Albania
Income Distribution, Poverty, and Social Safety Nets in the Transition, 1991-1993

This paper examines developments in Albania’s income distribution and poverty during the transition to a market-oriented economy. It pays particular attention to the impact of price liberalization on the agricultural terms of trade and production, the decline in state enterprise employment, emigrant remittances, and social safety nets. Income and consumption data produce conflicting results. Based on income data, including average presumptive agricultural incomes and state sector wages, there is a significant rise in real income in rural areas and a decline in real income in urban areas. Based on food consumption data, however, a large decline in urban real incomes is implausible. Poverty in both the urban and the rural population was mitigated by the presence of formal social safety nets, as well as informal arrangements in the form of emigrant remittances.

Abstract

This paper examines developments in Albania’s income distribution and poverty during the transition to a market-oriented economy. It pays particular attention to the impact of price liberalization on the agricultural terms of trade and production, the decline in state enterprise employment, emigrant remittances, and social safety nets. Income and consumption data produce conflicting results. Based on income data, including average presumptive agricultural incomes and state sector wages, there is a significant rise in real income in rural areas and a decline in real income in urban areas. Based on food consumption data, however, a large decline in urban real incomes is implausible. Poverty in both the urban and the rural population was mitigated by the presence of formal social safety nets, as well as informal arrangements in the form of emigrant remittances.

I. Introduction

The dislocation from the collapse of central planning and the restructuring of the state enterprise sector have led to a large decline in output and employment in Albania, as in other transition economies. At the same time, the Albanian Government, which faced severe supply shortages and annual budgetary deficits, progressively liberalized most consumer prices while raising the remaining administered prices to market-clearing levels. The Government also introduced a system of unemployment benefits and put in place compensating income transfers for price increases in order to protect low-income groups. This paper investigates the impact of these developments and policies on rural/urban income distribution and poverty. The main sources of data are cash income and emigrant remittances. As a check on the results, developments in the per capita consumption of food items are examined.

Income data reveal three main trends. First, there was a substantial shift in income distribution in favor of the agricultural sector. The ratio of average presumptive agricultural cash income to public sector income increased from ½ to 1 between 1991 and 1993. Second, real incomes in the rural sector increased by about 50 percent during this period. 1/ Real incomes in the urban sector (including government transfers and emigrant remittances) declined by about 12 percent between the first half of 1991 and the second half of 1993, and the share of the urban population (including pensioners) with incomes below subsistence levels increased from 6 to 25–30 percent. 2/ Based on annual data, real incomes in the urban sector declined by about 30 percent between 1991 and 1993, but this larger decline could reflect problems with the data for 1991 (see below). These developments reflect the mitigating impact of emigrant remittances and social safety nets (unemployment benefits, ad hoc indexation of pensions, social assistance, and transfers to low-income groups to compensate for price liberalization), without which poverty in urban areas would have encompassed the majority of the urban population. Poverty is difficult to measure in rural areas, but the introduction of a new law for social assistance in mid-1993 was aimed at eliminating rural poverty through the introduction of income supplements to all qualified applicants.

These results should be interpreted with caution because of several limitations of the data. First, for comparison with non-agricultural income, presumptive income in agriculture is estimated by assuming cash farming, notwithstanding the fact that a sizeable proportion of agriculture is for self-consumption (farmers’ consumption of their own production). Second, comparison with the period before price liberalization is inherently difficult because, owing to widespread rationing, cash income is not a good measure of purchasing power for the period before liberalization. This problem is particularly acute for the first half of 1991 (and by implication, for the full year), because large temporary wage and benefit increases in mid-1991 in the face of declining production, led to unusually high excess demand, rationing, and monetary overhang, so that income data overstate true purchasing power. The presence of rationing also poses a problem for the first half of 1991 data, but to a smaller degree. Third, even for the nonagricultural sector, the income data used are not always precise. Income distribution data cannot be compiled for certain population groups—unemployed, pensioners, military personnel, for whom only average incomes are available—and there is also uncertainty regarding the size of emigrant remittances. At the same time, there is no information at all on support (in-kind or other) from family members within the country, nor is the degree to which urban dwellers have the opportunity to grow their own food known. 3/

Because of these data limitations, the results are checked against developments in per capita food consumption estimated on the basis of production and net imports of selected items. Estimated per capita food consumption increased by 28 percent between 1991 and 1993, implying—assuming unit income elasticity for food consumption—an increase of 12 percent in per capita urban food consumption, as well as a similar increase in real urban income. This finding is difficult to reconcile with a decline in real income in urban areas estimated at 30 percent between 1991 and 1993 and suggests caution in interpreting the income analysis.

The income data can be partially redeemed by purging the impact of large wage and benefit increases in mid-1991 which led to rationing in 1991. Between the first half of 1991, i.e., before the large wage and benefit increases, and the second half of 1993, real urban income declined by 12 percent, a finding which is somewhat more in line with urban consumption data.

Notwithstanding general data problems, available data suggest strongly that there is large inequality among households depending on whether they have access to foreign remittances. A policy implication is that targeted poverty alleviation measures will be more effective than universal benefits, which would be appropriate if poverty was more widely distributed.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section II provides background information on price and output developments. Section III describes the methodology employed in the paper and section IV provides qualifications. Section V describes real income developments by sector and provides estimates of poverty. Section VI analyses developments in food consumption. Section VII describes and partially assesses the efficiency of the social safety nets. Section VIII provides conclusions.

II. Price and Output Developments

By end-1993, price reform that had begun in mid-1990 was almost complete, with virtually no remaining price controls or consumer subsidies. The earliest steps, taken in mid-1990, included autonomy in the pricing of non-essential industrial goods and the tolerance of parallel markets for private agricultural produce. Further liberalization of prices followed, beginning with the early liberalization of industrial goods and vegetable prices at end-1991, dairy products in August 1992, and rice and sunflower prices in January 1993. 4/ Currently, among food items, only the prices of wheat and sugarbeet remain under control, and these are priced at or near world market levels. While still controlled, the official price of bread was raised by 370 percent in August 1992 and doubled in July 1993, parallel with increases in the producer price of wheat, to avoid the emergence of budgetary subsidies. Among nonfood items, the prices of heating products, medicines, textbooks, and public utilities remain controlled.

Price reform thus far has resulted in an improvement in the terms of trade of agriculture. Based on year-on-year averages, agricultural producer prices increased by about 440 percent between 1990 and 1992, compared with an increase of only 300 percent in the nonfood CPI (and 340 percent in the CPI, which is the relevant measure in the case of complete reliance on markets for food consumption) (Table 1). The improvement in the terms of trade was partially reversed in 1993, with estimated growth in producer prices of 50 percent and in the non-food CPI of 80 percent.

Table 1.

Price Indices

(1990 = 100)

article image
Sources: Ministry of Agriculture, Ministry of Finance, and Department of Statistics

Real GDP recovered partially during 1993, after a drastic decline from 1990 to mid-1992, with agriculture taking the lead in the recovery. Agricultural output fell by 30 percent between 1989 and 1991 because of the breakdown of public distribution channels for agricultural inputs and outputs, the chaotic process of privatization (agricultural cooperatives were dismantled spontaneously in the second quarter of 1991), and a shortage of foreign exchange for critical inputs. Agricultural output recovered in 1992 and 1993 by a cumulative 32 percent, as these factors worked themselves out and the agricultural terms of trade improved. Nonagricultural output fell by almost 50 percent between 1989 and 1992 and increased by about 10 percent in 1993. Correspondingly, unemployment increased from 130,000 (8 percent of the labor force) in 1990 to about 400,000 (23 percent of the labor force) in 1993, with the increase occurring almost entirely in urban areas. 5/

Developments in nominal nonagricultural income were largely within the control of government policy, since the Government set wages in budgetary institutions, transfer incomes, and wage ceilings for state enterprises; the only exception was the private sector. 6/ The Government pursued an incomes policy as part of its stabilization measures and introduced compensatory income transfers in connection with the August 1992 and August 1993 agricultural price liberalization (see Section VII). In August 1992, workers in state enterprises and in budgetary institutions, the unemployed receiving unemployment benefits, the urban pensioners, and those on social assistance in cities received lek 280 per month, and an additional lek 200 per dependent, while low-income agricultural families received 100 lek per person. Rural pensioners were excluded, on account of low compliance with the requirement for social security contributions. 7/ In August 1993, compensation was 214 lek per person, again excluding rural pensioners. Table 2 shows the number of people covered by social safety nets. Table 3 provides information on benefit levels.

Table 2.

Population and Coverage of Social Safety Nets, 1991–93

(In thousands of persons)

article image
Sources: Ministry of Labor, Ministry of Finance, Ministry of Agriculture, Institute of Social Security, Department of Statistics, and author’s estimates.

Includes urban and rural recipients of unemployment insurance, social assistance, and pensions. Price compensation for employees is not included. Includes some double-counting in 1993: B2 when pensioners became eligible for social assistance.

Includes some stats sector workers/unemployed in rural areas.

Unemployment in the fleet half of 1992 refers to 80 percent payments to “idle workers.” Reported employment is net of “idle workers.”

Includes pensioners from state farms.

Includes recipients of social assistance in rural areas.

Total of the above after removal of rural social assistance which is counted twice.

Obtained as a residual and reflects (1) classification of rural state sector employees and unemployed and state farm pensioners under both ex-cooperatives in rural areas and under employed workers/unemployed from urban areas; (2) persons holding two Jobs; end (3) persons with a job and receiving assistance.

Excludes double counting.

Includes half of migration and private sector employment.

Number receiving benefits divided by number receiving benefits plus employed workers (excluding private sector workers).

Table 3.

wages and Benefit Levels under Social Safety Nets, 1992–93

(Lek per month)

article image
Sources: Ministry of Labor; Ministry of Finance and Economy; Institute of Social Security; and Fund staff estimates.

Includes some workers/recipients from rural areas (see Table 2).

Price compensation on July 1 and basic increase on August 1.

Military personnel was paid the first price compensation out of Ministry of Defense reserve funds.

Eighty percent wage payments to idle workers from July 1991–July 1992, when unemployment benefits were introduced.

Flat unemployment payments were introduced in October 1993, and the pension system reformed (maximum pensions were raised to two times minimum pensions, or 75 percent of the previous wage; 1 percent increment above the minimum for each year of insurance).

For families without outside income. Amounts are reduced in line with the outside income.

Rural wheat price compensation (August–October 1992 and after July 1993) is included; avarage amounts.

See Table 9.

See Table 10.

Under the new Social Assistance Law, social assistance is a fraction of two times the flat unemployment benefit. varying from 70 percent for a two-person family to 92 percent for a 7 person family.

III. Methodology

This section outlines the main methodological issues surrounding the measurement of nominal and real incomes and poverty in Albania. Appendices IIII provide more details.

1. Nominal incomes

a. Agriculture

Income data are not available for the agricultural sector. The approach taken here is to estimate presumptive income—the market value of the full agricultural output net of costs—on the basis of acreage and livestock per household (the latter constitutes half of agricultural production) (Appendix I). These incomes are suitable for comparison with urban incomes as long as farmers had access to markets. To the extent they did not have access to markets, these incomes would overstate welfare, since farmers would be constrained to consume their own production rather than having the option to trade their production for a preferred bundle of goods. 8/ Based on available data, presumptive income can be calculated by district, giving an idea of dispersion of incomes across geographical regions.

b. Remittances

Emigrant remittances were an important source of income. With an estimated 300,000–400,000 emigrees (more than 10 percent of the population, or one migrant per two families) in 1993, $200 million in remittances (20 percent of 1993 GDP), and assuming that each migrant supported one family, half the families received $10 per month capita. Half the number of the poor (based on cash income) are assumed to have had access to remittances in 1993. This follows if each migrant supported one family and migrants were distributed across the poor population as they were across the population in general (i.e., one migrant per two families). If migrants supported more than one family, poverty would be less than estimated in the paper.

while there was sizeable migration as early as 1990, relocation expenses and difficulties in remitting earnings (illegal initially) meant that remittances were small until 1992, and this paper assumes that remittances were negligible in 1991.

c. Taxes

Very few people paid personal income taxes (the exemption level was very high, at leks 4,000 or about 130 percent of the average state enterprise wage in the first half of 1993), 9/ and social security contributions have thus far been exclusively paid by the employers. Agricultural workers paid neither social security nor income tax. 10/ For these reasons, taxes are not incorporated in the analysis.

2. Real incomes

Calculation of real incomes is difficult for Albania because of the importance of subsistence agriculture, and because there is no readily available price deflator which reflects the consumption pattern of (a) rural families and (b) poor urban families.

a. Rural families

When farmers market all their produce, income can be measured by presumptive cash income (defined above), and real income by presumptive cash income deflated by the rural CPI. However, when agricultural production is entirely for self-consumption—either because this solution maximizes utility or because farmers do not have easy access to markets—output is a more appropriate measure of real income. 11/ Below, both presumptive cash income and real output growth are reported. 12/ Data on the degree of self-consumption by crop and district is spotty, so that more precise quantification of real income growth is not possible. Also, the rural CPI is not available, and the urban CPI is used to deflate presumptive income.

b. Poor urban families

Because of the timing of price liberalization, the prices faced by the poor (i.e., the prices of necessities) followed a different path from the CPI. In the early period, the prices of necessities were relatively flat, while in the later period, with price liberalization, the increases in the prices of necessities outpaced the CPI. As a result, changes in the CPI overestimate the erosion in real incomes of low income groups early on, and underestimate it later on. 13/ In the long run, the deflators move similarly, as long as relative prices were in equilibrium before liberalization. The CPI faced by the poor is calculated in Appendix II. Figure 1 shows the behavior of this subsistence CPI against the urban CPI. 14/

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Developments of Prices To Date

(December 1990 = 100)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1994, 123; 10.5089/9781451854541.001.A001

3. Poverty

a. Urban areas

A poverty estimate is derived for urban areas, on the basis of an estimate of the poverty line (defined in absolute terms, as the level of income necessary to purchase basic foodstuffs 15/ (at 2,000 calories per adult and 1,600 calories per child), and a few other necessities (housing, soap, medicines, and firewood) and income distribution data where available. The poverty estimate consists of both an estimate of the number of people receiving an income below the poverty line and the gap between their incomes and the poverty line (i.e., the “depth” of poverty). The poverty line, or the subsistence income, is estimated to be the following:

The number of the poor is assessed by comparing incomes with these subsistence incomes, taking into account family size and composition. The choice of unit is the nuclear family. That is, incomes of pensioner households and worker households are each checked against corresponding subsistence incomes. The impact of extended family arrangements is considered by estimating the effect on poverty of transfers from family members (see below).

Family composition by labor market status is not known, and two scenarios are investigated for the urban active family (80 percent of the working-age population is active, with two children on average). 16/ In the first, families are homogenous, that is, in two-parent households, both are either employed, unemployed, or retired. The estimate of poverty under this assumption will approximate true poverty to the extent that unemployment is localized and as long as the difference between unemployment benefits and wages (and pensions) is not too great (both of which appear to be the case in Albania).

In the second scenario, there is random matching among unemployed and employed workers with dependents. The pensioners are excluded, and unemployed and employed workers without dependents are treated as single. In this random matching scenario, the income distribution for two worker households is obtained by approximating the wage distribution by a gamma function, a function for which the distribution of the sum of two functions is easily derived. 17/ Figure 2 shows the (approximated) wage distribution and two-worker household income distribution. 18/ 19/

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

State Sector: Approximate Wage Distribution, 1993

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1994, 123; 10.5089/9781451854541.001.A001

Income distribution data are available only for state enterprises and civil service. For recipients of transfer incomes and workers in defense and police, average incomes have to be used. Appendix III describes the method used to derive the number of poor persons from income distribution data in the public sector.

b. Rural areas

It is difficult to estimate the number of poor persons in rural areas, for two reasons. First, there are no data on land distribution. Only district average presumptive cash income and average output are available. Second, establishing a benchmark for the rural subsistence level entails caloric analysis of production by district, when production is for self-consumption. In view of these limitations, this paper does not solely rely on average presumptive cash income, but also considers the number of families receiving social assistance as an indicator of poverty.

Both nuclear and extended family arrangements are considered, but the results based on extended family arrangements are considered as more reliable, given the prevalence of such arrangements in rural Albania. In the case of nuclear families, rural pensions are compared to the urban subsistence level.

Some information can be compiled on the “depth” of poverty in rural areas. The method (developed at the Ministry of Agriculture in Albania) consists of deriving and pricing a food deficit on the basis of the average amount and productivity of land held by social assistance recipients. The method is described in greater detail in Appendix II

IV. Qualifications

This section describes some of the limitations of income data, which have led to the use of consumption data as a check on the results.

1. Impact of rationing on comparisons

Comparison with the period before price liberalization is inherently difficult because cash income is not a good measure of purchasing power for the period before liberalization, owing to widespread rationing. 20/ Price liberalization took place in 1992–93, and in the base-year for comparison (1991), there was excess demand, implying that incomes overestimated true purchasing power.

2. Exclusion of certain incomes

Little is known about private sector incomes, and they are not incorporated in the analysis. Formal private sector employment—that corresponding to registered businesses—was about 130,000 by end-1993. The average wage in this sector was $200 a month in mid-1993, or about seven times the public sector average. 21/ With a range of $50–$250 a month, very few private sector workers earned incomes below subsistence levels, and the exclusion of this sector imparts an upward bias to the share of the population in poverty reported in this paper.

Although there are no estimates of employment or of wages in the informal private sector, it is safe to say that wages in the informal sector are lower than in the formal private sector. Some of informal sector jobs are held by either recipients of unemployment benefits or by employees in the public sector as second jobs. The exclusion of this informal sector income from the measurement of incomes of the unemployed and public sector employees is thus a second reason for upward bias to the estimate of poverty.

Finally, in-kind incomes are not incorporated in the analysis. The ability of urban dwellers to grow their own food is documented to be significant in many former centrally planned economies, but data are not available for Albania.

3. use of averages

The measurement of poverty among recipients of government transfers is imprecise because data on the size distribution of pensions and unemployment benefits—which depend on work history—are not available. When average pensions or unemployment benefits fall below the subsistence income, the estimate of the number of poor persons is potentially biased upward (some recipients have incomes above the subsistence income), and the converse is true when average benefits are above subsistence levels. 22/ The same limitations apply to district averages for presumptive agricultural incomes, emigrant remittances, and incomes of workers in defense and police.

Agricultural land was not returned to the pre-World War II landowners in the south, where unequal land distribution prevailed before collectivization, but was instead divided—presumably equally—among the people working the land. In the north, land was returned to the families of the pre-World War II smallholders, implying potentially larger variance in distribution than in the south. Correspondingly, poverty could be overestimated in the north when average incomes fell below subsistence levels.

Emigrant remittances were not equally distributed across districts. The number of migrants per family was highest in the south (about one per family) and lowest in the north (about one migrant per five families). In this case, the use of averages is likely to lead to an underestimate of poverty in rural areas, because both (presumptive) agricultural incomes and remittances were low in the north.

Further, if emigrant remittances per emigrant are higher in urban areas than in rural areas because of the tendency of rural workers to obtain less highly paid and less permanent seasonal jobs, the use of averages is likely to lead to an underestimate of poverty in rural areas and an overestimate of poverty in urban areas.

V. Income and Poverty Developments

1. Income developments by sector

This section studies incomes defined narrowly. The income measures do not include informal incomes, support from families (domestically or abroad, in-kind or other), or own food production. The impact of emigrant remittances is studied in a sub-section.

a. Agricultural income excluding emigrant remittances

Based on the methods outlined above and in Appendix I, nominal incomes in the agricultural sector (measured as the market value of private agricultural value added) increased by 270 percent between 1991 and 1992 and by a further 110 percent in 1993 (Table 6). Real incomes, measured as nominal incomes deflated by the CPI, rose 29 percent between 1991 and 1993 (25 percent in 1992 and an additional 5 percent in 1993). 23/ Real output, which is the appropriate measure of real income when subsistence agriculture dominates, grew by 31 percent (13 percent in 1992 24/ and 16 percent in 1993). 25/

Table 4.

Subsistance Income in Urban Areas

(In lek per month)

article image
Source: Table 23, Appendix II.

Family with equal number of adults and dependents.

Table 5.

Cost of Gap between Subsistence Consumption and Production in Poor Rural Households 1/

(In lek per month)

article image
Source: Table 27, Appendix II.

Cost of an unchanged bundle of goods corresponding to the deficit in food production for a family with 0.25 hectare of land.

Table 6.

Income Developments in Agriculture

(1991 = 100)

article image

These increases correspond to an increase in average agricultural Income per worker from 50 percent to 100 percent of the public sector average between 1991 and 1993 (Table 7). In one third of the districts, the agricultural wage exceeded public sector incomes by 1993 (Table 8). 26/

Table 7.

Income Developments in Private Agriculture and Public Sector, 1991–93

(Annual average)

article image
Sources: Department of Prices and Wages, Ministry of Finance, and Ministry of Labor; staff estimates.

Without remittances.

1993 projection based on output increase of 6 percent for livestock, 31 percent for crops; price increase of 66 percent for livestock and 77 percent for crops; excludes social assistance benefits and pensions.

The northeast and mountain regions comprise Shkoder, Tropoje, Puke, Kukes, Has, Mirdite, Diber, Bulquize, Librazdh, Pogradoc, and Mat.

Excludes idle workers receiving 80 percent of pay. Income levels are rounded.

Table 8.

Agricultural Incomes by District, 1993

(In lek)

article image
Sources: Ministry of Agriculture and author’s estimates.

Based on assumption of two workers par family.

Excluding social assistance.

The Northeast and Mountain (NEM) region comprises Shkoder, Tropoje, Puke, Kukes, Has, Mirdite, Diber, Bulquize, librazhd, Pogradec, and Mat.

Agricultural Incomes varied widely among districts, and the ratio between the highest and the lowest district average was 3 to 1 (Table 8). Incomes in the northeastern regions of the country—the remote mountainous areas—were 75 percent of the country average for in 1993. Taking into account the fact that there were fewer migrants per family in the northeast, income disparities were larger than indicated by agricultural income alone.

b. Nonagricultural income excluding emigrant remittances

Most categories of nonagricultural income declined substantially in real terms in 1992 and in the first half of 1993, and recovered partially in the second half of 1993 (Tables 9 and 10). 27/ By the second half of 1993, average real urban incomes declined to 65 percent of first half of 1991 levels excluding emigrant remittances (see below). Rural non-agricultural incomes—pensions and social assistance payments—declined to 55 percent of first half of 1991 levels. Real public sector wages declined to 73 percent of first half of 1991 levels.

Table 9.

Income Developments in the Public Sactor, 1991–93

(Half-year averages)

article image
Sources: Department of Prices and Wages; Ministry of Finance and Economy; Ministry of Labor; and Fund staff estimates.

Including compensation for food price liberalization. Income levels are rounded.

Excludes idle workers receiving 80 percent of pay.

Table 10.

Income Developments for Units below Subsistance Levels (Using Subsistence CPI)

(In thousand of persons or index)

article image
Source: Table 31.

Includes state farm workers and state farm pensioners.

Assuming half the population receives remittances of 810 par capita.

Assuming pansioners do not receive support of extended family.

The decline in real wages was less marked for workers in defense and police than in the civil service. While initially less severe than that in budgetary institutions, the decline in real wages in state enterprises was more prolonged, extending into the first half of 1993.

Real income declines for enterprise and civil service workers in the bottom quartile of the wage distribution (based on the subsistence CPI) were slightly more severe than those experienced by average income workers between the first half of 1991 and the second half of 1993 (Tables 9 and 31).

Real incomes of urban recipients of government transfers declined to 40–60 percent of first half of 1991 levels (Table 10 and Table 31, Appendix IV). 28/ The subsistence CPI is used in these calculations, since prices faced by the poor followed a different path from the overall CPI: they were relatively flat initially, but later outpaced the CPI as the prices of necessities were liberalized (Figure 1). 29/ The declines were more moderate for the more vulnerable groups, because compensation was more important for those transfer recipients at low levels of income (i.e., for those with dependents and those with relatively low levels of benefits such as social assistance recipients).

By the second half of 1993, the value of rural pensions declined to 30 percent of first half of 1991 levels, as the collapse of social security contributions from the rural sector, after the privatization of cooperatives, led the Government not to award pension increases or price compensation. 30/ The value of rural Social assistance payments to families with little land declined to 70 percent of first half of 1991 levels.

As indicated above, these measures of income do not include informal income, support from families (domestically or abroad, in-kind or other), or own food production, and comparison with the first half of 1991 is subject to the caveat that income did not correctly measure purchasing power before price liberalization because of widespread shortages.

c. Income developments including remittances

Taking into account remittances of $10 per person for half the families in 1993, real income developments are substantially more favorable. By the second half of 1993, average urban incomes declined to 88 percent of their level in the first half of 1991 (rather than to 65 percent as in the case without remittances). Average public sector wages declined to 91 percent, and incomes for those at or below subsistence levels (including public sector workers) declined to 83 percent, of their level in the first half of 1991. Real rural pensions and rural social assistance payments increased by 15 percent on average (rather than declining).

For comparison with developments in per capita consumption (see below) it is useful to express these developments in terms of annual averages for the urban and rural sectors. In urban areas, these developments translate into a decline in real incomes of 28 percent in urban areas (13 percent in the public sector, and 36 percent for those close to subsistence levels). In rural areas, developments in agricultural income and in pensions and social assistance imply a real income increase of 47 percent (71 percent in agricultural income and -15 percent for rural pensions and social assistance). The declines using annual data exceed those using semi-annual data (above) on account of large increases in wages and benefits in the second half of 1991.

2. Poverty developments

Poverty developments cannot be estimated precisely for Albania, as there is a general lack of data on the statistical distribution of benefits and wages. Again, comparisons over time are difficult, because income was not a relevant measure of purchasing power before mid-1992 owing to the existence of shortages. Finally, for lack of data no allowance can be made for informal sector income, transfers from family members (except foreign remittances), or access to land by urban dwellers for use in growing food.

Several restrictive assumptions are maintained in view of the data limitations. First, average incomes are used when the distribution is not known. Second, urban families are assumed to be nuclear and rural families extended. Third, in the case of urban families, marriage partners are assumed to have equal labor force status (active or inactive), with two variants: homogenous (with both marriage partners either employed or unemployed), 31/ 32/ and random matching among members of the labor force. 33/ In each case, the family size is assumed to be four. These two variants can be considered the extremes within which the true family composition lies.

The section covers both the extent and the depth of poverty, and includes a discussion of the impact of transfers from family members abroad.

a. Extent of poverty

(1) Urban sector

Before remittances, and using income estimates based on the assumption of homogenous families and the estimate of the urban subsistence level (see methodology above), the number of individuals with incomes (including government transfers) below subsistence levels in the urban sector is estimated to be 950,000 people (or 56 percent of the urban population 34/) in the second half of 1993, up from 85,000 people in the first half of 1991 (Table 10). Before the second half of 1992, only those on social assistance had incomes below subsistence levels; the other groups had incomes above subsistence levels. Average incomes of the unemployed receiving benefits and urban pensioners with dependents were less than subsistence incomes, from the second half of 1992. A fraction of workers with dependents also began to receive less than subsistence Incomes from the second half of 1992. Incomes for workers in the military and police were higher than subsistence levels throughout the period.

The number of persons with Incomes below subsistence levels in the urban sector (assuming homogeneous families) fell somewhat between the first and the second half of 1993 on account of an increase in real wages for state sector employees at the bottom quartile (Table 31). 35/

Tables 11 and 12 show the wage distribution in state enterprises and in the civil service which form the basis for the calculation of the number of workers earning less than the subsistence wage. Wages were distributed relatively equally, with the ratio of the highest wage to the lowest wage equal to three in the civil service and four in state enterprises. 36/ These wage distributions imply that 50,000 workers (15 percent of state enterprise workers and 12 percent of civil service workers) earned less than subsistence levels in the second half of 1993 (half the previous semester’s peak), while all workers earned more than subsistence levels before the second half of 1992. The validity of this comparison is in doubt, however, given widespread shortages of goods prior to mid-1992.

Table 11.

Wage Distribution in State Enterprises, 1987

article image
Source: Albanian Government Enterprise Survey, 1987
Table 12.

Wage Distribution in Civil Service, February 1993

article image
Source: Ministry of Finance, Wage and Price Department.

Under the assumption of random matching, the estimate for the number of poor persons in urban areas in the second half of 1993 is 820,000 (48 percent of the urban population), which is less than the estimate under the assumption of homogenous families (950,000, see Table 10) as incomes of the unemployed receiving benefits are raised above subsistence more frequently than the incomes of the employed are lowered below subsistence through marriage to someone with a different employment status. Only forty percent of families with at least one unemployed member received less than the subsistence income in the second half of 1993 under the assumption of random matching, compared to all households under the assumption of homogeneous families. Sixty thousand workers (15 percent of two-worker families and 30 percent of the mixed unemployed-employed households) received less than the subsistence income, compared to 50,000 under the assumption of homogeneous families. Families with a member working in defense and police received more than the subsistence income (on average), irrespective of the employment status of the spouse.

Including remittances, the range of estimates for the number of persons with incomes below the subsistence level is 410,000–475,000 persons in the urban sector in the second half of 1993 (higher figures pertain to homogenous families). These estimates represent a halving of the estimates based on income excluding remittances and are based on (i) the fact that average receipts of $10 per person (total remittances divided by the number of recipients of remittances) are sufficient to bring incomes of the poor above the subsistence level; and (ii) the assumption that half of poor Albanian families have access to remittances (see above).

(2) Rural sector

Based on income data (district averages), rural sector poverty on an extended family basis (average presumptive agricultural income plus pensions and social assistance) increased from 12 percent of the private rural population in 1991 and 1992 to 27 percent (485,000 persons) in 1993 (Table 13). These are rough estimates, as data on the household income distribution are not available, and the use of district averages will lead to the classification of some poor persons as having incomes above the subsistence level in rich districts, and vice versa. The surprising increase in poverty between 1991 and 1993 reflects both declining real incomes for pensioners and social assistance recipients, and a decline in value added deflated by the subsistence CPI between 1991 and 1993, for regions depending on animal production; these regions correspond to the low-income regions of the northeast.37/ These figures are of limited relevance, however, because poor agricultural families tend to produce for their own consumption, rather than for the market. 38/ Under those circumstances, the number of families with little land together with real output developments provide a better guide to poverty developments.

Table 13.

Districts with Rural Incomes balow the Subsistence Level, 1991–93

article image
Source: Table 32.

Based on assumption of two workers per family.

Including social assistance.

Household with two members in the labor force.

Household with two members in the labor force and average number of pensioners.

Excludes state farm workers.

The number of families in the countryside with little or poor quality land is currently 40,000 (or 208,000 persons) according to the Ministry of Labor, 39/ Data on land distribution are not available country-wide, This estimate instead reflects the number of families eligible for rural social assistance under the old social assistance law when eligibility was determined by the size and quality of land-holding. A total of 35,000 families qualified under this law. 40/ The new social assistance law introduced in mid-1993 broadened eligibility—previously restricted to families in the northeast of the country—to poor farmer families across the country, raising the estimate of the number of families with little land to 40,000. While the number of families receiving assistance in the countryside is currently about 100,000 families, this reflects both aid to families without land as a result of the recent breakup of state farms (about 11,000 families) and possibly generous application of the new law which devolves administration of social assistance to the local level. 41/ This paper uses the Ministry of Labor estimate of 40,000.

Since real output increased in all districts in 1992 and 1993, the number of families producing insufficient food for subsistence must have been above 40,000 in 1991 and 1992. 42/ Since social assistance was insufficient to provide transfers to raise all incomes up to the subsistence income in the second half of 1992 and the first half of 1993, the number of families with incomes below subsistence level must also have been above 40,000 families during that period (Table 31). 43/ While social assistance was sufficient to raise all incomes up to the subsistence level in the first half of 1992, restricted eligibility under the old law meant that about 5,000 families with little land were not covered under the old system of social assistance, and that 5,000 families had incomes below the subsistence level in 1991 and the first half of 1992. Assuming that all families with insufficient land were identified, no families had incomes below the subsistence level after mid-1993 when social assistance benefits were raised substantially and eligibility extended to the entire country.

Note that the estimate of the number of people whose agricultural income falls below the subsistence level in 1993 is much smaller when based on the number of families receiving social assistance (208,000) than when based on presumptive cash income (485,000). This paper retains only the former estimate.

Based on the preceding analysis on an extended family, the number of rural residents with incomes falling below the subsistence level is estimated at 26,000 in 1991 (2 percent of the rural population excluding state farms 44/) and 208,000 in the second half of 1992 and the first half of 1993, and zero in the second half of 1993. On a nuclear family basis, with pensioners relying on their own income, the number of rural residents with incomes falling below subsistence levels is estimated at 24,000 in 1991 (5,000 nuclear families) and 340,000 in the second half of 1992 and the first half of 1993 (40,000 nuclear families and 150,000 pensioners), and 150,000 in the second half of 1993.

b. Depth of poverty

The depth of poverty, measured as the difference between average and subsistence incomes, increased significantly after the first half of 1992 for those without access to emigrant remittances (Table 31). Incomes fell below subsistence levels in the second half of 1992 for a substantial fraction of the urban population, when recipients of unemployment insurance and pensioners with dependents and a fraction of state sector workers Joined social assistance recipients whose benefits were already below subsistence incomes. The depth of poverty almost doubled in size in the first half of 1993 for the urban poor, but declined substantially in the second half of 1993, to about 200 lek per person (8 percent of the 1993 per capita GDP) in unemployed and pensioner households with dependents, and 350 lek per person in families on social assistance.

The value of rural pensions declined in real terms, and the average rural pension fell below (urban) subsistence levels in the second half of 1992 and grew very wide (to lek 900) in the second half of 1993, as the collapse of social security contributions from the rural sector after the privatization of cooperatives led the Government not to award pension increases or price compensation. Social assistance payments also fell below the subsistence income for families with little land in the second half of 1992, and the gap widened to lek 160 per person in the first half of 1993 but was closed in the second half of 1993 following the introduction of the new social assistance law. 45/

VI. Developments in Per Capita Consumption

Income data have clear limitations in the case of Albania. First, comparison with the period before price liberalization is inherently difficult because cash income is not a good measure of purchasing power for the period before liberalization, owing to the rationing associated with price controls. Second, income data are not always available or precise, as in the case of informal sector income, formal sector private income, or emigrant remittances. Because of these data limitations, the results are checked against developments in per capita food consumption estimated on the basis of production and net imports. If per capita food consumption were a measure of purchasing power—which seems reasonable at the present low levels of income—a finding of rising per capita urban consumption between 1991 and 1993 would indicate that 1991 income overestimates real purchasing power, and/or that 1993 real income is underestimated using the methods in this paper.

Indeed, price liberalization began after the 1991 base-year for the comparisons, when there had been widespread excess demand and food shortages (in the wake of the spontaneous privatization of cooperatives, the uncertainty about ownership rights, shortages in agricultural inputs, and the breakdown of the state distribution and marketing system), large wage increases for all state employees in response to political pressures, and high financial savings. 46/

The facts to be reconciled with per capita consumption of food are an increase of 47 in real rural incomes (71 percent in agriculture and -15 percent for pensions and social assistance) and a decline of 28 percent in real urban incomes (-13 percent for average public sector incomes and -36 percent in incomes of those at or close to subsistence levels in urban areas) between 1991 and 1993. Per capita consumption is derived on the basis of data on gross production, net imports, use of food as inputs, and the change in food stocks (large for wheat in 1992 and 1993).

For the country as a whole, per capita consumption increased between 9 and 110 percent depending on the item (Table 14). This finding is difficult to reconcile with income developments. Assuming real income elasticity of 1 and relative price elasticity of 0, growth in per capita consumption implied by income developments is only 6 percent between 1991 and 1993. Growth in per capita consumption consistent with income is positive (47 percent) in rural areas and negative (-28 percent) in urban areas. 47/ in fact, the increase in per capita consumption exceeds 6 percent for all food items considered. The range of increases in per capita food consumption for different items in urban and rural areas implies, based on CPI expenditure weights, an increase of 28 percent in food consumption. This increase in turn Implies that, if one assumes the figure for rural areas (47 percent), urban consumption grew by 12 percent. The difference between this 12 percent growth, and the -28 percent implied by the income estimates of this paper, must reflect (1) excess demand in the base year or (2) incomplete measurement of incomes (urban or rural informal incomes, emigrant remittances).

Table 14.

Food Production and Consumption, 1990–1993

article image
Sources: Ministry of Agriculture and Ministry of Finance, Department of Counterpart Funds.

Apples, pears, peaches, and figs.

In thousands.

Wheat stocks were 100,000 ton in 1992 and 237,000 ton in 1993.

Part of the impact of rationing in 1991 can be removed by focussing on the period just before mid-1991 when large wage and benefit increases were granted. Between the first half of 1991 and the second half of 1993. real urban income fell by only 12 percent, which is somewhat more in line with developments in urban consumption.

VII. Social Safety Nets

The income data indicates that the net outcome of the dislocation from the collapse of the command economy, the adjustment of relative prices, and the restructuring of the state enterprise sector, mitigated by a social safety nets and remittances, has been an increase in poverty from 5 to some 25 percent of the population and a widening of the depth of poverty, between 1991 and 1993. While a more extensive safety net would have been able to avoid poverty, the gains would have to be balanced against higher costs (higher taxes, higher deficit, or lower other essential expenditures). Social safety net expenditures, defined to include spending on permanent institutions such as pensions, were already 15.4 percent of GDP in the second half of 1993 (Table 15), which was sizeable for countries in Albania’s GDP per capita range ($300 per year). A comprehensive assessment would involve an assessment of the mix of expenditure and revenue, expenditure composition, and the efficiency of individual categories of expenditures. Such a comprehensive assessment is beyond the scope of the paper, and only the efficiency of social safety net expenditures is considered here. The question addressed here is how well were poverty alleviation goals net, given the resources spent. This involves an assessment of how many members of the target group were not adequately covered by the safety net (the exclusion error) and of how many members of non-target groups were covered by it (the inclusion error). Various components of the social safety net introduced in the course of the transition (and still in place) are considered in turn. Table 2 (above) shows the number of people covered by the safety net. Table 3 (above) provides information on benefit levels.

Table 15.

Social Safety Net Expenditures

(in percent of GDP)

article image
Source: Author’s estimates.

Includes rural bread price compensation in 1992 (0.4 percent of GDP).

Price compensation for transfer recipients (subsumed under pensions, unemployment benefits, and targeted poverty programs) plus price compensation for employed person.