Bank Lending and Interest Rate Changes in a Dynamic Matching Model
Author:
Mr. Giovanni Dell'Ariccia
Search for other papers by Mr. Giovanni Dell'Ariccia in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
and
Mr. Pietro Garibaldi
Search for other papers by Mr. Pietro Garibaldi in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Contributor Notes

Authors’ E-Mail Address: gdellariccia@imf.org, pgaribaldi@imf.org

This paper presents theory and evidence on the dynamic relationship between aggregate bank lending and interest rate changes. Theoretically, it proposes and solves a stochastic matching model where credit expansion and contraction are time consuming. It shows that the response of bank lending to changes in money market rates is likely to be asymmetric and depends crucially on two structural parameters: the speed at which new loans become available, and the speed at which banks recall existing loans. Empirically, it provides evidence that bank lending in Mexico and the United States responds asymmetrically to positive and negative shocks in money market rates.

Abstract

This paper presents theory and evidence on the dynamic relationship between aggregate bank lending and interest rate changes. Theoretically, it proposes and solves a stochastic matching model where credit expansion and contraction are time consuming. It shows that the response of bank lending to changes in money market rates is likely to be asymmetric and depends crucially on two structural parameters: the speed at which new loans become available, and the speed at which banks recall existing loans. Empirically, it provides evidence that bank lending in Mexico and the United States responds asymmetrically to positive and negative shocks in money market rates.

I. INTRODUCTION

In a world with asymmetric information and other market imperfections, financial intermediaries provide credit to otherwise liquidity constrained agents. If lending without screening and monitoring entails large deadweight losses, and if market financing is prevented by free-rider problems, banks emerge as the only source of external financing for potentially productive agents (Diamond, 1984).1 As a result, the relationship between monetary perturbations and aggregate economic activity is necessarily linked to bank lending behavior.2 However, the response of bank lending to positive and negative interest rate changes may be inherently different, and potentially asymmetric. Even though several papers have studied the asymmetric effects of monetary policy on real economic activity, little attention has been paid to the asymmetric response of bank lending to interest rate changes.3

This paper has two aims. First, it proposes and solves a dynamic matching model, where credit expansion and contraction are time consuming, and shows that bank lending is likely to respond asymmetrically to interest rate changes.4 Second, it provides empirical evidence that bank lending in Mexico and the US responds asymmetrically to positive and negative innovations in money market rates.

The paper argues that lending expansion and contraction are time consuming activities, whereas buying and selling money market funds takes place without time delays. In reality, there are several reasons why lending expansion may be a time consuming process: investment opportunities might be difficult to find, or screening potential applicants might impose a time constraint on the banking system’s ability to issue new loans. In the case of existing bank-client relationships, these problems are potentially less severe. However, financial institutions still need to evaluate the profitability of expanding an existing loan. Similarly, recovering non-performing loans may require a time consuming legal procedure.5 As a result, the speed at which lending opportunities become available, and the speed at which banks can recall existing loans are important determinants of the dynamic response of bank lending to shocks in the money market. In particular, when banks can rapidly recall non-performing loans, but experience technological delays in expanding credit, the response of bank lending to interest rate changes is likely to be asymmetric: positive changes result in the immediate contraction of bank loans, whereas negative changes produce only a gradual expansion of bank lending.

A large literature in theoretical macroeconomics has emphasized the role of search frictions in the labor market, and the existence of a matching problem between vacant jobs and unemployed workers. Similar frictions are also relevant in intermediated capital markets, where banks are the main source of productive capital. As vacancies and workers search for each other in a world with imperfect information, so do bank’s capital and idle projects. Theoretically, we model the market for lending as a matching environment, where banks and entrepreneurs search for each other with a view toward establishing profitable relationships. A large microeconomic literature has shown that asymmetric information may lead to equilibrium credit rationing in the banking system.6 In this paper, even though we do not directly deal with informational asymmetries in bank-client relationships, we do model an aggregate form of credit-rationing. Throughout the analysis we assume that there is a positive probability that bank funds and idle projects do not succeed in finding each other in a given period. In other words, we assume that new loan contracts can profitably take place only after a bank and an entrepreneur have been randomly matched. This over-simplification, while extreme from the perspective of microeconomic theory, is meant to capture in an aggregate model the time consuming process of credit formation.

Banks are endowed with a given quantity of capital to be invested in two assets: money market funds and entrepreneurial projects. Technologically, the two assets differ in various respects. First, investments in the money market are risk free, whereas loans have an idiosyncratic probability of default, and are heterogeneous in terms of risk and return. Second, the technology to issue and recall loans is time consuming, while investing in the money market is not. From the banks’ perspective, the probability of forming a credit relationship, and the probability of recovering non-performing loans are two exogenous and independent stochastic processes7. Conversely, the timing for investing and disinvensting in the money market is deterministic and immediate. Hence, banks’ evaluation of entrepreneurial projects will reflect not only the immediate return generated by the associated loan, but also their value as an asset that might be difficult to replace.8

We show that banks monotonically rank individual projects, and optimally choose a reservation project below which buying money market funds is strictly preferred to project financing. Since the value of the marginal project depends on the return on the banks’ alternative asset, in equilibrium, any shock to the money market (securities) rates affects the optimal allocation of bank capital. The paper shows that the dynamic response of bank lending to interest rate shocks depends crucially on two structural parameters: the speed at which lending opportunities become available, and the speed at which banks can recall existing loans. From this perspective, econometric estimates that force lending to respond symmetrically to interest rate changes are likely to impose undue restrictions.

Empirically, we investigate whether the response of bank lending to interest rate changes is indeed asymmetric, as most of the parameterization of the model would suggest. Empirical evidence for the US and Mexico confirms our intuition: bank lending reacts asymmetrically to exogenous money market perturbations. In particular, we find that banks react more rapidly to market interest rate increases in both countries.9

The paper proceeds as follows. Section II introduces concepts and notations, while section III presents and solves the steady-state model, where returns to the money market are fixed and time invariant. Section IV solves a stochastic dynamic version of the model with shocks to market returns, provides numerical simulations, and briefly highlights the model’s empirical implications. Section V develops the empirical analysis and provides evidence of asymmetry in the response of aggregate lending to money market shocks in Mexico and in the United States. Section VI discusses policy implications and alternative theoretical interpretations. Section VII briefly summarizes and concludes the paper.

II. DESCRIPTION OF THE MODEL

We consider an economy populated by a fixed number of risk neutral banks and risk neutral entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurs are endowed with projects of different qualities and seek project financing. Banks are endowed with liquid funds and seek investment opportunities. Entrepreneurs have no private source of funds, and have no access to market financing, so that bank loans are their only source of external capital. Banks, however, may invest their capital in two alternative assets: money market bonds and project-loans. For simplicity, we assume that each entrepreneur is endowed with an indivisible project requiring an initial investment of $1 that is productive only when it is matched to a unit of bank capital. Since our focus is on loans, rather than on banks, we assume that each bank has a single unit of funding capital. As a result, we abstract from issues related to market structure in the banking system.

Throughout the analysis, the aggregate capital available to the banking sector, and the aggregate number of entrepreneurs/projects are constant and time invariant. However, we assume that there are n different types of projects, and k projects of each type, so that the aggregate number of projects is nk. For analytical convenience, we let nk be also the fixed number of banks or, alternatively, the stock of capital in the banking system.

Each bank can invest its indivisible unit of capital in two different assets: money market funds or project loans. We let the return on the money-market investment be risk-free, and we let rd indicate its instantaneous return. Conversely, a project of type i, with i(1,2,..,n) is characterized by a pair (yi, λi), where yi is a time-invariant return, and λi is an instantaneous probability of destruction, a Poisson process that measures the project’s idiosyncratic risk. Since most models predict that riskier projects must have higher returns, we assume that the elements of the pair (yi, λi) are positively correlated, and strictly increasing in i. Furthermore, in order to obtain a monotonic ranking of the projects, and reasonable aggregate results, we need to assume that yiλi>yjλj,  i>j. Thus, dividends grow faster than destruction rates, and the index i is a proxy of a project’s quality. Finally, each project can be in two different states, depending on whether or not it is matched to a bank. A financed project is active and it produces an idiosyncratic dividend yi, while an unfinanced project is idle and does not yield any dividend.

We model credit expansion and contraction as time-consuming processes. When time elapses in a continuous way, as we assume in the rest of the analysis, money market investment and disinvestment can be undertaken immediately, whereas loan expansions and contractions are time consuming. Formally, an analytically convenient way to model credit formation as a time-consuming process can be borrowed from the traditional matching literature (Diamond, 1982, and Mortensen and Pissarides, 1994, 1998). In what follows, we assume that the number of credit applications that are fully screened and evaluated in a given interval of time is described by a unique function of few aggregate variables: the stock of capital in the money market, and the number of idle projects.10 Thus, a function x(v, m), where m is the number of idle projects, and m is the stock of capital invested in the money market, records the number of loan applications completely screened and evaluated in a given period. In terms of the function x(.), the assumption that screening and evaluating projects are time consuming activities is equivalent to assuming that

x < min ( υ , m ) .

Furthermore, since every credit relationship involves one unit of funds and a single project, in our simple set-up, υ = m. If we also assume that credit formation can be described by a constant return technology, as we do in the rest of the paper, x can be written simply as

x = α υ , ( 1 )

where αx (1, 1) < 1, is the instantaneous probability that a bank screens a project in a infinitesimal time interval. Alternatively, given our symmetric structure, α is the probability that a credit application is completely screened.11 In other words, we are assuming that in the economy, during a short period of time δt there is a positive probability 1 − αδt that a unit of capital and an idle project do not succeed in finding each-other. As a result of equation (1), the economy is characterized by aggregate (and stochastic) credit rationing. Formally, we do not need to specify whether banks meet entrepreneurs randomly over time, or whether banks find new projects at an infinite speed but their screening technology is intrinsically time-consuming. Nevertheless, aggregate credit formation is time consuming, and the parameter α captures this property in a simple way.

When a unit of bank capital and an idle project match, all uncertainty is resolved, and the bank immediately knows the type of the project. An active loan is subject to idiosyncratic risk of destruction at rate λi. For the entrepreneur, the realization of the shock represents immediate bankruptcy, and its life-time utility immediately drops to zero. For the bank, the bankruptcy of a project brings to an end the income generated by the associated loan. Immediately thereafter, the bank initiates a costly and time consuming bankruptcy procedure. For analytical simplicity, we assume that recovering capital out of a bankrupt project involves a flow cost f, and an instantaneous probability of success equal to σ, where σ is the arrival rate of a simple Poisson process.12 This assumption captures the idea that bankrupt firms have assets that can potentially be liquidated, but only via a time consuming and (stochastic) device. Furthermore, to keep symmetry between banks’ aggregate capital and the entrepreneurial population, we assume that a new type i project appears idle only when the bank has successfully completed the bankruptcy procedure.

The existence of credit rationing and a finite α generate a pure economic rent to be split between entrepreneurs and banks that successfully match. As a result, to formally close the model, we need a sharing rule that determines the interest rate charged to different projects. We follow the standard matching literature and assume that the total surplus generated by an active project is continuously shared in fixed proportions, and we let β represents the bank’s share.

Banks choose a search strategy that maximizes the expected value of their capital; they select a decision rule that describes whether to finance a specific project, whenever it becomes available. Since the present value of financing each loan is monotonic in i, the bank’s decision rule satisfies a “reservation” property. We show that in equilibrium each bank selects a cut-off quality i*, such that for projects of quality lower than i* banks prefer to invest in the money market. In the model, an equilibrium is a reservation rule i*, or alternatively, a stationary allocation of capital (a distribution of bank capital among project financing, recovery loans, and money market investments) that is consistent with the optimal reservation rule.

III. THE MODEL: STEADY STATE

This section presents and solves the steady state model, with a fixed and time invariant money market rate (rd). In what follows, we shall indicate with Vi and Ji, the present discounted values for a type i entrepreneur of, respectively, an idle project and an active project, while ρ < 1 shall be the discount rate, which is assumed to be the same for the banks and the entrepreneurs. Even though idle projects do not yield any dividend, their present discounted value may still be positive, by virtue of an expected capital gain associated with successful matching.13 More formally, if α is the entrepreneur’s probability of having his or her project screened, the valuation of an idle type i project is

ρ V i = α ( max [ V i ; J i ] V i ) , ( 2 )

where the max operator in equation (2) indicates that an entrepreneurs has always the option to leave his or her project inactive. An active, or financed, type i project yields an instantaneous dividend yi, and is characterized by an instantaneous destruction probability λi. If a destroyed project yields a zero value to the entrepreneur, the present discounted value of an active project reads

ρ J i = y i r i λ i J i , ( 3 )

where ri is the interest that a type i project pays to the bank.

Similarly, we shall indicate with Ci the bank’s value of a unit of capital invested in a type i loan, and with D the value of investing in the money market. Finally, B shall indicate the present discounted value of a bad loan (a unit of capital in the recovery state). If the interest rate on the money market is rd, and α is the probability of completely screening a project, the value of investing a unit of capital in the money market reads

ρ D = r d + α [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( C j ; D ) D ] . ( 4 )

Equation (4) is one of the key equations of the model, and the max operator in the capital gain term encodes the bank’s choice between investing in project loans or in money market bonds. Once a bank has successfully (or luckily) screened a project j, it will convert its funds into a type-j loan as long as Cj is greater than D. Ex-ante, however, the bank does not know the quality of the project, but only its overall distribution, which we have assumed uniform for analytical convenience. Hence, the summation term in equation (4) represents the conditional value of a loan.

The asset valuation of a type i loan depends on the interest rate charged, ri, and the capital loss suffered by the bank in case of bankruptcy. Since the bank will start the bankruptcy procedure when the project is hit by an idiosyncratic shock14, the value of a type i loan reads

ρ C i = r i + λ i ( B C i ) , ( 5 )

where B is the present discounted value of a bad loan. In the recovery state the bank pays a flow cost f, and expects to successfully recover its capital with instantaneous probability σ. Since the bank will immediately invest the capital that it has successfully recovered in the money market, B solves

ρ B = f + σ ( D B ) . ( 6 )

For the bank, establishing a credit relationship is optimal as long as Ci > D. Similarly, for the entrepreneur, having an active project is optimal as long as Ji > Vi. As a result, the surplus from a credit-match can be formally represented as the net value of establishing a credit relationship, and reads

W i = J i V i + C i D , ( 7 )

where Wi, the surplus of a type i loan, is the measure of the quasi-rent generated by the match. To formally close the model, we need a rule that determines how the bank and the entrepreneur will divide the surplus generated by a match. Since we assume that the bank gets a fixed share β of the total surplus, it must be true that

C i D = β W i , ( J i V i ) = 1 β β ( C i D ) . ( 8 )

Equation (8) reflects two characteristics of the model’s equilibrium: first, it is profitable for the bank and the entrepreneur to establish a credit relationship as long as the total surplus is positive; second, there is agreement between the bank and the entrepreneurs on which projects should be financed. Making use of equations (5), (3), (2) and (4), the surplus from the credit relationship (7) can be conveniently written as

( ρ + λ i ) W i = y i a i r d α β a i [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) ] α ( 1 β ) b i max ( W i ; 0 ) λ i f σ + ρ , ( 9 )

where

a i = ρ + σ + λ i ρ + σ , b i = ρ + λ i ρ .

After dividing both sides by (ρ + λi), the right hand side of equation (9) is a mapping. Unfortunately, equation (9) does not satisfy the Blackwell sufficient conditions for a contraction. Nevertheless, Appendix I shows that a simple restriction on the parameters provides us with a sufficient condition for the mapping of equation (9) to be a contraction, and thus, to guarantee the existence of a fixed point.15

The surplus function Wi is a monotonic increasing function of i. Intuitively, as long as the dividends of higher quality projects grow faster than the associated bankruptcy probability, the total rent generated by a project should be monotonic in i. This result, albeit analytically intuitive, is formally derived in Appendix II. By virtue of (8), monotonicity of projects’ surplus implies monotonicity of the bank’s surplus, which allows us to characterize banks’ behavior through the reservation property. In other words, banks select a marginal type i*, or a cut-off value Wi*, below which investment in the money market is the optimal policy. More formally, i* solves

i * : W i * 0 , W i * 1 < 0 . ( 10 )

In the case in which Wi*0, from equation (9), the marginal returns of the project can be conveniently written as

y i * = a i * r d + α β a i * [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) ] + λ i * f σ + ρ . ( 11 )

Equation (11) describes in a simple way the return on the marginal project. In order to be worthwhile to grant a loan, the marginal project i* must at least compensate the bank for three different elements: the per period return on the money market (ai*rd), the expected value of an alternative project (the expression in square brackets), and the expected cost of recalling the loan if conditions turn bad (λi*fσ+ρ).

Before analyzing several comparative static results, we solve for the equilibrium interest rate ri. Rearranging equation (3), and making use of equation (8), the interest rate on a type i loan reads

r i = y i ( ρ + λ i ) β W i . ( 12 )

Finally, making use of equations (5) and (4), the interest rate can be simply written as

r i = ρ D + λ i ρ D σ + ρ + ( ρ + λ i ) β W i ( 13 )

Equation (13) shows that the interest rate on a type i project is equal to the return on the alternative banks’ asset (ρD), augmented by a strictly positive spread. Furthermore it is possible to show that the spread component of equation (13) is monotonic in the quality i, so that banks earn higher returns on riskier projects. For this purpose, it is sufficient to show that the interest rate is increasing in i. Making use of equation (13), the spread between two different quality projects can be conveniently written as

r i r i j = ρ β ( W i W i j ) + β ( λ i W i λ i j W i k ) + ( λ i λ i j ) ( ρ D σ + ρ ) . ( 14 )

Since Wi > Wij and λi > λij, it immediately follows that ririj > 0 for any positive integer j. As a result, the interest rate spread between a type i loan and an alternative investment grows monotonically with the quality i.

We are now in the position to analyze the most important comparative static results of this section, namely the relationships between the money market rate, rd, the interest rates on loans, ri, and the banks’ optimal portfolio allocation, as described by the reservation quality i*. In general, changes in rd will affect both the amount of lending and the interest rate charged on loans. First, following an increase (decrease) in rd, it is quite likely that some project becomes immediately unprofitable (profitable) relative to the money market investment. Since the surplus of a type i match is decreasing in the money market rate,16

W i r d < 0 i , ( 15 )

an increase in rd may affect the bank’s equilibrium allocation between project loans and money market investments. If Wi*0, equation (15), by virtue of (10) produces an immediate change in i*. In general, for any marginal increase (decrease) in rd, if n is sufficiently large, the bank will change its optimal asset allocation and it will decrease (increase) its share of loans. Similarly, making use of equation (13), the effect of a change of the money market rate on the interest rate charged to a type i project is

r i r d = ( ρ + α ) ( 1 β ) ( ρ + σ + λ i ) [ ρ + α ( 1 β ) ] ( ρ + σ ) ( 1 + α β 1 n j | W j 0 W j r d ) > 0 ( 16 )

Appendix III. shows that both terms in the brackets of equation (16) are positive. Thus, there is a positive pass-through effect between money market rates and interest rate changes. Equation (16) shows that the magnitude of the pass-through, albeit strictly positive, crucially depends on several structural parameters. First, rird is a decreasing function of β. If we take β as a proxy for the bank’s market power, this result implies that the pass through is larger in less concentrated markets, a result familiar in the industrial organization literature (Tirole, 1988). Second, when β is zero and σ tends to infinity, the pass-through is exactly one. In this case, bank lending to private entrepreneurs does not entail any recovery risk, and banks have no market power. Hence, all projects pay to the bank the money market return.

Now we can specify the equilibrium allocation between alternative investments. In equilibrium, banks will finance only projects of type ii*, leaving unfunded the remaining types. Nevertheless, the economy experiences continuous turnover of projects, and to complete the model we need to specify the distribution of banks’ asset among active loans, bad loans and money market investment. If we indicate with υi, bi, and ci the steady state quantity of type i projects which are, respectively, idle, bankrupt, and fully active, the flow balance conditions are

α υ i = λ i c i i i * ( 17 ) σ b i = λ i c i i i * c i + b i + υ i = k i .

Solving the system of equations (17) yields, for ii*, the following equilibrium quantities

c i = k α σ σ ( α + λ i ) + α λ i b i = k α λ i σ ( α + λ i ) + α λ i υ i = k α λ i σ ( α + λ i ) + α λ i , ( 18 )

while for i < i*, all projects are idle and υi = k. The comparative static properties of the quantities in equations (18) show that υi is a decreasing function of α. The easier the screening process, the larger the proportion of funds kept in the money market. Similarly, higher σ leads to a lower quantity of projects in the bankruptcy state. Finally we aggregate equation (18) over different quality indices to obtain

c = i i * k α σ σ ( α + λ i ) + α λ i b = i i * k α λ i σ ( α + λ i ) + α λ i υ = nk c b ( 19 )

From equations (19), it is clear that an increase in market rates, by raising i*, reduces aggregate lending c and the quantity of capital in the bankruptcy state. As a result, the capital invested in the money market rises. The next section looks at interest rate changes in a stochastic setting.

IV. STOCHASTIC SHOCKS TO THE MONEY MARKET

We now extend the analysis of the previous section and consider a world in which money market returns are stochastic and time variant. For analytical simplicity, we assume that the money market rate jumps stochastically between two different values, rdT and rdE, with rdT>rdE. Since the money market can be in two different states, in what follows we shall call rdT the tight state, and rdE the easy state. We also assume that the state of the money market moves according to a symmetric Markov process, and we shall indicate with μ the instantaneous probability of a state switch. To solve the model, we need to specify a full set of state contingent value functions, which makes the analytic of the model particularly cumbersome. Hence, we do not provide a close form solution of the model, or comparative static results. However, as a way to maintain the discussion at an intuitive level, we describe the dynamics of the model through numerical simulations.

A. The Model

Since there are now two states of the money market, each bank’s behavior is described by two indices of reservation quality, that we shall indicate by iT* and iE*, depending on whether the state of the market is easy or tight. Furthermore, since rDT>rdE, it will be generally true that iT* > iE*. More formally, if the probability of a state switch is μ, the value of an inactive project of quality i when conditions are “easy” is

ρ V i E = α max [ J i E ; 0 ] + μ ( V i T V i E ) , ( 20 )

where the capital gain term μ(ViTViE) reflects the possibility that the state of the money market switches to tight. With respect to equation (3), the value of a type i project to an entrepreneur when the market is easy is

ρ J i E = y i r i E λ i J i E + μ [ max ( V i T ; J i T ) J i E ] ( 21 )

where the max operator in the last term reflects the fact that, following a state switch, an entrepreneur might be better off inactive. For the bank, the value of a type i loan when the market is easy reads

ρ C i E = r i E + λ i ( B E C i E ) + μ [ max ( B T ; C i T ) C i E ] . ( 22 )

The last term in equation (22) suggests that, conditional on the rate rDE switching to tight, the bank might find it profitable to recall the capital, in such a way that the corresponding loan enters the bankruptcy state. This term, absent in the steady-state version of the model, is the novel feature of this section. From equation (22) it is clear that a loan enters the recovery state BE when there is a shock λi, and it might enter the state BT when there is a state switch. The bank’s value function of a type i loan in the bankruptcy state reads

ρ B T = f + σ ( D T B T ) + μ ( B E B T ) ,

when the state of the money market is tight, and

ρ B E = f + σ ( D E B E ) + μ ( B T B E ) ,

when the state of the money market is easy. Finally, the asset value of money market investment is

ρ D E = r d E + α [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( C j E ; D E ) D E ] + μ [ D T D E ] . ( 23 )

When the state of the market is tight, the value functions for the banks and the entrepreneurs are very similar to those presented for the steady state. In particular, they do not embed any new element of choice in correspondence to the possible state switch, but only an extra capital gain term. The value function of the entrepreneur when the money market is tight is

ρ V T = α max [ V T ; 0 ] + μ ( V E V T ) , ( 24 )

for an idle project, and

ρ J T = y i r i T λ i J T + μ [ J E J T ] ( 25 )

for an active project. Similarly, for the bank, the value of an active loan is

ρ C T = r i T + λ i ( R i T C T ) + μ [ C E C T ] , ( 26 )

and the value of investing in the money market is

ρ D T = r d T + α [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( C T ; D T ) D T ] + μ [ D E D T ] . ( 27 )

Proceeding as in the previous section, it is possible to derive an expression that describes the surplus from the match in the tight and in the easy state17. As μ grows, the money market shock becomes less persistent and, at the limit, the value function ceases to be state contingent. The intuition for this result is as follows. As the expected duration of each state tends to zero, so does the capital gain (loss) associated with a discrete change in money market conditions, and in the limit case, the bank’s allocation decision becomes time invariant.18

To complete the dynamic model, and to describe bank lending behavior in different market states, we need a set of differential equations. Since it is always true that ci + bi + υi = K, we have only to specify the dynamics of active loans and bad loans (loans in recovery state), obtaining money market investment as a residual. The differential equations are

db i S dt = σ b i S + λ i b i S ( 28 ) dc i S dt = λ i c i S + α υ i S , S = T , E .

The next section presents numerical simulations of the model’s dynamics.

B. The Aggregate Dynamics: Simulations and Discussions

This section simulates the aggregate dynamic response of bank lending to changes in market conditions. In what follows we assume that time is discrete and that the state of the money market (tight, rdT or easy, rdE) is realized at the beginning of the period, and constant throughout. The timing of the decision is as follows. Banks observe the money market realization, and immediately select a reservation i*T or i*E. Thereafter, each entrepreneur learns whether his or her project has been screened, the credit allocation (c, r, υ) is determined, interest rates are paid, and the period is completed.

In a well behaved equilibrium, given the n project qualities, there is always a subset of project types whose quality at time t is above the highest reservation quality (ii*T), and another subset of projects whose quality is below the lowest one (i < i*E). For these projects, the allocation of capital is not affected by regime switches, even though the interest rate charged on the associated loans will be conditional on the state of the market. More formally, for ii*T, the shares of projects that are financed, not-financed, or are in the recovery state are those described by equations (18).

Conversely, for types i < i*E no project is ever financed, and we just have υi = k. However, for those projects whose quality lies between the two reservation thresholds (i*Ei < i*T), the composition of projects that are financed, not-financed, or are in the recovery state is state dependent. If we let x(t) be an indicator function

x ( t ) = { i T * if   r d = r d T i E * if   r d = r d E

that records the state of the money market at time t, the dynamics of a type i project is

c i , t + 1 = ( 1 Φ 1 ) ( 1 λ i dt ) c i , t + Φ 2 α υ i , t dt ( 29 )
b i , t + 1 = ( 1 σ dt ) b i , t + ( 1 Φ 1 ) λ i c i dt + Φ 1 c i , t ( 30 ) c i , t + b i , t + υ i , t = k i , t ,

where

Φ 1 = { 1 if   x ( t + 1 ) = i * T , x ( t ) = i * E , W i T < ρ D t ρ + σ 0 otherwise ( 31 )

and

Φ 2 = { 1 if   x ( t + 1 ) = i * E 0 otherwise ( 32 )

Consider first the dynamics of equations (29) and (30). If the state switches from easy to tight (Φ1 = 1), all active projects enter the bankruptcy state bi, while when there is no state switch the flow from active to recovery is governed by the natural turnover λi. Conversely, successfully screened projects are converted into active loans only when the market is easy, and the indicator function Φ2 keeps track of this condition in equation (29).

In what follows, we simulate the dynamic response of the aggregate economy using the baseline parameter values specified in Table 1. We focus on two aggregate statistics, the aggregate credit (ct) and the average interest rate on active loans, which we formally indicate with

r ¯ t = i > x ( t ) n r it c it i > x ( t ) n c it ,
Table 1.

Baseline Parameter Values

article image
Source: Authors’ calculation

where cit is described by equation (29) for i*Ei < i*T, and by equation (18) for ii*T.

Figures 1 to 4 plot the dynamics response of ct and r¯t for different values of α and σ. Figure 1 plots the dynamics response of ct for σ > α along a full easy-tight-easy cycle, σ is the institutional parameter that describes the average speed of recovering a loan, while α is the technological parameter that describes the average screening period of a credit application. In Figure 1, when the market state turns tight (approximately at period 9 in Figure 1) i*E jumps to i*T, and all projects whose idiosyncratic quality lies between the two reservation qualities i*Ei < i*T are rapidly recalled. Since σ is relatively high, the average duration of the recovery state is very short, and the bank rapidly recovers the invested capital. When the market state switches to tight (approximately at period 30 in Figure 1), i*T jumps immediately to i*E, but the dynamic response of aggregate credit is time consuming. As the interest rate falls, banks immediately change the reservation quality, but they still have to process the additional loan applications, and the associated credit expansion takes place only at rate α. Thus, when σ > α, there is a short-run asymmetric response of aggregate lending to interest rate changes. However, as the projects are successfully screened, credit returns to its original level, without any long-run asymmetry. These results represent a first set of empirical implications of our model. Figure 2 plots the dynamic response of the average interest rate when σ > α. In general, the dynamic response of r¯t to changes in the money market rate is affected by two different effects. First, there is an instantaneous pass-through effect, linked to the translation of the new rd into the existing ri, as was formally described by equation (16). Second, there is a portfolio effect, induced by the modification of the bank’s optimal portfolio towards more profitable projects. When rd switches to tight in Figure 2, the average interest rate immediately jumps to a new level, as a result of the portfolio effect and the pass-through effect. However, when policy switches to easy, on impact, the change in rd is only related to the pass-through effect, since the portfolio effect is time-consuming. From Figure 2, is clear that the asymmetric response of the average interest rate depends entirely on the portfolio effect.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Banks’ Capital Allocation over a easy-tight-easy cycle; σ > α

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1998, 093; 10.5089/9781451951318.001.A001

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Average Interest Rate over an easy-tight-easy cycle; σ > α

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1998, 093; 10.5089/9781451951318.001.A001

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Banks’ Capital Allocation over a easy-tight-easy cycle; σ = α

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1998, 093; 10.5089/9781451951318.001.A001

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Average Interest Rate over an easy-tight-easy cycle; σ = α

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1998, 093; 10.5089/9781451951318.001.A001

Figures 3 and 4 plot the dynamic response of ct and r¯t along a full easy-tight-easy cycle when σ = α. Qualitatively, the dynamic profile of Figure 3 is clearly different from the dynamic profile of Figure 1. In Figure 3, when the market turns tight (approximately at period 9) i*E jumps to i*T, but nothing happens on impact, neither to aggregate credit nor to the recovery state. To properly understand Figure 3 it is necessary to go back to equation (22). When rd switches to tight, and σ is very low, banks expect a very long and costly recovery process, and may well prefer to keep active some of the projects with i < i*T. When the latter is true, banks prefer to wait for the natural bankruptcy of the project, rather than go through a costly separation. Nevertheless, during the tight phase banks choose not to finance projects that are successfully screened but have an idiosyncratic quality below i*T. Basically, projects of quality i, with i*Ei < i*T, are destroyed at rate λi, but are not replaced at rate α. As a result, aggregate credit gradually falls. When the policy switches to easy (approximately at period 30 of Figure 3), banks begin to finance all projects with reservation quality greater than i*E, and aggregate credit rises smoothly. Overall, there is no asymmetry over the full cycle. Comparing Figures 3 and Figure 1, it is clear that the dynamic response of aggregate credit to interest rate changes depends crucially on the relative values of σ and α. Finally, Figure 4 plots the dynamic behavior of the average interest rate. When σ = α, there is no portfolio reallocation and, as a result, there is almost no asymmetry in the dynamic response of the average interest rate.

V. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

In this section we provide some empirical evidence on the effects of interest rate changes on bank lending, focusing on the difference between positive and negative shocks. We consider two countries, in representation of mature and emerging markets: the United States and Mexico. The data for the US are quarterly, and run from 1960 to 1997. For Mexico we have monthly data, from 1982 to 1997. The source of all the data is the International Financial Statistics. Market rates are taken from line 60b, which records the most representative short term rates.19 We use “claims on the private sector” (line 22d) as a proxy for loans. This choice, as was the use of IFS data, was mainly motivated by the need of international comparability. For the US we use the Consumer Price Index (CPI) and GDP growth as a way to construct exogenous interest rate shocks. For Mexico we use Industrial Production in the absence of monthly GDP data.

A. Methodology

We employ a two-step procedure similar to that applied by Cover (1992) and Garibaldi (1997), but adapted to consider the stationarity problems of aggregate credit. First, we estimate the money market rate processes, and we use the associated residuals for constructing positive and negative interest rate shocks. Second, we estimate the effect of those shocks on a properly defined specification of aggregate credits.20

In the first step we estimate an autoregressive-distributed lag model (ARDL) of the money market rate, CPI inflation, and GDP (or industrial production). If MM is the money market rate, the ARDL regression reads

MM t = a + i = 1 M α i MM t i + i = 0 N β i G t i + i = 0 Q γ i P t i + ε t , ( 33 )

where G is the real output growth, and P is the CPI inflation. When the lags are properly chosen, εt mimics a simple white noise process, and we take its estimated values as exogenous shocks to the money market rate. As a way to test the robustness of our generated shocks, we use the Akaike and Schwartz criteria to optimally select M, N, and Q (the order of the ARDL)21. Results of regression (33) are reported in Table (2) for the US and Table (3) for Mexico. Next, we divide the residuals generated in regression (33) into positive and negative values, and we introduce two different variables. More specifically, we define a positive shock to the money market interest rate as

tight t = max ( ε t , 0 ) ,
Table 2.

U.S Federal Fund Rate

article image
Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses One, two and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent respectively.

ARDL order selected with Akaike criterion

b ARDL order selected with Schwartz criterion Source: Authors’ calculation
Table 3.

Mexico Money-Market Rate

article image
Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses One, two and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent respectively.

ARDL order selected with Akaike criterion

b ARDL order selected with Schwartz criterion Source: Authors’ calculation

and a negative shock as

easy t = min ( ε t , 0 ) .

In the second regression we use “claims on the private sector over CPI” as a proxy for aggregate real loans, and we regress this variable on its lagged values, the lagged values of real deposits, and the lagged values of positive and negative market rate shocks. Real deposits are included as a control variables to take into account changes in the amount of funds available to the banking system.22 The ARDL model of the second step is

L t = b + i = 1 R δ i L t i + i = 0 S ϑ i D t i + i = 1 U φ i tight t i + i = 1 V ψ i easy t i + ξ t + η t ( 34 )

where Lt is the log of real claims on the private sector, Dti is the log of real deposits, t is a time trend, and η is a white noise error. Since we need to allow credit to react to interest rate changes we do not include the contemporaneous values of easy and tight, and the variables tight and easy in equations (34) are only lagged.

To check the stability of the model, we employ the two-stage procedure proposed in Pesaran et al. (1996). We use the error correction specification of regression (34), and perform a variable deletion test on the coefficients of the lagged levels of L, D, tight, and easy. The null hypothesis is the non-existence of a long-run relationship, or in other words, the instability of the model. This procedure allows us to avoid the pre-testing problems associated with standard cointegration analysis, which requires the classification of variables into I(1) and I(0). Fortunately, we are able to reject the null hypothesis of instability (no-cointegration) for both countries.23

B. Results and Robustness Checks

The results of our estimation indicate that the response of bank lending to interest rate shocks is asymmetric. More specifically, a structural interpretation of the results would suggest that frictions that slow down credit formation are particularly important. Indeed, bank lending seems to react more rapidly to positive interest rate shocks than to negative interest rate shocks. For both countries we are able to identify a negative effect of interest rate increases on aggregate loans, while we find only weak evidence of the effect of interest rate cuts. Tables 4 and 5 report the results of regression (34) for the US and Mexico. These results suggest that any regression that does not take explicitly into account the asymmetric structure of the different shocks is likely to be over-restrictive.

Table 4.

Mexico: Aggregate Lending

article image
Notes: One, two and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent respectively.

Shocks in the first stage selected with Akaike and Schwartz criteria

Source: Authors’ calculation
Table 5.

US: Aggregate Lending

article image
Notes: One, two and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent respectively.

Shocks in the first stage selected with the Akaike criterion

Shocks in the first stage selected with the Schwartz criterion

Source: Authors’ calculation

To test the aggregate significance of the coefficients easy and tight in equation (34), we run “variable deletion tests” in the main ARDL regression. For both Mexico and the US we can easily reject the null for tight, but not for easy. This result suggests that bank lending is more sensitive to interest rate increases than decreases. We also directly test for asymmetry, by performing a Wald restriction test in two different forms. First we focus on the marginal impact of easy and tight on aggregate lending, by testing the null hypothesis that φ1 = ψ1 in equation (34). Second we test the asymmetry of the overall dynamic structure, and we test the hypothesis that (φi=ψii) in equation (34). The results of these tests are reported in Table 6 Clearly, we are able to reject the null of symmetry of all the coefficients for both countries. Moreover, for Mexico we also reject the null of a symmetric marginal impact. Table 7 reports tests of the long-run effects of tight and easy on aggregate lending. Our theory has a clear long-run prediction. Eventually, the cumulative effects on lending of a positive and negative change in interest rate should be symmetric. Even though most of the coefficients in Table 8 are correctly signed, their overall significance is low. In particular, there is no evidence of a long-run negative relationship between tight and lending, while there is some evidence of a long-run negative relationship between easy and lending. One reason for the lack of evidence of our long-run prediction may well be linked to the fact that in the long-run banks are able to substitute deposits with other liabilities. To that extent, deposits are no longer a good proxy for the banks’ lending capacity.

Table 6.

Tests of Asymmetry Aggregate Lending

article image
Notes: One, two and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent respectively.

Wald Statistic under the null that the impact coefficient on tight (ψ1) is equal to the impact coefficient on easy (φ1) Distributed as χ(1).

Wald Statistic under the null that the each coefficient on tight (ψi) is equal to the corresponding coefficient on easy (φi) Distributed as χ(7) for Mexico and χ(3) for the US.

Shocks generated with the Akaike criterion, see Table (5)

Shocks generated with the Schwartz criterion, see Table (5)

Shocks generated with the Schwartz and Akaike criterion, see Table (4)

Source: Authors’ calculation
Table 7.

Variable Deletion Tests

article image
Notes: One, two and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent respectively.

F-statistics under the null that the joint coefficients on tight (ψi) are equal to zero

F-statistics under the null that the joint coefficients on easy (φi) are equal to zero

Shocks generated with the Akaike criterion, see Table (5)

Shocks generated with the Schwartz criterion, see Table (5)

e Shocks generated with the Schwartz and Akaike criterion, see Table (4) Source: Authors’ calculation
Table 8.

Long Run Coefficients

article image
Notes: One, two and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent respectively.

t statistics of the long-run effect of tight in Table (5)

b t statistics of the long-run effect of easy in Table (5) c Shocks generated with the Akaike criterion, see Table (5) d Shocks generated with the Schwartz criterion, see Table (5) e Shocks generated with the Schwartz and Akaike criterion, see Table (4) Source: Authors’ calculation
Table 9.

US: Restricted Regression

article image
Notes: One, two and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent respectively.

Shocks in the first stage selected with the Akaike criterion

Shocks in the first stage selected with the Schwartz criterion

shocktj = easytj + tighttjj =, 1, 2, 3.

Source: Authors’ calculation

In order to test the robustness of our results, we explicitly take into account the possibility of structural breaks in the interest rate processes. For the US we perform two robustness checks. First, we run the regressions (33) and (34) for a limited sample -1961 to 1979- so as to exclude the Volcker period; second, we include a Dummy for the period 1979:4-1982:4, when the Federal Reserve deemphasized the funds rate. For Mexico, we limit the sample to the period 1985-1997, so as to exclude the financial turmoils of the early 80s, and we include a dummy for the 1994 crisis.24 The results of these regressions checks are reported in Table 10 and 11. Overall, the asymmetry between lending expansion and contraction is confirmed by these different specifications.

Table 10.

US: Robustness Checks

article image
Notes: One, two and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent respectively.

Wald Statistic under the null that the impact coefficient on tight (ψ1) is equal to the impact coefficient on easy (φ1) Distributed as χ(1).

Wald Statistic under the null that the each coefficient on tight (ψi) is equal to the corresponding coefficient on easy (φi) Distributed as χ(3)

F-statistics under the null that the joint coefficients on easy (φi) are equal to zero

F-statistics under the null that the joint coefficients on tight (ψi) are equal to zero

Source: Authors’ calculation
Table 11.

Mexico: Robustness Checks

article image
Notes: One, two and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent respectively. Regression includes 3 lags of real lending, real deposits, a consant and a trend. The first stage regression included a dummy for the 1994 crisis.

Wald Statistic under the null that the impact coefficient on tight (ψ1) is equal to the impact coefficient on easy (ψ1) Distributed as χ(1).

Wald Statistic under the null that the each coefficient on tight (ψi) is equal to the corresponding coefficient on easy (ψi) Distributed as χ(3)

F-statistics under the null that the joint coefficients on easy (φi) are equal to zero

F-statistics under the null that the joint coefficients on tight (ψi) are equal to zero

Source: Authors’ calculation

Finally, to check the robustness of our approach, we test a restricted version of the model, by exogenously imposing symmetry on the coefficients of the interest rate shocks. Results in Table 9 confirm that not taking into account the possibility of an asymmetric response may lead to misleading results. The shock coefficients in the regression of Table 9 perform worse than the coefficients of the unrestricted regression, reported in Table 5. Furthermore, if the shocks are generated with the Akaike criterion, we can not reject a variable deletion test, while in the Schwartz case we reject it at the 10 percent level. Overall, the results in this section confirm an empirical prediction of our theory: the response of bank lending to interest rate shocks is gradual and asymmetric. However, as we discuss in the next section, these results are also consistent with other models, and further empirical research is needed for identifying competing theories.

VI. POLICY RELEVANCE AND ALTERNATIVE INTERPRETATIONS

If the shocks to the money market rate are interpreted as policy innovations, our framework provides some insights on the dynamic effects of monetary policy. However, before entering into a policy discussion, it is useful to position our theory in the context of the standard monetary transmission channels (Mishkin, 1995). Even though lending plays a key role in the transmission of policy shocks, our approach has important differences from the “lending” channel of monetary policy transmission (also known as the “credit view”). As in our approach, the credit view considers bank loans as important determinants of the real economic activity. Our entrepreneurs do not have access to market financing, and bank lending is the only element through which monetary policy may affect economic activity. However, the “credit view” focuses on the existence of a direct link between policy impulses and lending response, beyond the indirect effects induced by the classical interest rate channel. If monetary policy affects the supply of deposits to the banking system, the banks’ ability to issue new loans may be directly affected, independently of what happens to the interest rate.25 This effect is certainly absent in our model, which limits the analysis of bank lending to the asset side of the banks’ balance sheet, and abstracts from the relationship between policy impulses and the capital available to the banking system. In our approach, changes in bank lending are induced by changes in interest rate, in a way that is consistent with the traditional interest rate channel.

In particular, we have shown that the dynamic response of aggregate lending to interest rate shocks depends crucially on two independent processes: the banking system’s ability to find and screen new projects, and the banking system’s ability to recall existing loans. Since these processes are inherently different, it is quite likely that bank lending will respond asymmetrically to positive and negative innovations. This theoretical intuition was also confirmed by our empirical evidence on lending behavior in Mexico and the US. Hence, the design and implementation of monetary policy should take into account the asymmetric lag structure between policy contractions and policy expansions, and react consequently.

An extensive literature has addressed the issue of the asymmetric effects of monetary policy on real economic activity. The traditional explanations focus on price rigidity, on informational asymmetries, and on the structure of the labor market. If prices are more flexible upward than downward, monetary contractions will produce mainly quantity adjustments, while monetary expansions will cause prices to rise with a smaller effect on output26. If informational asymmetries produce binding liquidity constraints, monetary contractions induce reduction in consumption for liquidity constrained agents, in a way that does not have a counterpart during monetary expansions.27 Finally, if hiring is costly and time consuming, while firing is immediate, job creation and destruction respond asymmetrically to changes in money market rates28. In this paper, we have argued that the technological and institutional structure of the credit markets are likely to produce asymmetry in monetary policy, in a way that has been previously neglected.

The relationship between deposit (and lending) rates and changes in money market rates has been the focus of an extensive banking literature. In that literature, the evidence of asymmetries in upward and downward adjustments of banks’ interest rate is linked to the existence of oligopolistic behavior in the banking industry (Hannan and Berger, 1991). In our approach, asymmetries in banks’ interest rate are completely independent of the market structure, and are linked to “technological” characteristics of bank lending. Since the processes that describe credit formation and contraction are completely independent, albeit time-consuming, prices and volumes of bank lending may adjust asymmetrically to interest rate changes, regardless of the underlying competitive structure. Even though in reality the “technological” and “oligopolistic” approaches may both be relevant, they provide us with very different implications. In our model, the dynamic and static equilibria are entirely determined by technological and institutional factors, and by the structural parameters that describe the speed of loan formation and of loan contraction. In order to affect those equilibria, it is necessary to deal with technological and institutional innovations. Conversely, in the oligopolistic view, the credit allocation may be affected by changes in the market structure, and by policies aimed at increasing competition. Hence, determining the empirical relevance of these two frameworks would certainly be important, at least from a regulatory standpoint. Unfortunately, aggregate data do not allow us to discriminate between these two models.29

Finally, we need to deal with efficiency considerations. The previous discussion has suggested that institutional and technological changes may affect the equilibria of the model. Certainly, the existence of stochastic lags in the banks’ ability to recall its invested capital is a measure of inefficiency, and policies aimed at speeding up this process (e.g. improvements in bankruptcy laws, increased enforcement of property rights) are likely to be welfare improving. Other things equal, the higher is σ, the more efficient is the banking system. Efficiency considerations on the bank’s ability to screen projects are more subtle. In a first-best world with perfect information, α is infinitely large, lending is instantaneous and bank loans lose the special role played in this paper. However, in a second-best world, α is a physiological parameter, related only to information technology. Changing the latter is certainly an economic activity, but its discussion is beyond the topic of the present paper.

VII. CONCLUDING REMARKS

This paper has proposed and solved a dynamic model of bank lending, where loan expansion and contraction are time consuming activities. We have shown that the speed at which lending opportunities become available, and the speed at which banks can recall existing loans are key determinants of the dynamic response of bank lending to exogenous innovations in the money markets. Since these two processes are inherently different, bank lending is likely to respond asymmetrically to interest rate changes. This empirical implication is broadly consistent with the evidence on aggregate lending in Mexico and the US. In both countries, positive innovations to money market rates take time to produce credit expansion, while negative innovations appear to produce immediate contractions. As a result, the design and implementation of monetary policy should take these asymmetries into consideration, and react accordingly.

Further research is needed. Theoretically, we have focused on the probability that a credit application is accepted, while we have not modeled the way in which banks select the optimal screening time. A natural extension of the model would consider a world in which banks endogenously invest resources in the screening process. Such resources are likely to be dependent on the state of the market, and their proper consideration would further enrich the dynamics of the model. Empirically, the availability of disaggregated data on specific loan contracts would help to distinguish between our technological asymmetries, and asymmetries linked to banks’ oligopoly power it would be necessary to use disaggregated data.

APPENDIX I

Sufficient Conditions for the Existence of an Equilibrium

The function implied by Eq. 9:

W i = y i = a i r d α β a i [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) ] α ( 1 β ) b i max ( W i ; 0 ) ( ρ + λ i ) ( 1 )

does not satisfy the Blackwel’s sufficient conditions for a contraction. However, it is easy to show that, under certain restrictions on the parameters, that mapping is a contraction mapping, that guarantees the existence of a unique fixed point.

We can define Eq. 1 as a function T: RnRn. We can also define a sort of aggregate average discount factor, ψ, dependent on both the actual discount factor, ρ, and the parameters describing death processes, λi, as:

ψ = α ( 1 β ) ρ + 1 n i = 1 n α β ( ρ + σ + λ i ) ( ρ + σ ) ( ρ + λ i )

Now consider two vectors X and Y elements of Rn and a metric d, where d(X,Y)=||XY||=i=1n|xiyi|, then we can write the following proposition:

Equilibrium Existence

If ψ < 1, then for any X,YRn,φ(0,1) such that: ||T(X)T(Y)||φ||XY|| The ith element of ΔT = T (X) − T (Y) reads as:

Δ T i = A i [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( x i ; 0 ) 1 n j = 1 n max ( y i ; 0 ) ] B i [ max ( x i ; 0 ) max ( y i ; 0 ) ]

where:

A i = a i α β ( ρ + λ i ) = α β ( ρ + σ + λ i ) ( ρ + σ ) ( ρ + λ i ) > 0 B i = b i ( ρ + λ i ) = B = α ( 1 β ) ρ > 0

then:

| | T ( X ) T ( Y ) | | = i = 1 n | B [ max ( x i ; 0 ) max ( y i ; 0 ) ] A i [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( x i ; 0 ) 1 n j = 1 n max ( y i ; 0 ) ] |

changing all signs within the absolute value, and applying the triangular inequality we get:

T ( X ) T ( Y ) i = 1 n | B [ max ( x i ; 0 ) max ( y i ; 0 ) ] | ( 2 )
+ i = 1 n | A i [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( x i ; 0 ) 1 n j = 1 n max ( y i ; 0 ) ] | ( 3 )

now, we know that:

| max ( x i ; 0 ) | max ( y i ; 0 ) | | x i y i |

thus:

i = 1 n | B [ max ( x i ; 0 ) max ( y i ; 0 ) ] | = i = 1 n B | [ max ( x i ; 0 ) max ( y i ; 0 ) ] | i = 1 n B | x i y i |

and finally:

i = 1 n B | x i y i | = B · i = 1 n | x i y i | ( 4 )

Now consider the second term in Eq. 2, given Ai > 0 for any i, we have:

i = 1 n | A i [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( x i ; 0 ) 1 n j = 1 n max ( y i ; 0 ) ] | = i = 1 n A i | 1 n j = 1 n [ max ( x i ; 0 ) max ( y i ; 0 ) ] |

for the triangular inequality we have:

i = 1 n A i | 1 n j = 1 n [ max ( x i ; 0 ) max ( y i ; 0 ) ] | i = 1 n A i · 1 n j = 1 n | max ( x i ; 0 ) max ( y i ; 0 ) |

and, as before:

i = 1 n A i · 1 n j = 1 n | max ( x i ; 0 ) max ( y i ; 0 ) | ( i = 1 n A i ) · ( 1 n j = 1 n | x i y i | ) ( 5 )

Now, putting together Eq. 4 and Eq. 5 we obtain:

T ( X ) T ( Y ) B · i = 1 n | x i y i | + ( i = 1 n A i ) · ( 1 n j = 1 n | x i y i | )

and a sufficient condition for T to be a contraction mapping can be written as:

B · i = 1 n | x i y i | + ( i = 1 n A i ) · ( 1 n j = 1 n | x i y i | ) φ j = 1 n | x i y i |

that is equivalent to:

B + 1 n i = 1 n A i φ

or:

α ( 1 β ) ρ + 1 n i = 1 n α β ( ρ + σ + λ i ) ( ρ + σ ) ( ρ + λ i ) φ < 1

q.d.e.

APPENDIX II

Monotonicity of the Surplus Function

In the following proposition we state the conditions for the monotonicity of the surplus function.

Monotonicity

i[1,2,,n], and k<i, if:

λ i > λ i k y i > y i k y i y i k > λ i λ i k

then Wi > Wik.

Assume that Wi < Wik then:

W i k W i ( 6 )
= y i k a i k r d α β a i k 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) α ( 1 β ) b i k max ( W i k ; 0 ) ρ + λ i k ( 7 ) y i a i r d α β a i 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) α ( 1 β ) b i max ( W i ; 0 ) ρ + λ i > 0

substituting we can see that for any j:

α ( 1 β ) b j max ( W j ; 0 ) ρ + λ j = α ( 1 β ) max ( W j ; 0 ) ρ

then, by assumption:

α ( 1 β ) max ( W i k ; 0 ) ρ > α ( 1 β ) max ( W i ; 0 ) ρ

that means that:

W i k W i < y i k a i k r d α β a i k 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) ρ + λ i k y i a i r d α β a i 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) ρ + λ i

Also by assumption, we know that:

y i ρ + λ i > y i k ρ + λ i k

thus:

W i k W i < a i k r d α β a i k 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) ρ + λ i k a i r d α β a i 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) ρ + λ i ( 8 )

we can rewrite the right hand side of Eq. 8 as:

[ 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) + r d ] · ( α i ρ + λ i α i k ρ + λ i k )

now, we can show that the second term in this expression is negative, and that contradicts the initial assumption Wi < Wik.

a i ρ + λ i < a i k ρ + λ i k ρ + σ + λ i ( ρ + σ ) ( ρ + λ i ) < ρ + σ + λ i k ( ρ + σ ) ( ρ + λ i k )

that is equivalent to:

ρ + σ + λ i ρ + λ i < ρ + σ + λ i k ρ + λ i k

that, given λi > λik, is verified for any ρ, and σ positive.

APPENDIX III

Comparative Static Results

Effects of rd on Surplus

Wird<0 for any i.

Start from the following equation:

( ρ + λ i ) W i = y i a i r d α β a i [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) ] α ( 1 β ) b i max ( W i ; 0 ) ( 9 )

First consider that for any Wi < 0, we have max(Wi;0)rd=0, so that we can write:

1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) r d = 1 n j | W j 0 max ( W j ; 0 ) r d = 1 n j | W j 0 W j r d ( 10 )

for the Wi ≥ 0 Eq. 9 can be rewritten as:

W i = y i a i c i r d α β a i c i [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( W j ; 0 ) ]

where:

c i = ( ρ + λ i ) + α ( 1 β ) b i

and, using Eq. 10 we have:

W i r d = a i c i α β a i c i 1 n j | W j 0 W j r d ( 11 )

summing for all the non negative Wi, and solving, we get:

j | W j 0 W j r d = j | W j 0 a i c i 1 + α β n j | W j 0 a i c i < 0 ( 12 )

from Eq. 11 we can write:

W i r d · c i a i = 1 α β 1 n j | W j 0 W j r d ( 13 )

that is Wird·ciai is a constant respect to i. Thus, given ciai>0, from Eq. 12 and 13, it has to be:

W i r d < 0

q.d.e.

Effect ofrdonrirird>0 for any i.

We can write the lending rate for projects of type i as:

r i = ( ρ + λ i ) β W i + ( 1 + λ i σ + ρ ) ρ D ( 14 )

then we have:

r i r d = ( ρ + λ i ) β W i r d + ( 1 + λ i σ + ρ ) ρ D r d ( 15 )

now, from Eq. 4 and the previous proposition we know that:

ρ D r d = 1 + α β 1 n j | W j 0 W j r d > 0 ( 16 )

then, using Eq. 11, Eq. 15 becomes:

r i r d = ( 1 + λ i σ + ρ a i c i ( ρ + λ i ) β ) ( 1 + α β 1 n j | W j 0 W j r d ) ( 17 )

where we can rewrite the first term in Eq. 17 as:

( ρ + α ) ( 1 β ) ( ρ + σ + λ i ) [ ρ + α ( 1 β ) ] ( ρ + σ ) > 0

which, together with Eq. 16, means that:

r i r d > 0

q.d.e.

APPENDIX IV

On The Timing of The Bankruptcy Procedure

In this section we show that in the presence of a positive flow cost f, banks never choose to start the recovery process before a project is bankrupt. Let Li be the value to the bank of an active project for which the bank started a bankruptcy procedure involving an flow cost f, the equation reads:

ρ L i = r i f + λ i ( B L i ) + σ ( max [ D , L i ] L i ) ( 18 )

where D is the value of one unit of deposits:

ρ D = r d + α [ 1 n j = 1 n max ( L j ; D ) D ]

Then we have the following proposition:

For dt arbitrary small, any f > 0, implies Ci > Li.

Consider the problem in discrete time, Eq. 18 reads as

ρ dt L i = r i dt fdt + λ i dt ( B L i ) + σ dt ( max [ D , L i ] L i ) + λ i dt σ dt ( D L i )

or, dividing by dt

ρ L i = r i f + λ i ( B L i ) + σ ( max [ D , L i ] L i ) + λ i σ dt ( D L i )

that means:

lim dt 0 ρ L i = r i l + λ i ( R i L i ) + σ ( max [ D , L i ] L i ) ( 19 )

However, in steady state, the last term in Eq. 19 is always zero, so that we have:

ρ L i = r i l + λ i ( R i L i )

that is smaller than ρCi for any l > 0. q.d.e.

References

  • Aspe, P., (1993), Economie Transformation the Mexican Way, MIT Press: Cambridge.

  • Ball, L., and N. G. Mankiew, (1994), “Asymmetric Price Adjustment and Economic Fluctuations”, Economic Journal Vol. 104.

  • Bernanke, B and M. Gertler, (1995), “Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy TransmissionThe Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9, Num. 4, pp. 27-48.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bernanke, B. and A. Blinder, (1988), “Credit, Money, and Aggregate Demand”, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, pp. 435-439.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bernanke, B. and A. Blinder, (1992), “The Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of Monetary transmission”, American Economic Review, Vol. 82 pp. 901-921.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burdett, K, and R. Wright, (1998), “Two-Sided Search”, Review of Economic Dynamics, forthcoming.

  • Bhattacharya, S. and A. Thakor, (1993), “Contemporary Banking TheoryJournal of Financial Intermediation, 3, pp. 2-50.

  • Caplin, A. and J. Leahy (1991), “State-Dependent Pricing and the Dynamics of Money and Output”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, August, pp. 683-708.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cover, J.P. (1992), “Asymmetric Effects of Positive ad Negative Money-Supply Shocks”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. CVII, pp. 1261-82

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, D. (1984), “Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring”, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 51, pp. 393-414.

  • Diamond, P. (1982), “Wage Determination and Efficiency in Search Equilibrium.” Review of Economic Studies. Vol. 49: 217-227.

  • Garibaldi, P. (1997), “The Asymmetric Effect of Monetary Policy on Job creation and Destruction”, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 44, pp. 557-84.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garibaldi, P. (1998), “Job Flow Dynamics and Firing restrictionsEuropean Economic Review, Vol. 42, No. 2 245-275.

  • Greenbaum, S., Kanatas, G. and I. Venezia (1989), “Equilibrium Loan Pricing under the Bank-Client Relationship.” Journal of Banking and Finance. Vol. 13, pp. 221-235.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hannan, T. and A. Berger (1991), “The Rigidity of Prices: Evidence form the Banking Industry.” American Economic Review. Vol. 81, pp. 938-945.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hubbard, R. (1994), “Is There a ’Credit Channel’ for Monetary Policy”, NBER Working Paper, No. 4977.

  • Jackman, R. and J. Sutton, (1982), “Imperfect Capital Markets and the Monetarist Black Box: Liquidity Constraints, Inflation and the Asymmetric Effects of Interest Rate Policy,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 92, pp. 108-28.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kashyap A. and J. Stein, (1993), “Monetary Policy and Bank Lending”, NBER Working Paper, No. 4317.

  • Mishkin, F. (1995) “Symposium on the monetary transmission mechanismJournal of Economic Perspectives Vol. 9 pp. 3-10.

  • Mortensen, D. and C. Pissarides, (1994), “Job Creation and Job Destruction in the Theory of Unemployment”, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 61 (July) pp. 397-415.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mortensen, D. and C. Pissarides, (1998), “New Developments in Models of Search in the Labor Market”, forthcoming Handbook of Macroeconomics, North Holland, Amsterdam.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Neumark, D. and S. Sharpe, (1992), “Market Structure and the Nature of Price Rigidity: Evidence from the Market for Consumer Deposits”, Quarterly Journal of Economics pp. 657-681.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pesaran, M.H., Y. Shin, and R. Smith (1996), “Testing for the Existence of a Long-Run relationship”, DAE Working Paper No. 9622, Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Scholnick, B. (1996), “Asymmetric adjustment of commercial bank interest rates: evidence from Malaysia and Singapore”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 15, No. 3, pp. 485-96.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sharma, S. (1987), “On the Existence and Uniqueness of Value Functions in Models of Labor Market Dynamics”, Economic Letters Vol. 24, pp. 349-352.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stiglitz, J. and A. Weiss, (1981), “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information”, American Economic Review, Vol. 71, pp. 393-410.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tirole, J. (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization, Cambridge: MIT Press.

1

We benefited from comments and suggestions of Fabio Bagliano, Eduardo Borensztein, Luis Cubeddu, Ilan Goldfajn, Vincent Hogan, Sunil Sharma, and seminar participants at the IMF. We are particularly indebted to Robert Marquez, Michael Mussa, and Miguel Savastano. Address for correspondence: Giovanni Dell’Ariccia (or Pietro Garibaldi), International Monetary Fund, 700 19th Street, N.W., Washington D.C.

1

In the rest of the paper we use the term financial intermediaries and banks interchangeably.

3

See section VI for a brief review of the existing literature.

4

The model follows the most recent developments of the matching literature (Burdett and Wright (1998), and Mortensen and Pissarides, 1998).

5

In reality, a significant component of aggregate bank lending is represented by line of credits, which banks can close without time delays. However, recalling the portion of funds actually withdrawn by clients requires a time consuming procedures.

6

See in particular Stiglitz and Weiss (1981). Bhattacharya and Thakor (1993) provide an extensive survey.

7

Within the related labor market literature, Garibaldi (1998) proposes a model in which firing is stochastic and time consuming.

8

In this sense this paper relates to Greenbaum, Kanatas and Venezia (1989).

9

These results are partly related to the literature that analyzes empirically the relationship between bank lending rates and money market rates. See Hannan and Berger (1991), Neumark and Sharpe (1992) and Scholnick (1996).

10

This assumption implies that the amount of capital invested in existing loans does not affect the number of applications screened. Relaxing this assumption would make the analytic of the model much more cumbersome, but it would not alter its conclusions.

11

W can also say that the banking system issues new loans with an average waiting time 1α.

12

This assumption rule out banks’ effort as a determinant of the probability of recovery.

13

We will show that in equilibrium some project are never financed, and have zero value.

14

The appendix shows that the alternative banks’ policy of entering the recovery state when the loan is still viable is never optimal when time is continuous, and the idiosyncratic shock λi is independent of the probability of recovering the capital.

15

The proof in the Appendix is in the spirit of Sharma (1987), who shows the existence and uniqueness of a fixed point in traditional dynamic matching models.

17

We do not report the expressions for the match’s surplus in tight and easy states, but the detailed expressions are available from the authors upon request.

18
Consider, for example, equation 20. We can rewrite it as:
ViE=αρ+μmax[VE;0]+μρ+μ(ViT)
so that we obtain:
limμViE=ViT

and similarly for the other value functions.

19

For the U.S. we use the Federal Fund Rate.

20

To obtain meaningful results we have to take into account all those factors that affect both the money market interest rate and bank lending, and that, if excluded, would bias our estimates. An alternative procedure could have been to include the variables that influence the money-market rate directly in the final regression.

21

For Mexico both criteria gave the same results, so that we have only one set of shocks.

22

Our theoretical framework assumes that the banking system is endowed with a fixed amount of capital.

23
After writing regression (34) in the error correction form
ΔLt=c+ζ0Lt1+γ0Dt1+ν1tightt2+μ1easyt2+i=1R1ζiLti+i=1S1γiDti+i=2U1νitightti+i=2V1μieasyti+χt+ωt,

we test the following null hypothesis of instability: ζ0 = γ0 = ν1 = μ1 = 0. The F-statistic for this test is non-standard, and its critical values are reported in Pesaran et al. (1996). In this case the critical bound values at the 99 percent level are 5.315 and 6.414. The computed F—statistic for Mexico and for the US are, respectively, 7.7 and 6.5 when the shocks are obtained with the Akaike criterion, and 6.6 when the US shocks are obtained through the Schwartz criterion. Thus, we comfortably reject the null of instability at the 99 percent level.

24

See Aspe (1993) for discussion of developments in Mexico economy during the 80s.

25

This idea relies on the particular role of deposits as a source of funds for the banks. See Kashyap and Stein (1993).

28

Garibaldi (1997) analyses the asymmetric effects of monetary policy on job creation and destruction in a dynamic matching model.

29

Our theory is consistent with asymmetric adjustment of lending volumes at the individual and aggregate level, while it predicts a symmetric adjustment of lending rates at the individual loan level. Microdata on banks’ lending would allow us to test this empirical implication.