Drift in Producer Price Indexes for the Former Soviet Union (FSU) Countries
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

The purpose of this paper is to show that, under the price fluctuations that characterize most transition economies, the commonly used chain index derived from the published month-to-month price change of the PPI in some cases dramatically overstates the rate of price inflation. The analysis is based in part on a seminal paper by Szulc, who studies the problem of drift for a wide class of index formulae, and in part on the observations of price movements made by the Fund’s missions. Greatest during the year 1992, the drift declines with slower rates of inflation and, possibly, with changing patterns of price increases, but is still important for countries such as Russia, where monthly inflation continues to run well into the double digits.

Abstract

The purpose of this paper is to show that, under the price fluctuations that characterize most transition economies, the commonly used chain index derived from the published month-to-month price change of the PPI in some cases dramatically overstates the rate of price inflation. The analysis is based in part on a seminal paper by Szulc, who studies the problem of drift for a wide class of index formulae, and in part on the observations of price movements made by the Fund’s missions. Greatest during the year 1992, the drift declines with slower rates of inflation and, possibly, with changing patterns of price increases, but is still important for countries such as Russia, where monthly inflation continues to run well into the double digits.

I. Introduction

Economists who have worked with Former Soviet Union (FSU) price data have noted the striking difference between the cumulative price increase derived by chaining the reported monthly Producer Price Index (PPI) 2/ and the reported change of this index over 12 months 3/.

The purpose of this paper is to show that, in the context of the price fluctuations characterizing most transition economies, a chain index derived from the month-to-month price change of the PPI dramatically overstates the rate of price inflation in some cases. The analysis is based in part on a seminal paper by Szulc, 4/ who studied the problem of drift for a wide class of index formulae, and in part on observations made by the Fund’s technical assistance missions on price statistics of detailed price movements in the FSU countries. Greatest during the year 1992, the drift declines with slower rates of inflation (and possibly with changing patterns of price increases) but remains important for countries, such as Russia, in which monthly inflation continues to run well into the double digits. 5/

Consequently, the current version of the PPI should not be used as a deflator of the value of production to obtain a volume indicator. Indexes of industrial production so derived would largely underestimate the growth (or overestimate the decline) in output. As the bias under discussion is measured in relation to the Laspeyres standard, the overestimation of price change would be effectively eliminated if the basis for calculation of the PPI were changed to a Laspeyres formula.

The paper also provides an explanation for the difference between the chained monthly index and the t/t-12 version of the PPI and guidance on which of these indices should be used.

II. Background

If the fixed-base Laspeyres index is selected as the standard for comparison, the use of a certain nonstandard chained formula leads to excessive drift in measured price change.

1. A Nonstandard Formula

Fund economists have been aware for some time that the formula used to compile the PPI in FSU countries is not the Laspeyres formula used in most countries. 6/ Because producer price indicators were used to monitor a central economic plan, a time series with a fixed reference base was of less interest to users of the data than a set of indicators comparing prices in the current month with those of the previous month, and those of the current month with those of same month in the previous year. These specialized comparisons were formed by averaging the price relatives appropriate for the time period under consideration with a set of weights from a fixed reference period. To form a fixed reference base series from the monthly data compiled in this fashion, it was necessary to chain the monthly indices together. If the index formula implied by this practice is examined, it can be seen as a slight generalization of the Sauerbeck index studied by Szulc (1983), and it might therefore be called “the generalized Sauerbeck index.” 7/

a. The Sauerbeck Index Versus the Laspeyres Index

The generalized Sauerbeck, or Weighted Average of Price Relatives (WAPR), index formula used in the wholesale price indexes of a number of FSU countries is:

PWAPR0,tΠτ=1tΣi=1nwi0piτpiτ1(1)

In this formula, the i subscript indexes item, the t superscript indexes time period (month), the 0 superscript represents the base period, ρ represents price, and w represents the item weight from the base period. For each item i, w is computed as:

wi0 = pi0qi0Σi=1npi0qi0(2)

From the formula, it can be seen that this is a chain of fixed-weighted averages of short-term price relatives.

The Laspeyres index formula is

pL0,tΣi=1npitqi0Σi=1npi0qi0 = Σi=1n[wi0pit1pi0]pitpit1(3)
= Πτ=1tΣi=1n[wi0piτ1pi0Σi=1nwi0piτ1pi0]piτpiτ1(4)

which, as shown, can be also be expressed as a chain of averages of short-term price relatives, but in contrast with equation (1), with weights that vary from period to period. The formulas in equations (1) and (4) look deceptively similar and, by inspection, are in fact identical for the first time period following the base when t = 1.

A comparison of the Laspeyres and Sauerbeck formulas shows that negative serial correlation, under which the relatives assume higher than average values that are followed by lower than average values and vice versa, induces an upward bias in the Sauerbeck formula. Such negative correlation is a rather common occurrence in transition economies. Positive correlation, which is characterized by more uniform price changes across commodities, results in a downward drift in the Sauerbeck.

b. Szulc’s argument

To specialize Szulc’s notation somewhat for the purpose of this paper, let

ritpitpit1yitqit1qi0citwi0pit1pi0(5)

In the language of practitioners, the first item is the “short-term price relative,” the second is the “long-term quantity relative,” and the last is the “cost weight.”

The chain form of the Laspeyres index in equation (4) can then be expressed as:

PL0,t = Πτ=1tΣi=1nciτriτΣi=1nciτ(6)

For comparative purposes, one may select any chain index (including the WAPR/generalized Sauerbeck) with period-to-period links that can be expressed as an average of short-term price relatives and assume that the weights are revised and a new link is introduced every period. In this case (if several minor algebraic steps are omitted) the chain index can be expressed in terms of the cost weights of the Laspeyres index as:

PC0,t = Πτ=1tΣi=1nciτriτyiτΣi=1nciτyiτ(7)

Szulc defines the cumulative drift of the chain series in relation to its “direct” Laspeyres counterpart as the ratio of (7) to (6) and applies a theorem of Bortkiewicz to show that the drift can be written as:

D0,tΠτ=1tΣi=1nciτriτyiτ/Σi=1nciτyiτΣi=1nciτriτ/Σi=1nciτ
=Πτ=1t(1+corr(rt,yt)cv(rt)cv(yt))(8)

In equation (8), corr(r, y) refers to the correlation between r and y, and cv(r) and cv(y) refer to the coefficients of variation of r and y. (The cv is the ratio of the standard deviation to the mean.) Equation (8) is Szulc’s central result and elegantly decomposes drift into its component factors. In each period, both the direction and magnitude of drift critically depend on the (cost-weighted) correlation across items between the short-term price relatives (r) and the long-term quantity relatives (y). From the term in equation (8) that depends on (cost-weighted) coefficients of variation (cvs), it can be inferred that highly variable and negatively correlated price and quantity movements across items for a given time period (because these effects increase the cvs of r and y) also increase the magnitude of drift, but do not affect its direction.

Drift in the Sauerbeck index may now be analyzed. In any specified period t, the “quantity weights” of the WAPR/generalized Sauerbeck index are proportional to the base period share weight divided by the price of the previous period, as the following equation shows:

qWAPR,it1wi0pit1(9)

The long-term quantity relative (y) for each item (i) (which is the above quantity expression divided by the fixed quantity level for that item in the base period) is proportional to the reciprocal of the price (p) of the previous period, and, by inspection, so is the short-term price relative (r). Since r and y share a common factor, a strong case can be made that they will be positively correlated across items in most situations and that, in comparison with the Laspeyres, the WAPR will drift upward. 8/ For the WAPR, positive correlation between r and y is implied by negative serial correlation in the short-term price relatives. Similarly, a negative correlation between r and y is implied by a positive serial correlation in the short-term price relatives. 9/ Drift will be exacerbated by high own-variability and negative contemporaneous correlation between price relatives (r) across items, because these two effects will increase the coefficient of variation in both r and y for the WAPR formula.

2. Relevance to the Context of Former Soviet Union Countries

Positive serial correlation in price relatives is typical of market economies in a steady state: all prices move more or less together and with small variations in rates of change over time. Strong negative serial correlation in the relatives and high variability in rates of change across items is typical both of market economies encountering unanticipated sectoral shocks, and transition economies. In the latter case, price movements are characterized by price “liberalization” in fits and starts, sector by sector, as the government resets prices according to evolving notions of their equilibrium levels and political feasibility. Under these conditions, monthly price relatives for selected classes of goods typically follow a pattern of assuming a value of unity, then a value substantially greater than unity, then unity again. Since higher-than-average values succeed lower-than-average values, this form of price adjustment produces negative serial correlations in the monthly relatives.

The potential for bias resulting from use of the Sauerbeck formula is dramatically illustrated by Szulc’s “bouncing” price relatives example. 10/

article image

In this case, the direct index (which directly compares period 4 to period 1) is equal to 1 in period 4 while the chained index is equal to 2.44—a 144 percent drift over an interval of five periods.

Linking non-fixed-base indexes can lead mechanically to a difference between the chained index and the direct index. In the case under discussion, the chained index is the monthly WAPR PPI, and the direct index is the “corresponding month of the previous year” version of the PPI. The difference can be positive or negative; results depend on the path of item price changes. It should be emphasized that the difference between the annual change in the chained monthly index and the annual change in the direct index is a result of the different formulas, and not related to differences in weighting per se, to price collection, or introduction of new products.

III. Evidence

The available evidence supports the presumption that the pattern of price changes in FSU countries in 1992 approximated conditions leading to an upward drift of the WAPR month-to-month chained index in most republics. 11/ This evidence also indicates that the drift can be large. The chained index produces overestimations of inflation that range from about 40 percent in Latvia to 450 percent in Turkmenistan for the year 1992. For the Russian Federation, the drift was 84 percent for the same year. Armenia is the only country in which the measured drift was downward in 1992. The following table gives the results of a comparison of the WAPR index and the t/t-12 version of the PPI over the December 1991—December 1992 period for FSU countries for which the data are available:

Producer Price Indices in Selected FSU countries Percent Change from Dec. 1991 to Dec. 1992

article image

More recent results for the Russian Federation and Kazakhstan show that, although the drift has diminished from the peak of December 1992 13/, it is still quite significant. Average monthly drift was 10 percent in Russia in July 1993 and 17 percent in Kazakhstan in September 1993. The following tables show the annual drift in column (1), the average monthly drift 14/ in column (2), and the average monthly price change in column (3). For example, for the Russian Federation in March 1993, the annual drift is equal to 1.34, the monthly drift is equal to 1.02 (two percent per month); the latter can be compared to an average monthly inflation of 20 percent during the last 12 months.

Drift in the Producer Price Index of the Russian Federation

article image

Drift in the Producer Price Index of Kazakhstan

article image

IV. Conclusions

The WAPR/generalized Sauerbeck index clearly should not be used as a measure of producer price change—particularly under conditions of high inflation and negative serial correlation in short-term rates of price change. To use it under these conditions as a deflator for the value of output leads to underestimated growth (or, more precisely in the case of FSU countries, to overestimated decline) in industrial production. Although having certain conceptual shortcomings 15/, the t/t-12 version of the PPI is definitely a better measure of inflation for a specified one year period. However, this index, unfortunately, cannot be used to derive a consistent monthly time series.

There are, therefore, three possibilities for an economist desiring monthly constant price indicators for the FSU countries: (1) use other deflators, (2) use other figures based directly on quantities or volume of production if available, or (3) wait for the national compilers to implement a Laspeyres PPI in cooperation with the IMF Statistics technical assistance missions on price statistics.

References

  • Koen, Vincent, and Steven Phillips,Price liberalization in Russia: The Early Record, International Monetary Fund Working Paper 92 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Koen, Vincent, and Steven Phillips,Price Liberalization in Russia: Behavior of Prices, Household Incomes and Consumption in the First Year,Occasional Paper No. 104 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, June 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Moulton, Brent,Basic Components of the CPI: Estimation of Price Changes,in U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Monthly Labor Review (Washington: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, December 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Szulc, Bohdan,Linking Price Index Numbers,” in W.E. Diewert and C. Montmarquette, eds., Price Level Measurement: Proceedings of a Conference Sponsored by Statistics Canada (Ottawa: Statistics Canada, 1983), pp. 537562.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1/

The authors would like to thank V. Koen, D. Citrin, and M. Dieckman of the Fund’s European II Department; R. Dippelsman and P. Cotterell of the Fund’s Statistics Department; and Ralph Turvey, London School of Economics, for their useful discussion and comment.

2/

The PPI is often referred to as the wholesale Price Index (WPI) or, in Russian, as optoviy. This nomenclature is misleading as the observed prices are, in fact, producer prices (ex-factory gate) and not wholesale prices.

3/

See, among others, the two papers by Vincent Koen and Steven Phillips on price liberalization in Russia: IMF Working Paper 92, 1992, and IMF Occasional Paper 104, June 1993.

5/

It should be noted that the problem with the Producer Price Index formula that is the subject of this paper also exists, in some instances, for the Consumer Price Index (CPI). Correction of this problem with the CPI should therefore be undertaken wherever it is encountered with countries of the FSU. However, the problem may not be limited to transition economies. An interesting instance of similar linking problems seems to have occurred at low levels of aggregation in the U.S. CPI, although with less serious consequences (see Moulton (1993)).

6/

This fact is not necessarily well known outside the Fund, however. The recent OECD publication entitled Short-term Economic Indicators for Central and Eastern Europe: Sources and Definitions incorrectly attributed a Laspeyres methodology to the Estonian PPI.

7/

Szulc refers to a chain of unweighted averages of price relatives for adjacent pairs of time periods as “the Sauerbeck formula.” The formula used in FSU countries is a chain of weighted averages in which the weights remain constant from period to period—hence the term “generalized Sauerbeck.”

8/

Szulc points out that the Sauerbeck is consistent with the assumption of very strong substitution effects. From equation (9), it may be seen that this is also true of the generalized Sauerbeck/WAPR index. The correlation between percentage changes in ρ and q from the same time period for the same item is clearly -1.

9/

This relationship between serial correlation in r and contemporaneous correlation between r and y may not be obvious from equations (8) and (9). Since

pit1 = pi0Πτ=1t1riτ

it may be argued that, for the WAPR, the correlation between r and y becomes a function of the correlations between r in the current period and its reciprocal from previous periods back to the base. If the short-term relatives are positively serially correlated, the correlation between r in the current period and the product of its past values would be positive. By implication, the correlation of current period r with the reciprocal of the product of its past values would be negative. The correlation between r and y will therefore be negative for the WAPR formula when the short-term relatives are positively serially correlated, and the WAPR will display downward drift in comparison with the Laspeyres. If the same reasoning is used, it may be argued that negative serial correlation in r will induce upward drift.

10/

The example uses the Sauerbeck formula and thus equally weights the price relatives in constructing each chain link.

11/

The data needed to calculate drift are not available in all republics of the former Soviet Union. Some republics, such as Lithuania and Georgia, do not publish a PPI. Others, such as Uzbekistan and Tajikistan, do not publish both one- and twelve-month indexes. In Belarus, the statistical office corrected calculation of the index for aggregation of regional data to the national level, but problems remain in the effective index formula used by some of the regions. The one- and twelve-month indexes are therefore consistent at the national level and drift is not evident in the most recently revised data. However, inconsistencies leading to drift at lower levels of geographical aggregation remain but cannot be measured because the necessary data are not published.

12/

The drift is equal to [(1)+100] / [(2)+100].

13/

December 1992 registers the highest yearly drift. The year 1992 began with a large price shock in January, making it the most inflationary annual period in these countries in recent years.

14/

The monthly drift is equal to the (1/12)th power of the annual drift.

15/

For example, the base period, 0 in wi0, is in general not the same as the t-12 period for the price relative, Pit/Pit-12, as would be required by the Laspeyres formula.

Drift in Producer Price Indexes for the Former Soviet Union (FSU) Countries
Author: Mr. Kimberly D. Zieschang and François Lequiller