country should promote one nonprimary sector over another.

It is shown first that the efficient exchange rate policy in the context of this model conforms to conventional wisdom: the local currency must depreciate following a negative shock to primary goods prices to offset the rigidity in wages and limit the increase in unemployment. Then, it is shown that higher economic integration, whether in the form of higher elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign goods, or in the form of higher volume of trade that stems from higher investment in export-oriented industries, lessens the effects of shocks to the primary sector and enhances macroeconomic stability. The reason is that, in both cases, economic integration makes demand for domestic products relatively more price elastic. Hence, income is less affected by negative shocks.

However, higher economic integration in the form of a higher volume of trade that stems from a drop in the domestic consumption of home goods relative to foreign goods has ambiguous effects on macroeconomic stability. The higher volume of trade implies a more price elastic demand for home goods and, hence, promotes stability, but it also implies greater effects on income from trade following shocks, which impairs stability. Nonetheless, in all three forms of economic integration, a shift of resources from the less-integrated to the more-integrated nonprimary sector is shown to enhance macroeconomic stability.

In sum, if the shocks to the primary sector dominate other shocks, then the home country may be better off investing in a single nonprimary sector. If the nonprimary sectors are also subject to important shocks, then further diversification may be called for.

APPENDIX Detailed Derivation of the Equilibrium

Recall, in equilibrium,

L=Ω[PW]1α,(1)
C=11αΩ[PW]1αα,(2)
LX=[AXPXPPW]1α,Li=[AiP0iPPW]1α,(i=A,B),(3)

and

MP=χ(1α)σΩσ[PW]σ(1α)α,(4)

where

Ω=nX[AXPXP]1α+nA[AAP0AP]1α+nB[ABP0BP]1α,(5)

or in log-deviations from steady state,

αΩ^=nXn(p^Xfp^f)+nAn(p^0Afp^f)+nBn(p^0Bfp^f)+nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn=αXp^Xf+(α0Ap^0Afα1Ap^1Af)+(α0Bp^0Bfα1Bp^1Bf)+nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn(6)

Under flexible wages

(WP)Θ=(11α)ασ(λλ1)αΩα(ϕ+σ),(7)
CΘ=(11α)α+ϕ(λ1λ)1αΩα(1+ϕ),(8)
LΘ=(1α)σ(λ1λ)Ωα(1σ),(9)
Y¯Θ=(11α)α+ϕ((λ1λ)nα(1σ))1α(10)
LX=[AXPXPPW]1α,Li=[AiP0iPPW]1α(i=A,B)(11)

where

Θ=α+ϕ+σ(1α).(12)

Thus, to reproduce with predetermined wages the level of real wages that obtains under flexible wages, it suffices to set the money supply so that

PΘ=(11α)ασ(λλ1)αΩα(ϕ+σ)WΘ.(13)

Substituting this expression in that of real money balances provided above, it follows

MΘ=χΘ(11α)σϕ(λ1λ)α+σ(1α)Ωαϕ(σ1)WΘ.(14)

Alternatively, using the representations of P, Pf, and Ω, in log-deviations, e.g.,

p^=(ϕ+σ)ΘαΩ^,(15)

and

p^f=γXp^Xf+γAγ0Ap^0Af+γAγ1Ap^1Af+γBγ0Bp^0Bf+γBγ1Bp^1Bf,(16)

the monetary policy rule above can be expressed in the form,

s^=p^fp^=(γX+(ϕ+σ)ΘαX)p^Xf+(γAγ0A+(ϕ+σ)Θα0A)p^0Af+(γBγ0B+(ϕ+σ)Θα0B)p^0Bf+(γAγ1A(ϕ+σ)Θα1A)p^1Af+(γBγ1B(ϕ+σ)Θα1B)p^1Bf+(ϕ+σ)ΘnXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn(17)

where s is the nominal exchange rate (expressed as the price of a unit of domestic currency in foreign currency).

A. All Prices Exogenously Given

Under flexible wages, the markup of prices over wages in the primary goods sector, in logdeviation from steady state (with prices of nonprimary goods kept constant) is

p^Xw^=p^Xfp^f+p^w^=(1γX(ϕ+σ)Θ(nXnγX))p^Xf.(18)

If σ ≤ 1, then ϕ+σΘ=ϕ+σϕ+σ+α(1σ)1 and p^Xw^ has the same sign as p^Xf (since 1γXnXnγX). In other words, a drop in the price of primary goods induces a smaller drop in wages. It follows that, in this case, output and labor in the primary goods sector, as well as aggregate labor, unambiguously decrease with a decrease in the relative price of primary goods. If σ > 1, however, then ϕ+σΘ>1 and the sign of p^Xw^ is ambiguous. Simple derivatives show that the larger is α, the smaller is ϕ, and the larger is σ, the larger is ϕ+σΘ, and, hence, the smaller is 1γXϕ+σΘ(nXnγX), the larger the drop in wages, and the more likely are p^Xw^ and p^Xf of opposite signs.

Likewise, the larger the share of exports of primary goods, αX=nXnγX, the smaller is 1γXϕ+σΘ(nXnγX), the smaller the drop (if any) in labor and output in the primary goods sector, and the more likely is labor and output in this sector to actually increase following a decline in the relative price of primary goods.

B. Prices of Home-Produced Nonprimary Goods Endogenous

Equality between supply and demand of home-produced nonprimary goods imply

γ0AγAPPAC+α0AnY¯(PflevelPAf)μA=nA11αAA1α(P0APA)η[P0AW]1αα(19)

hence

γ0AγAPPAC+α0AnY¯(PflevelPAf)μA=nA11αAA1α(P0APA)1α+αηα[PAP]1αα[PW]1αα.(20)

Substituting the expressions for C and PW, it follows

γ0AγAPPA(11α)α+ϕΘ(λ1λ)1αΘΩα(1+ϕ)Θ+α0AnY¯(PflevelPAf)μA=nA(11α)α+ϕΘAA1α(P0APA)1α+αηα[PAP]1αα(λλ1)1αΘΩα(1+ϕ)Θ1(21)

Taking log-deviations from the steady state, and recalling nY¯=(11α)α+ϕΘ(λ1λ)1αΘnα(1+ϕ)Θ,

γ0AγAγ0AγA+α0A[p^p^A+α(1+ϕ)ΘΩ^]+α0Aγ0AγA+α0AμA[p^flevelp^Af]=1αa^A+1α+αηα(p^0Ap^A)+1αα[p^Ap^]+(α(1+ϕ)Θ1)Ω^(22)

hence

(1αα0AnnA)[p^p^A]+α0AnnAμA[p^flevelp^Af]=1αa^A+1α+αηα(p^0Ap^A)+(α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA1)Ω^(23)

Substituting the expression for Ω^, expanding the various price indexes into its constituents, and using the fact that the foreign price-level, p^flevel, is insignificantly affected by the shocks under consideration, we have

[(1αα0AnnA)γAγ0A+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)α0A1α((η1)(1γ0A)+α0AnnA(μA1)γ0A)]p^0Af+[(1αα0AnnA)γBγ0B+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)α0B]p^0Bf=[(1αα0AnnA)γX+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)αX]p^Xf+((1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+1α(24)

and the corresponding equation for B-goods is

[(1αα0BnnB)γAγ0A+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)α0A]p^0Af+[(1αα0BnnB)γBγ0B+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)α0B1α((ν1)(1γ0B)+α0BnnB(μB1)γ0B)]p^0Bf[(1αα0BnnB)γX+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)αX]p^Xf+((1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+1α(25)

The system of two equations above can be solved to provide expressions for p0Af,p0Bf as functions of pXf and the technological shocks:

Λp0Af=ΠpXf+N(26)
Λp0Bf=ΓpXf+T(27)

where

Λ=Λ(nA,nB)=[(1αα0AnnA)γAγ0A+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)α0A][(1αα0BnnB)γBγ0B+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)α0B][(1αα0AnnA)γBγ0B+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)α0B][(1αα0BnnB)γAγ0A+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)α0A][(1αα0AnnA)γAγ0A+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)α0A][1α+((ν1)(1γ0B)+α0BnnB(μB1)γ0B)][(1αα0BnnB)γBγ0B+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)α0B][1α+((η1)(1γ0A)+α0AnnA(μA1)γ0A)]+[1α+((η1)(1γ0A)+α0AnnA(μA1)γ0A)][1α+((ν1)(1γ0B)+α0BnnB(μB1)γ0B)]=1α(1(1+ϕ)Θ)(α0AnnAα0BnnB)(α0AγBγ0BγAγ0Aα0B)[(1αα0AnnA)γAγ0A+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)α0A][1α+((ν1)(1γ0B)+α0BnnB(μB1)γ0B)][(1αα0BnnB)γBγ0B+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)α0B][1α+((η1)(1γ0A)+α0AnnA(μA1)γ0A)]+[1α+((η1)(1γ0A)+α0AnnA(μA1)γ0A)][1α+((ν1)(1γ0B)+α0BnnB(μB1)γ0B)](28)
Π=[1α((1+ϕ)Θ1)(α0AnnAα0BnnB)](γBγ0BαXα0BγX)p^Xf+[1α+((ν1)(1γ0B)+α0BnnB(μB1)γ0B)][(1αα0AnnA)γX+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)αX]p^Xf(29)
Γ=[1α(1+ϕΘ1)(α0BnnBα0AnnA)](γAγ0AαXα0AγX)p^Xf+[1α+((η1)(1γ0A)+α0AnnA(μA1)γ0A)][(1αα0BnnB)γX+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)αX]p^Xf,(30)
N=[(1αα0BnnB)γBγ0B+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)α0B][((1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+1αa^A][(1αα0AnnA)γBγ0B+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)α0B][((1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+1αa^B]+[1α((ν1)(1γ0B)+α0BnnB(μB1)γ0B)][((1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+1αa^A](31)
T=[1α((η1)(1γ0A)+α0AnnA(μA1)γ0A)][((1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+1αa^B]+[(1αα0AnnA)γAγ0A+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)α0A][((1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+1αa^B][(1αα0BnnB)γAγ0A+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)α0A][((1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+1αa^A](32)

Substituting the expressions above into Ω, it follows

αΩ^=Kp^Xf+Q, and s^=Hp^Xf+R,

where

K=K(nA,nB)=αX+1ααXΛ(1+ϕΘ1)(α0AnnAα0BnnB)(α0AγBγ0Bα0BγAγ0A)+α0BΛ[1α+((η1)(1γ0A)+α0AnnA(μA1)γ0A)][(1αα0BnnB)γX+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB)αX+α0AΛ[1α+((ν1)(1γ0B)+α0BnnB(μB1)γ0B)][(1αα0AnnA)γX+(1α(1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA)αX(33)
Q=α0ANΛ+α0BTΛ+nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn=1Λ[(1αα0BnnB)(α0AγBγ0Bα0BγAγ0A)1αα0A][((1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn1Λ[(1αα0AnnA)(α0AγBγ0Bα0BγAγ0A)+1αα0B][((1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+α0AΛ[((ν1)(1γ0B)+α0BnnB(μB1)γ0B)][((1+ϕ)Θα0AnnA1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+.+α0BΛ[((η1)(1γ0A)+α0AnnA(μA1)γ0A)][((1+ϕ)Θα0BnnB1α)nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn+.+nXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn(34)
H=γX+γAγ0AΠΛ+γBγ0BΓΛ+(ϕ+σ)ΘK(35)
R=(γAγ0A+ϕ+σΘα0A)NΛ+(γBγ0B+α0Bϕ+σΘ)TΛ+(ϕ+σ)ΘnXa^X+nAa^A+nBa^Bn(36)

The behavior of K and H in relation to the model’s parameters, such as the elasticities of substitution and the volume of trade, is examined numerically, although, in some special cases, one can provide analytical arguments.24

References

  • Aghion, P., P. Bacchetta, and A. Banerjee, 1999, “Capital Markets and the Instability of Open Economies,” CEPR Discussion Paper 2083 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Betts, C., and M.B. Devereux, 1996, “The Exchange rate in a Model of Pricing to Market.” European Economic Review, Vol. 40 No. 3–5, pp. 721.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bowman, D., and B. Doyle, 2003, “New Keynesian, Open-Economy Models and Their Implications for Monetary Policy,” International Finance Discussion Papers No. 762 (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cashin, P., H. Liang, and C. J. McDermott, 2000, “How Persistent are Shocks to World Commodity Prices,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 47, No. 2 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cashin, P., C. J. McDermott, and A. Scott, 2002, “Booms and Slumps in World Commodity Prices,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 66, pp. 277296.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cashin, P., and C. J. McDermott, 2002, “The Long-Run Behavior of Commodity Prices: Small Trends and Big Volatility,” Staff Papers, IMF, Vol. 47, No. 2 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clarida, R., J. Gali and M. Gertler, 2001, “Optimal Monetary Policy in Open versus Closed economies: An Integrated Approach,” American Economic Review Vol. 91, No. 2, pp. 24852.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Collier, P., and J. Dehn, 2001, “Aid, Shocks, and Growth,” World Bank Working Paper 2688 (Washington: World Bank).

  • Collier, P., J. W. Gunning, and Associates, 2000, “Trade Shocks in Developing Countries,” (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

  • Corsetti, G., and P. Pesenti, 2002, “Self validating Optimum Currency Areas,” NBER Working Paper No. 8783 (National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devereux, M.B., and C. Engel, 1998, “Fixed vs. Floating Exchange Rates: How Price Setting Affects the Optimal Choice of Exchange-Rate Regime,” NBER Working Paper No. 6867 (National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devereux, M.B., and C. Engel, 2000, “Monetary Policy in the Open Economy Revisited: Price Setting and Exchange rate Flexibility,” NBER Working Paper No. 7665 (National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edison H., 2002, “Capital Account Liberalization and Economic Performance: Survey and Synthesis,” NBER Working Paper No. 9100 (National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gali, J., and T. Monacelli, 2002, “Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy,” NBER Working paper No. 8905 (National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Knight, Malcolm, 1998, “Developing Countries and the Globalization of Financial markets,” IMF Working Paper 98/105 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lane, P.R., 2001, “The New Open Economy Macroeconomics,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 54, pp. 23566.

  • Obstfeld, M., 2001, “International macroeconomics: Beyond the Mundell-Fleming Model,” IMF Staff Papers, Special Issue 47, pp. 139 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff, 1995, “Exchange Rate Dynamics Redux,” Journal of Political Economy, June, Vol. 103, pp. 62460.

  • Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff, 1996, “Foundations of International Macroeconomics,” (Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press).

  • Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff, 2000, “New Direction for Stochastic Open Economy Models,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 50, No. 1, pp. 11753.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tille, C., 1999, “The Role of Consumption Substitutability in the International Transmission of Monetary Shocks,” Journal of International Economics Vol. 53, No. 2, pp. 42144.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tille, C., 2002, “How Valuable Is Exchange Rate Flexibility? Optimal Monetary Policy under Sectoral Shocks,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Staff Report No. 147.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Warnock, F.E., 1998, “Idiosyncratic Tastes in a Two-Country Optimizing Model: Implications of a Standard Presumption,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Papers No. 631.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

Gabriel Srour is a Senior Economist in the IMF Institute. The author would like to thank Samir El-Khouri, Andrew Feltenstein, and participants at an IMF Institute departmental seminar for helpful comments.

2

See for instance Knight (1998) on the impact of financial market liberalization on developing economies; Aghion, Bacchetta, and Banerjee (1999) for analyzing the role of financial liberalization as a source of instability; and Edison et al. (2002) for a survey of the evidence on the links between capital markets liberalization and economic performance

3

See for instance Cashin et al. (2000) on the persistence of shocks to commodity prices; Cashin et al. (2002) and Cashin and McDermott (2002) on the cyclical and long-run behavior of commodity prices; and Collier and Gunning (2000) and Collier and Dehn (2001) on their impact on developing countries.

4

Of course, the benefit of such a shift can become marginal if the nonprimary sectors are also subject to important shocks in which case further diversification may be called for.

5

Arguably, this case is more representative of economic integration with the rest of the world than the previous one.

6

See Lane (2001) and Bowman and Doyle (2003) for surveys of the literature on new open-economy macroeconomics; Obstfeld (2001) for a broad review of international macroeconomics; and Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (2001).

8

The model can easily be extended to include nontraded goods as well.

9

The limit case of an elasticity of substitution between home-produced and foreign-produced goods equal to 1 is identified with the Cobb-Douglas functional form.

10

The price index of a composite good can be defined as the minimum expenditure needed to buy one unit of the composite good.

11

Wi can be interpreted as the minimum cost of a unit of composite labor.

12

Except for the relative weights of the sectors that they affect, the different types of technological innovations have identical implications.

13

And fluctuations across sectors are uncorrelated.

14

By equipping all firms with the same decreasing returns to scale technology, we have essentially reduced technological differences between sectors, and hence comparative advantage between countries, to differences in endowments of capital, i.e., number of firms, in each sector.

15

We neglect to mention technological shocks.

16

While the case σ > 1 seems more plausible in developing countries, the implication that aggregate labor increases following a negative shock is counterintuitive. This result depends, however, on the assumption of full labor mobility, and does not necessarily hold otherwise.

17

Which may obtain, for instance, as a result of export subsidies or taxes on domestic consumption.

18

To see this note that γX+ϕ+σΘαX=nX+(ϕ+σΘ1)αX and ϕ+σΘ1=α(σ1)Θ.

19

Since prices of foreign goods have been assumed to be exogenously given, while prices of domestic goods are endogenous, one cannot expect the foreign and home countries to have the same market structure. One possible specification is that, even though the foreign country is large, its consumption of home-produced i-goods is relatively small because of stronger preference for foreign goods or because of greater access to a variety of other goods. Under these conditions, the foreign price-level, Pflevel, is not identical to the home price-level denominated in foreign currency, Pf, and can be assumed to be exogenous.

20

We ignore from now on technological shocks.

21

The numerical estimations are available from the author upon request.

22

This claim is shown numerically for certain values of the model’s parameters.

23

This can be due, for instance, to industry specialization and/or economic integration in the form of greater access to other foreign goods.

24

For example, one can show analytically that at the point where the two nonprimary sectors are perfectly symmetric except for the elasticities of substitutions, η, and ν, KnA has the opposite sign of (ην).