Changes in the Structure of Earnings During the Polish Transition
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

Authors’ E-Mail Addresses: michael.keane@yale.edu; eprasad@imf.org

This paper documents that inequality in labor earnings increased substantially during the economic transition in Poland. One surprising result is that earnings inequality increased markedly in both the private and public sectors, indicating that even state-owned enterprises in Poland moved toward competitive wage setting during the transition. Education premia increased sharply, while experience premia declined. Increases in within-group inequality account for about 60 percent of the increase in overall wage inequality. But, contrary to the experience of countries like the United States, increases in within-group inequality in Poland were very different across skill groups, with much larger increases for highly educated workers.

Abstract

This paper documents that inequality in labor earnings increased substantially during the economic transition in Poland. One surprising result is that earnings inequality increased markedly in both the private and public sectors, indicating that even state-owned enterprises in Poland moved toward competitive wage setting during the transition. Education premia increased sharply, while experience premia declined. Increases in within-group inequality account for about 60 percent of the increase in overall wage inequality. But, contrary to the experience of countries like the United States, increases in within-group inequality in Poland were very different across skill groups, with much larger increases for highly educated workers.

I. Introduction

Poland experienced a dramatic change in its political and economic structures during the last decade. This transition from a communist to a market economy was launched with a radical set of reforms in late 1989 and early 1990 that has become known as the “big bang.” The communist government ended food price controls as it left power in August 1989, and the new Mazowiecki government implemented the Balcerowicz plan in January 1990, ending price controls on most other products. Other aspects of the reforms included reductions in state orders for manufactured goods and the imposition of hard budget constraints on state-owned enterprises (SOEs). The hardening of budget constraints arose both through elimination of direct state subsidies and the reform of the National Bank in late 1991.2

The pace of privatization of SOEs in Poland has been rather slow compared to a number of other Eastern European countries. For instance, Pinto, Belka, and Krajewski (1993) report that, out of a sample of 75 of the 500 largest firms in Poland, only 3 had been privatized by June 1992 (two and one-half years into the transition).3 However, the private sector’s contribution to GDP rose sharply during the transition (from 29 percent in 1989 to 60 percent in 1995) due largely to an explosion of small-scale entrepreneurship. In addition, there is strong evidence that hard budget constraints and import competition resulted in rapid adjustment by SOEs to the new market environment. Pinto and others (1993) provide a good discussion of the nature of these adjustments, which included massive labor shedding, changes in product lines and marketing strategies, and attempts to improve efficiency through investment.4

The transition process has also involved significant changes in labor market institutions. For instance, constraints on layoffs and redundancies have been significantly eroded over time. The unemployment rate rose from essentially zero in 1988 to a peak of 16.4 percent in 1994. Furthermore, there has been a massive inter sectoral reallocation of labor.5 The rapid rise of the private sector—which is far less unionized than the public sector and much less subject to regulations in terms of wage setting—has also resulted in greater labor market “flexibility” in many dimensions. And very generous pensions led massive numbers of older workers to take early retirement during the early phase of the transition.

After a sharp contraction of output in 1990–91, Poland has experienced sustained economic growth, which became quite rapid in the mid-1990s. As Keane and Prasad (2002) discuss, Poland has been the greatest success story of the transition process. By 1999, its GDP stood at 22 percent above its pre-transition (1988) level, while even the best performing of the remaining transition countries had only managed to recover to within a few points plus or minus their pretransition levels. At the same time, Poland experienced only a very modest increase in income inequality. Given its relative success, it is particularly important to document what happened during the transition process in Poland.

In this paper, we document changes in the structure of labor earnings in Poland over the period 1985–96. Our analysis is based on microdata from the Polish Household Budget Surveys (HBS). The relatively long span of the dataset allows us to trace out changes in the structure of earnings for an extended period of time, both leading up to and following the “big bang.” We find that overall earnings inequality rose significantly during the transition period of 1989-96. For instance, we estimate that the log 90/10 percentile ratio for individual labor earnings (of employed workers) increased steadily from 0.97 in 1988 to 1.12 in 1996 (using a sample of individuals aged 18–60 for whom labor earnings is the primary source of income), a 16 percent increase in the 90/10 ratio (exp(0.15)). For male workers, the increase was slightly greater, with the log 90/10 ratio rising from 0.94 in 1988 to 1.15 in 1996, a 23 percent increase.

To put this increase in earnings inequality in perspective, Juhn, Murphy, and Pierce (1993) report an increase in the log 90/10 ratio for wages of male U.S. workers from 1.27 in 1979 to 1.48 in 1989, a 23 percent increase in the 1980s. Thus, by this measure, the increase in earnings inequality in Poland from 1988 to 1996, was very similar to that for the United States in the 1980s. Of course, our measure of the increase in earnings inequality in Poland, based only on employed workers, understates the actual increase, because it ignores the effect of the 16 percentage point increase in unemployment.6

We also conduct a detailed examination of the sources of the increase in earnings inequality. Prior to the transition, the wage structure in Poland was highly compacted, with wages of college-educated white-collar workers little different from those of manual workers. A common view is that the rise of the private sector, in which there is competitive wage setting and, hence, a more unequal wage distribution, is the main source of increasing earnings inequality during transition. But our results contradict this view. In Poland, earnings inequality is indeed higher in the private sector (e.g., the log 90/10 earnings ratio in 1996 was 1.19 in the private sector and 1.05 in the public sector), and the private sector share of (nonagricultural) employment did increase from 5 percent in 1988 to 39 percent in 1996.7 Still, we find that reallocation of labor from the public to the private sector accounted for only 39 percent of the total increase in earnings inequality (as measured by the change in variance of log earnings).

The majority of the increase in earnings inequality during the Polish transition (52 percent) was due to increased variance of wages within both the public and private sectors. That is, earnings inequality within both the private and public sectors grew substantially, and by similar amounts.8 This illustrates how even SOEs in Poland have engaged in substantial restructuring, as suggested by Pinto and others (1993) and others. Consistent with our findings, Commander and Dhar (1998) report (p. 127) a substantial increase in the heterogeneity of wages across SOEs between 1990 and 1994, with those that performed better in terms of sales offering higher wages.9

The transition also involved substantial shifts in the industry composition of employment. The share of employment in manufacturing dropped from 37.2 percent in 1988 to 30.6 percent in 1996, while shares of various service industries grew. But this interindustry labor reallocation had a negligible impact on earnings inequality. A within versus between industry decomposition indicates that 97 percent of the increase in earnings inequality is within industry.

Our estimates of standard human capital earnings functions indicate that education premia rose rapidly during the transition. But the premium for labor market experience declined in the early years of transition and the position of older workers deteriorated relative to younger workers, consistent with rapid obsolescence of industry- and firm-specific skills. These patterns are even stronger in the private sector than in the aggregate economy.

We find that a substantial fraction of the increase in overall earnings inequality is attributable to changes in within-group inequality. A striking result is that increases in within-group inequality are concentrated among workers with higher levels of formal education.10

It does not appear that existing models of transition can fully capture the changes in the structure of earnings that we observe for Poland. For instance, Aghion and Commander (1999) and Commander and Tolstopiatenko (1998) consider a model with a state sector and a private sector. In the state sector, firms operate under a zero-profit constraint with no capital accumulation (insiders extract all of the surplus) and wages are set equal to average product. Private sector firms behave competitively. The state sector is less efficient (as captured by a lower constant in the Cobb-Douglas production function). State firms face a probability of closure, and can choose to restructure, in which case they shed excess labor and become like private firms. There is unemployment if hiring by private firms falls short of exits from state firms. Inequality within each sector is set exogenously in the model, and the authors assume a higher level in the private sector. When this model is simulated, higher inequality arises during the transition for two main reasons: (1) workers shift from the relatively low inequality state sector to the higher inequality private sector, and (2) mean wages are higher in the private sector (due to its greater productivity). The latter feature leads to a Kuznets curve (i.e., an inverse U-shape for inequality) because, with a mean wage differential between the two sectors, the contribution of between sector inequality to total inequality peaks when the allocation of workers between the two sectors is equal.

As our analysis reveals, this type of model misses several key features of the data. First, mean wage differences between sectors are not an important factor driving changes in inequality (and, furthermore, mean wages are actually lower in the private sector than in the public sector). Second, inequality has grown within both sectors over time, and this is the main factor driving changes in inequality. Third, inequality has not followed a Kuznets curve but has trended upward until reaching a plateau. Fourth, the model does not account for the greater increase of inequality among the more educated, which also happens to be the group that has had the least reallocation into the private sector.

The model could be modified to explain rising inequality of earnings in the state sector over time if it accounted for restructuring of SOEs in the absence of privatization—the phenomenon that Pinto and others (1993), Commander and Dhar (1998) and others suggest is important. Clearly, as the fraction of firms engaged in competitive wage setting grows (both through increases in the size of the private sector and restructuring of SOEs), the relative demand for skilled labor will increase in the economy as a whole. Through this mechanism, inequality will also grow in the private sector during the transition.11

Assuming the state sector has moved closer to competitive wage setting, another source of increasing inequality within that sector may have been price liberalization and opening to trade. For example, energy prices were held artificially low prior to 1990, and oil could be imported cheaply from the former U.S.S.R. As Keane and Prasad (1996) note, there is a large body of empirical work suggesting that energy is complementary with unskilled labor and substitutable with both capital and skilled labor in manufacturing production. Thus, an increase in the price of energy would increase the demand for skilled labor relative to the unskilled labor. This is the same mechanism whereby a falling price of capital increases skill premia in Krusell, Ohanian, Rios-Rull, and Violante (2000).

In addition, the transition can be interpreted as a period of technical change, not in the sense that the technical frontier has shifted out, but rather in the sense that SOEs have reorganized to achieve greater technical efficiency, and modified production processes to reflect market prices of inputs (in particular, by eliminating labor hoarding). Much of the existing capital was presumably rendered obsolete. There are a number of models where more educated workers are better able to adapt to rapid changes in production processes (see, e.g., Acemoglu, 1998; Caselli, 1999), and this mechanism may help explain rising returns to skill.

A rapid pace of change may also help explain rising within-group inequality. For instance, Violante (2002) proposes a model in which technology is embodied in capital of different vintages. Given frictions in the matching of workers with new technology, an acceleration of the rate of technical progress (i.e., updating of capital) leads to increased wage dispersion among identical workers. Growth in within-group inequality can then be explained by frictions in the matching of workers with the new technology. Clearly, however, this framework needs to be modified to account for the fact that increases in within-group inequality in Poland are positively correlated with education level.12

In the next Section of the paper we review prior work on the distribution of earnings in Poland. In section III we describe the HBS data that we use in our analysis. Section IV contains our analysis of changes in earnings inequality, and Section V contains our estimates of human capital earning functions and an analysis of changes in the structure of earnings during the transition. Section VI concludes.

II. Prior Research on Earnings Distributions in Poland and Other Transition Countries

Most earlier work on the Polish earnings distribution has relied on aggregate statistics that are released annually by the Polish Central Statistical Office (CSO). These aggregate statistics are described in detail in Atkinson and Micklewright (1992). Each September, starting in 1981, the CSO conducted a census of enterprises, and “the information requested of the enterprise was the total persons in a number of discrete earnings bands.” The CSO then published aggregate statistics such as total numbers of employees in various earnings bands, and deciles of the earnings distribution. From this data, it is possible to construct approximate measures of earnings inequality, such as approximate Gini coefficients. A number of other countries, such as Hungary, the former Czechoslovakia, and the former U.S.S.R., had similar data collection and reporting procedures for earnings.

Using such data, Atkinson and Micklewright (1992) compare the degree of earnings inequality across several communist countries in 1986. They obtain Gini values for Czechoslovakia (1987), Hungary, Poland, and the U.S.S.R. of 0.197, 0.221, 0.242, and 0.276, respectively. And they report 90/10 decile ratios of 2.45, 2.64, 2.77, and 3.28, respectively.13

Thus, there was a clear ranking of inequality (consistent across both measures), with Czechoslovakia being the most equal, the U.S.S.R. the least equal, and Poland in the middle. As a point of comparison, these authors report a Gini coefficient and 90/10 decile ratio of 0.267 and 3.23, respectively, for the United Kingdom in 1986. Thus, the earnings distribution in Poland prior to the transition was noticeably more compact than in the United Kingdom Based on the same data, Atkinson and Micklewright (1992) also calculate that earnings inequality in Poland declined over the period 1986–89. They report Gini values of 0.242, 0.230, 0.212, and 0.207 for these years, and decile ratios of 2.77, 2.76, 2.60, and 2.43.

Rutkowski (1996a) uses the same September earnings distribution survey to examine changes in the Polish earnings distribution during the transition. His calculations indicate that earnings inequality jumped dramatically in the early phase of the transition, with the Gini and decile ratio rising to 0.242 and 2.86, respectively, in 1991. By 1993, the last year of his study, these had risen further, to 0.257 and 3.03. Rutkowski also reports that earnings inequality was much greater in the private sector than in the public sector in 1993, that the ratio of white collar to blue collar wages rose substantially in the transition, and that this ratio was much higher in the private sector. Rutkowski (1998) extends this analysis to 1995, by which time the Gini for earnings increased to 0.288 and the decile ratio to 3.38, a large increase in inequality over 1993. Recall that, for 1986, Atkinson and Micklewright (1992) reported a Gini of 0.242 and a decile ratio of 2.77. So the increase in (gross) earnings inequality for Poland from 1986–95 implied by these data is somewhat greater than what they report for the United Kingdom in the 1980s.14

Rutkowski (1996b) presents a cross-country analysis of changes in earnings inequality using similar data sources for several transition economies. These results indicate that, by 1993, the earnings distribution for Czechoslovakia had become very similar to that for Poland, while the Gini and decile ratio for Hungary had risen to 0.315 and 3.67 (more unequal than Poland). Thus, given the baseline figures from Atkinson and Micklewright (1992), it appears that both Czechoslovakia and Hungary experienced larger increases in earnings inequality from 1986 to 1993 than did Poland. Newell (2001) reports similar results.

As both Atkinson and Micklewright (1992) and Rutkowski (1996) describe, there are a number of limitations of the September earnings survey data for Poland. First, the aggregate nature of the data may lead to approximation errors in inequality measures, and limits the type of analysis that can be performed. Second, the coverage of establishments is incomplete because small firms (i.e., less than 6 employees) are not sampled. This is especially a problem for the transition in Poland because, according to OECD (1998, p. 107), “Poland’s recent growth performance rests on a strong entrepreneurial basis, with many dynamic small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs) and creations of new firms … SMEs make up the bulk of Poland’s 2.2 million registered non-agricultural enterprises … almost 90 percent [are] micro-enterprises (employing 1 to 5 persons).” Third, this data does not account for in-kind payments, which have been important in Poland. Fourth, this survey reports gross earnings. This creates comparability problems over time, because a progressive income tax (with rates up to 45 percent) was introduced in 1992. Failure to account for this will tend to exaggerate the measured increase in inequality of net earnings.

Another survey that has been used by some authors to examine recent changes in the Polish wage structure is the Polish Labor Force Survey that was introduced in 1992 (see, e.g., Newell and Socha, 1998). However, this survey is clearly not useful for understanding changes in wage inequality in the crucial early years of transition or changes relative to the pretransition wage structure.

Existing work on other transition economies has focused mostly on the early years of transition (a recent exception is Newell, 2001). For instance, Orazem and Vodopivec (1995) analyze microdata from Slovenia and report that, from 1987 to 1991, wage inequality increased markedly, with returns to both education and experience rising over this period. Using grouped data, Flanagan (1993) finds that the returns to education rose while the returns to experience declined in the Czech Republic in the initial phase of transition. Brainerd (1998) reports that, from 1991 to 1994, the return to a year of education almost doubled for workers in Russia. Garner and Terrell (1998) find that wage dispersion in the Czech and Slovak Republics increased in the early years of transition. Using data from the International Labor Organization, Freeman and Oostendorp (2000) have created the new Occupational Wages Around the World file and, using this dataset, find that overall earnings inequality and skill differentials increased in transition economies during the 1980s and 1990s.

III. The Household Budget Survey

The CSO has been collecting detailed microdata on household income and consumption at least since 1978, using fairly sophisticated sampling techniques. The Household Budget Survey (HBS) attempts to obtain a random sample of Polish households.15 The typical sample size is about 25,000 households per year. The CSO uses HBS data to create aggregate tabulations that are then presented in their annual Statistical Bulletins, or Surveys.

The HBS contains detailed information on sources and amounts of income both for households and individuals within each household. Total income is broken down into four main categories: labor income (including wages, salaries and nonwage compensation); pensions; social benefits and other transfers; and other income. A key point is that the labor income data include measures of the value of in-kind payments from employers to workers, which have been an important part of workers’ compensation in Poland and other transition economies. There were no taxes on personal income until 1992.16 After that year, we use net incomes in the analysis.

The HBS also contains information on demographic characteristics of all household members and on labor earnings of all employed individuals in each household. Unfortunately, data on individual workers’ earnings were not collected in 1993. Hence, the dataset we use in this paper in fact goes from 1985 to 1992 and then from 1994 to 1996.

The HBS includes a limited panel element—a part of the dataset contains households that are surveyed for four successive years before being rotated out of the sample. However, the panel was changed completely a couple of times over the period 1985-96. In our analysis, we treat the data as a set of repeated cross sections.

The structure of the survey instrument and the sampling scheme were both kept essentially unchanged throughout the transition period. However, one major change was introduced in 1993 that has important implications for analyzing cross-sectional inequality. In 1993, the CSO switched from quarterly to monthly data collection. Since earnings are more variable at the monthly than the quarterly frequency, this shift alone would have created a substantial increase in measures of cross-sectional earnings inequality. Indeed, as we demonstrate in the next section, failure to account for this change in survey frequency has quantitatively important effects on measures of earnings inequality.

In the Appendix, we develop a technique for adjusting the 1994–96 earnings data for the increased variability that may be attributable to the shift from quarterly to monthly reporting. Our approach models earnings as the sum of a permanent or predictable component (determined by workers’ education, age and other observable characteristics) and a mean zero idiosyncratic component. We then assume that the variance of the idiosyncratic component would not have jumped abruptly after the fourth quarter of 1992.17 Rather, we assume that the variance of idiosyncratic earnings varied smoothly over time (measured in months) according to a polynomial time trend. We estimate this polynomial trend, along with a dummy for the post-1992 period that captures the discrete jump in variance that occurred with the change to monthly earnings reporting. Then, at the individual level, we scale down the idiosyncratic component of the post-1992 earnings statistics to eliminate this jump in variance.

Our procedure for adjusting for the spurious increase in inequality stemming from the switch to the monthly reporting interval relies on access to the HBS microdata. In particular, the variance correction requires access to the data for an extended period of time. Our study is unique in that it is based on the HBS microdata for a long sample period extending from four years prior to the “big bang” to seven years after. To our knowledge, no prior study of earnings inequality in Poland has adjusted for the change in survey design in 1993.18

We restrict our earnings analysis sample to individuals between the ages of 18 and 60 who report that labor income is their principal income source. We deflate nominal earnings using the aggregate CPI (1992Q4 = 100) for the survey quarter until the end of 1992 and for the survey month thereafter. Prior to 1993, there were seven education categories reported for individuals in the survey. Beginning in 1993, two of these categories (basic vocational training and some high school) were combined into a single category; for consistency, we combine these categories in a similar manner for the 1985–92 period. We also combined primary school and less than primary school into a single base category (among workers, the latter group is quite small), thereby yielding a total of five educational categories over the full sample.

Table 1 reports sample means for some of the variables used extensively in our analysis of wage inequality.19 The demographic characteristics of the cross-sectional samples remain quite stable during and after the transition. The means of the education dummies indicate a small increase in average levels of educational attainment in the 1990s. It is important to note the very high participation rate of women in Poland. They made up roughly 45 percent of the workforce prior to the start of the transition, and this rose to 48 percent by 1996.

Table 1.

Sample Means for Selected Years: Wage Analysis Sample

article image
Notes: The wage analysis sample includes workers between the ages of 18 and 60 who report a positive wage and who report that labor income was their primary source of income.

Only 5 percent of the sample was employed in the private sector in 1988, and this rises to 39 percent in 1996. As we noted above, self-employment grew tremendously in Poland in the early phase of the transition. A limitation of the HBS prior to the 1993 is that it contained an under representation of the self-employed. The redesign of the survey in 1993 was in part meant to rectify this problem. Thus, our data presumably understates private sector employment in the early transition period (1990–92).

IV. Changes in Earnings Inequality

In this section, we examine changes in the distribution of earnings for individual workers. For the years 1994-96, we use earnings measures that are adjusted (using the procedure described in the Appendix) for the increase in idiosyncratic variance that occurred with the shift to a monthly reporting period.

A. Measures of Overall Earnings Inequality

The first panel of Table 2 reports 90–10 and 75–25 percentile differentials of log earnings for all workers. Earnings inequality is quite stable in the pre-transition years 1985–88, followed by a period of rapid growth in inequality that begins in 1989, the first year of transition (recall that the transition began in August 1989). Between 1988 and 1996, the log 90/10 ratio increased from 0.97 to 1.12. This is a 16 percent increase in the 90/10 ratio (exp(0.15)), which is sizeable for an 8-year period. The increase in the 75–25 percentile differential, from 0.50 in 1988 to 0.59 in 1996, is also sizable.20 It is interesting that the 90/10 ratio seems to have flattened out in 1994–97, suggesting that earnings inequality has reached a plateau (although the 75/25 ratio continues to show slow growth).

Table 2.

Precentile Differentials

article image
Notes: The percentile differentials reported above are for log quarterly (1985-92) or monthly (1994-96) earnings. The data for 1994-96 are adjusted for the change in survey frequency after 1992, unless indicated otherwise. Wage residuals are from annual OLS regressions of earnings on a constant, four education dummies, experience and its square, and dummies for gender, urban residence, and employment in the private sector.

Despite the growth in earnings inequality in Poland during the transition, the structure of earnings as of 1996 was still considerably more compressed than in the United States. For instance, Juhn, Murphy and Pierce (1993) report that the log 90/10 ratio for wages of full-time male workers in the United States was 1.46 in 1988.21 Interestingly, however, earnings differentials are greater in Poland than in certain continental European countries such as Germany in the 1990s (see Prasad, 2000).

In Table A1, we present results using an alternative measure of inequality—the Gini coefficient. It is evident that the patterns of changes in inequality revealed by the Gini are, in general, quite similar to those indicated by the percentile ratios. For instance, the Gini coefficient for the full sample rises sharply from 0.221 in 1988 to 0.261 in 1996. The Gini is relatively flat from 1994 through 1996, suggesting again that inequality has reached a plateau.

Our results for earnings inequality in the HBS differ in a number of important ways from the results of Atkinson and Micklewright (1992) and Rutkowski (1998), who used aggregated data from the census of enterprises conducted by the CSO each September. We do not find evidence of the sharp drop in inequality from 1986–89 that they report. And we find more modest increases in inequality after 1989. Starting from a base year of 1986 (when our figures roughly agree) and ending with 1995 (the final year in their analysis) we obtain a 16 percent increase in the 90/10 ratio and an 0.042 point increase in the Gini, while their figures imply 30 percent and 0.076 point increases, respectively. Given the much more representative population coverage of the HBS data, we view our results as more accurate.

As discussed earlier, we adjusted the earnings data for 1994–96 to account for the change in survey frequency. In the second panel of Table 1, we show the percentile ratios for 1994–96 based on the unadjusted data. Clearly, the adjustment makes a significant difference for our inferences regarding growth in inequality. For instance, if we ignored the shift to monthly reporting, we would conclude that the 90/10 ratio increased by about 20 percent from 1988 to 1996 (as opposed to our preferred estimated of 16 percent). Still, this figure remains well below the 30 percent figure that previous authors obtained using the September census of enterprises. Thus, our lower figure for the growth in earnings inequality arises primarily from our different data set, rather than from our adjustment procedure.22

It is possible to get some sense of the accuracy of our adjustment for the change in survey frequency in 1993 using data from the Polish Labor Force Survey, which began in 1992. Using these data, Newell and Socha (1998) report that the 90/10 ratio for labor earnings was flat from 1992 to 1996. Since we find about a 3 percent increase in inequality over the same period, this suggests that our adjustment procedure is not overcompensating for the effect of the change in survey frequency.23

B. Earnings Inequality in the Public and Private Sectors

In this section we compare the earnings distributions in the state and private sectors. The first four columns in the lower panel of Table 2 show log percentile ratios separately for workers employed in each sector. In absolute terms, inequality is higher in the private sector than in the public sector. However, whether inequality increased more in the private or public sector during the transition is ambiguous. For instance, from 1988 to 1996, the log 90/10 ratio rises from 0.96 to 1.05 in the public sector (+10 percent) and from 1.04 to 1.19 in the private sector (+16 percent). However, the 75/25 ratio rises by 0.06 in the public sector and 0.05 in the private sector. A finer breakdown of the percentile differentials confirmed that, in the private sector, inequality increases have been greater above the median and, in particular, near the top end of the distribution.

In order to resolve the contradictory messages presented by the 90/10 and 75/25 ratios, and, more generally, to obtain a better understanding of changes in the shape of the entire earnings distribution in each sector, we next examine kernel density estimates. Figure 1 presents kernel density estimates for (log) real earnings for a few selected years (1988, 1992, 1994, and 1996).24

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Kernel Density Estimates: By Sector

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2002, 135; 10.5089/9781451855715.001.A001

In 1988 (pretransition), the mode of the private sector earnings distribution was slightly to the right of that for the public sector. In fact, the private sector distribution almost stochastically dominated the public sector distribution, except for a small bump in the left tail. By 1992, there was not yet much change in this picture. But, by 1994, the situation was dramatically different. The mode of the private sector earnings distribution had shifted left, and the public sector distribution began to stochastically dominate. By 1996, the dominance of the public sector earnings distribution is even clearer.

Figure 2 (left panel) plots the differential between (unconditional) median private and public sector earnings. As we see, the median earnings in the private sector dropped from about 10 percent above that in the public sector in 1992 to about 12 percent below in 1994.25 Compositional effects are important in driving these changes. Somewhat surprisingly, it is low education workers who have primarily shifted into the emerging private sector.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Wage Differentials

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2002, 135; 10.5089/9781451855715.001.A001

The top panel of Figure 3 examines the change in shape of the public sector earnings distribution from 1988 to 1996. In order to focus on the change in shape, we scaled earnings to have the same mean in each year.26 It is obvious from the figure that inequality in the public sector earnings distribution increased. Most obviously, the mass near the mode clearly drops from 1988 to 1996. At same time, some mass is shifted into the right tail, and the distribution becomes clearly skewed to the right.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Kernel Density Estimates, 1988 vs. 1996

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2002, 135; 10.5089/9781451855715.001.A001

The bottom panel of Figure 3 examines the change in shape of the private sector earnings distribution. The loss in mass near the mode is not obviously greater in the private sector than in the public sector. However, there is much more mass shifted into the extreme tails. This explains our earlier finding that when one looks at 75/25 differentials it appears that inequality increased slightly more in the public sector, but when one looks at 90/10 ratios it appears that inequality increased more in the private sector.

To sum up, although the increase in earnings inequality was higher in the private sector (at least according to two of the three summary measures we examined), workers in public sector enterprises also experienced significant increases in earnings inequality during the transition. In other words, the rapid reallocation of labor from the public sector to the private sector cannot by itself explain much of the increase in earnings inequality during the transition in Poland. We explore this more formally below.

C. Changes in the Structure of Employment and Earnings Inequality

In this section we decompose the increase in overall earnings inequality into components attributable to changes in the composition of employment across sectors or industries versus

increases in inequality within sectors or industries. Consider the following decomposition:

σt2=jsjtσjt2+jsjt(wjtw¯t)2(1)

where σt2 is the cross-sectional variance of log hourly earnings, sjt is the employment share of sector j, σjt2, is the within-sector variance of earnings, wjt is sector j mean earnings, w¯t is grand mean earnings in the sample, and the subscript t is a time index. Using this formula, the change in variance over time can be decomposed into changes attributable to within- and between-sector components, as well as composition effects within and between sectors.

The top panel of Table 3 shows this variance decomposition based on the state and private sectors.27 The overall increase in log earnings variance from 1988 to 1996 is 7.00 (the figures in the table are multiplied by 100). Of this, 3.63 points, or 52 percent, is due to increases in variance within the state and private sectors. 2.71 points or 39 percent of the increase in variance is attributable to the shift of workers from the (relatively low variance) public sector to the private sector. Note that the two variance components that arise due to the differences in mean earnings between the two sectors (last two columns) are of minor importance.

Table 3.

Effects of Sectoral Shifts on Changes in Wage Inequality

(Variance decomposition)

article image
Notes: Variance (of log wages) and its components multiplied by 100. For the results in the first panel, workers were classified into one of two sectors - private or public. For the second panel, workers were classified into 13 broadly defined sectors. These sectors and their employment shares in 1988 and 1996 are as follows: manufacturing and mining (37.2, 30.6); construction (8.7, 8.0); agriculture, forestry, and fishing (11.7, 4.7); transport and communications (8.5, 8.5); trade, hotels, and restaurants (9.6, 11.5); real estate and housing (3.7, 3.0); science and technology (1.0, 0.7); education and culture (8.6, 9.7); health and hygiene (5.6, 8.5); recreation and tourism (0.7, 1.2); public administration (2.5, 7.2); finance and insurance (0.9, 2.5); and other services (1.2, 3.8).

These results suggest, somewhat surprisingly, that the shifting of workers from the state to the private sector, while important, is not the main factor driving increased earnings inequality during the Polish transition. Rather, within sector increases in earnings inequality constitute the most important factor driving the increase in overall earnings inequality. A key factor driving this result is that earnings inequality in the state sector has grown substantially, as we documented in sections IV.1 and IV.2. In 1996, the state sector still accounted for almost two-thirds of nonagricultural employment in Poland, so developments there remain critical for the shape of the overall earnings distribution. Despite the slow pace of privatization in Poland, work by Pinto and others (1993), Commander and Dhar (1998) and others suggests that substantial restructuring of SOEs has nevertheless occurred, as managers have responded to removal of government subsidies and import competition. This presumably led to increased earnings inequality in the state sector as that sector has moved closer to competitive wage setting.

Table 3 also breaks down the increase in overall earnings variance into subperiods. Note that there were sharp increases in earnings variance from 1988 to 1992 and from 1992 to 1994, with a subsequent much more moderate increase from 1994 to 1996. It is interesting that composition effects were of almost no importance in the early transition period (1988–92). But in the most recent period, the shifting of workers from the public to the private sector was the main factor driving increased earnings inequality. As shown in Table 2, in 1994–96 earnings inequality reached a plateau in both the public and private sectors. Indeed, within sector earnings dispersion appears to have fallen marginally from 1994 to 1996. Thus, compositional effects dominate the (modest) growth in earnings inequality during this latter period.28

The composition of employment by industry also changed dramatically from 1988 to 1996. For instance, as noted in the footnote to Table 3, the share of manufacturing dropped from 37.2 percent to 30.6 percent. In the bottom panel of Table 3 we present a variance decomposition for 13 broadly defined industrial sectors of the economy.29 The key result is that virtually all of the increase in overall earnings variance is attributable to within-industry increases in variance. The between-industry component of the change in variance (due to changes in the relative means of earnings across industries) is positive in all three sub-periods, but is roughly offset by within- and between-industry composition effects. Thus, industry employment shifts do not seem to have played much of a role in influencing patterns of overall earnings dispersion.30

In summary, growth of earnings inequality within sectors and industries is the main source of increased overall earnings inequality. Labor reallocation from the public sector to the private sector has also contributed importantly to the rise in overall inequality. However, despite the large shifts in industry employment shares, interindustry labor flows do not appear to have contributed directly to the rise in earnings inequality. These two sets of results are reconciled by the fact that, while industry shares of total employment changed significantly for only a few industries, increases in the shares of private sector employment within each industry were very large.31

D. Within-Group Earnings Inequality

In this section we examine changes in within-group earnings inequality. First, we look at inequality within education groups, with workers classified into four groups: college degree, high school graduate, vocational training, and primary school. Table 4 reports log percentile ratios for workers in each group. Prior to the transition, the degree of inequality within each group (as measured by the 90/10 and 75/25 ratios) was quite similar.

Table 4.

Within-Group Inequality: Percentile Differentials

article image
Notes: The percentile differentials reported above are for log quarterly (1985-92) or monthly (1994-96) earnings. The data for 1994- 96 are adjusted for the change in survey frequency after 1992.

During the transition, inequality grew at quite different rates within these four education groups. From 1988 to 1996, the log 90/10 ratio increased by 0.18, 0.12, 0.05, and 0.09, respectively, within the four groups. And the log 75/25 ratio increased by 0.12, 0.08, 0.05, and 0.03, respectively. Thus, workers with college degrees experience by far the greatest increase in inequality during the transition by either measure. For workers with only basic vocational training or a primary school degree, the increases in within-group inequality were much more modest. Thus, increases in within-group inequality seem to be a prominent feature of the transition mainly for highly educated workers.

Based on our earlier findings, one might surmise that the explanation for these results is that better-educated workers were more likely to migrate to private sector, where inequality is higher. Indeed, the private sector employment shares of all education groups rose sharply during the transition. But, somewhat surprisingly, movement into the private sector was most pronounced for workers with lower levels of education.32 Hence, differential patterns of reallocation of labor across the public and private sectors cannot explain our finding.33

The finding that within-group inequality grew much more rapidly for more educated workers during the transition in Poland is in sharp contrast to the experiences of the United States and the United Kingdom in the 1970s and 1980s, where inequality grew by comparable levels within all education groups (for the United States, see Juhn, Murphy, and Pierce, 1993, and Gould, Moav, and Weinberg, 2001; for the United Kingdom, see Machin, 1996, and Machin and Van Reenen, 1998). Thus, explaining this pattern is a theoretical challenge for models of transition.

Next, we examine the evolution of inequality within broadly defined (synthetic) experience groups. Table 5 (top panel) reports log percentile ratios for groups of workers with different experience levels (given how experience is defined, these are also age cohorts). There are fairly significant increases in inequality for all groups, consistent with the plausible interpretation of these increases as reflecting time effects. For instance, from 1988 to 1996, the log 90/10 ratio rises by between 0.12 and 0.22 for all experience groups. Over the same period, the 75/25 ratio rises by about 0.10 for all groups.

Table 5.

Wage Inequality Within Synthetic Experience Groups and Cohorts

article image
Notes: The percentile differentials reported above are for log quarterly (1985-92) or monthly (1994-96) earnings. The data for 1994-96 are adjusted for the change in survey frequency that occured after 1992. Cohorts are defined on the basis of year of birth. Results are reported only for cell sizes greater than 100.

We also examined the evolution of overall inequality within birth cohorts. The middle panel of Table 5 reports log percentile ratios for synthetic cohorts defined on the basis of birth year. It is, of course, impossible to separate out age effects from time effects by looking at these differentials for any one cohort.34 But the fact that all cohorts experienced larger increases in inequality during the transition than during the pretransition period, with a substantial fraction of this increase occurring between 1988–89 and 1992–94, suggests that time effects are important.

Note that the group of younger workers, born between the years of 1966 and 1975, experiences an increase of the 90/10 ratio from 0.75 in 1988 (when the oldest members of the cohort are 22) to 0.99 in 1992 (when the oldest members are 26). Much of this increase is presumably simply due to age effects. But it is worth noting that the within-cohort share of private sector employment (relative to total employment) during the transition is much greater for this cohort than for the older ones.35

As discussed above, it is impossible to disentangle age, cohort and time effects on overall inequality. But a plausible way to identify time effects was suggested by Juhn, Murphy and Pierce (1993, p. 424–26). Using the results in the top panel of Table 5, if we take the average (across age/experience groups) of changes in inequality between any two points in calendar time, we get changes that combine cohort and time effects. Using the results in the middle panel of Table 5, if we take the average (across cohorts) of changes in inequality between any two points in calendar time we get changes that combine age and time effects. So these two measures will have time effects in common. If they move together, it is plausible that they do so because time effects are the dominant factor (rather than because age and cohort effects just happen to be equal). The bottom panel of Table 5 shows that changes in inequality (for different sub-periods) are indeed quite similar when averaged across cohorts vs. age (experience) groups, suggesting that much of the increase in the dispersion of the overall earnings distribution can plausibly be attributed to time effects.36

E. Residual Earnings Inequality

Another commonly used method to examine within-group earnings inequality is to regress earnings on observed attributes such as gender, education, and experience and to examine the dispersion of the residuals. These earnings residuals arguably control for between-group differences across many different group characteristics and indicate the evolution of inequality within narrowly defined groups.

Log percentile ratios for log earnings residuals are reported in the last (top right) panel of Table 2.37 Comparing these to the ratios for log earnings themselves, we see that about four-fifths of the level of overall earnings inequality is accounted for by within-group inequality. Changes in within-group inequality also account for a substantial fraction of the increase in overall inequality. For instance, the log 90/10 ratio for the log earnings residuals increases by 0.09 from 1988 to 1996, which accounts for about 60 percent of the increase in total wage inequality over that period. This is similar to the experience of the United States, where the change in residual inequality accounted for two-thirds of the total increase in wage inequality during the 1970s and 1980s (Juhn, Murphy, and Pierce, 1993).

It is also interesting to compare the increases in residual earnings inequality in the public and private sectors. These results are reported in the last four columns in the bottom panel of Table 2. Note that the increase in residual earnings inequality was very similar in the two sectors. For instance, from 1988 to 1996, the log 90/10 percentile ratio increased by 0.05 in each sector. But, as we have already seen, the 90/10 ratio for the level of log earnings increased more in the private sector than in the public sector. As we will see in section V, the explanation for this is that inequality between education groups increased much more in the private sector, especially at the upper quantiles.

We next examined changes in residual inequality within specific education groups. To do this, we took the squared earnings residuals and regressed them on education group dummies and interactions of these dummies with time, along with controls for private sector, gender, and urban residence. The time trend interaction terms then capture changes over time in within-group inequality for each education group, controlling for other observed characteristics. Consistent with our earlier findings in Section IV.4, the time trend for college-educated workers was substantially larger than that for the other groups.38 This confirms the relatively higher increase in inequality within this group, even after controlling for other observed characteristics. We also ran these type of regressions separately for public and private sector workers, and, in each sector, the time trend was much larger for the college educated group.39

To summarize, we find that the increase in within-group inequality accounts for about 60 percent of the total increase in earnings inequality during the Polish transition—which is similar to the experiences of the Unite States and other industrial economies in the 1970s and 1980s. However, there are some important differences across groups. In particular, within-group inequality rose significantly among highly educated workers but increased far less for workers with lower levels of formal education. And within-group inequality accounts for less than half the overall increase in inequality within the private sector where (as we will see in Section V) between-group changes were more important.

F. The Behavior of Extreme Quantiles

Appendix Table A1 also reports variances of log earnings as an alternative inequality measure. From 1988 to 1996 the variance of log earnings increased by 0.07, which was a 47 percent increase. This is far greater than the 16 percent increase in the 90/10 ratio, or the 18 percent increase in the Gini, that we have emphasized earlier. The reason is that the variance is much more sensitive to behavior in the tails of the distribution.

In order to focus more on what happened in the tails, Table 6 reports a set of extreme quantile ratios and compares them to the 90/10 ratio. Clearly inequality as measured by the log 99/1 ratio increased much more substantially. In fact, the log 99/1 ratio increased from 1.82 in 1988 to 2.40 in 1996, which corresponds to a 79 percent increase in the 99/1 ratio itself.

Table 6.

Extreme Percentile Differentials

article image
Notes: The percentile differentials reported above are for log quarterly (1985-92) or monthly (1994-96) earnings. The data for 1994-96 are adjusted for the change in survey frequency after 1992.

If we decompose the increase in the log 99/1 ratio into the increases in the 99/50 and 50/1 ratios, we see that the latter increased by 0.22 and 0.36, respectively. This suggests that the majority of the increase in the 99/1 ratio is actually due to increased inequality at the low end of the earnings distribution.

Not surprisingly, the 99/1 ratio increased much more dramatically in the private sector (+118 percent) than the in the public sector (+ 26 percent). This is consistent with our earlier results in section IV.2 that increases in inequality near the mode were similar in the two sectors, but that the private sector saw a greater increase in mass in the extreme tails. Much of this is due to an increase in the number of very low earnings individuals in the private sector.

Finally, it is also interesting to look at the variance of the residuals from log earnings equations, which are also reported in Table A1. Note that residual variance increased by 39 percent from 1988 to 1996, which is somewhat less than the increase in the overall earnings variance. Hence, the fraction of earnings variance that is within group declined slightly, from 72 percent in 1988 to 68 percent in 1996. This is again consistent with the dramatic increase in inequality between education groups, especially in the private sector, that we document in detail in Section V.40

G. Earnings Inequality Among Men and Women

Next, we examine the evolution of earnings inequality among men and women. Most of the literature on earnings inequality in the United States and United Kingdom has focused only on male earnings inequality. This omission has been largely driven by the fact that prime age men have very high employment rates, while women have much lower employment rates and are more likely to enter and exit from employment over time. Thus, the study of earnings inequality among women confronts severe selection problems, which must be dealt with by modeling women’s employment decisions (a difficult task).

But in Poland, women have traditionally had employment rates nearly as high as those for men, and in our sample they make up 45 percent to 48 percent of employed workers. Thus, we feel it is not too implausible to study earnings inequality for women in Poland just as it has typically been done for men in the United States and United Kingdom, as we have done in this paper. In this section we analyze the evolution of earnings inequality for men and women separately, and also examine their respective impacts on the overall earnings distribution.

Table 7 shows log percentile ratios separately for men and women. As in many other countries in the 1980s and 1990s, the increase in male earnings inequality is greater than the increase in inequality among women. For instance, from 1988 to 1996, the 90/10 percentile ratio goes from 0.94 to 1.15 for men (a 23 percent increase) and from 0.85 to 1.00 for women (a 16 percent increase). Similarly, the increase in the 75–5 differential from 1988 to 1996 is 0.12 for men and 0.07 for women. To put the 23 percent increase in the 90/10 ratio for men from 1988 to 1996 in perspective, it is the same as the 23 percent increase in the 90/10 ratio for male wages in the United States in the 1980s reported by Juhn, Murphy, and Pierce (1993).

Table 7.

Percentile Differentials by Gender

article image
Notes: The percentile differentials reported above are for log quarterly (1985-92) or monthly (1994-96) earnings. The data for 1994-96 are adjusted for the change in survey frequency after 1992. Wage residuals are from annual OLS regressions of earnings on a constant, four education dummies, experience and its square, and dummies for gender, urban residence, and employment in the private sector.

It is worth noting that the increase in male earnings inequality is greater than the increase in overall inequality, a phenomenon that has been documented for numerous other countries as well during the 1980s and 1990s. For instance, Fortin and Lemieux (2000) show that, for the United States in the 80s and 90s, the male and female wage distributions moved much closer together (both in terms of their means and overall shape), and that this was a force acting to reduce inequality in the overall wage distribution. They argue that, except for changes around the minimum wage (which declined substantially in real terms), the overall wage distribution in the United States was very stable during the 1980s.

We examined whether any similar phenomenon occurred in Poland. Figure 4 presents employment-share weighted kernel density estimates for the real earnings of men and women for the years 1988, 1992, 1994, and 1996. It is hard to discern any tendency for the two distributions to converge over time. Throughout the period 1988-96, the female earnings distribution is to the left of the male earnings distribution at virtually all percentile points.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Weighted Kernel Density Estimates: By Gender

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2002, 135; 10.5089/9781451855715.001.A001

The right panel of Figure 2 (right panel) shows that the median earnings differential between men and women fell from about 30 percent to about 20 percent during the early stages of transition, but then rebounded and, after 1992, has stabilized at around 25 percent. Although the earnings premium for men is higher in the private sector in the early years of transition, it, too, levels off at about 25 percent after 1992. This is in sharp contrast to the experiences of many industrial countries, where the gender wage differential has declined substantially over the last few decades.

Evidence from other transition economies is more in line with that for industrial countries. For instance, Hunt (2002) reports that German unification resulted in a 10 percentage point decline in the gender wage gap in the former east Germany but notes that this was accompanied by a much greater decline in female employment than in male employment. She also finds that low earners were more likely to leave employment after unification and that these low earners were disproportionately female. In Poland, by contrast, our evidence suggests that the relative share of women in total employment actually increased slightly during the transition (see Table 1). Thus, there appear to be very different forces at work in Poland in terms of influences on the gender earnings gap.

V. Regression Analysis of the Structure of Earnings

In this section, we conduct a regression analysis of the structure of earnings to gain more insight into changes in between-group earnings inequality during the transition. In Table 8, we present estimates of standard human capital earnings functions (see Willis, 1986) for a selected set of years during the 1985–96 period.41 The coefficients on the educational category dummies show that premia for educational qualifications increased substantially during the transition. For instance, the college degree coefficient increases from 0.383 in 1988 to 0.527 in 1992 and further to 0.683 in 1996. This implies that the college premium (relative to primary school, which is the omitted group) was approximately 47 percent in 1987, 69 percent in 1992, and 98 percent in 1996. The high school premia for the same three years are 23, 30, and 41 percent, respectively. Note that this implies a widening of the college-high school premium as well. These results also imply that, by 1996, the high school and college premia in Poland were toward the high end of estimates typically obtained using data from Western countries.

Table 8.

OLS Earnings Regressions

article image
Notes: The sample includes employed workers between the ages of 18 and 60, who report labor income as their primary source of income. The dependent variable is log quarterly real labor income for 1985-92 and log monthly real log income for 1994-96. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. An asterisk indicates statistical significance at the 5 percent level.

Our findings of a sharp increase in education premia during the transition are consistent with those of Gorecki (1994), based on his examination of aggregate Polish earnings data, and of authors who have examined the structure of earnings in other transition economies. For instance, Ham, Svejnar, and Terrell (1995) examine surveys conducted by the Federal Ministry of Labor in Czechoslovakia in 1988 and 1991. They find that the wage gap between university and elementary school graduates increased from 58 percent in 1988 to 63 percent in 1991. Brainerd (1998) examines survey data for Russia and reports that, from 1991 to 1994, the return to a year of education rose from 3.1 percent to 6.7 percent for men and from 5.4 percent to 9.6 percent for women.

One interesting question is whether academic qualifications acquired in the communist era have the same value in the labor market as more recently acquired qualifications. Unfortunately, it is difficult to answer this question decisively with our sample, since it ends in 1996, seven years after the big bang. As a first pass, we constructed a dummy variable for individuals who, based on their age and imputed years of education, attained their highest degree on or after 1992. This dummy, and its interactions with the education dummies, did not show any strong evidence that recent degrees command a premium relative to older degrees.42

Since (potential) labor market experience (age-years of education-6) enters the regressions as a quadratic, returns to experience need to be evaluated at specific levels of experience. The OLS estimates imply a decline in experience premia in the early years of the transition, followed by a subsequent rebound.43 For instance, for workers with 25 years of potential labor market experience, the return to an additional year of experience is 0.41 percent in 1988, drops to 0.36 percent in 1990 and then rises to 0.48 percent by 1996. For younger workers with 5 years of potential experience, this return drops from 2.64 percent in 1988 to 2.46 percent in 1990 and then partially recovers to 2.52 percent by 1996.

The returns to experience that we estimate for Polish workers are much smaller than those found in Western data sets. For instance, for prime-age workers with 15 years of experience, our estimates for 1994–96 imply that the return to an additional year of experience is about 1.5 percent. Estimates for the United States, from Blau and Kahn (1997), show that the comparable number for 1988 is in the range of 2.4 percent (women) to 2.8 percent (for men).

Consistent with the evidence from the previous section, the earnings premium for men relative to women drops by about 5 percentage points in the early years of transition, but then rises again and stabilizes at around 30 percent after 1992. The earnings premium for workers in urban areas relative to those in rural areas, on the other hand, almost doubles by the mid-1990s relative to pretransition levels.

Until 1992, the survey contains a question that can be used to determine if the respondent worked for a privately owned firm. For the 1994–96 surveys, this question is refined, so we can determine if the respondent works for one of three types of privately owned firms: small firms (including the self-employed); large privately-held firms; and large mixed-ownership firms with majority ownership by the private sector. So, in the later years, we include separate dummies for these three categories.

In the years up until 1992, the private sector dummy coefficient is always significantly positive, and generally around 0.08. Recall from Figure 2 that the unconditional private sector earnings premium was around 10 percent from 1985 to 1992, but that this premium turned sharply negative in 1994–96. Our results for 1994–96 indicate that earnings of workers in small private firms were about 10 percent below those of similar workers (controlling for observed education, experience, etc.) in the public sector.44 But workers in large private firms (including large foreign-owned firms) earn approximately 20 percent more than observationally similar workers in the public sector, while people who work for large firms with mixed but majority private ownership earn about 11 percent more. A separate dummy for employment in mixed-ownership firms with majority state ownership was small and not significant.45

We also ran regressions separately for workers in the public and private sectors. Some of the main results, and a comparison with the results for the full sample, are summarized in Figure 5. Two aspects of the results are worth noting. First, education premia rose much more sharply in the private sector during the transition. Prior to the transition, the college and high school premia were quite similar in the two sectors (about 40 percent and 20 percent, respectively). By 1996, these premia had risen to about 60 percent and 30 percent, respectively, in the public sector, and to about 90 percent and 40 percent, in the private sector.

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Education and Experience Premia

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2002, 135; 10.5089/9781451855715.001.A001

The second interesting aspect is that, for older workers (25 years of potential labor market experience) in the private sector, the return to an additional year of experience was close to zero before the transition. After the transition, this return begins to rise and, by 1996, is close to 0.6 percent, even higher than in the public sector (0.4 percent). We conjecture that this reflects selection effects and the fact that experienced workers who were able to obtain private sector employment after the transition have strong unobserved attributes. For younger workers (five years of potential labor market experience), the returns to an additional year of experience are in the range of 2.5–3.0 percent in both sectors before the transition. By 1996, this return declines to 2.3 percent in the private sector and rises marginally to 2.7 percent in the public sector. One possible explanation for this pattern is that the relative supply of younger workers looking for private sector jobs rose sharply during the transition, thereby driving down the returns to experience (at low levels of experience). This is consistent with the figures presented earlier showing that the most recent birth cohort in our dataset has a disproportionately large share of private sector employment.

We also computed the earnings regressions separately for men and women. To conserve space, we do not report those results in detail. One intriguing finding from this set of regressions was that, before the transition, education premia were substantially higher for women than for men. For instance, in 1988, the college and high school premia (relative to a primary school degree) for women were 58 percent and 30 percent, respectively, compared to 38 percent and 16 percent, respectively, for men. By 1996, these premia for both men and women had converged to about 95 percent and 40 percent. Thus, although both men and women experienced substantial increases in education premia during the transition, these increases were much greater, in relative terms, for men than for women.

The roles of selection effects and changes in patterns of labor supply for male and female workers with different skill attributes in explaining these differences remain to be investigated. Another possibility, especially given the sharper increases in education premia in the private sector noted earlier, is that men have disproportionately benefited from employment growth in the private sector. Interestingly, a cursory examination of the data strongly refutes this hypothesis. Although the share of women and men in public sector employment has remained roughly equal over our entire sample, the share of private sector employment accounted for by women in fact rose from about 20 percent before the transition to about 40 percent by 1996.

A. Quantile Regressions

Next, we follow Buchinsky (1994) in noting that a more complete picture of the evolution of returns to different skill characteristics can be obtained by use of quantile regression. This enables us to characterize in a parsimonious way the changes in the entire conditional distribution of earnings. We ran quantile regressions of log real quarterly (monthly for 1994–96) labor earnings on the same set of regressors as in the OLS regressions. Regressions were run for the 0.10, 0.25, 0.50, 0.75, and 0.90 quantilcs.

Table 9 reports the college and high school premia (relative to primary school) obtained from the quantile regressions. Note that the college premium jumps sharply from 1988 to 1996 at all quantile points. For example, median earnings were approximately 48 percent (exp(0.39)) higher for college graduates than primary school graduates in 1988, and this premium increases to 95 percent (exp(0.67)) by 1996.

Table 9.

Education Premia: Quantile Regressions

article image
Notes: COL–college degree; HS–high school degree. The full set of regressors included four education dummies, experience and its square, and dummies for gender, urban residence and employment in the private sector. The dependent variable is log real quarterly (monthly for 1994–96) labor income.The excluded education dummy is for primary school degree. Hence, the coefficients reported above are interpretable as the income premia, in percent (multiply by 100), for workers with a college or high school degree, respectively, relative to workers who have only a primary school degree. Bootstapped robust standard errors are reported in parentheses below the coefficient estimates.

It is interesting that the increase in the college premium is relatively greater at higher quantiles. By 1996, the college premium is considerably greater at both the 0.75 and 0.90 quantiles than it is at the median. At the 0.90 quantile, it is as high as 120 percent.

The high school premium also rises substantially from 1988 to 1996 at all quantile points. For example, median income was approximately 20 percent higher for high school graduates compared to primary school graduates in 1988, and this premium increases to 43 percent in 1996. The levels of the high school premium, and its behavior during the transition years, are quite similar across quantiles.

When we ran the quantile regressions limiting the sample to private sector workers, we found greater increases in the levels of college premia by 1996 at all quantile points. For instance, in 1996 the college premium was about 150 percent at the median of the distribution and over 170 percent at the 0.90 quantile. The high school premium is also higher in the private sector, although only marginally. By 1996, the pattern of distribution across quantiles of college premia (higher at the upper quantiles) and high school premia (similar across quantiles) in the private sector is quite similar to that in the full economy.

Overall, the quantile regressions reveal a rather interesting pattern in terms of how education premia changed during the transition. While the changes in the high school premium were similar at different points of the distribution, the growth of the college premium was markedly greater at higher quantiles.

Table 10 shows returns to experience, evaluated at 5, 15, and 25 years. As noted earlier, these returns to experience are smaller than those found in Western data sets. This is true both before and after the big bang. The numbers in Table 10 are in percentage terms. So, for example, in 1986, for workers with 5 years of experience, an additional year of experience raises earnings by about 2.9 percent at the (conditional) median of the earnings distribution. For the United States, Buchinsky (1994) reports a corresponding figure of 4.97 percent for 1985, which is about 70 percent higher. For those with 15 years of experience, the return to experience at the median in 1986 is smaller (1.67 percent) and, for those with 25 years of experience, it is even smaller (0.42 percent). The results are similar at other quantile points. In contrast, Buchinsky (1994) finds returns to experience for U.S. workers with 15 years of experience to be about 2.9 to 3.0 percent at all quantile points in 1985, nearly double the figure for Poland.

Table 10.

Returns to Experience: Quantile Regressions

article image
Notes: The numbers reported above are derivatives of log real quarterly (monthly for1994-96) labor income with respect to the experience level of the worker, evaluated at the indicated experience levels. The results are expressed in percentage terms. Standard errors for these derivatives, based on bootstrapped robust standard errors for the regression coefficients, are reported in parentheses. The full set of regressors included four education dummies, experience and its square, and dummies for gender, urban residence and employment in the private sector.

A break is apparent after the big bang. In 1990, returns to experience dropped relative to their pretransition levels. This is true at almost all quantile points for workers with 5 or 15 years of experience. In the 1992–96 period, there is some recovery in experience returns, especially at higher experience levels. In 1996, the returns to experience at the 25-year experience level range from 0.59 percent at the 0.10 quantile down to 0.41 percent at the 0.90 quantile. These figures are much higher than those for 1990, especially at the lower quantiles. After 1991, experience premia are relatively stable for workers with 15 years of experience but continue to decline for younger workers with only 5 years of experience. Thus, somewhat surprisingly, recent labor market entrants are the only group for whom experience returns are systematically lower in 1996 than in 1987.

In earlier work (Keane and Prasad, 2002), we have noted the marked increase in the relative generosity of pensions in 1991-92 and the consequent surge in the pension rolls in those years. Indeed, in our sample, the share of total employment accounted for by workers in the 51–60 age group fell from about 13 percent in 1989–90 to 11 percent in 1991–92 and, further, to 9 percent by 1996. In other words, it is possible that self-selection of workers with weaker unobserved attributes into retirement could account for the recovery in experience premia observed in the mid-1990s at higher experience levels.

The key finding from this section is that the returns to general human capital, as measured by education premia, rose markedly during the transition while the returns to experience declined in the early years of the transition. This is consistent with the notion of rapid obsolescence of firm- or industry-specific skills during a period of rapid industrial restructuring (see Svejnar, 1996). Workers with higher levels of general human capital are better able to adapt to such changes. Our results also reveal important differences between the structure of earnings in Poland and that in industrial economies. By 1996, education premia had risen to a level in line with, if not somewhat greater than, those found in many industrial economies. But, compared to countries like the United States, the divergence in returns to experience became, in some respects, larger than before the transition.

VI. Conclusion

This paper has analyzed changes in the structure of earnings in Poland over the period 1985-96. This period covers the last few years of the pretransition era, the “big bang” in 1989-90, and six subsequent years of transition. In our view, it is particularly important to document what happened during the Polish transition, because Poland has (so far) been the most successful of all the transition countries.

As expected, we found that earnings inequality rose substantially during the transition. We also expected to find that most of this increase was attributable to substantial reallocation of labor from the state-owned sector, where wages are compressed because they are not set competitively, to a dynamic private sector that exhibits much greater earnings inequality—a view consistent with the framework in Aghion and Commander (1999), for example. But, to our surprise, we found that the largest single factor driving increased earnings inequality was the growth of within sector inequality. Indeed, inequality within the state-owned sector itself grew substantially.

The main area where Poland has lagged behind other transition economies is in the pace of privatization of SOEs. Indeed, the state sector still accounted for over 60 percent of total nonagricultural employment by 1996.46 But a number of authors, including Pinto and others (1993) and Commander and Dhar (1998), have argued that substantial restructuring of SOEs has occurred even in the absence of privatization. Our findings of increased earnings inequality within the state sector, including substantially increased education premia, are consistent with this view, since they suggest that the state sector has indeed moved closer to having a competitive wage structure.

Our results indicate that education premia grew substantially during the transition, by about 50 percent in the state sector and 100 percent in the private sector. Presumably, a key factor driving increasing returns to skill in Poland is simply the rising fraction of firms engaged in competitive wage setting. As this fraction grows—both through increase in the size of the private sector and restructuring of SOEs—the relative demand for skilled labor will increase in the economy as a whole. Through this mechanism, education premia are driven up in both the private and public sectors during the transition.

In contrast to education premia—which increased to the point where they now appear to be at least as great as those observed in the United States and United Kingdom—experience premia in Poland have not systematically increased, and remain very low relative to levels observed in the advanced Western economies. This is consistent with the notion of rapid obsolescence of firm- or industry-specific skills during a period of rapid industrial restructuring (see Svejnar, 1996).

We also found that increases in within-group inequality account for about 60 percent of the overall increase in earnings inequality. These results are similar to those for industrial economies such as the United States and the United Kingdom that experienced large increases in both between- and within-group inequality during the 1980s. However, one striking finding is that increases in within-group inequality appear to have been much greater for highly educated workers in Poland. By contrast, in the United States and the United Kingdom, virtually all skill groups experienced large increases in within-group inequality, and there is evidence that increases in inequality were actually greater within low education groups (see Gould, Moav, and Weinberg, 2001). Thus, it is a challenge for models of transition to generate this pattern of greater increases in inequality among more educated workers.

APPENDIX I

Accounting for the Change in Survey Frequency After 1992

Most aspects of the HBS, including the two stage sampling scheme and the structure of the survey instrument, were left unchanged during the transition. However, a few refinements were introduced in 1993. While most of these modifications were relatively minor, one important change was that, starting in 1993, households were surveyed for only one month rather than for a full quarter in an attempt to further improve survey response rates. The change in survey frequency has important implications for the purposes of measuring changes in cross-sectional inequality. In this appendix, we develop a technique for adjusting the 1994–96 earnings data for the increased variability that may be attributable to the shift from quarterly to monthly reporting.

We begin by assuming the following statistical model for earnings:

Yht=α1t+βtXht+σtεhat(1)

where Yht is labor income of person h in period t, Xht is a vector of individual-specific characteristics used to predict labor income, and εht is the unpredictable or idiosyncratic component of labor income scaled to have a standard deviation of unity. The time-specific standard deviation that scales the idiosyncratic component of labor income is denoted by σt. Our objective is to estimate the increase in σt for the 1994–96 period that is due solely to the switch to a monthly reporting interval.

We begin by estimating equation (1) separately for each quarter during 1985-92 and each month for the period 1994–96.47 The variables included in Xht are controls for education level, experience and its square, sex, urban residence, and sector of occupation. A key feature of the results is that the R2 values drop sharply after the shift to monthly reporting in 1994. Presumably, the bulk of this drop is due to greater idiosyncratic variability of income, as well as greater relative importance of measurement error, when income is reported at monthly rather than quarterly frequencies.

Next, we assume that the standard deviation of the residuals from estimation of equation (1) follow the process:

ln σt=π0+π1t+π2t2+π3t3+π4YBt+π5PVTSHRt+π6I[t>96]+ηtt=2,4,,95; t=109, 110,,144.(2)

Here t is a monthly time index. For the years 1985 through 1992, the data are quarterly, so t is assigned as the midpoint of the interval covered by each quarter (that is, t = 2, 4,…., 95). The variable I[t>96] is an indicator for the post-1992 period in which the data is monthly. Thus, π6 captures the structural shift in the error standard deviation attributable to the shift to a monthly data frequency. The time polynomials capture the evolution of the error standard deviation over time due to changes in within-group income inequality, controlling for the group characteristics included in Xht. The term YBt controls for the effect of changes in mean income on the error standard deviation. PVTSHRt is the share of total employment in the private sector. This share increased markedly after the transition (see Table 1) and, given that earnings inequality tends to be higher in the private sector, could be an important determinant of overall earnings inequality. Finally, ηt captures purely idiosyncratic period-specific changes in income variability. Note that, since we do not have earnings data for 1993, we assume smooth adjustment from the end of 1992 through the beginning of 1994, with no discrete breaks in the intervening year.

After estimating the first and second stage equations, we adjust labor income data for 1994–1996 to account for the increase in the idiosyncratic variance that we estimate occurred solely due to the shift to a monthly reporting period after 1992. We define adjusted income for the 1994–96 period as:

YAht=α1t+βtXht+{σt/exp(π6)}^htt=109, 110,, 144.(3)

Here ^ht is the estimated residual from equation (1) and π6 is our estimate from equation (2) of the increase in the log of the residual standard deviation due to the switch to monthly income reporting.

The scale factor exp(π6) that we estimated was 1.051. This implies that the change in survey frequency results in an estimated increase of about 5 percent in the residual error variance. Thus, even though employed workers (a majority of whom are salaried) have reasonably stable labor earnings streams, there is still a significant increase in earnings variability in going from a quarterly to a monthly frequency.

Interestingly, the corresponding adjustment factor that we estimated in Keane and Prasad (2002) for total incomes of worker-headed households was 1.179. One would indeed expect the variability of household income (and household labor earnings) to be higher than for individual employed workers. Note that we observe wages for workers only if they are employed. On the other hand, we do observe zero labor incomes for worker households. This, in addition to variability in employment status among household members, suggests that there is likely to be greater cross-sectional variability in labor earnings and total income of households compared to the sample of employed workers. Furthermore, as the estimated adjustment factors indicate, the increase in cross-sectional variability at higher frequencies is greater for households than for individual employed workers.

Table A1.

Gini Coefficients and Variance

article image
Notes: Gini coefficients are for real income (levels, not logarithms). Wage residuals are from annual OLS regressions of log earnings on a constant, four education dummies, experience and its square, and dummies for gender, urban residence, and employment in the private sector.

References

  • Acemoglu, Daron, 1998, “Why Do New Technologies Complement Skills? Directed Technical Change and Wage Inequality,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 113 (November), pp. 105589.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aghion, Philippe and Simon Commander, 1999, “On the Dynamics of Inequality in the Transition,” Economics of Transition, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp. 27598.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aghion, Philippe, Peter Howitt, and Gianluca Violante, 2000, “General Purpose Technology and Within-Group Inequality” (unpublished; London: University College).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Atkinson, Anthony B. and John Micklewright, 1992, Economic Transformation in Eastern Europe and the Distribution of Income (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blau, Francine D. and Lawrence M. Kahn, 1997, “Swimming Upstream: Trends in the Gender Wage Differential in the 1980s,” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 15, No. 1, pp. 142.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brainerd, Elizabeth, 1998, “Winners and Losers in Russia’s Economic Transition,” American Economic Review, Vol. 88 (December), pp. 1094116.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buchinsky, Moshe, 1994, “Changes in the U.S. Wage Structure 1963-1987: Application of Quantile Regression,” Econometrica, Vol. 62, pp. 40558.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caselli, Francesco, 1999, “Technological Revolutions,” American Economic Review, Vol. 89 (March), pp. 78102.

  • Commander, Simon, and Sumana Dhar, 1998, “Enterprises in the Polish Transition,” in Enterprise Restructuring and Unemployment in Models of Transition, ed. by Simon Commander (Washington: World Bank) pp. 10942.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Commander, Simon, and Andrei Tolstopiatenko, 1998, “The Role of Unemployment and Restructuring in the Transition,” in Enterprise Restructuring and Unemployment in Models of Transition, ed. by Simon Commander (Washington: World Bank) pp. 16992.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coricelli, Fabrizio, Krzysztof Hagemejer, and Krzysztof Rybinski, 1995, “Poland” in Unemployment, Restructuring and the Labor Market in Eastern Europe and Russia, ed. by Simon Commander and Fabrizio Coricelli (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flanagan, Robert, 1995, “Wage Structures in the Transition of the Czech Economy,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 42 (December), pp. 83654.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fortin, Nicole M., and Thomas Lemieux, 2000, “Are Women’s Wage Gains Men’s Losses? A Distributional Test,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 90 (May), pp. 45660.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Freeman, Richard, and Remco Oostendorp, 2000, “Wages Around the World: Pay Across Occupations and Countries,” NBER Working Paper No. 8058 (Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frydman, Roman, and Andrzej Rapaczynski, 1994, Privatization in Eastern Europe: Is the State Withering Away? (London: Central European University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Galor, Oded, and Omer Moav, 2000, “Ability-Biased Technological Transition, Wage Inequality, and Economic GrowthQuarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115 (May), pp. 46997.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garner, Thesia, and Katherine Terrell, 1998, “A Gini Decomposition of Inequality in the Czech and Slovak Republics During the Transition,” Economics of Transition, Vol. 6 (May), pp. 2346.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gorecki, Brunon, 1994, “Evidence of a New Shape of Income Distribution in PolandEastern European Economics, Vol. 32, No. 3 (May–June), pp. 3251.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gould, Eric D., Omer Moav, and Bruce A. Weinberg, 2001, “Precautionary Demand for Education, Inequality, and Technological Progress,” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 6 (December), pp. 285315.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ham, John C., Jan Svejnar, and Katherine Terrell, 1995, “Czech Republic and Slovakia,” in Unemployment, Restructuring and the Labor Market in Eastern Europe and Russia, ed. by Simon Commander and Fabrizio Coricelli (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hunt, Jennifer, 2002, “The Transition in East Germany: When Is a Ten Point Fall in the Gender Wage Gap Bad News?Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 20 (January), pp. 14869.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Juhn, Chinhui, Kevin M. Murphy, and Brooks Pierce, 1993, “Wage Inequality and the Rise in Returns to Skill,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101 (June), pp. 41042.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keane, Michael P., and Eswar S. Prasad, 1996, “The Employment and Wage Effects of Oil Price Changes: A Sectoral Analysis,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 78, No. 3 August, pp. 38999.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keane, Michael P., and Eswar S. Prasad, 2002, “Inequality, Transfers and Growth: New Evidence from the Economic Transition in Poland,” Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krusell, Per, Lee E. Ohanian, José-Victor Ríos-Rull, and Giovanni Violante, 2000, “Capital-Skill Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis,” Econometrica, Vol. 68 (September), pp. 98195.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lehmann, Hartmut, and Jonathan Wadsworth, 2000, “Tenures that Shook the World: Worker Turnover in Russia, Poland, and Britain,” Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 28 (December), pp. 63964.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Machin, Stephen, 1996, “Wage Inequality in the U.K.,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 12, pp. 4764.

  • Machin, Stephen, and John Van Reenen, 1998, “Technology and Changes in Skill Structure: Evidence from Seven OECD Countries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 113 November, pp. 121544.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Milanovic, Branko, 1998, Income, Inequality and Poverty During the Transition from Planned to Market Economy (World Bank Regional and Sectoral Studies; Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Newell, Andrew, and Mieczyslaw Socha, 1998, “Wage Distribution in Poland: The Roles of Privatization and International Trade, 1992–96,” Economics of Transition, Vol. 6 (May), pp. 4765.

    • Search Google Scholar