How Persistent Are Shocks to World Commodity Prices?
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

This paper examines the persistence of shocks to world commodity prices, using monthly IMF data on primary commodities between 1957–98. We find that shocks to commodity prices are typically long–lasting and the variability of the persistence of price shocks is quite wide. The paper also discusses the implications of these findings for national and international schemes to stabilize earnings from commodity exports and finds that if price shocks are long–lived, then the cost of stabilization schemes will likely exceed any associated smoothing benefits.

Abstract

This paper examines the persistence of shocks to world commodity prices, using monthly IMF data on primary commodities between 1957–98. We find that shocks to commodity prices are typically long–lasting and the variability of the persistence of price shocks is quite wide. The paper also discusses the implications of these findings for national and international schemes to stabilize earnings from commodity exports and finds that if price shocks are long–lived, then the cost of stabilization schemes will likely exceed any associated smoothing benefits.

I. Introduction

This paper examines a key characteristic of the behavior of commodity prices—the persistence of shocks to the prices of primary commodities. This is a topic of great importance, given that about 25 percent of world merchandise trade consists of primary commodities, and both long-term trends and short-term fluctuations in primary commodity prices are key determinants of developments in the world economy. On the supply side of the market, many developing countries continue to rely heavily on one or two primary commodities for the bulk of their export earnings, and primary commodities (including fuel and energy) constitute, on average, about half of export revenues of developing countries (see Table 1). On the demand side, commodity markets play a nontrivial role in transmitting business cycle disturbances and in affecting inflation rates in industrialized nations (Borensztein and Reinhart (1994), Beckerman and Jenkinson (1986)). Our main goal in this paper is to estimate the duration of shocks to commodity prices. For commodity-dependent countries, knowledge of the duration of such shocks is an essential input to the design of policies to dampen the domestic economic effects of external shocks. In this paper we measure the persistence of shocks to commodity prices over the period 1957 to 1998, using data on 60 indices of primary commodity prices.

Table 1.

Countries Dependent on a Single Primary Commodity for Export Earnings

(Annual average of export data, U.S. dollars, 1992-97)

article image
article image
article image
Source: International Monetary Fund.Notes: Trade data denominated in local currency was converted to U.S. dollars using the period-average exchange rate.

An extensive literature exists on long-term trends in primary commodity prices. Classical economists suggested that the long-run trend of raw material prices was rising, because of limited supplies of natural resources in the face of diminishing returns to commodity production and growing populations. However, the Prebisch-Singer (1950) hypothesis argued that there was a declining long-term trend in primary commodity prices relative to manufactured goods, due to the low income elasticity of demand for commodities and rapid increases in supply. The evidence in support of a persistent downward trend in relative commodity prices is rather mixed. While most scholars agree that relative commodity prices are nonstationary, they disagree as to whether the nonstationarity of prices takes the form of a deterministic trend, a stochastic trend, or whether there are structural breaks (Grilli and Yang (1988), Cuddington and Urzúa (1989), Reinhart and Wickham (1994), and León and Soto (1997)).

For policy purposes, a good understanding of the cyclical behavior of commodity prices is equally as important as an understanding of their underlying long-run trends.2 In particular, reliable estimates of the duration of commodity price cycles are essential when considering counter-cyclical stabilization policies in primary-commodity exporting countries. Traditionally, however, the estimation of cycles is crucially dependent on whether the commodity price series are characterized as a unit root process. If the commodity price series are better modeled as a trend-stationary process, innovations in prices have no permanent effects. In such cases innovations are entirely cyclical, and commodity exporting countries can potentially benefit from price stabilization policies, such as the operation of a commodity stabilization scheme. On the other hand, if there is a unit root in the underlying data-generating process, shocks will have permanent effects, leaving very little room for any price stabilization scheme to work successfully. In contrast to this stark, and relatively uninformative, dichotomy between finite and permanent effects of innovations in commodity prices, in this paper we calculate the length of time typically taken for the effects of price shocks to dissipate.

The contributions of this paper are fourfold. First, we use the median-unbiased estimator proposed by Andrews (1993) to obtain an exact point and interval estimate of the autoregressive parameter in the commodity price data. This econometric procedure is superior to the results emanating from standard (least squares) unit root regressions, as least squares estimates are biased and any associated unit root test has low power. The low power problem means that a failure to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root cannot be construed as providing evidence for accepting the null. While there is little that can be done to improve the power of unit root tests, an interval estimate of the autoregressive parameter does yield useful information as to whether a failure to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root is due to the null being true or due to the uncertainty of the estimate of the autoregressive parameter.

Second, using unbiased estimates of the autoregressive parameter we calculate scalar measures of the duration (in terms of the number of periods) of typical price shocks, and the exact confidence interval surrounding the estimated median duration of shocks. Importantly, the confidence intervals are useful in their own right, as indicators of the variability of the persistence of shocks. The median-unbiased measures we use are potentially more informative to policy makers as to the persistence of shocks in comparison with either: (i) analyses of the trend stationary or difference stationary dichotomy of standard unit root tests, which focus only on whether shocks are mean-reverting (finite persistence) or not (infinite persistence); and (ii) nonparametric estimators, such as Cochrane’s (1988) variance ratio, which only provides information on the share of the long-run variance in the total variance of price shocks. Third, we extend the results of Andrews (1993). Using Monte Carlo methods we estimate the median and 90 percent confidence interval of the median function of the autoregressive/unit root model, for those cases when there are between 300 and 500 observations. Fourth, unlike earlier studies we focus our attention on the duration of shocks to individual commodities, rather than aggregate indices, as the persistence of shocks to aggregated series can differ greatly from the persistence of shocks to individual time series.3

We find that, on average, shocks to commodity prices are very long-lasting. For the majority of individual commodities it typically takes more than five years for half of the effect of the initial shock to dissipate. Moreover, the confidence intervals surrounding the estimated median duration of price shocks are typically quite wide, indicating that the persistence of shocks is variable in length. Unlike previous work, which claimed that finite persistence indicates that commodity stabilization schemes can be successful in stabilizing export revenues (León and Soto (1997)), our unbiased scalar measures of persistence indicate that there are many commodities for which shocks are finite, yet very long-lived, which casts doubt on the efficacy of stabilization schemes.

Our results highlight the need for policy makers to be cautious when implementing schemes designed to ameliorate the domestic effects of shocks to world commodity prices. In using policies such as national stabilization arrangements (through buffer stock schemes), international stabilization arrangements (through international commodity agreements) or compensatory financing, knowledge of the typical duration of price shocks is crucial. If price shocks are typically short-lived, then scope exists for policy initiatives to smooth national income and consumption. Alternatively, if price shocks are typically long-lived, then adjustment to the new long-run levels of national consumption and income is the preferred policy response. Our findings indicate that, for those commodities which typically experience highly-persistent price shocks, caution should be exhibited in implementing these schemes, as for long-lasting shocks it is more likely that their associated storage, financing and output-reduction costs will exceed the consumption- or income-smoothing benefits flowing from the smoothing of commodity prices.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section II sets out a median-unbiased estimator of first-order autoregressive/unit root (AR/UR) models, and its advantages as a measure of the persistence of shocks to economic time series. Section III describes the data used in the study, while Section IV presents the main empirical findings regarding the persistence of shocks to commodity prices during the period 1957 to 1998. Several implications for public policy of the findings regarding the persistence of commodity price shocks are discussed in Section V. Some concluding comments are contained in Section VI.

II. Why Use a Median-Unbiased Estimator?

The median-unbiased estimation procedure proposed by Andrews (1993), rather than unit root tests, is used to determine the persistence of shocks to commodity prices. Standard unit root testing procedures (such as those of Dickey and Fuller (1979), Phillips (1987), and Phillips and Perron (1988)) suffer from two main disadvantages: (i) the least squares estimates of the autoregressive parameter in unit root regressions will be biased toward zero (Orcutt (1948)); and (ii) they have low power against plausible trend-stationary alternatives (DeJong et al. (1992)). If standard unit root tests fail to reject the null, then, because of low power problems, nothing can be confidently implied about the persistence of shocks to the series.

The median-unbiased estimator of Andrews combines unbiasedness with the use of point and interval estimators in achieving a more accurate estimate of the persistence of shocks to economic time series. Interval estimation addresses the power problem by informing us whether we are failing to reject the null because it is true or because there is too much uncertainty. The bias correction delivers an impartiality property to the decision making process, because there is an equal chance of under- or over-estimating the autoregressive parameter in the unit root regression, and thus the probability of selecting the correct model is at least as large as the probability of selecting the incorrect model. Moreover, an unbiased estimate of the autoregressive coefficient will allow us to calculate an unbiased estimate of the persistence of shocks.

In comparison with standard least squares-based estimators of AR/UR models, other advantages of median-unbiased estimation are: (i) it is accurate when using finite data, as for first-order AR processes it is an exact procedure rather than an asymptotic one (as most standard unit root tests are); (ii) although it is based on normally-distributed innovations, it is robust to a range of nonnormal innovations (such as ARCH) in the unit root model; (iii) it exhibits a smooth transition between the (trend) stationary case and the unit root (random walk) case; (iv) the median-unbiased estimator is unbiased whether the AR parameter α is fixed or (as in a Bayesian setting) is random; and (v) it enables the calculation of unbiased scalar measures of the persistence of shocks (Andrews (1993))4.

The Andrews (1993) median-unbiased estimator is concerned with the estimation of first-order AR/UR models with independent identically distributed normal errors. The models of the time series {Yt: t=0,…,T} considered include those without an intercept (model 1); those with an intercept (model 2); and those with an intercept and time trend (model 3):5

Model 1:Yt=αYt1+tfort=1,,T,where α(1,1),Model 2:Yt=μ*+αYt1+tfort=1,,T,where μ*=μ(1α),andα(1,1],Model 3:Yt=μ*+αYt1+β*t+tfort=1,,T,where μ*=μ(1α)+αβ,β*=β(1α),andα(1,1],(1)

where εt are the innovations of the model, µ is the intercept and t is the trend. As model 1 is not of great practical importance (given that the mean is rarely known and equal to zero), both Andrews (1993) and this paper focus on the latter two models, in particular model 3 (including an intercept and time trend).

To calculate the median-unbiased estimator, suppose α^ is an estimator (of the autoregressive parameter, α) whose median function (m(α)) is uniquely defined ∀α ε (-1,1], then α^u (the median unbiased estimator of α) is defined as

α^u={1ifα^>m(1),m1(α^)ifm(1)<α^m(1),1ifα^m(1)(2)

where m(-1) = limα→-1 m(α), and m−1:(m(-1),m(1)→(-1,1] is the inverse function of m(.) that satisfies m−1(m(α)) = α for α ε (-1,1]. That is, if we have a function that for each true value of α yields the median value of α^, then we can simply use the inverse function to obtain a median unbiased estimate of α. For example, if the least squares estimate of α equals 0.8 then we do not use that estimate, but instead use that value of α which results in the least squares estimator having a median of 0.8.6 7 In addition, using the 0.05 and 0.95 quantile functions of α^ we can construct two-sided 90 percent confidence intervals or one-sided 95 percent confidence intervals for α. These confidence intervals can be used either to provide a measure of the accuracy of α^, or to construct exact one- or two-sided tests of the null hypothesis that α=α0. In this paper we use confidence intervals only to provide a measure of the accuracy of α^.8

The median, 0.05 quantile (lower band) and 0.95 quantile (upper band) of the function m(α) for the AR/UR model without and with constants and time trends has been computed for various sample sizes up to T+1=200 in Andrews (1993, Tables 13). In this paper we extend these results, using Monte Carlo simulations (of 10,000 replications) to estimate the median, lower band (0.05 quantile) and upper band (0.95 quantile) of the function of the AR coefficient for Andrews’ models 2 and 3, for sample sizes of T+1=300, T+1=400 and T+1=500 (see the tables in Appendixes IV and V).9 For sample sizes neither given in the tables of Andrews (1993) nor calculated in this paper, m(α) can be obtained by interpolation.

Table 2.

Results of Median-Unbiased Autoregressive/Unit Root Estimation, Commodity Price Indices, 1957:1-1998:12

article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
Source: Authors’ calculations.Notes: The results of this table are based on Model 3 of Andrews (1993)—see equation (1). IR(h) denotes the impulse response function at time horizon h (see equation (3)). CIR denotes the cumulative impulse response. HLS is, for the autoregressive parameter α≥ 0, the length of time until the impulse response of a unit shock to an economic time series is half its initial magnitude (see equation (4)). The entries in the rows labeled LS are the estimates of α, IR(h), CIR and HLS obtained using the least squares estimates of α from the regression equation (1), model 3. The entries in the rows labeled median-unbiased are the median-unbiased estimates of α^,IR^(h),CI^RandHL^S of α, IR(h), CIR and HLS, respectively, as defined in Section II. The intervals in square brackets below the median-unbiased estimates are the 90 percent confidence intervals. The median-unbiased estimates and exact confidence intervals given in this table were determined using quantiles generated by Monte Carlo simulation (involving 10,000 replications) and interpolation for sample sizes not given in Andrews (1993) or in Appendixes IV and V of this paper.Those commodities denoted by bold and an asterisk are not weighted in the all commodities index (for example, natural gas*); those commodities indented and denoted by bold are components of the all commodities index (for example, nonfuel and petroleum); those commodities indented and denoted by bold and italics are components of the nonfuel commodities index (for example, food); those commodities indented and denoted by italics are sub-components of the components of the nonfuel commodities index, which comprise those which are aggregated from more than one individual commodity index (for example, cereals) and individual commodity indices (for example, tea); those commodities indented are the individual indices of the sub-components of the nonfuel commodities index (for example, maize). For a description of the commodity price series, and their weights in the aggregate indices, see Appendix II.
Table 3.

Persistence of Price Shocks (HLS), Individual Commodities, 1957:1-1998:12

article image
Source: Authors’ calculations, derived using equation (4) and the median-unbiased estimates of the autoregressive parameter (α) set out in Table 2.Notes: HLS is, for α ≥0, the length of time until the impulse response of a unit shock to an economic time series is half its initial magnitude (see equation (4)). For a description of the commodity price series, see Appendix II.

To illustrate the use of the tables, consider the least squares estimator for model 2 and sample size T+1=300. Suppose the least squares estimate of the autoregressive parameter is 0.92 then, as shown in Appendix IV, the median estimate is 0.93, the 0.05 quantile is 0.97, and the 0.95 quantile is 0.89 (0.92 is 80 percent of the way between 0.887 and 0.928, therefore we choose 80 percent of the way between 0.85 and 0.90, which is 0.89). Thus the two-sided 90 percent confidence interval is (0.89, 0.97).

Our interest in this paper concerns the persistence of shocks to economic time series. The measures we will use to quantify this persistence are the impulse response function (IRF), the cumulative impulse response function (CIR), and the half-life of a unit shock (HLS). The IRF of a time series {Yt: t=1,2,…} measures the effect of a unit shock occurring at time t (that is, εt→εt +1 in equation (1)) on the values of Yt at the future time periods t+1, t+2,… The IRF quantifies the persistence of shocks to individual time series. For a series with a unit root the IRF never dies out; however, for a trend-stationary series the IRF does die out. In any event, whether an individual time series is trend stationary or has a unit root, the relative magnitude of the IRF across different time horizons indicates the extent of the persistence of shocks to the individual series. The IRF is defined as

IRF(τ)=ατforτ=0,1,2,(3)

Rather than consider the whole IRF, Andrews (1993) provides two scalar measures of persistence that summarize the impulse response function: the cumulative impulse response (CIR) and the half-life of a unit shock (HLS). Whereas the CIR gives the total cumulative effect of a unit shock on the entire future of a time series (that is, the sum of the IRF over all time horizons), for α ≥ 0 the HLS gives the length of time until the impulse response of a unit shock is half its original magnitude. These measures are defined as

CIR=τ=0IRF(τ)=(1α)1andHLS=ABS(log(1/2)/log(α)).(4)

Exactly median-unbiased estimators and exact confidence intervals are also calculated for the IRF, CIR and HLS, which provide information on the variability of the scalar measures of persistence. The median-unbiased estimate for these measures of persistence is calculated by using the median-unbiased estimate of α in the formulae of equation (4). Similarly, the two-sided 90 percent confidence interval is calculated using the 0.05 and 0.95 quantiles in the formulae of equation (4).10

III. Data

In this study of the persistence of shocks to commodity prices, we use the monthly commodity price data taken from the nominal price indices reported in the International Monetary Fund’s International Financial Statistics (IFS) for the period January 1957 to December 1998. The data used in this study are real commodity price series, formed as the ratio of the chosen IFS nominal commodity index (defined in U.S. dollars per unit) deflated by the index of manufacturing unit values (base year 1990).11 The nominal commodity indices are for 44 individual commodities, 8 subaggregates of similar commodity indices (cereals, vegetable oils and protein meals, meat, coffee, timber, hardwoods, softwoods and wool), and 8 aggregations of particular indices (all commodities, nonfuel commodities, agricultural raw materials, beverages, fertilizer, foods, metals and sugar).12 The data are expressed in logarithmic form.

Descriptive statistics of the real commodity price data are given in Appendix I; the definition and derivation of each nominal commodity index is given in Appendix II. For most of the real commodity price series there is evidence of statistically significant skewness, with p-values for the skewness measure less than 0.05. The majority of the series exhibit negative skewness, implying that the median exceeds the mean (skewness to the left). Most commodities (apart from copper, hides, cotton and wheat) also demonstrate substantial kurtosis, with tails of their distribution much thicker than those of the normal distribution. This result is consistent with the findings of Deaton and Laroque (1992), who provide a model of commodity cycles that attempts to mimic the occasional sharp peaks (due to the exhaustion of stocks) and long-lived flat bottoms which characterize actual commodity price cycles.

The all commodities index and its components (nonfuel commodities and petroleum) are presented in Figure 1. This shows the rapid rise in petroleum prices in the 1970s and their downward movement in the mid-1980s; the gradual fall in commodity prices since the peaks of the early-1970s and mid-1980s, and the decline to record lows at end-1998; it also illustrates the increasing volatility of commodity prices since the early 1970s. Figures 2 and 3 depict the recent evolution of petroleum prices (which have returned to their pre-oil-shock levels) and nonfuel commodities (which have fallen to near record lows since their recent peak in early 1997).

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Prices of Primary Commodities, 1957:1 - 1998:12

(Log of Real Price Indices, 1990=100)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1999, 080; 10.5089/9781451850284.001.A001

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Spot Prices of Crude Petroleum, 1997-99

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1999, 080; 10.5089/9781451850284.001.A001

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Index of Prices of Nonfuel Primary Commodities, 1997-99

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1999, 080; 10.5089/9781451850284.001.A001

Each of the eight aggregated price indices is presented in Figure 4, as well as the petroleum price index, in both real and nominal (U.S. dollar) terms. Noticeable in many figures is the jump in nominal prices in 1972, following the depreciation of the dollar. There appears to be a tendency for the price indices to trend downward over the period, particularly for nonfuel commodities, beverages, metals and food. Many of the price indices also exhibit a good deal of year-to-year variability. For example, the evolution of the beverages index is highlighted by the supply shock of the mid-1970s (due to a severe Brazilian frost in 1975 which sharply cut available stocks). Sharp price movements in other indices are often associated with the formation and suspension of international commodity agreements designed to support world commodity prices. The petroleum index displays the spikes in prices associated with the Organization for Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) oil shocks of 1973 and 1979, while the fall in the metals index after 1985 is associated with a general lack of demand, expanding production and the collapse of the International Tin Agreement. The peaks in the sugar index in 1963, 1974 and 1980 reflect, respectively, the suspension of the International Sugar Agreement, a rapid decline in the ratio of world stocks to sugar consumption, and adverse supply shocks in key exporting countries. The peaks in the food, raw materials and metals indices in 1973-74 partly reflect the influence of adverse supply shocks, but are also largely attributable to strong demand for commodities from fast-growing industrialized countries, prior to the oil-shock-induced recessions of the 1970s (IMF (1986)).

Figure 4.
Figure 4.
Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Prices of Primary Commodities

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1999, 080; 10.5089/9781451850284.001.A001

IV. Empirical Results

In this Section we apply the median-unbiased procedures to the series of world real commodity prices described in Section III. The 60 commodity price series are analyzed using Andrews’ (1993) model 3 (including an intercept and time trend). Table 2 sets out the results. As an example of how to interpret the table, we take the particular cases of tea, coarse wool and tobacco. For tea, the median-unbiased (MU) estimate of α is 0.936, as opposed to the least squares (LS) estimate of 0.926. While the difference between these two estimates is small in absolute terms, this has a relatively large effect on calculations of the persistence of the shocks. The length of the 90 percent confidence interval for the median-unbiased estimate of α (0.906, 0.967) indicates that α is estimated fairly precisely. The IRF decline monotonically toward zero (that is, the IRF eventually die out). The estimates yield a [LS 13.514; MU 15.625] 16 percent increase in the estimate of CIR (the total cumulative effect of a unit shock on the future evolution of the price series). This indicates that a unit shock to tea generates an eventual (t=∞) 15.625 unit displacement of the level of the price of tea. Moreover, the time it takes for half of the impulse response of a shock to the price of tea to dissipate is 9.016 months for the LS estimate and 10.480 months for the MU estimate. Accordingly, shocks to tea do not appear to be particularly persistent.

Alternatively, for wool (coarse) the median-unbiased estimate of α is 0.990, as opposed to the least squares estimate of 0.976. The IRF decline monotonically toward zero, yet do not die out. The length of the 90 percent confidence interval for the MU estimate of α (0.969, 1.00) indicates that α is estimated fairly precisely (and with more precision than for tea). Moreover, the LS estimate of α is relatively close to the lower bound of the MU estimate’s 90 percent confidence interval, which indicates that the series for coarse wool exhibits large differences between the LS and median-unbiased measures of persistence to shocks. The estimates yield a [LS 41.667; MU 100.724] 142 percent increase in the estimate of CIR (the total cumulative effect of a unit shock on the future evolution of the price series). This indicates that a unit shock to coarse wool generates an eventual (t=∞) 100.724 unit displacement of the level of the price of wool. Moreover, the time it takes for half of the impulse response of a shock to the price of coarse wool to dissipate rises from 28.533 months for the LS estimate to 69.649 months for the MU estimate. Accordingly, shocks to coarse wool do appear to be rather persistent, and given that the median-unbiased measure of HLS for coarse wool lies outside the 90 percent confidence interval for the estimated HLS for tea, shocks to coarse wool are significantly longer than those affecting tea.13

For tobacco the median-unbiased estimate of α is 1.00, as opposed to the least squares estimate of 0.989. As for tea, while the difference between these two estimates is small in absolute terms, it has a large effect on calculations of the persistence of the time series. The length of the 90 percent confidence interval for the median-unbiased estimate of α (0.992, 1.00) indicates that α is estimated very precisely. Also, the IRF for the MU estimate do not decline monotonically toward zero. The estimates yield an infinite [LS 90.989, MU ∞] increase in the estimate of CIR (the total cumulative effect of a unit shock on the future evolution of the price series). This indicates that, for example, a unit shock to tobacco generates an eventual (t=∞) infinite displacement of the level of the price of tobacco—the effect of a unit shock becomes a permanent component of the time series. Moreover, the time it takes for half of the impulse response of a shock to the price of tobacco to dissipate is 62.666 months for the LS estimate, while the MU estimate indicates that price shocks do not dissipate. Accordingly, shocks to tobacco are permanent, and so tobacco prices do not display mean-reverting behavior in response to a shock to prices. The MU estimates of HLS and the associated confidence intervals indicate that there is much better evidence in favor of very long-lived shocks for tobacco than for coarse wool.

In general, the median-unbiased estimates of α are closer to 1.00 than the least squares estimates, with the difference between them (a measure of the downward bias of the least squares estimator) ranging between 0.004 and 0.05 (see Table 2). In turn, these differences generate median-unbiased estimates of the CIR and HLS that are between near zero and 326 percent larger than those generated from the least squares estimates. Bananas has the lowest estimate of α (of 0.748). The 90 percent confidence intervals for most series range between 0.950 and 1.00; the confidence interval for other series differs somewhat, ranging in length from 0.001 (gold) to 0.156 (heating oil).

Of interest is the persistence results for the 8 aggregated series, in comparison with the results for the 44 individual commodity series. Shocks to the all commodities, nonfuel, beverages and food series do not dissipate, indicating that shocks to these aggregated commodity series are permanent.14 For these series, the current price can be expressed as the price in the previous period, plus a random shock; accordingly, currently low prices will tend to remain low in subsequent periods, and will not tend to revert to an average level. In contrast, the aggregated series for agricultural raw materials, fertilizer, metals and sugar exhibit relatively short half-lives. For these series, prices do eventually revert to their average values. Accordingly, it is important to examine the time series properties of individual commodities before making judgements about the persistence of shocks affecting them, as the persistence of shocks to the aggregated series may differ greatly from the persistence of shocks to individual time series.

The above results indicate that, using the median-unbiased model, the majority of the 44 individual commodity series are subject to price shocks which are not permanent (that is, less than infinitely persistent). Given that most price shocks have their origin on the supply side of the market, we typically find that those commodities with less-persistent shocks are those where the weather plays a key role in the generation of supply shocks. Those commodities with more-persistent shocks tend to be those where weather plays a limited role. For persistent shocks it is likely that the entry of new producers could have long-run effects on the evolution of prices (metals, fuels and fertilizers), and that those commodities where shocks have a greater possibility of originating from the demand side of the market could result in long periods of excess supply or demand (such as in the development of synthetic substitutes (wool and cotton), or technological change in demand for inputs (metals)). Persistent shocks could also arise due to the formation or termination of international commodity price agreements (Gersovitz and Paxson (1990)). The strong showing of beverages in the persistence of price shocks is most likely due to supply shocks which have long-lasting effects on prices for tree crops (such as frosts, fires and diseases). For both beverages and metals, high prices induce investment activity which, because of long periods of gestation, can result in extended periods of excess productive capacity and flat prices.

An alternative method of calculating persistence to that derived here is the nonparametric estimator of Cochrane (1988), which measures the fraction of a price shock which can be expected to persist into the indefinite future. Gersovitz and Paxson (1990) apply Cochrane’s method to estimate persistence, using annual World Bank commodity data for the period 1950-87. They find persistence measures which are typically lower than would be suggested by low-order ARMA models.15 Cochrane’s (1988) approach does provide information as to whether the volatility of commodity price shocks is mostly in the short run or mostly in the long run, but such information is of limited use to policy makers in determining how to respond to shocks. The key question for policy makers concerns the typical duration of price shocks to commodities; that is, whether shocks are typically shortlived (in which case scope may exist for price stabilization or consumption-smoothing policies) or typically long-lived (in which case structural adjustment to the new equilibrium is warranted). In contrast to Cochrane (1988), the Andrews (1993) approach used in this paper to measure persistence does enable the calculation of unbiased scalar measures of the duration and variability of typical price shocks.

Finally, while it is important to ascertain the duration of shocks to commodity prices, knowledge of the size of price shocks is also of great interest. Very small, yet long-lived, price shocks will have different implications for the appropriateness of any policy response (particularly the efficacy of price stabilization schemes) than very large, long-lived price shocks. In this connection, our estimation of persistence enables a calculation of the size of shocks to commodity prices. For example, in the case of petroleum (spot crude), the standard error of the regression (equation (1)) is 0.0827, indicating that one-third of the time, the market for petroleum will be faced with the prospect of a price change of greater than 8 percent. Using the specific case of oil-dependent Nigeria as an example, in 1998 Nigerian petroleum traded at about US$12.80 per barrel. Accordingly, in any given month there is a one-in-six chance that the realized price of petroleum would drop by about US$1.06 per barrel or more. Nigerian oil exports totaled about 2 million barrels per day in 1998, and so, given our findings as to the permanence of shocks to oil, there is a one-in-six chance that such an adverse shock may occur, which would result in a reduction of its petroleum export revenues by about 8 percent (about US$750 million per year in 1998 dollars) in perpetuity (see Tables 12, and IMF (1999)). Clearly, not only are shocks to petroleum very long-lived, but they can also be large in magnitude.

V. Policy Issues

Variability in the prices of major commodity exports contributes greatly to variability in the export revenues of commodity-dependent countries. When there is a fall in the real price of a commodity-exporting country’s dominant export, then it experiences a decline in the international purchasing power of a given basket of its national output. Clearly, both short-run volatility and long-run trend movements in commodity prices present serious challenges for many developing countries, because of their large impacts on both the balance of payments and on government budgetary positions. In the design of an appropriate policy response, it is important to have knowledge of the typical duration of shocks to commodity prices. For example, a key input to the composition, sequencing and duration of structural adjustment programs for countries suffering depressed world prices for their important exports will be expectations as to whether export returns will bounce back quickly or instead are expected to continue to be depressed for a long period. In addition, the efficacy and efficiency of government commodity stabilization schemes will be dependent on whether price shocks to major exports are expected to be short-lived or long-lasting.

A. Schemes to Ameliorate Price Variability

Variable commodity prices may result not only in variable export revenues, but also in variable producer surpluses, variable patterns of consumption and variability in government fiscal positions. While borrowing and lending can in principle offset the impact on consumers, producers and government, in many developing countries poorly functioning financial systems and sovereign risk problems limit their recourse to domestic and external financing as a response to price variability. Instead, the attention of policy makers has been largely focussed on the need to stabilize commodity export earnings, and one or more of the following measures have typically been adopted:16

(i) stabilization of world commodity prices (through the exercise of market power by a monopolistic producer or producer cartel, or through international commodity agreements involving both importing and exporting countries); (ii) stabilization of producer revenues, given producer prices (using risk management instruments such as swaps and forward, futures and options contracts); (iii) stabilization of government revenues, given world commodity prices (by the implementation of revenue stabilization funds, designed to undertake precautionary savings to absorb cyclical variation in export revenues and profits from state utilities); (iv) compensatory financing to offset variability in export revenues, given world commodity prices (through domestic stabilization funds or international schemes for compensatory finance); and (v) stabilization of domestic producer and/or consumer prices, given world prices (through a variable export tax or tariff, the activities of agricultural marketing boards or the operation of domestic stockpiles and stabilization funds).

As our interest in this paper is not with the policy implications of stabilizing producer17 or government revenues,18 we will concentrate on the implications of our persistence analysis for policy issues in the remaining aspects of public intervention to stabilize commodity price shocks. It should also be recognized that apart from the consumption-smoothing arguments for stabilization schemes (which essentially stand or fall on the persistence of shocks), there may be risk-reduction arguments for such schemes. We will not be directly discussing the policy response to price volatility in this paper—a discussion of this can be found in Reinhart and Wickham (1994) and Borenzstein and Reinhart (1994), among others.

Traditionally, governments in developing countries have assumed a major role in smoothing the domestic effects of fluctuations in world commodity prices, typically by stockholding activities designed to curtail price variability. The rationales for government intervention are usually based on market imperfections, such as financial market imperfections and information problems (Newbery and Stiglitz (1981) and Deaton (1992)). These policy actions often set price stabilization as a major objective, and at the domestic level are typically implemented through institutional arrangements such as agricultural marketing boards and stabilization funds. At the international level, commodity agreements and compensatory financing from international organizations (such as the International Monetary Fund’s Contingency and Compensatory Financing Facility (CCFF)) have also been used to smooth the effects on export earnings of shocks to world commodity prices. Aside from the issue of whether the government is better at managing commodity price shocks than private agents, the success of such intervention strategies critically hinges on the assumption that the nature of the commodity price shock is temporary, and accordingly is expected to reverse itself in the short-run.19 Using the results presented in Section IV, we examine these issues further below.

B. Differences in the Persistence of Shocks to Commodity Prices

The findings of this study suggest that shocks to most commodity prices are typically finite in duration, with 43 of the 60 aggregated and individual series having finite median HLS measures (Table 2). Were we to follow the standard practice in the literature, we would then most likely conclude that for these price series, scope did exist for commodity stabilization schemes and external borrowing to smooth the path of national consumption (León and Soto (1997)).

However, the scalar measures of persistence derived from the Andrews (1993) method indicate that for many of the commodity price series exhibiting finitely-persistent shocks, the mean reversion of prices typically takes an extremely long time. If we arbitrarily choose a generous HLS of five years (60 months) as the cutoff point beyond which the cost (involving storage, financing and output-reduction costs) of maintaining any stabilization scheme would be likely to become prohibitive, then 17 of the 44 individual commodity price series are in excess of this cutoff, yet still have finite persistence (see shaded panels of Table 3 and Figures 5c–5d). For these 17 series, it is doubtful that the consumption-smoothing gains arising from price stabilization would exceed the cost of maintaining the stabilization agreement. In fact, we find that the persistence of price shocks (measured in terms of HLS) is less than 5 years (60 months) for only 17 of the 44 individual commodity price series (see Table 3 and Figures 5a–5b). Panel one of Table 3 and Figure 5a reveal that commodity stabilization schemes are on firmest ground, in terms of persistence of shocks lasting less than one year, for just 7 of the 44 individual commodity price series.20

Figure 5.
Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Results of Median-Unbiased Autoregressive/Unit Root Estimation, Median and 90 Percent Confidence Interval of HLS, Individual Commodities, 1957:1 - 1998:12

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1999, 080; 10.5089/9781451850284.001.A001

Source: Authors’ calculations. The median HLS is denoted by the circle, while the 90 percent confidence interval for the median HLS is denoted by the range of the bar. These results match the median-unbiased results of the last column of Table 2. See Table 2 for additional details, and Appendix II for a description of the commodity price series.

In interpreting Table 3 it should also be kept in mind that the actual HLS for any given commodity has a 50 percent chance of being lower than the estimated median HLS, and a 50 percent chance of exceeding the estimated median HLS. For example, while the estimated median HLS for rubber is 43 months (Tables 23 and Figure 5b), half of the actual realizations of the HLS for rubber will be less than, and half will exceed, the estimated median HLS. If the maximum length for the sustainability of any rubber stabilization scheme was a HLS of 5 years (60 months), then policy makers would need to factor in the likelihood that actual shocks to rubber prices could last longer than this, notwithstanding that the estimated median is within the sustainable period of time. In contrast, if the maximum length for the sustainability of any tea stabilization scheme was also a HLS of 5 years (60 months), then policy makers might feel more comfortable implementing such a scheme for tea than for rubber, given that the estimated median HLS for tea is only 10 months, which is much further from the maximum length of financial sustainability.21

As set out in Table 3 and Figure 5e, for 10 of the 44 individual commodity price series, we find that their price shocks are typically very long-lived (permanent). If commodity price shocks are highly persistent, then national or international arrangements to smooth price shocks will not be sustainable, and countries dependent on international trade in commodities affected by these long-lived shocks will need to adjust their macroeconomic and structural policies to conform with their new steady state levels of national income, consumption and wealth.

By providing median-unbiased measures of persistence and their associated confidence intervals, the Andrews (1993) approach allows policy makers to determine their own particular level of tolerance of the risk of the realization of a highly-persistent shock to their commodity of interest. Using the HLS as our measure of persistence, and again taking the examples of tea and rubber, respectively, we find that the estimated 90 percent confidence intervals range from 7 to 21 months and from 18 months to infinity. Accordingly, 5 percent of the actual realizations of the HLS for tea will exceed 21 months, while 5 percent (or more) of the actual realizations of the HLS for rubber will be permanent. This implies that a stabilization scheme for tea is much less likely to collapse than one established for rubber. If we look at all of the 44 individual commodity price series, and again assume that the maximum length for the sustainability of any stabilization scheme is a HLS of 60 months, then there are only five commodities (tea, sugar (EU), bananas, hides and lamb) for which 95 out of 100 realizations of the HLS will be within this sustainability limit (Tables 23 and Figures 5a–5b). While these results do not entirely rule out the successful operation of stabilization schemes for those commodities outside the five mentioned above, they do highlight the much greater likelihood that such schemes will confront shocks which last longer than the maximum sustainable length of time, and thus may not be financially sustainable.22

In addition, while our analysis does not differentiate between positive and negative shocks to commodity prices, it is clear that in the actual commodity price data upward movements in prices are typically shorter in duration than downward movements in prices (Deaton and Laroque (1992)). Accordingly, an implication of our analysis is that most of the long-lived shocks are likely to be downward movements in prices, which have important policy consequences for domestic and international schemes to stabilize earnings from commodity exports.

C. Implications of Persistence Measures for Stabilization Schemes

What should be the policy response (if any) of commodity-exporting developing countries to shocks to world commodity prices? If the persistence of such shocks is relatively short-lived, then scope does exist for domestic and international stabilization schemes to dampen the effects of price shocks, and for external borrowing and compensatory finance to smooth the path of national income and consumption. In such circumstances, it is less likely that the financing, storage and output-reduction costs of stabilization schemes will exceed any consumption-smoothing benefits derived from the stability of export returns. However, if shocks to the price of any given country’s commodity of interest are demonstrated to be long-lived, then the cost of operating a stabilization scheme will most likely exceed any associated smoothing benefits. In this situation there is likely to be little scope for domestic or international stabilization schemes to be successfully implemented.

Domestic stabilization schemes

Domestic price stabilization schemes, typically taking the form of either buffer stock schemes or those that operate a buffer fund, are often implemented in commodity-exporting countries to reduce the effects of volatile world commodity prices on domestic prices or export returns. Attempts by government to stabilize prices to smooth the incomes of producers will most likely involve such stabilization funds holding a large amount of foreign reserves, or having the capacity to borrow large amounts of external capital, if there is a slow process of mean-reversion following (adverse) shocks to commodity prices. The opportunity cost of such reserves is likely to be large, given that the rate of return from investment in many capital-deficient developing countries is likely to exceed the return on foreign reserve holdings (Deaton (1992), Borenzstein et al. (1994)). In addition, the accumulation of reserves during long-lasting price booms would be expensive (in terms of forgone earnings), most likely politically difficult to maintain, and prone to be used to fund unproductive investments (Deaton (1992)).

Many national commodity stabilization schemes, typically involving countries with market power in the determination of world prices for particular commodities, were terminated during the 1980s and 1990s due to their financial unsustainability. A prominent example of the demise of a national stabilization arrangement concerns the collapse of the Australian wool stabilization scheme in 1992 (Bardsley (1994)). Our findings for wool indicate that while coarse wool and fine wool both have finite persistence (median HLS of 70 and 57 months, respectively), their associated 90 percent confidence intervals include infinity. Accordingly, while half the actual realizations of the HLS for both types of wool will be less than the median HLS (and so potentially financeable under any buffer stock arrangement), half will exceed the median, and 5 percent (or more) of the realizations will be permanent. Accordingly, both types of wool do not appear to be likely candidates for the successful operation of any price stabilization arrangement.

International commodity agreements

Many international commodity agreements designed to stabilize world commodity prices and raise returns to commodity producers (typically through buffer stock operations or export controls) also failed in the 1980s and 1990s, as the cost of maintaining them in the face of persistent price falls became unsustainable. International commodity agreements, typically using buffer stocks and/or export controls as tools of market intervention, were terminated for the following commodities: International Sugar Agreement (commenced in 1954, lapsed in 1984 due to the expiry of export quotas); International Tin Agreement (commenced in 1954, collapsed in 1985 due to the exhaustion of the resources of buffer stock scheme); International Cocoa Agreement (commenced in 1972, suspended in 1988 due to an inability to finance the buffer stock scheme); and the International Coffee Agreement (commenced in 1962, suspended in 1989 after export quotas were allowed to expire). Only the International Natural Rubber Agreement (commenced in 1980) continues to give rise to active market intervention, although its role is being increasingly questioned by major producing countries.

While most international commodity agreements either lapsed or collapsed in the 1980s, the continuing relative decline and high variability of primary commodity prices in the 1990s may provide the catalyst for associations of producer countries to increasingly attempt to take unilateral action (as in the case of coffee in 1993-94) to manage supply in order to raise world prices (Gilbert (1996)). Our findings indicate that for those commodities which experience very slow reversion in prices to their mean, of which coffee is a prime example, the temptation to take such action should be resisted, as the long-lived nature of shocks to coffee prices makes such schemes likely to be unsustainable (Table 2 and Figures 5d–5e).

International commodity agreements and their national counterparts (particularly domestic stabilization funds) have all suffered from a predilection to stabilize prices at an excessively high level, either due to a failure to properly account for deterministic trends or in an effort to subsidize producer returns.23 For a buffer-fund-based commodity agreement to remain viable, support prices need to be flexible downward when the current level proves to be unsustainable; in practice, such a price movement often becomes politically impossible, leading to the demise of such arrangements.

Not coincidentally, many of these failed international stabilization schemes involved commodities which our analysis demonstrates exhibit long-lived shocks—tin, cocoa, coffee and sugar (see Tables 23 and Figures 5d–5e). In contrast, our analysis finds that rubber, which has the one surviving international commodity agreement, experiences relatively short-lived shocks (see Tables 23 and Figure 5b). Our findings also indicate that the commodity associated with the most famous producer cartel, petroleum, also experiences highly-persistent shocks (see Tables 23 and Figure 5e). While the association of petroleum producers survives, OPEC’s membership has not been broad enough to enable it to influence prices without subsequent loss of market share.24

Compensatory finance

An important example of compensatory financing is the IMF’s CCFF. The CCFF, which began in 1988, was preceded by the Compensatory Financing Facility (CFF), which began in 1963. The CCFF is designed to smooth the effects of a temporary, exogenously-caused shortfall in merchandise export receipts in a particular country below its medium-term trend. It recognizes the distinction between short-lived and long-lived shocks, and that the latter should not be financed but involve structural adjustment of the economy to its new long-run level of national income and consumption (Goreux (1980), Kaibni (1986)).25 The CCFF seeks to provide countries lacking either sufficient reserves, or the capacity to borrow externally, with the capacity to smooth the path of national consumption in the presence of a temporary shock to export earnings. Use of the CCFF by developing countries peaked at 48 percent of credit extended by the IMF in 1978. While drawings under the CCFF were active in the 1980s and early 1990s, drawings after 1993 were minimal until 1998, when use of the CCFF jumped sharply to comprise over 10 percent of IMF credit.26

The long-lived nature of shocks to many commodity prices indicates that in these highly-persistent cases the scope for commodity stabilization policy is limited. Similarly, income-stabilizing schemes providing compensatory finance (such as the IMF’s CCFF) are predicated on the assumption that the temporary shortfall in export earnings will be self-reversing. This assumption will not hold true (on average) where the shortfall in export earnings is (for given supply) caused by an adverse price shock to commodities which are subject to long-lived price shocks.27 Of course, on average this assumption may hold true where the shortfall in export earnings is caused by either: (for given supply) an adverse price shock to commodities which are subject to short-lived price shocks; or (for given price) a temporary fall in supply.

The resurgence of lending by the IMF under the CCFF in the late-1990s has largely involved countries experiencing adverse supply shocks to important commodity exports. For example, both Pakistan (December 1998) and Azerbaijan (January 1999) have received funds under the CCFF for temporary shortfalls in export earnings arising from weather-induced, adverse shocks to their harvests of cotton, an important exportable (see Table 1). While the temporary nature of these supply-based shocks to export earnings is clear, our empirical findings indicate that the case for a CCFF to provide compensatory finance for any shortfall in cotton export earnings arising from an adverse shock to cotton prices (given supply) would be much weaker. While cotton has price shocks of finite persistence, they are typically very long-lived (median HLS of 151 months), and its associated 90 percent confidence interval includes infinity (Tables 23 and Figure 5d). Although half the actual realizations of the HLS for cotton will be less than the median HLS (and so potentially temporary in nature), half will exceed the median HLS, and 5 percent (or more) of the realizations will be permanent. Accordingly, cotton does not appear (on average) to be a commodity which experiences price-based temporary shocks.

VI. Conclusion

Movements in commodity prices are a key determinant of the performance of the world economy. They affect the level and stability of export incomes earned by developing countries, the cost of inputs to production in industrial countries, the allocation (sectoral and spatial) of world capital flows, and in particular rates of national economic growth. Knowledge of the persistence of shocks to commodity prices is an important input into the design of stabilization schemes to ameliorate the real macroeconomic effects of such shocks, particularly in developing countries.

In comparison with results from standard unit root regressions, which are largely uninformative on the question of the persistence of shocks, the scalar persistence measures used in this paper allow for a determination of the typical duration of price shocks as well as the variability of this duration. Using monthly International Monetary Fund data on 60 commodity price series over the period 1957 to 1998, this study finds that shocks to the prices of many primary commodities are typically long-lasting, and that the variability of the persistence of price shocks is quite wide. Consequently, it is incorrect to view shocks to commodity prices as generally being temporary phenomena that largely reflect short-lived variability in supply interacting with relatively unchanging demand. Notwithstanding this, the persistence of shocks to commodity prices does vary greatly across commodities, with tree crops and metals typically having long-lasting shocks and softwoods typically having short-lived shocks.

If shocks to commodity price series are extremely persistent, then an adverse price shock to any given commodity is likely to engender depressed prices for a long period of time. In such circumstances, government-supported price-stabilization activities and compensatory financing are likely to be ineffective, and external borrowing for consumption-smoothing is likely to be unsustainable. Even where shocks to commodity price series are relatively less persistent, the likelihood that the benefits of smoothing the path of domestic prices (given world commodity prices) exceeds the cost of operating stabilization schemes or servicing external borrowing remains open to question. Moreover, while our results do not entirely rule out the successful operation of stabilization arrangements for many commodities, they do highlight the potential risk that such schemes will confront shocks which last longer than typically observed, and thus may not be financially sustainable.

APPENDIX I

Descriptive Statistics, Commodities, 1957:1 to 1998:12

article image
article image
article image
Notes: For all variables, the data is monthly over the sample period 1957:1 to 1998:12, except for the following price indices which all end at 1998:12 but begin at the following dates: gasoline (1982:6); gold (1964:1); hardwood (1982:5); hardwood (logs, 1982:5); hardwood (sawn, 1982:5); heating oil (1986:6); natural gas (1985:1); softwood (1982:5); softwood (logs, 1982:5); softwood (sawn, 1982:5); and tobacco (1967:12). The variables (described in Section III) are the logarithm of the real commodity index, where the real index is the nominal commodity price index deflated by the index of the export unit value of manufactures (MUV). The statistics are sample moments. The numbers in parentheses are probability values under the null hypothesis of normality. For a description of the commodity price series, see Appendix II. The skewness and kurtosis formulae, and the test statistics based upon them, are taken from Kendall and Stuart (1958).

APPENDIX II

Specifications for Commodity Prices

article image
article image
article image
Source: International Monetary Fund.

Average of daily quotations.

Average of weekly quotations.

Monthly quotations.

The price is quoted in cents per 1 percent Fe dry metric ton f.o.b. (DMTU). For 64.3 percent Itabira fines, a price of 28.6 cts/DMTU is equal to US$18.38 per metric ton.

APPENDIX III

Persistence of Commodity Price Shocks Across Exchange Rate Regimes

To assume that the time series properties of commodity prices are unchanged over time is potentially restrictive, especially given the nature of the shocks to the world economy during the sample period examined here. Cuddington and Liang (1997) show that the volatility of commodity prices increased significantly after the Bretton Woods system broke down.28 We examine whether the breakdown of the fixed exchange rate system in the 1970s also lead to a change in the cyclical behavior of the levels of real commodity prices.

From a theoretical point of view, a class of “equilibrium models” demonstrate neutrality of the nominal exchange arrangement for the behavior of real macroeconomic variables such as real exchange rates (Helpman (1981)). On the other hand, the observed relatively slow adjustment of goods prices compared with those of asset prices, such as exchange rates and commodity prices, suggests that nominal exchange rate movements may have an impact on real economic variables (Mussa (1986)). Although both primary commodities and manufactures are internationally traded, their underlying market structures have long been perceived to be different. While the prices of most non-oil primary commodities are largely determined in well-organized auction markets, the markets for many manufactured goods are thought to be much less competitive. Consequently, how fast changes in the exchange rate pass through to the prices of final goods may be quite different for the two goods (Liang (1998)). Therefore, it is conceivable that the differing speeds of exchange rate pass-through may lengthen the persistence of price shocks in the presence of flexibility in the nominal exchange rate. If we assume that the processes generating real shocks to commodity prices (from either the supply or demand sides) are not exchange rate regime-dependent, the degree of shock persistence may increase under a flexible exchange regime if manufactured goods prices respond more slowly to nominal exchange rate changes than do the prices of primary commodities.

To examine this contention empirically, this Appendix compares the persistence of real commodity price shocks across nominal exchange rate regimes for those commodities with monthly data for the full sample (January 1957 to December 1998), and follows Eichengreen (1994) and Cuddington and Liang (1997) in denoting the fixed exchange rate regime as January 1957-July 1971, and the flexible exchange rate regime as August 1971-December 1998.

For the 51 commodity price series with observations in both exchange rate regimes, in 23 series the median-unbiased calculation of the HLS (derived from equation (4)) is less than permanent in only one of the two regimes; for another 15 series the HLS is permanent (infinitely persistent) in both regimes; and for 13 series the HLS is permanent (infinitely persistent) in neither regime.29 Of the 36 cases with HLS less than infinity in at least one of the two regimes, in 17 of the cases the persistence is lower in the fixed exchange rate regime, and in 10 of these 17 cases the difference in HLS is statistically significant (as the confidence interval of the HLS for the fixed exchange rate regime does not contain the HLS for that same commodity estimated for the flexible exchange rate regime).30 Conversely, in the 19 cases where the persistence is lower in the flexible exchange rate regime than in the fixed regime, in only two of the cases are the difference in HLS across exchange rate regimes statistically significant (as the confidence interval of the HLS for the flexible exchange rate regime contains the HLS for that same commodity estimated for the fixed exchange rate regime).

Table 4 reports the HLS for the abovementioned 12 commodity price series that exhibit a significant difference in the persistence of shocks across exchange rate regimes. Shock persistence was higher in the fixed exchange rate period only for sugar (EU) and wool (coarse), both of which traditionally have their prices determined in markets subject to public intervention. On the other hand, for most of the market-determined prices for the eight individual commodities, shock persistence increased dramatically after the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate arrangement collapsed in 1971. The HLS increased from about 15 months to infinity for both the all commodities and food indices.

Table 4.

Effect of Nominal Exchange Rate Regime on the Median HLS for Commodities, 1957:1-1998:12

article image
Source: Authors’ calculations, derived using equation (4) and the median-unbiased estimates of the autoregressive parameter (α).Notes: HLS is, for α≥0, the length of time until the impulse response of a unit shock to an economic time series is half its initial magnitude (see equation (4)).

In summary, unlike the conclusions reached by Cuddington and Liang (1997) regarding volatility, we find only weak support for the hypothesis that the nominal exchange rate regime has had a significant impact on the extent to which shocks to the level of commodity prices persist over time. Nevertheless, these findings still shed light on how we should analyze the interactions between the movements of nominal exchange rate and commodity prices.

There is a rich literature on the question of how dollar-denominated primary commodity prices respond to changes in the value of the dollar against other currencies (see Ridler and Yandle (1972) and Dornbusch (1985)). A large number of studies have found that dollar commodity prices have a greater than unit response to changes in the value of the dollar.31 On the other hand, most empirical studies on how responsive trade prices of manufactures are to exchange rate changes, especially in the U.S. economy, have found that exchange rate pass-though has been far from unity (Mann (1986)). The findings of this paper support the hypothesis that, at least for certain commodities, exchange pass-through mechanisms for primary commodities and manufactured goods are different. In addition, for those individual commodities that do exhibit significantly different patterns of shock persistence across exchange rate regimes, our findings suggest that it has most likely become more difficult for countries that specialize in these commodities to smooth the fluctuations in their export earnings in a world with greater exchange rate flexibility.

APPENDIX IV

Monte Carlo Estimates of Quantiles of the Least Squares Estimator of α for Mode