Saving Behavior in Low and Middle-Income Developing Countries
A Comparison
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund
  • | 2 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

The impact of changes in real interest rates on saving and growth is a central issue in development economics. According to one familiar view, a financial liberalization program which increases real interest rates should encourage saving, thereby boosting investment and growth. While such liberalizations have indeed typically succeeded in raising real interest rates, their impact on private saving has been mixed. This paper uses macroeconomic data for a sample of countries with diverse income levels to estimate a model in which the intertemporal elasticity of substitution varies with the level of wealth. The estimated parameters are then used to calculate, in the context of a simple endogenous growth model, the responsiveness of saving to real interest rate changes for countries at differing stages of development.

Abstract

The impact of changes in real interest rates on saving and growth is a central issue in development economics. According to one familiar view, a financial liberalization program which increases real interest rates should encourage saving, thereby boosting investment and growth. While such liberalizations have indeed typically succeeded in raising real interest rates, their impact on private saving has been mixed. This paper uses macroeconomic data for a sample of countries with diverse income levels to estimate a model in which the intertemporal elasticity of substitution varies with the level of wealth. The estimated parameters are then used to calculate, in the context of a simple endogenous growth model, the responsiveness of saving to real interest rate changes for countries at differing stages of development.

I. Introduction

The impact of changes in real interest rates on saving, investment, and economic growth, is a central issue in development economics. According to one familiar view (see, for example, McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973)), an increase in real interest rates in developing countries should encourage saving and expand the supply of credit available to domestic investors, thereby enabling the economy to grow more quickly. Indeed, a number of liberalization programs supported by the international financial institutions over the years have had as their explicit objective to increase interest rates from levels that in many cases were substantially negative in real terms. While increases in real interest rates have often been the outcome of such liberalization episodes (see, for example, Galbis (1993)), their impact on domestic saving and investment has been unclear. 1/

There is little consensus in the empirical literature on the interaction between saving and the real rate of interest (see, for instance, Savastano (1994) and Schmidt-Hebbel, et al. (1992) for a review of this literature). Some researchers have been unable to detect much of an effect of changes in real interest rates on domestic saving in developing countries. For example, Giovannini (1985) finds that in only five of the eighteen developing countries in his sample are consumption and saving sensitive to changes in the real interest rate. He concludes that for the majority of cases, “the response of consumption growth to the real rate of interest is insignificantly different from zero” (page 215) and that one should therefore expect “negligible responses of aggregate saving to the real rate of interest [in developing countries]” (page 197). Rossi (1988) also finds that “increases in the real rate of return are not likely to elicit substantial increases in savings, especially in low-income developing countries” (page 104). In a model with a single consumption good, Ostry and Reinhart (1992) confirm these findings; but when a disaggregated commodity structure that allows for traded and nontraded goods is assumed, these authors find higher and statistically significant estimates of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. However, regional differences emerge, with Asian countries showing a greater responsiveness to real interest rate changes. 2/

The finding of a zero or near-zero interest rate sensitivity of saving in a number of developing countries has led researchers to consider a number of alternative hypotheses that could help to explain this result. One such hypothesis is that consumption in developing countries may be more related to subsistence considerations--particularly in the case of low-income countries--than to intertemporal consumption smoothing. 1/ If households must first achieve a subsistence consumption level, letting intertemporal considerations guide their decisions only for that portion of their budget left after subsistence has been satisfied, then the intertemporal elasticity of substitution and the interest-rate sensitivity of private saving will be close to zero for countries at or near subsistence consumption levels, and rising thereafter.

A second reason why the intertemporal elasticity of substitution may be smaller for low-income countries concerns the relative share of necessities in the budgets of relatively poor households. If necessities (for example, food) are less substitutable through time than other goods, then the intertemporal elasticity of substitution will be lower for households with a larger proportion of necessities in their budgets than for households where such goods are less important. The implication would be that for relatively poor countries where budget shares of food are relatively high, the interest-rate elasticity of saving would be relatively low. 2/

It is indeed noteworthy that food consumption accounts for a markedly lower share of total expenditure in high income than in low income countries. As shown in Table 1, food consumption accounts for less than twenty percent of total expenditure in most industrial countries and for only 8 percent of total consumption in the United States. For middle-income countries such as Mexico and Thailand, the share is often 30-40 percent, while for the poorer countries the share of food approaches 60-70 percent (see Mitchell and Ingco (1993)).

Table 1.

Food as a Percent of Total Personal Expenditure for Selected Countries

(1990)

article image
Note: For classification of economies by income level see World Bank (1994b)Sources: Jones Putnam and Allshouse (1993) and Mitchell and Ingco (1993).

Empirical support for these hypotheses is found in Atkeson and Ogaki (1993). Specifically, using a panel of data on Indian households, they find that the intertemporal elasticity of substitution of the richest six households in their data set is approximately 1.6 times that of the poorest six households. Thus, from their results, the effects of the level of wealth on the intertemporal elasticity of substitution would indeed appear to be economically significant.

There are, however, additional reasons why saving may be less responsive to changes in real interest rates in low-income than in middle-income countries. Rossi (1988), for example, argued that low-income developing countries are characterized by pervasive liquidity constraints which imply that consumption growth in such countries is more likely to follow income growth than changes in expected rates of return. 1/ The empirical evidence appears to point to the presence of liquidity constraints in many developing countries; however, Haque and Montiel (1989) highlight that the severity of these constraints varies considerably across countries. More recently, Vaidyanathan (1993) showed that the incidence of liquidity constraints among households is inversely related to the degree of economic development which would imply--following Rossi (1988)--that saving in poorer countries should be less responsive to interest rate changes. 2/

Lastly, it could be argued that failure to detect a systematic relationship between saving and real interest rates across countries and across time may also be due to considerable variation in the economic significance and information content of the real rates of return themselves. Lack of sophistication and depth in domestic financial markets or direct regulation may result in nominal interest rates that do not adequately reflect expectations about the underlying economic fundamentals. This problem may be particularly severe for some of the poorer countries. In addition, lack of information on inflation expectations is a problem that, as the literature on the peso problem has shown, may be especially relevant for high-inflation countries and/or episodes.

While a number of hypotheses have been put forward to suggest that saving behavior in developing countries is affected by the level of development, there has so far been little systematic empirical investigation of this issue at the macroeconomic level in the literature. Yet from a policy perspective, the issue is of central importance, since for example, the effects on--inter alia investment and growth--of a number of policy actions frequently undertaken by developing countries--including financial liberalization, reducing capital controls, and the transmission of fiscal and commercial policy changes to the current account--will all be governed to some degree by the responsiveness of saving to interest rate changes. 1/

With this in mind, the purpose of this paper is to quantify empirically the response of consumption/saving to changes in the real rate of interest. We proceed in two steps. First, we use macroeconomic data for a sample of countries with diverse income levels to estimate a model that allows the intertemporal elasticity of substitution to vary with the level of wealth. We then use the estimated parameters to calculate, in the context of a simple endogenous growth model, the elasticity of saving with respect to changes in the real rate of interest.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section II presents some stylized facts on saving behavior and income levels and focuses on the differences between low- and middle-income developing countries. Section III describes the analytical framework, while Section IV discusses the empirical methodology and summarizes the estimation results. The response of saving to changes in real interest rates is examined in the context of a simple endogenous growth model in Section V. The implications for policy and future research are taken up in the final section.

II. Stylized Facts

A model, such as the one developed in this paper, that emphasizes the role of subsistence consumption, has two main predictions about saving behavior. First, saving rates should increase with the level of wealth at the initial stages of development, with the largest increases in the saving rate occurring as a country moves from low- to middle-income levels. 1/ Second, saving should become more responsive to changes in real interest rates as countries become richer. The first prediction follows directly from the role of subsistence consumption in the low-income developing countries, and the fact that the share of subsistence in total consumption declines with income. 2/ The second prediction may also be related to subsistence considerations, since intertemporal incentives should only affect that portion of the budget left over after subsistence has been achieved, that is, discretionary income.

With regard to saving rates, a model that stresses the role of liquidity constraints offers a different prediction; if poor consumers cannot borrow but face an uncertain income stream, the demand for precautionary saving rises (see, for instance, Deaton (1989)). 3/ Hence, it may be the poorest liquidity-constrained consumers that save more. However, as with the subsistence model, the responsiveness of saving to changes in interest rates rises with the level of wealth as liquidity constraints become less binding.

Among countries in various income groups, the patterns of saving rates that emerge are broadly consistent with the predictions of the subsistence model. As Table 2 highlights for selected countries, private saving is, on average, considerably lower for the poorest developing countries, where the saving rate is about one half that of the high-income group. 4/ In fact, such differences also appear within regions. According to the World Bank (1994a), median gross domestic saving as a percentage of GDP (1987-91 average) was 5.6 percent for the low income African countries and 19.0 percent for the middle-income African countries (the average was 7.7 percent).

Table 2.

Personal Saving Rates for Selected Countries

(1985–1993 averages, unless otherwise noted)

article image

Average for 1987–91 from World Bank (1994a).

Average for 1985–92 from Savastano (1994).

Note: For classification of economies by income level see World Bank (1994b)Sources: World Economic Outlook, IMF, Savastano (1994). World Bank (1994a).

As predicted, the relationship between the level of income and the saving rate appears to be nonlinear for the countries in our sample (see Rebelo (1992)); the largest increases in the saving rates occur in the transition from low- to lower middle-income, where the average personal saving rate rises by 5.5 percent (Table 2). The average for the upper middle-income countries is still 2.8 percent above that of the lower middle-income group, but there appears to be relatively little difference (0.5 percent) between the average saving rates in the high-income and upper middle-income countries in our sample.

Still, there appear to be sharp differences in savings rates that cannot be accounted for by the subsistence model. For example, saving rates in Latin America are well below those observed in many Asian countries, despite similar income levels. 1/ As pointed out in World Bank (1993), gross domestic saving as a percentage of GDP was nearly 40 percent for the high-performing (middle-income) Asian economies in 1990; it is argued that these relatively high saving rates were an engine of growth in many of these countries, since they financed higher rates of investment as well.

The role of real interest rates in saving behavior is more difficult to gauge. One problem--which is particularly important in Africa, is that financial markets remain thin and governments set interest rates, frequently at non-market levels. As pointed out in a recent World Bank study on Africa (World Bank (1994a)), “most countries [in Africa] have few banks, and…there is little scope for ‘true’ market-determination of interest rates” (page 114). This feature of credit markets in low-income countries may itself make saving less responsive to interest rates.

Nevertheless, there is some evidence that financial savings increased as a result of the increase in real interest rates associated with liberalization of financial markets, both in Africa and elsewhere among developing countries. For example, among the Asian countries, the increase in real interest rates in Taiwan Province of China in 1949 contributed to a sharp increase in savings. Similar results were achieved by Indonesia and Korea, and more recently, by Argentina, Chile, Mexico, and Pakistan (see World Bank (1993) and the references therein). There is also some evidence that reform programs in Africa have succeeded in raising domestic savings. For example, as documented in World Bank (1994a), median gross domestic saving climbed 3.3 percentage points for the six African countries with a large improvement in macroeconomic policies (which consisted of five main indicators, one of which was interest rate policy), compared to a decline of 3.3 percentage points for countries with policy deterioration. In general, moving real interest rates from sharply negative to mildly positive levels seems to be a positive factor in mobilizing domestic savings, although there is no particular evidence that the effectiveness of such policies rises with the level of development, as the subsistence model would suggest. An investigation of this issue is undertaken in the following three sections.

III. Analytical Framework

We begin by describing the maximization problem faced by a representative household in a given country. Since our ultimate purpose is to examine cross-country differences in saving behavior, we do not assume that representative households in different countries have identical preferences. As in Ostry and Reinhart (1992), we adopt a two–good framework that distinguishes between traded and nontraded goods. As argued in that paper, it is important to estimate the intertemporal elasticity of substitution with a two–good model in order to avoid bias when the relative price of traded and nontraded goods (the real exchange rate) varies considerably through time, as we will discuss later. We allow for cross–country variation in both the intratemporal elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded goods and the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. The assumption is that the latter varies systematically with the level of wealth. We begin by describing, in equations (1)–(7) below, the optimization problem at the national level. 1/

Consider then an economy with an infinitely–lived representative household whose objective is to choose a consumption stream that maximizes:

σ(σ1)E0Σt=0[amt11/ϵ+nt11/ϵ]11/σ11/ϵ,(1)a,β,ϵ,σ>0,β<1,

subject to the series of budget constraints:

ptmt + qtnt=ptm¯t + qtn¯t + X¯t+Bt (1/Rt1*)Bt1,t0,(2)

and the transversality condition:

limtαΠit=0(1/Ri*)Bt=0,(3)

where E0 is the expectations operator conditional on information available at time 0; Bt denotes the real level of debt carried from period t to period t+1 with B-1 given; (1/Rt*)1=rt* is the real interest rate (in terms of the numeraire) on the debt so Rt* is the associated world real discount factor; m (n) denotes consumption of importables (nontradables) and p (q) denoted the relative price of m (n) in terms of the numeraire; β is the subjective discount factor; and ϵ (σ) denotes the intratemporal (intertemporal) elasticity of substitution. 1/ An intratemporal elasticity of substitution greater (less) than one implies gross substitutability (complementarity) between traded and nontraded goods; a value of unity corresponds to the logarithmic utility case. The intertemporal elasticity of substitution reflects the sensitivity of consumption (and therefore saving) to changes in intertemporal prices (i.e. the consumption rates of interest), with higher values indicating greater sensitivity.

The problem of the representative consumer in a given country is to choose an optimal sequence {mt, nt, Bt} that maximizes (1) subject to (2) and (3). The first order necessary conditions for an optimum are:

Et{ptRt*pt+1[amt+111/ϵ+nt+111/ϵamt11/ϵ+nt11/ϵ]σϵσ(ϵ1)[mt+1mt]1ϵ}=1β,(4)
Et{qtRt*qt+1[amt+111/ϵ+nt+111/ϵamt11/ϵ+nt11/ϵ]σϵσ(ϵ1)[nt+1nt]1ϵ}=1β,(5)
a(nt/mt)1/ϵ=pt/qt(6)

Equation (4) is the intertemporal Euler equation associated with importables consumption in two consecutive periods; it states that the marginal utility cost of giving up one unit of m at time t should be equated to the expected utility gain from consuming one more unit of m at t+1. Equation (5) is the analogous condition relating the marginal rate of substitution between consumption of good n at t and t+1 to the relevant intertemporal relative price. Finally, equation (6) is the nonstochastic first order condition equating the intratemporal marginal rate of substitution between importables and nontradables to the corresponding relative price ratio. It can be verified that equations (4)–(6) are not independent. Specifically, combining equation (6) with either of the two remaining equations yields the third. Therefore, given that the nonstochastic first order condition holds, equations (4) and (5) do not provide independent restrictions on the evolution of consumption through time.

The main difference between the model described above and standard Euler–equation models that have been applied previously to developing countries (for example, Giovannini (1985) and Rossi (1988)) relates to the goods structure. In the above model, we allow for consumption of tradables and nontradables since the latter appear to account for a large fraction of the consumption basket in many developing countries. Moreover, imposing a one good structure can seriously bias the resulting estimates of preference parameters. If the real exchange rate (the relative price of traded and nontraded goods) varies over time, as is the case in most developed and developing countries, aggregate consumption will respond to those price changes. This is because a change in the real exchange rate alters the consumption rate of interest. As such channels are ignored in a one–good structure, the empirical results from such models may be biased. 1/ For example, the finding that intertemporal elasticities of substitution are insignificantly different from zero in the majority of developing countries was found by Ostry and Reinhart (1992) not to be robust to a relaxation of the one–good assumption.

Given time series data on importables and nontradables consumption, and on interest rates, and import, export, and nontradables prices, it is possible to estimate the system consisting of (4)–(6) and recover the main parameters of interest. Since (6) must hold identically (in the absence of measurement error), and since (4) and (5) are not independent given that (6) holds, we can eliminate (4) or (5) from the estimation. The restrictions on the joint behavior of consumption of importables and nontradables, the terms of trade, and the relevant rate of return, implied by the maximization of the expected utility function given by (1) subject to the constraints given in (2) and (3), are summarized in equation (4). In addition, given the assumption of rational expectations, we can use equation (4) to define the disturbance:

ut={ptRt*pt+1[amt+111/ϵ+nt+111/ϵamt11/ϵ+nt11/ϵ]σϵσ(ϵ1)[mt+1mt]1ϵ}1β,(7)

where ut must be uncorrelated with any variable that is in the information set of agents at time t.

With the optimization problem of a representative household in a given country fully described, it remains to be specified how intertemporal parameters governing saving behavior vary systematically across countries. In what follows, we take a particularly simple approach motivated by a Stone–Geary preference specification (as described, for example, by Rebelo (1992)). We adopt a specification in which the intertemporal elasticity of substitution is an increasing function of the gap between permanent income and the subsistence level of consumption, viz:

σi=σ(1γyip)(8)

where σi denotes the intertemporal elasticity of substitution in country i; ypi is a measure of permanent income in country i; and γ is a constant which reflects subsistence consumption. Clearly, equation (8) is similar to the Stone–Geary preference specification but with permanent income replacing consumption. Conceptually, we focus on income rather than consumption in order to make transparent the connection between the intertemporal elasticity of substitution and the level of development (i.e., income per capita). Equation (8) shows that the interest–rate sensitivity of aggregate consumption (as well as the level of saving itself) will be lower as the ratio, γ/ypi approaches unity and wealth is only sufficient to support a subsistence level of consumption.

IV. Estimation Strategy and Empirical Results

1. Data issues

The parameters of the representative household’s utility function outlined in the previous section are estimated using annual time–series data for thirteen countries. The low–income countries in the sample are: Egypt, Ghana, India, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka; the low–middle income countries consist of Colombia, Costa Rica, Côte d’Ivoire, Morocco, and the Philippines; three upper–middle–income countries are also included in the analysis: Brazil, Korea, and Mexico. Data coverage for each country begins in 1968 and ends anywhere between 1983 and 1992.

As equations (7) and (8) highlight, estimation of the intertemporal and intratemporal elasticities of substitution requires data on household consumption of traded and nontraded goods, the terms of trade, and permanent income or wealth. While time series on the terms of trade are readily available, consumption data are generally not disaggregated into traded and nontraded goods and estimates of wealth are scarce. With regard to the disaggregation of consumption, the methodology applied is described in detail in Ostry and Reinhart (1992). Basically, we assume that the nontraded goods sector of the economy consists of public and private services while traded goods production emanates from the agriculture, mining and industrial sectors. Consumption of importables can then be constructed using the supply–side data and data on exports and imports of consumer goods. Consumption of nontraded goods are calculated residually as total private consumption less consumption of importables. The relevant price deflators for the consumption of traded and nontraded goods are price indices for imports and services, respectively. Deposit rates of interest were used when available and, in the absence of these, a money market rate was employed. Finally, as a proxy for permanent income, an average of real income per equivalent adult for the period 1980–87 was used. 1/

2. Empirical methodology and estimation results

In this subsection, we apply Cooley and Ogaki’s (1991) two–step procedure to obtain estimates for the intratemporal elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded goods and for the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. A similar procedure, which was applied independently by Ostry and Reinhart (1992), uses a cointegration approach to obtain first–stage estimates of the intratemporal parameter and Hansen and Singleton’s (1982) Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) approach to obtain (second–step) estimates of the intertemporal parameters.

a. The first step: estimating the intratemporal elasticity of substitution

Many economic time series can be modelled as being difference stationary with drift. Under such conditions, the notions of stochastic and deterministic cointegration are useful in examining the interaction between two or more variables of interest. 2/ Suppose that the components of a vector series X(t) are I(1) processes with drift; if a linear combination of X(t), say λX(t), is trend stationary, the components of X(t) are said to be (stochastically) cointegrated with a cointegrating vector λ. Consider an additional restriction that the cointegrating vector eliminates the deterministic trends as well as the stochastic trends, so that λ’X(t) is stationary. This restriction is called the deterministic cointegration restriction.

Standard unit root tests suggest that it is reasonable to model the relative price of traded and nontraded goods and the consumption ratio (of nontraded to traded goods) as I(1) processes. 3/ We now focus on the relationship among these two variables. The intratemporal first order condition (equation 6) implies that the log of the relative price and the log of the consumption ratio are cointegrated with the deterministic cointegration restriction.1/ If cointegration obtains, we can recover a consistent estimate of the intratemporal elasticity of substitution, ϵ. 2/ To test for cointegration, we employ Park’s (1992) Canonical Cointegrating Regression (CCR) procedure.3/

There are several advantages associated with CCR. First, the estimated parameters, a and ϵ in this case, are not only consistent (as is OLS), but also asymptotically efficient and median unbiased. Second, unlike OLS, the asymptotic distributions of CCR estimators are nuisance–parameter free and normal conditioned on the regressors. This latter feature allows for the usual interpretation of the standard errors and therefore for hypothesis testing. Third, as Monte Carlo experiments show (see Park and Ogaki (1991)), CCR estimators have better small sample properties than Johansen’s estimators. This latter feature makes CCR particularly attractive for the present application, where the data are annual and the sample size is limited.

Rearranging terms, taking logs, and introducing a disturbance term (to allow, for example, for measurement error) equation (6) becomes;

ln(nt/mt)=ϵln(a)+ϵln(pt/qt)+ut(9)

Equation (9) is likely to suffer from simultaneity bias, since relative prices are determined endogenously, and the error term may be serially correlated. 4/ To correct for the potential presence of such nuisance parameters, long–run covariances are estimated and used to transform the data. As shown in Park (1992), the transformed data will be cointegrated with the same parameter vector as the original data.

Under the null of cointegration, an important property of the CCR procedure is that linear restrictions can be tested by X2 tests. 5/ These X2 tests are used in a regression with spurious deterministic trends added to test for deterministic and stochastic cointegration. For this purpose, the CCR procedure is applied to a regression

ln(nt/mt)=ϵln(a)+Σi=1qniti+ϵln(pt/qt)+ut(10)

Let H(p,q) denote the standard Wald statistic to test the hypothesis ηp+1p+2=…ηq=0, where the variance of ut has been replaced with elements or the long run covariance matrix (see Park (1990)). Under the null of cointegration H(p,q) converges to a xqp2. In particular, the H(0,1) statistic tests the deterministic cointegrating restriction, which is suggested by the intratemporal first order condition. On the other hand, the H(l,q) tests for stochastic cointegration.

Table 3 reports the CCR results. 1/ As shown in column (1), with the exception of Korea, the intratemporal elasticity of substitution, ϵ, is estimated to be positive, consistent with our theoretical priors. In the case of Korea, where the estimate of ϵ is significantly negative, the H(0,1) test statistic presented in column (2) also rejects the specification, implied by the model at the 0.1 percent level. It is possible that the assumption of homothetic preferences implied by the CES utility function is causing problems in this case. 2/ For the remaining countries, the point estimates for ϵ range from a low of 0.38 to a high of 2.16; for eight of the 13 countries the intratemporal elasticity of substitution exceeds unity, implying gross substitutability between traded and nontraded goods. For the Philippines, the point estimate of ϵ is positive but is not significantly so, and the H(0,1) test is significant at the 1 percent level, implying that the null of deterministic cointegration is rejected; however, the null of stochastic cointegration cannot be rejected (columns (3) and (4)) at standard significance levels. For the other countries, none of the H(0,1) test statistics are significant at the 1 percent level and only a few of them are significant at the 5 percent level, indicating that the null hypothesis of deterministic cointegration cannot be rejected.

Table 3.

Canonical Cointegrating Regression Results

article image
Note: Park and Ogaki’s (1991) method with Andrew’s (1991) automatic bandwidth parameter estimator was used to estimate long–run correlation.

To summarize, we find evidence that the CES specification of preferences is not rejected by the data for all the sample countries except Korea, and, possibly, the Philippines. On this basis, we proceed with this specification when estimating the intertemporal elasticity of substitution.

b. The second step: estimating the intertemporal parameters

In the first step, consistent estimates of the intratemporal parameters were obtained via a cointegration regression. In the second step, we impose the country–specific estimated values of e and a and apply GMM to the Euler equation defined by (7) in order to obtain estimates of the intertemporal parameters. This two–step procedure does not alter the asymptotic distribution of the GMM estimators or test statistics because our cointegrating regression estimator is super–consistent and converges at a rate faster than T1/2.

As discussed previously, we assume that the intertemporal elasticity of substitution of country i satisfies the Stone–Geary condition given in equation (8), reproduced below,

σi=σ(1γyip)(11)

where yip is a measure of permanent income of country i, and γ is a constant that reflects the subsistence level. In the GMM estimation, we fix γ and estimate a. Since it is difficult to assess the real dollar value of the subsistence basket (i.e., γ), we allow γ to vary across a fairly broad range of values. Its minimum level of 100 is slightly below the value of US$123 (1985 prices) found for India by Atkeson and Ogaki (1992) and its upper level of 400 was determined by the income level of the poorest countries since, for (9) to make sense, it must be that (1γ/yip)0. In any case, the sensitivity of the results with respect to the choice of γ is reported.

We apply GMM to the Euler equation defined by (7) in a panel data set of countries, imposing (11) as a cross–country restriction. 1/ For each country, a and ϵ are set at the values obtained in the first step cointegrating regression for that country. We restrict the discount factor, β, to be the same across countries in order to obtain more precise estimates of σ, which is the main parameter governing the responsiveness of saving to changes in the real rate of interest. Hence, in the second step, we estimate two parameters, σ and β. Because the sample size is not the same for all countries, we use the panel data estimation method described in Ogaki (1993d). Since there are many moment restrictions from many countries, we only use constants as instruments and avoid the use of lagged variables as instruments. Because lagged instrumental variables are not used, our method is robust to the time aggregation problem.

Table 4 presents the second–step GMM results. We report results for twelve of the developing countries in our sample (all except Korea) for different values of γ. The panel excludes Korea because the CES specification is rejected by the data in this case. Our point estimates of σ are positive and significant while the point estimates of β are larger than one. Hansen’s J test statistics do not reject the overidentifying restrictions implied by the model at conventional levels. An attractive feature of the results is that they are not very sensitive to the choice of γ for the broad range used.

Table 4.

The Intertemporal Parameters: Generalized Method of Moments Results

article image
Notes: In columns 2 and 3, the standard errors are in parentheses. Column 4 reports Hansen’s J test and the corresponding asymptotic P–values are given in parentheses. The last column gives the degrees of freedom for Hansen’s J statistic.

We recover the country–specific value of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, σi, by employing the Stone–Geary specification given in equation (11). Chart 1 plots, for the sample countries, the intertemporal elasticity of substitution against the ratio of the country’s permanent income to U.S. income, for the case of γ=400. It can be seen that the intertemporal elasticity of substitution rises markedly with the level of income when low—to middle–income countries are compared; the change from middle– to high–income levels makes less of a difference. The nonlinearities that were evident in the relationship between the saving rate and income are also present here.

Chart 1.
Chart 1.

The Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution

The Sample Countries

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1995, 003; 10.5089/9781451841848.001.A001

Notes: The point estimates for the intertemporal elasticity of substitution and the the income level and as a share of U.S. income are taken from columns (4) and (2), respectively from Table 5.
Table 5.

The Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution:

Low– and Lower Middle–Income Countries

article image

Average for 1980–85.

Average for 1980–86.

Notes: The lower\upper bounds are constructed by subtracting\adding one standard error to the point estimate.An * denotes that the country was included in the sample.
Table 5 (cont.).

The Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution:

Upper Middle– and High–Income Countries

article image

Average for 1980–85.

Average for 1980–86.

Notes: The lower\upper bounds are constructed by subtracting\adding one standard error to the point estimate.An * denotes that the country was included in the sample.

To examine the implications of our results for a broader set of countries, we employ the estimated value of σ and measure permanent income as for the “within–sample” countries. In the fourth column of Table 5, we provide the estimate of each country’s σi for the case where γ=400. In addition, we report (in columns (3) and (5)) the range of values that result from adding and subtracting one standard error from the point estimate. As Table 5 makes clear, the range of variation of σi is wide, from a low value of about 0.05 for Uganda and Ethiopia, the poorest countries in our sample, to a high of about 0.64 for the United States and several of the other high–income countries. These estimates are in line with several earlier studies: Atkeson and Ogaki (1992), who examine Indian panel data; Ostry and Reinhart (1992) who focus on regional patterns; and Reinhart and Végh (1994), who apply a monetary model to several chronic inflation countries. The implications for saving behavior of these cross–country differences are taken up in the next section.

V. Saving and the Rate of Interest

Having estimated the key parameters that characterize household consumption and saving behavior, we now turn to the implications of our estimates for the interaction between saving and the real rate of return. As noted earlier, the attempt to encourage saving by raising real interest rates is at the heart of adjustment programs in a number of low– and middle–income developing countries. Higher saving, it is argued, can finance higher investment and lead to faster growth. In addition, the external current account effects of fiscal policy changes which alter domestic interest rates will be sensitive to the elasticity of private saving with respect to changes in the rate of return. To examine the interactions between interest rates, saving, investment and growth, it is necessary to have some model in which these variables are determined endogenously. Rebelo’s (1991) endogenous growth model is particularly well–suited to the issue at hand because it allows us to calculate the effects of different values of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution on saving rates very easily.

1. A simple model of endogenous growth

Since the aim is illustrative, we make a series of simplifying assumptions and focus on a linearized, continuous–time version of Rebelo’s (1991) model also used by Barro (1990). The reader is referred to these papers for further details.

The household problem is outlined in equations (1)–(7), except that now we focus on a continuous time version of the model and assume that the technology is such that the traded good can be transformed into the nontraded good at a constant rate, so that the equilibrium relative price of these goods is constant. 1/ Hence, total consumption is given by,

ct=mt+nt(12)

Production takes place under a linear technology and employs a single type of capital good which is a composite of physical and human capital,

yt=Azt(13)

where A represents the technology level and yt (zt) is output (capital). The linear technology, which is a common feature of a class of endogenous growth models (see Romer (1989)), ensures that the rate of return to capital does not decline as the capital stock increases. Finally, output is either consumed or used for capital accumulation, viz.:

yt=ct+z˙t(14)

Production efficiency equates the marginal product of capital to the rate of return:

A=1+r(15)

where r is the real rate of interest.

The standard equations of motion for consumption and the accumulation of capital that arise from the optimization problem are given by:

c˙tct=σi(rδ)(16)
z˙tzt=σi(rδ)(17)

where δ > 0 represents the constant rate of time preference and a- is, as before, the intertemporal elasticity of substitution for country i. 1/ Hence, in this economy all real variables grow at the same constant rate.

Saving is defined as:

St=ytct=σi(rδ)zt(18)

and the saving rate, st, is given by:

st=σi[1(1+δ)(1+r)](19)

To determine the response of the saving rate to changes in the real rate of interest, we differentiate (19) with respect to r and obtain:

sr=σi1+δ(1+r)2(20)

Equation (20) highlights the key role that the intertemporal elasticity of substitution plays in determining how saving rates react to changes in real interest rates. 2/ Specifically, as σi approaches zero, saving declines, growth declines, and saving ceases to respond to real interest rates altogether. In the remainder of this section, the estimated parameters are used to calculate, under the assumption that these economies share a common technology and thus face a common interest rate, the response of saving to real interest rate changes for a broad spectrum of countries with very different income levels.

2. Results

Using equation (20), the point estimates of σi reported in Table 5, and a variety of plausible values for the real rate of interest and the subjective discount factor, we can calculate the implied response of saving to changes in the real rate of interest under various scenarios.

There are several features of the results presented in Table 6 that are worth noting. First, as implied by this simple analytical framework, the intertemporal elasticity of substitution plays a central role in determining how much (or how little) saving rates respond to changes in the real rate of interest. Indeed, the saving elasticities presented in Table 6 closely resemble the σi reported earlier (Table 5). Second, it follows from the previous observation that the cross–country variation is wide. For the poorest countries, a one percentage point rise in the real rate of interest should elicit a rise in the saving rate of only about one–tenth of one percentage point; 1/ for the wealthiest countries, the rise in the saving rate in response to a similar change in the real interest rate is about two thirds of a percentage point. 2/ Third, as columns (2) and (3) of Table 6 highlight, the saving elasticity is not very sensitive to the level of the real rate of interest assumed nor to the subjective discount factor (columns (4) and (5)).

Table 6.

The Interest Sensitivity of Saving:

Low– and Lower Middle–Income Countries

article image
Table 6 (cont).

The Interest Sensitivity of Saving:

Upper Middle– and High–Income Countries

article image

As noted earlier, this simple framework also suggests that for the poorer countries (where σi is lower), the saving rate will be lower (equation (19)) and, since output grows at the same rate as the capital stock (equation (17)), growth will also be lower for the poorer countries in the sample.

VI. Conclusions

This paper has sought to investigate the effect exerted by the level of development on saving behavior in developing countries. The main issue with which we were concerned related to the responsiveness of saving to interest rate changes, and whether there were any economically significant behavioral differences within a sample of countries at different stages of development. This issue was argued to be of relevance to policymakers because the investment and growth effects of, for example, financial liberalization, will depend on how responsive consumption/saving is to changes in real rates of return. Other policy questions–for example, the relationship between government deficits and the current account–will also depend on the responsiveness of private saving to real interest rates to the extent that changes in public (dis)saving alter domestic rates of return.

The main conclusion that emerged from our analysis was that much of the considerable cross–country variation in both the level of saving and the responsiveness of saving to the real rate of interest could be systematically explained by the country’s income level. Specifically, the hypothesis that the saving rate and its sensitivity to interest rate changes were a rising function of income found strong empirical support. There is, of course, an often wide variation in saving behavior across countries with similar income levels that remains unaccounted for by the simple framework presented here. With these limitations in mind, however, our results may help explain why the rising real interest rates that typically accompany financial liberalization have often failed to elicit an appreciable rise in private saving. They may also shed some light on the wide cross–country variation in the response of the current account to fiscal policy changes which alter domestic interest rates.

The results presented here suggest that higher saving rates may not be forthcoming, even with relatively large increases in real interest rates, if the country in question is at the lower end of the income spectrum. In addition, the simple endogenous growth model presented in Section V suggested that the growth effects of higher interest rates would also tend to be relatively small for relatively poor countries.

Financial liberalization may also be associated with costs, particularly if regulation and supervision of the financial sector are weak or nonexistent. Distortions such as implicit deposit insurance and moral hazard could give rise to serious difficulties or even crises in the banking sector. Typically, these problems also have large fiscal implications. Hence, a more general message from the analysis in this paper would be that the tradeoff between costs and benefits may vary considerably across countries and would appear to be steeper for countries with lower income.

References

  • Aghevli, Bijan, James M. Boughton, Peter J. Montiel, Delano Villanueva, and Geoffrey Woglom, The Role of National Saving in the World Economy, IMF Occasional Paper No. 67, (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andrews, Donald K., “Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation,” Econometrica, Vol. 59, (1991), pp. 81758.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andrews, Donald K., and J. Cristopher Monahan, “An Improved Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator,” Econometrica, Vol. 60, (1992), pp. 95366.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Atkeson, Andrew, and Masao Ogaki, “Wealth–Varying Intertemporal Elasticities of Substitution: Evidence from Panel and Aggregate Data,” mimeo, (1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, “Financial Deregulation and Household Saving,” Economic Journal, Vol. 103, (1993), pp. 143243.

  • Calvo, Guillermo A., “On the Costs of Temporary Policy,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 27 (October 1987), pp. 24561.

  • Calvo, Guillermo A., “Costly Trade Liberalizations: Durable Goods and Capital Mobility,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 35 (September 1988), pp. 46173.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., “Incredible Reforms,” in Debt. Stabilization and Development, ed. by Guillermo A. Calvo and others (Oxford; New York: Blackwell, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Campbell, John Y., and Pierre Perron, “Pitfalls and Opportunities: What Macroeconomists Should Know About Unit Roots NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1991, (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1991), pp. 141200.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cooley, Thomas F. and Masao Ogaki, “A Time Series Analysis of Real Wages, Consumption, and Asset Returns under Optimal Labor Contracting: A Cointegration-Euler Equation Approach,” Rochester Center for Economic Research Working Paper No. 285, (1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deaton, Angus, “Saving in Developing Countries: Theory and Review,” in Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1989, (Washington: World Bank, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Melo, Jaime, and James Tybout, “The Effects of Financial Liberalization on Savings and Investment in Uruguay,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, (1986), pp. 56187.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Easterly, William, “Economic Stagnation, Fixed Factors, and Policy Thresholds,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 33, (1994), pp. 52557.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, and Jonathan D. Ostry, “Anticipated Protectionist Policies, Real Exchange Rates and the Current Account,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 9, (1990), pp. 20619.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frenkel, Jacob A. and Assaf Razin, Fiscal Policies and the World Economy: An Intertemporal Approach, Second Edition, MIT Press, (1992).

  • Galbis, Vicente, “High Real Interest Rates Under Financial Liberalization: Is There A Problem?,” IMF Working Paper WP/93/7, (1993).

  • Ghosh, Atish R., and Jonathan D. Ostry, “Export Instability and the External Balance in Developing Countries,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 41, (1994), pp. 21435.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giovannini, Alberto, “Saving and the Rate of Interest in LDCs,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 18, (1985), pp. 197217.

  • Gupta, Kanhaya L., “Aggregate Savings, Financial Intermediation, and Interest Rate, Review of Economics and Statistics, (1987), pp. 30311.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hall, Robert E., “Stochastic Implications of the Life Cycle-Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 86, (1978), pp. 97187.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hansen, Bruce, “Efficient Estimation and Testing of Cointegrating Vectors in the Presence of Deterministic Trends, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 53, (1992), pp. 87121.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hansen, Lars P., and Kenneth J. Singleton, “Generalized Instrumental Variable Estimation of Nonlinear Rational Expectations Models,” Econometrica, Vol. 50, (1982), pp. 126986.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haque, Nadeem U., and Peter. J. Montiel, “Consumption in Developing Countries: Tests for Liquidity Constraints and Finite Horizons,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 71 (1989), pp. 40815.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald I., Money and Capital in Economic Development, (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1973).

  • Mitchell, Donald O., and Merlinda D. Ingco, The World Food Outlook, (Washington: The World Bank, 1993)

  • Ogaki, Masao, “Unit Roots in Macroeconometrics: A Survey,” Monetary Economic Studies, 11, (1993a), pp. 13154.

  • Ogaki, Masao, “CCR: A User’s Guide,” Rochester Center for Economic Research Working Paper No. 349, (1993b).

  • Ogaki, Masao, “GMM: A User’s Guide,” Rochester Center for Economic Research Working Paper No. 348, University of Rochester, (1993c).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ogaki, Masao, “Generalized Method of Moments: Econometric Applications,” in Handbook of Statistics, Vol. 11: Econometrics, ed. by G.S. Maddala, C. R. Rao, and H.D. Vinod, (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1993d), pp. 45588.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ogaki, Masao, and Joon Y. Park, “A Cointegration Approach to Estimating Preference Parameters,” Rochester Center for Economic Research Working Paper No. 209, (1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ogaki, Masao, and Carmen M. Reinhart, “Measuring Intertemporal Substitution: The Role of Durable Goods,” mimeo, (1994).

  • Ostry, Jonathan D., “The Balance of Trade, Terms of Trade, and Real Exchange Rate: An Intertemporal Optimizing Framework,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 35, (1988), pp. 54173.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., “Tariffs, Real Exchange Rates, and the Trade Balance in a Two–Country World,” European Economic Review, Vol. 35, (1991a), pp. 112742.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., “Trade Liberalization in Developing Countries,” Staff Papers, Vol. 38, (1991b), pp. 44779.

  • Ostry, Jonathan D., “Government Purchases and Relative Prices in a Two-Country World,” Economic Record, Vol. 70, (1994), pp. 14961.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., and Joaquim Levy, “Household Saving in France: Stochastic Income and Financial Deregulation,” IMF Working Paper, WP/94/141, (1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., and Carmen M. Reinhart, “Private Saving and Terms of Trade Shocks: Evidence from Developing Countries,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 39, (1992), pp. 495517.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., and Andrew K. Rose, “An Empirical Evaluation of the Macroeconomic Effects of Tariffs,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 11, (1992), pp. 6379.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Park, Joon Y., “Testing for Unit Roots and Cointegration by Variable Addition,” Advances in Econometrics, Vol. 8, (1990), pp. 10733.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Park, Joon Y., “Canonical Cointegrating Regressions,” Econometrica, Vol. 60, (1992), pp. 11943.

  • Park, Joon Y., and Masao Ogaki, “Inference in Cointegrated Models Using VAR Prewhitening to Estimate Short-run Dynamics,” Rochester Center for Economic Research Working Paper No. 281, (1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Putnam, Judith Jones, and Jane A. Allshouse, Food Consumption. Prices and Expenditures, 1970-1992, Statistical Bulletin No. 867, United States Department of Agriculture.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Razin, Assaf, and Lars Svensson, “Trade Taxes and the Current Account,” Economics Letters, Vol. 13, (1983), pp. 5557.

  • Rebelo, Sergio, “Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy, 99, (1991), pp. 50021.

  • Rebelo, Sergio, “Growth in Open Economies,” Carnegie—Rochester Series on Public Policy, 36, (1992), pp. 546.

  • Reinhart, Carmen M. and Carlos A. Végh, “Intertemporal Consumption Substitution and Inflation Stabilization: An Empirical Investigation,” mimeo, (1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Romer, Paul M., “Capital Accumulation in the Theory of Long-Run Growth,” in Modern Business Cycle Theory, ed. by Robert J. Barro, (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1989), pp. 51127.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rossi, Nicola, “Government Spending, the Real Interest Rate and the Behavior of Liquidity Constrained Consumers in Developing Countries,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 35, (1988), pp. 10440.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sarel, Michael, “On the Dynamics of Economic Growth,” mimeo, (1994).

  • Savastano, Miguel, “Private Saving in Fund Programs,” (Unpublished manuscript, IMF (1994)).

  • Schmidt–Hebbel, Klaus, Steven B. Webb, and Giancarlo Corsetti, “Household Saving in Developing Countries: First Cross—Country Evidence,” The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 6, (1992), pp. 52947.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shaw, Edward, Financial Deepening in Economic Development, (New York: Oxford University Press, 1973).

  • Svensson, Lars and Assaf Razin, “The Terms of Trade and the Current Account: The Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Effect,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91, (1983), pp. 97125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Vaidyanathan, Geetha, “Consumption, Liquidity Constraints and Economic Development,” Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 15, (1993), pp. 591610.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Van Wijnbergen, Sweder, “Interest Rate Management in LDCs,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12, (1983), pp. 43352.

  • West, Kenneth D., “Asymptotic Normality When Regressors Have a Unit Root,” Econometrica, Vol. 56, (1988), pp. 13971417.

  • World Bank, The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy, World Bank Policy Research Report, (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, Results, and the Road Ahead, World Bank Policy Research Report, (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994a).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, World Development Report 1994: Infrastructure for Development, World Development Indicators, (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994b).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1/

Ogaki: Department of Economics, Ohio State University; Ostry and Reinhart: Research Department, International Monetary Fund. Any views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the institutions with which they are affiliated. The authors wish to thank seminar participants at the IMF and Ohio State University, as well as Sergio Rebelo, Michael Sarel, Miguel Savastano, and Peter Wickham for helpful comments and suggestions, and Jared Romey for excellent research assistance.

1/

For a view running contrary to the McKinnon-Shaw hypothesis, see Buffie (1982) and van Wijnbergen (1983). For an analysis of the Uruguayan experience with financial liberalization, see de Melo and Tybout (1986).

2/

Ostry and Reinhart (1992) attributed these differences to the presence of more binding liquidity constraints in Africa and Latin America than in Asia. Using a reduced form approach, similar regional differences in the interest-rate sensitivity of saving were found by Gupta (1987).

1/

For models that stress the role played by subsistence considerations in consumption/saving decisions, see Rebelo (1992) and