The Real Effects of Monetary Policy in the European Union
What Are the Differences?

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: rramaswamy@imf.org; and nats@cbs.dk

The main finding of this paper is that the European Union (EU) countries fall into two broad groups according to the effects of monetary policy adjustments on economic activity. Estimates based on a vector autoregression model indicate that the full effects of a contractionary monetary shock on output in one group of EU countries (Austria, Belgium, Finland, Germany, Netherlands, and United Kingdom) take roughly twice as long to occur, but are almost twice as deep as in the other group (Denmark, France, Italy, Portugal, Spain, and Sweden). The paper discusses the implications of these results for the effective conduct of monetary policy in the euro area.

Abstract

The main finding of this paper is that the European Union (EU) countries fall into two broad groups according to the effects of monetary policy adjustments on economic activity. Estimates based on a vector autoregression model indicate that the full effects of a contractionary monetary shock on output in one group of EU countries (Austria, Belgium, Finland, Germany, Netherlands, and United Kingdom) take roughly twice as long to occur, but are almost twice as deep as in the other group (Denmark, France, Italy, Portugal, Spain, and Sweden). The paper discusses the implications of these results for the effective conduct of monetary policy in the euro area.

I. Introduction

The advent of European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) scheduled for the beginning of 1999 has sparked off a debate about the best way of conducting monetary policy in the euro area. One dimension of this discussion concerns the preferred framework for conducting monetary policy—i.e., about whether the European Central Bank (ECB) ought to target inflation, monetary aggregates, or the exchange rate. A second is about differences in the effects of changes in monetary policy on activity in different EU countries, related to differences in the transmission mechanism.

Opinions have tended to be divided on the question of the preferred monetary policy framework for the euro area, although recently, there appears to be a consensus emerging in favor of informal inflation targeting, accompanied by monitoring of monetary aggregates and other indicators.2 In any event, policy discussions have in general tended to focus less on questions relating to the real effects of monetary policy in the EU than on the issue of the appropriate framework for conducting monetary policy in the euro area. This may be partly due to the fact that many of the issues pertaining to identification of the monetary transmission mechanism tend to be econometric rather than economic. Nevertheless, a proper understanding of possible differences in the effects of changes in monetary policy on activity among the EU countries is crucial for an appreciation of the difficulties that may arise from the implementation of a unified monetary policy throughout the euro area. And this issue is the main focus of the paper.

Recent empirical studies of the effects of monetary policy on activity have focused mainly on a sub-set of EU countries. Gerlach and Smets (1995), using a vector autoregression (VAR) approach with long-run identifying restrictions, found that the effects of a change in the monetary stance on output was somewhat larger in Germany than in France or Italy, while the United Kingdom fell somewhere in between. However, the differences in the transmission of monetary policy documented in the Gerlach-Smets study were not found to be very large. Barran, Coudert, and Mojon (1996) estimate a VAR using the recursive Choleski identifying assumptions, to document the differences in the transmission of monetary policy for a group of EU countries. They find that the effect of a contractionary monetary shock on output is relatively long lasting in Germany, with output (relative to baseline) bottoming out about 10 quarters after the shock, somewhat less long lasting in the UK with output bottoming out after about 8 quarters, whilst in France output reaches the trough about 6 quarters after the shock.3 A recent Bank of England study by Britton and Whitley (1997), which simulates a variant of the Mundell-Flemming model to analyze the transmission mechanism, found that the response of output to an interest rate shock was smaller in the UK than in Germany or France, but that the differences in the transmission of monetary policy among these countries were not very large.

An interesting finding that emerges from these studies, which use different estimation strategies, is that there are differences in the effects of monetary policy on activity among the large EU countries. However, these differences do not correspond closely to popular perceptions about how output may be expected to respond to changes in monetary policy. In particular, some of these studies indicate that the response of output to monetary policy actions is not more sensitive in the UK than it is in some “core” EU countries.4

This paper analyses the nature of the differences in the effects of monetary policy on activity in the EU by examining a larger set of EU countries than previous studies.5 Moreover, unlike previous empirical studies which have each relied on one particular model specification for estimating the dynamics of the transmission of monetary policy, this paper examines the robustness of the estimates of the response of output to monetary shocks in the different EU countries with respect to alternative specifications of the VAR approach. The main finding is that, based on estimates using the VAR approach, the EU countries fall into two broad groups as far as the transmission of monetary policy is concerned. In one group (Austria, Belgium, Finland, Germany, the Netherlands, and the UK) output (relative to baseline) typically bottoms out about 11 to 12 quarters following a contractionary monetary shock, with the decline in output being in the range of 0.7 to 0.9 percent from the baseline.6

In the other group (Denmark, France, Italy, Portugal, Spain, and Sweden) output typically bottoms out about 5 to 6 quarters after a contractionary monetary shock, with the decline in output being in the range of 0.4 to 0.6 percent from baseline. It is interesting to note in this context that while these two groups of EU countries bear a relatively close resemblance to the “core” and the “periphery”, respectively, that are distinguished in the literature on asymmetric shocks, there are some important differences. The response of activity to monetary shocks in Finland and the UK corresponds more closely to that of the “EU-core”, whereas the real effects of monetary policy in France appears to correspond more closely to that of the “EU-periphery”.7

This paper is organized as follows. Section II discusses the conceptual issues pertaining to the monetary transmission mechanism. Section III discusses the estimation strategy used in the paper, and the main results regarding the differences in the effects to changes in monetary policy on activity among the EU countries. Section IV concludes. Technical issues regarding specification and identification in the VAR approach are discussed in the Appendix.

II. The Transmission Mechanism: Conceptual Issues

Why does a change in the nominal interest rate affect the level of activity in the economy? An increase in the nominal interest rate is transformed in the short run into an increase in the real interest rate, given that prices are sticky over the near-term horizon.8 But why does an increase in the real short-term interest rate have relatively strong effects on long-lived assets such as residential and non-residential investments? The answer to this question leads to the core of the debate on the monetary transmission mechanism. Opinions tend to be divided on the importance of the channels through which an interest rate shock affects activity, although there is a widespread consensus that monetary shocks have real effects in the short run.

There are a number of different channels through which a tightening of monetary policy tends to depress activity. The direct effects of a monetary shock operate through the interest rate channel--the increase in the cost of capital leads to declines in the interest sensitive components of aggregate demand. The exchange rate channel of the transmission mechanism becomes more important in small open economies--a monetary tightening causes the nominal exchange rate to appreciate, which given nominal rigidities, translates into a short-run appreciation of the real exchange rate, which tends to compress net exports. Some have emphasized the asset price channel as the crucial ingredient in explaining the short-run real effects of monetary policy.9 An increase in short-term interest rates leads to falls in the prices of a wide range of assets, which in turn reduces consumption expenditure through wealth effects, and investment expenditure through Tobin’s q-effects. The credit channel of the monetary transmission mechanism has been emphasized by economists who are skeptical of the strength of the cost-of-capital and wealth effects on aggregate demand.10 Thus, in the “credit-view”, the contractionary impulses of monetary policy are transmitted to a large extent through declines in bank lending.

Given the ongoing debate about the relative importance of the different channels of the monetary transmission mechanism, the choice of any one particular structural model over another for empirical estimation may tend quickly to get mired in controversy. Consequently, recent empirical investigations of the transmission of monetary policy have tended to be based largely on reduced form vector autoregressions (VARs). A VAR essentially consists of a set of equations in which each variable in the system is determined by its own lagged values and the lags of all the other variables in the system. The VAR approach, despite its black-box nature, is particularly useful when the main objective of the empirical exercise is to derive an estimate of the statistical relationship between a set of variables--as in this case, between monetary shocks and output--without necessarily wanting to unravel, or to establish the relative importance of, the various channels of the transmission mechanism. The VAR approach also provides an appropriate framework for making cross-country comparisons--the same reduced form equations can be used in all countries for estimating the response of output to monetary shocks.

In order to draw valid empirical inferences about the response of output to changes in monetary policy we need an appropriate way of identifying the monetary shocks inherent in the data. As noted in the introduction, there are two dimensions to the conduct of monetary policy. One is that central banks adjust the instruments of monetary policy--usually one or more key short-term interest rate--in response to changes in variables related to their objectives--the reaction function. The other is that actions taken by the central bank to adjust the instruments of monetary policy affect the real economy. Since our interest in this paper is on this latter issue, it requires an empirical strategy for identifying the policy-induced component of changes in output. A starting point for doing this is to focus on short-term interest rates rather than on money or reserves for identifying monetary policy innovations. Most central banks smooth overnight or other short-term interest rates, changing them only when they deliberately intend to change the stance of monetary policy. Consequently, changes in money or commercial banks’ reserves typically reflect demand shocks rather than policy induced shocks.11 The estimation strategy adopted in this paper for quantifying the impact of a policy-induced change in short-term interest rates on output is discussed in the Appendix. Given proper identifying restrictions, the fact that the monetary authorities in different countries may have different reaction functions should not in principle affect estimated cross-country differences in the effects of monetary policy in the EU.

III. Empirical Estimations

This paper follows the general convention in the empirical literature on the transmission of monetary policy by estimating a VAR with three variables for all EU countries: the level of output, the level of prices, and a short-term interest rate.12 The data span the period from 1972:1 to 1995:4. As can be seen from Table A1, both the Dickey-Fuller and the Phillips-Perron tests indicate that both the level of output and the level of prices are non-stationary in all the EU countries used in the sample. Why then is the VAR specified in levels rather than in the first differences of the variables, given that time-series normally ought to be stationary for making valid statistical inferences? The answer to this question involves an assessment of the trade-off between the loss of efficiency (when the VAR is estimated unrestricted in levels) and the loss of information (when the VAR is estimated in first differences). The Appendix discusses the methodological issues concerning this trade-off, and the reasons for preferring the unrestricted version of the VAR to that of imposing cointegration restrictions. The robustness of the results to alternative specifications of the VAR are also examined in the Appendix. The VAR is estimated with two lags based on both the Akaike and Schwartz criteria (Table A2). Experimenting with longer lag lengths (both 4 and 6 lags) did not change the results of the estimations very much.

Figures 1 and 2 trace the response of output in the various EU countries to a standardized monetary shock. The EU countries fall into two broad groups as far as the response of output to monetary shocks is concerned. In one group (Austria, Belgium, Finland, Germany, the Netherlands, and the UK) output typically bottoms out (relative to baseline) about 11 to 12 quarters after a contractionary monetary shock. There are some small differences within this group in the magnitude of the decline in output from baseline. In Austria, Germany, the Netherlands, and the UK, the decline in output following a monetary shock is about 0.7 to 0.8 percent from baseline. The decline in output following an interest rate shock is, however, deeper in Belgium and Finland (about 0.9 percent from baseline), but the impact of the monetary shock tends to dissipate after about 12 quarters in these two countries. In the other group of countries (Denmark, France, Italy, Portugal, Spain and Sweden) output typically bottoms out about 5 to 6 quarters after a contractionary monetary shock. Again, there are some differences within this latter group in the magnitude of the decline in output from baseline. In Denmark, France, and Spain, the decline in output following a monetary shock is about 0.3 to 0.4 percent from baseline, while it is about 0.5 to 0.6 percent from baseline in Italy, Portugal and Sweden. The impact of the monetary shock on output tends to dissipate after bottoming out in most of this latter broad group of countries. These results are relatively stable when estimations are carried out with the inclusion of the nominal exchange rate in the VAR, except most notably in the case of Sweden, where there was a dampening of the response of output to the interest rate shock (see Appendix, Figures 5 and 6).13 Imposing cointegration restrictions on the VAR does not in general change the shape of the impulse responses derived from the unrestricted VAR for the EU countries, but alters the deviation of output from baseline for some EU countries (see Appendix for details). Using a shorter sample period for the estimations (1981:1 to 1995:4) also did not change the results markedly.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Impulse Response of Output to an Interest Rate Shock1

(In percent deviation from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1997, 160; 10.5089/9781451857719.001.A001

1Dotted lines denote two standard error bands.
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Impulse Response of Output to an Interest Rate Shock1

(In percent deviation from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1997, 160; 10.5089/9781451857719.001.A001

1Dotted lines denote two standard error bands.

IV. Conclusion

There are two basic preconditions that determine the ability to conduct monetary policy smoothly in the euro area. One is a framework that can provide stable feedback rules for the monetary authority to react in a timely way to prospective changes in activity and inflation. The other is the need for the real effects of monetary policy to be relatively uniform across the different EU countries. The latter issue has been the focus of this paper, with the main finding being that the EU countries fall into two broad groups. Based on the results from the methodological approach used in this paper, the full effects of a contractionary monetary shock on activity take roughly twice as long to occur but the resulting decline in output is almost twice as deep in one group of EU countries (Austria, Belgium, Finland, Germany, the Netherlands, and the UK) as in the other group (Denmark, France, Italy, Portugal, Spain, and Sweden). It is interesting to note in this context that the distinction between the two groups of EU countries in relation to the effects of monetary policy does not overlap fully with the traditional distinction made between the “core” and the “periphery of the EU.

Thus, based on past experience, there appear to be marked differences in the real effects of monetary policy among the EU countries. However, the important question is to what extent these differences are likely to carry through once the euro comes into circulation. The answer to this question can, of course, only be speculative. On the basis of the results in this paper about the extent of the differences in the effects of monetary policy on activity among the EU countries, the conjecture is that the task of conducting monetary policy at the EU-wide level is likely to be a challenging one in the initial years of the monetary union. However, the creation of a single financial market, and the operation of the common monetary policy is likely to narrow over time the differences in the transmission of monetary policy among the EU countries. It is perhaps very likely that the harmonization of the transmission of monetary policy will take place more rapidly than the harmonization of the “real-side” of the EU countries.

APPENDIX

Specification and Identification Strategies

The appendix discusses in greater detail two sets of conceptual issues relating to the estimation strategy that were noted in the main text. The first is on the appropriate specification of the VARs; the second is on the method used for identifying monetary shocks. The main issue regarding specification is whether the model should be estimated in levels, pure differences, or as a vector error correction model. This section discusses the criteria for choosing among them. It turns out that in the case of the EU countries, for the sample period under consideration, the impulse-responses of output to an interest rate shock do not in general change significantly when alternative specifications are used. The issue of identification is related to the empirical strategy of obtaining a measure of the purely policy induced change in interest rates.

A. Specification

In deciding on which particular specification of the VAR to use, it is necessary to confront the trade-off between (statistical) efficiency and the potential loss of information that takes place when economic time series are differenced. A VAR specified in differences, when the time series are non-stationary, will generate estimates that are efficient, but will ignore potential long-run relationships of importance.

More generally, there are three different ways of specifying a VAR when the time series under consideration are non-stationary. The VAR can be specified in pure differences; it can be specified in levels without imposing any restrictions; and third, the VAR can be specified as a vector error correction model to allow for the existence of cointegration. In general, the vector error correction specification can generate efficient estimates without loosing information about the long-run relationships among the variables.

If cointegration exists, and the true cointegrating relationship is both known and can be given an economic interpretation, the VAR should be estimated using the vector error correction model with the reduced rank estimation suggested by Johansen (1995). However, if the true cointegrating relationships are unknown, and furthermore, when the relationships are not the main focus of the analysis, then imposing cointegration may not be the appropriate estimation strategy. Imposing inappropriate cointegration relationships can lead to biased estimates and hence bias the impulse-responses derived from the reduced form VARs. In cases where there is no a priori economic theory which can suggest either the number of long-run relationships or how they should be interpreted (as is the case with the set of variables under consideration in this paper), it is reasonable not to impose the restriction of cointegration on the VAR model.14

Consequently, an unrestricted VAR in levels has been chosen as the preferred specification in this paper. It is, nevertheless, still interesting to test how robust the results are to alternative specifications of the VAR. In order to do this, cointegration is imposed as follows. We first test for the number of cointegrating relationships in the VAR, and then impose these cointegrating vectors on the VAR. The cointegrating vectors are derived assuming a linear trend in the data and furthermore an intercept but no trend in the cointegrating vector. The impulse-responses generated from this vector error correction model (i.e. by imposing cointegration on the basic VAR) are reported in Figures 3 and 4. It can be seen that imposing cointegration on the VAR does not in general change the shape of the impulse-responses derived from the unrestricted VAR for the EU countries, but alters the deviation of output from baseline for some EU countries. Figures 5 and 6 show the impulse responses generated by including the nominal exchange rate in the unrestricted VAR.15

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Impulse Response of Output to and Interest Rate Shock

(In percent deviation from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1997, 160; 10.5089/9781451857719.001.A001

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Impulse Response of Output to an Interest Rate Shock

(In percent deviation from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1997, 160; 10.5089/9781451857719.001.A001

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Impulse Response of Output to an Interest Rate Shock (Exchange Rate Included)1

(In percent deviation from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1997, 160; 10.5089/9781451857719.001.A001

1Dotted lines denote two standard error bands.
Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Impulse Response of Output to an Interest Rate Shock (Exchange Rate Included)1

(In percent deviation from baseline)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1997, 160; 10.5089/9781451857719.001.A001

1Dotted lines denote two standard error bands.
B. Identification

The VAR model that is estimated is of the reduced form

Xt=A1Xt1++ApXtp+ut(1)

where Xt is a vector of variables at time t and with the variance covariance matrix E[ut ut] = Ω of the innovations, ut.

This reduced form can be represented in terms of its structural version

Xt=B0Xt+B1Xt1++BpXtp+εt(2)

where εt is called the primitive shocks and they are the one’s we are trying to identify through the estimates of the reduced form in equation (1).

Rewriting the reduced form in terms of the structural form and defining A(0) = [I-B0]−1 we get Ai = A(0)Bi for i=1,…,n. This in turn leads us to the relationship between the innovations and the primitive shocks

ut=A(0)εt(3)

hence,

E[ut ut]=Ω=A(0)A(0)(4)

The impulse-response functions to the structural shocks can be obtained through the MA-representation

Xt=[IB(L)]1εt=ϒ(L)εt(5)

from (2) and (3) we can calculate ϒ(L) as

ϒ(L)=[IA(L)]1A(0)(6)

We now have to identify the structural shocks, and this is done by determining the n2 elements of A(0). As the variance-covariance matrix is known from the estimation of (2), we have to solve equation (4) for A(0), and then calculate εt from (3). However, (4) provides only n(n+1)/2 non-linear restrictions on the n2 elements of A(0). Hence n(n-1)/2 additional restrictions are needed for identification.

There are different identification approaches that can be used: (1) the traditional Choleski decomposition, where it is assumed that A(0) is lower triangular, and a recursive decomposition of the Ω matrix is used; (2) restrictions of the form that some variables cannot contemporaneously affect each other (through restrictions on B0) - which we call the Bernanke-Blinder restrictions; (3) long-run a priori theoretical restrictions on B(1) or A(1); and (4) some combination of these three identification schemes, for example by restricting elements of the covariance matrix to be of a certain value using what are called “informal restrictions on the reasonableness of the of the impulse-responses”16.

In using the VAR approach we are primarily interested in the response of output to a shock to the interest rate. In order to do this we assume that a shock to the interest rate has no contemporaneous effect on output. This assumption can be implemented either through the recursive Choleski decomposition or the Bernanke-Blinder restrictions. Put more technically, both the recursive Choleski decomposition and the Bernanke-Blinder restrictions identify monetary policy by taking the residuals from the reduced form of the interest rate equation and regressing them on the residuals from the output and the price equations17. Since we are only interested in the effects of monetary policy on output, these two identification schemes yield the same impulse-response functions. The only difference between these two identification procedures is that the Choleski decomposition, unlike the Bernanke-Blinder restrictions, assumes in addition that prices have no contemporaneous effect on income.

C. Data Sources

Data are obtained from the International Financial Statistics of the International Monetary Fund (IFS) and from the Analytical Database of the OECD. Output and prices are in logs and are seasonally adjusted.

The series on real GDP is defined in national currency and is obtained from the OECD database (the series called GDPV). The series on the consumer price index is obtained from IFS (no. 64 for each national series). The nominal interest rate is the money market rate, and is obtained from the IFS (series no. 60b).

For all countries quarterly data is used covering the period 1972:01-1995:04 except for Finland where we only had data covering 1978:01-1995:04; for Portugal 1981:01-1994:04.

Table A1.

Unit Root Analysis

(The number of lagged differences included in the Dickey-Fuller test is 2 and for the Phillips-Perron test the Bartlett Kernel is 3)

article image
Notes: Y denotes real GDP; P denotes the consumer price index; and i denotes the money market interest rate. Critical values (1, 5, and 10 percent) taken from MacKinnon (1991); Dickey-Fuller and Phillips-Perron without trend (-3.50, -2.89, -2.58); Dickey-Fuller and Phillips-Perron with trend (-4.06, -3.46, -3.15).
Table A2.

Choice of Lag Length

(Carried out for basic model with output, consumer prices, and short interest rate)

article image
article image

References

  • Barran, Fernando, Virginie Coudert, and Bernoit Mojon, 1996, “The Transmission of Monetary Policy in the European Countries,” CEPII Working Paper No. 96-03 (February).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, T. and B. Eichengreen, 1996, “Operationalizing the Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 1484 (October).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Begg, David, 1997, “The Design of EMU,” IMF Working Paper Series WP/97/99 (August).

  • Bernanke, Ben and Alan Blinder, 1992, “The Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of Monetary Transmission,” American Economic Review, Vol. 82, No. 4 (September).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bernanke, Ben and Mark Gertler, 1995, “Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9, No. 4 (Fall).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bernanke, Ben and Ilian Mihov, 1996, “What does the Bundesbank Target?NBER Working Paper, No. 5764 (September).

  • Britton, Erik and John Whitley, 1997, “Comparing the monetary transmission mechanism in France, Germany, and the United Kingdom: Some Issues and Results,” Bank of England (May), Vol. 37, No. 2.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • CEPR, 1997, The Ostrich and the EMU: Policy Choices Facing the U.K. (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

  • Christiano, Lawrance, Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles Evans, 1994, “Identification and the Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks,” Working Paper Series, WP-94-7, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Monetary Institute, 1997, The Single Monetary Policy in Stage Three: Specification of the Operational Framework (January).

  • Faust, Jon and Eric Leeper, 1997, “When Do Long-Run Identifying Restrictions Give Reliable Results?Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 15, No. 3 (July).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gerlach, Stefan and Frank Smets, 1995, “The Monetary Transmission Mechanism: Evidence from the G-7 Countries,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 1219 (July).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johansen, Soeren, 1995, Likelihood-based Inference in Cointegrated Vector Autoregressive Models (Oxford University Press).

  • Leeper, E., Sims, C, and Zha, T., 1996, “What Does Monetary Policy Do?Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2.

  • Levy, Joachim and I. Halikias, 1997, “Aspects of the Monetary Transmission Mechanism under Exchange Rate Targeting. The Case of France,” IMF Working Paper Series No. WP/97/44 (April).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul, and Bart Turtelboom, 1997, “Characteristics of the Euro, the Demand for Reserves, and Policy Coordination Under EMU,” IMF Working Papers Series, WP/97/58 (May).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Meltzer, A.H., 1995, “Monetary, Credit (and other) Transmission Processes: A Monetarist Perspective,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9, No. 4 (Fall).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Montecelli, C. and L. Papi, 1996, European Integration, Monetary Coordination, and the Demand for Money (Clarendon Press: Oxford).

  • Ramaswamy, Ramana, 1997, “Monetary Frameworks: Is There a Preferred Option for the European Central Bank,” IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment, PPAA/97/6 (June).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sims, Christopher, 1992, “Interpreting the Macroeconomic Time Series Facts. The Effects of Monetary Policy,” European Economic Review 36, pp. 975-1011.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Taylor, J, 1995, “The Monetary Transmission Mechanism: An Empirical Framework,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9, No. 4 (Fall).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Thomas, Alun, 1997, “The Monetary Transmission Mechanism in Sweden” in Sweden Selected Issues, IMF SM/97/205.

1

The authors thank, without implicating, Graham Hacche, Alex Hoffmaister, Paul Masson, Donogh McDonald, Guy Meredith, and Eswar Prasad for comments on an earlier version of this paper.

3

In this context, a recent study using higher frequency data by Levy and Halikias (1997) indicates that the response of output to changes in the short-term interest rate in France is relatively muted.

4

A good example of popular perceptions about the transmission mechanism in the EU countries is CEPR (1997), which argues that the impact of an interest rate shock on output would be disproportionately large in the UK because a relatively high proportion of private sector debt is at variable interest rates, partly reflecting the predominance of variable-rate mortgages for house purchase.

5

The empirical analysis in this paper covers all EU countries except Greece, Luxembourg and Ireland. These three countries were excluded because of the absence of a sufficiently long quarterly time series of national income accounts.

6

The monetary shock is of the same dimension for all the countries--a one standard deviation shock to the orthogonalized error term of the interest rate equation in the VAR. It corresponds approximately to a 1 percentage point shock to the interest rate for most EU countries in the sample period under consideration. See Appendix for details on how the monetary shock is measured. The focus of this paper is on the response of output to monetary shocks, and not also on the response of prices to monetary shocks. This is done in order to keep the scope of cross-country comparisons of the transmission mechanism more focused, and also because we do not want to enter in this paper into a detailed discussion of the so-called “price puzzle” for the entire set of EU countries. The price puzzle is the tendency for prices to rise immediately following a contractionary monetary shock; see Leeper, Sims, and Zha (1996) for a more detailed discussion of issues pertaining to the price puzzle.

7

See Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1996) for an overview of the discussion on asymmetric shocks in the EU.

8

For discussions regarding the emerging consensus on the real effects of monetary shocks, see Bernanke and Gertler (1995); Taylor (1995); and the symposium on “Is There a Core of Practical Macroeconomics that We Should All Believe In” in the American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, May 1997,

9

See Meltzer (1995) for good overview of the monetarist position.

10

See Bernanke and Gertler for a discussion of the “credit-view” (1995).

11

For a more detailed discussion of these issues see Bernanke and Blinder (1992), Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (1994), and Bernanke and Mihov (1995).

12

See the Appendix for a description of the data sets used in this study.

13

The impulse response function estimated with the three variable VAR for Sweden is broadly consistent with the results obtained by Thomas (1997), using a simulation model of the IS/LM variety for Sweden.

14

A number of empirical studies of the transmission mechanism have tended to follow the route of estimating VARs that are unrestricted in levels. See for instance Bernanke and Blinder (1992), Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (1994) and Leeper, Sims, and Zha (1996). In this context, Faust and Leeper (1997) argue that imposing long-run restrictions does not necessarily provide a reliable basis for drawing structural inferences.

15

The nominal exchange rate used is the bilateral deutsche mark exchange rate for all countries. In the case of Germany, the bilateral dollar exchange rate is used.

16

See Leeper, Sims, and Zha (1996) for a more detailed discussion.

17

Actually two identification schemes are suggested in Bernanke and Blinder (1992), we however only focus on the scheme where there is no contemporaneous effect of monetary policy on output. Their other identification scheme suggests that the policy variable does not respond contemporaneously to changes in the non-policy variables.

The Real Effects of Monetary Policy in the European Union: What Are the Differences?
Author: Mr. Ramana Ramaswamy and Mr. Torsten M Sloek
  • View in gallery

    Impulse Response of Output to an Interest Rate Shock1

    (In percent deviation from baseline)

  • View in gallery

    Impulse Response of Output to an Interest Rate Shock1

    (In percent deviation from baseline)

  • View in gallery

    Impulse Response of Output to and Interest Rate Shock

    (In percent deviation from baseline)

  • View in gallery

    Impulse Response of Output to an Interest Rate Shock

    (In percent deviation from baseline)

  • View in gallery

    Impulse Response of Output to an Interest Rate Shock (Exchange Rate Included)1

    (In percent deviation from baseline)

  • View in gallery

    Impulse Response of Output to an Interest Rate Shock (Exchange Rate Included)1

    (In percent deviation from baseline)