Abstract
The paper analyzes the role of labor market segmentation and relative wage rigidity in the transmission process of macroeconomic shocks in a two-sector optimizing model of a small open economy. The analysis is first conducted in the context of perfect intersectoral labor mobility. The discussion is then extended to consider the existence of short-run constraints on labor movements. The results highlight the role of efficiency considerations in the behavior of sectoral wages. A deflationary policy induces a reallocation of labor across sectors, but has no long-run effect on the unemployment rate.
I. Introduction
The nature and extent of labor market segmentation in developing countries has been the subject of much debate over the years, particularly in the context of discussions related to urbanization and migration between rural and urban areas. In a seminal paper, Harris and Todaro (1970) showed that the existence of a binding minimum wage in the urban sector leads, even if the rural labor market is competitive, to a persistent wage differential between the rural and urban sectors and to the emergence of unemployment in equilibrium. Moreover, expansion of labor demand or real wage restraint in the urban sector will not restore full employment.
More recent work has focused on the role of labor market segmentation in the context of trade and structural reforms.1/ By contrast, the implications of various types of labor market dualism for the short-run determination of output and employment in an open economy have not received much attention in the existing literature.2/ The importance of accounting for labor market segmentation and the degree of wage flexibility for a proper understanding of the effects of macroeconomic shocks on unemployment can be illustrated with a simple graphical analysis. Consider a small open economy producing traded and nontraded goods using only labor, the supply of which is given. The determination of wages and employment under four different assumptions regarding labor market adjustment are shown in Figure 1 to 4. In all four figures the horizontal axis measures total labor available to the economy,
Labor Market Adjustment with Flexible Wages and Perfect Inter-Sectoral Mobility
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1993, 079; 10.5089/9781451850161.001.A001
Labor Market Adjustment with Partial Wage Rigidity and Perfect Inter-Sectoral Mobility
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1993, 079; 10.5089/9781451850161.001.A001
Labor Market Adjustment with Partial Wage Rigidity and No Inter-Sectoral Mobility
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1993, 079; 10.5089/9781451850161.001.A001
Labor Market Adjustment in a Harris-Todaro Framework
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1993, 079; 10.5089/9781451850161.001.A001
Figure 2, 3 and 4 assume that the wage rate in the traded goods sector is fixed at
Suppose that the demand for labor in the traded goods sector falls, as a result of a macroeconomic shock—a reduction, say, in autonomous demand for tradables—shifting the labor demand curve to the left, from
Consider now what happens in the presence of a sector-specific wage rigidity. If labor is perfectly mobile across sectors, the demand shock leads again to a reallocation of the labor force across sectors, together with a fall in wages in the nontraded goods sector (Figure 2). However, if workers cannot move across sectors—because, say, different skills are required for different activities—the reduction in demand leads to an increase in unemployment in the traded goods sector (from
While the foregoing analysis was presented in a partial equilibrium framework, the remainder of this paper analyzes the effects of macroeconomic policy in a dynamic, general equilibrium model of a small open economy with segmented labor markets. Section II presents the basic framework, under the assumption that labor is homogeneous and perfectly mobile across sectors. Section III examines the short- and long-run effects of a deflationary macroeconomic policy, which takes the form of a permanent reduction in the devaluation rate. Section IV extends the basic model to account for the existence of gradual labor mobility across sectors and contrasts the effects of macroeconomic policy on unemployment with the results obtained previously. Finally, Section V summarizes the main implications of the analysis.
II. A Basic Framework
Consider a small open economy in which there are four types of agents: producers, households, the central bank, and the government. All firms and households are identical. The official exchange rate is devalued at a predetermined rate by the central bank. The economy produces two goods, a nontraded good that is used only for final domestic consumption, and a traded good whose price is determined on world markets. The capital stock in each sector is fixed during the time frame of the analysis, while labor is assumed initially homogenous and perfectly mobile across sectors. The labor market consists of two sectors: a primary segment, where employment is determined by firms in the traded goods sector, and a secondary segment, which corresponds to the nontraded goods sector. An above-equilibrium real wage is set in the primary market as a way to elicit effort and maintain productivity, while in the secondary market wages are fully flexible and adjust to equilibrate supply and demand.7/ Firms in the traded goods sector make their employment decisions first. The secondary sector absorbs all workers that are not hired in the primary segment of the market, so that unemployment cannot emerge. Households consume both traded and nontraded goods, supply labor inelastically and hold two categories of financial assets in their portfolios: domestic money (which bears no interest) and a traded bond issued abroad, which bears a real rate of return determined on world markets. Domestic households and firms can borrow and lend freely at that rate, which varies inversely with the economy's total stock of foreign assets. 8/ The government consumes only nontraded goods, collects lump-sum taxes and receives transfers from the central bank. It finances its budget deficit either by borrowing from the central bank, or by varying taxes on households. Finally, while agents form rational expectations with regard to exchange rate and price movements, wage and employment expectations—which play a role only under imperfect sectoral mobility—are assumed to depend on prevailing conditions in the labor market.
1. Output and the labor market
Setting the world price of traded goods to unity, the domestic price of traded goods is given by
where
where
The representative firm in the traded goods sector maximizes its real profits, given by
with respect to
These optimality conditions imply:
which indicates that in equilibrium the elasticity of effort with respect to the product wage is unity. Equation (4) generalizes the “Solow Condition” (see Solow, 1979) to a two-sector economy and can be solved for the real efficiency wage in the traded goods sector for a given value of the secondary sector wage:11/
Consider, for instance, the case where the effort function takes the form
which satisfies
Solving equation (4) yields
which indicates that the efficiency wage is always higher than the opportunity cost of effort. A graphical determination of the efficiency wage is shown in Figure 5.
Efficiency Wages and Effort
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1993, 079; 10.5089/9781451850161.001.A001
Substituting the optimal value of
The effect of an increase in the real wage in the nontraded goods sector on the demand for labor in the traded goods sector is, in general, ambiguous. Using the effort function defined by (2'), however, indicates that
Substituting equations (2), (5) and (6) in (1) yields
An increase in the real wage in the nontraded goods sector has an unambiguously negative effect on output of traded goods (regardless of whether it increases or lowers labor demand) because of its positive effect on the efficiency wage.
Production in the nontraded goods sector is determined by
and real profits (in terms of prices of traded goods) are given by
where
from which labor demand can be derived as
where
The mechanism through which equilibrium of the labor market obtains in this economy is as follows.13/ Each period, available workers queue up to seek employment in the primary segment of the labor market. Firms in the primary market determine the real efficiency wage and hire randomly from the queue—since labor is homogenous, firms treat workers symmetrically—up to the point where their optimal demand for labor is satisfied. Workers who are unable to obtain employment in the primary sector become suppliers in the secondary market and, together with demand there, determine the wage that equilibrates the secondary market. Formally, let
which, for a given value of the real exchange rate, can be solved for the equilibrium value of
2. Consumption and the dynamics of wealth
Households supply a quantity of labor
where
Nominal wealth of the representative household
where
where
where
Households are subject to a cash-in-advance constraint on total purchases of home and foreign goods: 15/
where v denotes the velocity of circulation, assumed constant. Equation (18) can be written equivalently as
Households treat
in addition to (17) and the transversality condition
Equation (19a) shows the familiar result according to which in equilibrium the marginal utility of consumption of traded goods is equal to the marginal utility of wealth
3. Money, deficits, and the balance of payments
There are no commercial banks in the economy considered here, and credit only flows from the central bank to the government. The nominal money stock is therefore equal to
where Dt denotes the stock of domestic credit allocated by the central bank to the government, and Rt the stock of net foreign assets, measured in foreign currency terms. The change in the foreign currency value of the central bank's reserves is determined by
The government's revenue sources consist of lump-sum taxes on households and transfers from the central bank resulting from interest receipts on net foreign assets and revaluation of foreign exchange reserves. 16/ It consumes nontraded goods and finances its budget deficit by borrowing from the central bank or varying taxes. In nominal terms, the government's budget constraint can be written as:
or, in real terms,
where
Suppose that the central bank fixes the rate of growth of the nominal credit stock at
Suppose also that the central bank sets the rate of growth of domestic credit so as to compensate the government for the loss in value in the outstanding stock of credit resulting from exchange rate depreciation
To close the model requires specifying the equilibrium condition for the nontraded goods market. Using equation (11) yields
III. Devaluation, Real Wages and Employment
Before examining the long-run properties of the model, it is convenient to re-write it in a more compact form. The labor market clearing equation (13) yields a solution in which, fc>r the effort function (2'),
where, for simplicity,
Suppose also that
where
In general, the net effect of a real depreciation on output of nontraded goods is ambiguous
Solving equation (26') yields the equilibrium solution for the real exchange rate:18/
Substituting equations (12) and (25) to (29) in equation (17) together with
which determines the rate of accumulation of foreign assets. Finally, equation (19d) can be re-written as
Equations (30) and (31) determine the behavior of foreign assets and the marginal utility of wealth over time, while equation (29) determines the equilibrium level of the real exchange rate, for given values of
A linear approximation around the steady state to equations (30) and (31) yields
where
Given that the stock of foreign assets is predetermined, the system described by (32) is locally saddlepoint stable. 20/ The steady-state equilibrium is depicted in Figure 6, under the assumption that
Steady-State Equilibrium
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1993, 079; 10.5089/9781451850161.001.A001
Consider now a permanent, unanticipated reduction at t = 0 in the devaluation rate, from a value of
Reduction in the Devaluation Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1993, 079; 10.5089/9781451850161.001.A001
The transmission mechanism of this policy shock can be described as follows. On impact, the reduction in the devaluation rate leads to a one-to-one reduction in the nominal interest rate (since the stock of foreign assets, and therefore the world interest rate, remains constant) and reduces the opportunity cost of money holdings, which tends to increase consumption of traded goods. However, the marginal value of wealth must jump upwards on impact since the stock of bonds is given in the short run. This upward jump reduces consumption of traded goods. The net effect—given the assumption of a logarithmic instantaneous utility function—is a reduction in consumption of traded goods on impact. For a given level of the real exchange rate, consumption of nontraded goods also falls. This reduction requires a depreciation of the real exchange rate to dampen output of nontraded goods, mitigate the initial fall in demand, and therefore maintain equilibrium in the home goods market. The resulting reduction in the demand for labor compounds the initial downward movement in the real wage in that sector, and leads to a fall in the real efficiency wage in the traded goods sector. 22/ This reduction in wages has a positive net effect on output of traded goods (despite the negative impact on effort), increasing the demand for labor in that sector. The ensuing outflow of workers seeking employment into the traded goods sector dampens the downward pressure on the product wage in the nontraded goods sector.
During the transition to the new steady-state equilibrium, the marginal value of wealth falls while the economy continues to accumulate foreign assets. Consumption of traded and nontraded goods therefore rises over time, leading to a gradual appreciation of the real exchange rate. The increase in the relative price of nontraded goods reduces output and lowers the demand for labor in the traded goods sector. The flow of labor away from the traded goods sector exerts an upward pressure on the real wage (measured in terms of traded goods) in the nontraded goods sector. Under the assumptions made above, the net effect of the real appreciation and the movement in the real wage is a fall in the product wage in the nontraded goods sector, which has a positive effect on output and increases the demand for labor in that sector—therefore mitigating the reduction in the product wage. Because consumption of traded goods rises and output falls over time, the rate of accumulation of foreign assets is gradually reduced (thus dampening the rise in consumption over time). A permanent, unanticipated reduction in the devaluation rate is associated with a steady-state depreciation of the real exchange rate.
IV. Labor Mobility and Adjustment
The foregoing analysis was based on the assumption that workers who cannot find a job in the traded goods sector can apply for work in the nontraded goods sector, implying that there was no involuntary unemployment in the economy. However, the assumption of perfect mobility across sectors is not very appealing, particularly in a short-run context.23/ In migrating across sectors, workers typically incur a variety of costs (training, relocation expenses, etc.) that may prevent instant reallocation of the labor force. We now assume that, although labor is perfectly mobile across sectors in the long run, adjustment takes place gradually so that the allocation of labor to each sector is predetermined at any moment in time.
Let
which can again be solved for the real wage:
Substituting equation (34) in (11) and solving equation (26) yields the equilibrium real exchange rate:
Substituting this equation, together with (34), in equation (7) yields the supply function of traded goods:
Workers migrate across sectors in response to the perceived degree of labor market tightness in the two segments of the market. Wage expectations and the probability of finding a job are assumed to depend on current labor market conditions.25/ The expected payoff from queueing in, say, the primary market is equal to the primary sector wage weighted by the probability of being hired in the traded goods sector. Assuming that hiring is random, this probability is simply equal to the number of primary sector jobs over the number of workers seeking employment. Accordingly, the expected payoffs
Over time, labor moves across sectors in response to the discrepancy between the payoffs available in the two sectors:26/
where K denotes the speed of adjustment. Using the equilibrium solutions for wages as a function of the real exchange rate, and substituting out the equilibrium condition (29') in (36) yields
In general, the signs of the partial derivatives appearing in equation (37) are ambiguous since they all depend on
The dynamic system driving the economy consists now of equations (30)—after substitution of equation (35) for qy—(31), and (37). A linear approximation around the steady state to this system can be written as
where we assume that
The system now has two predetermined variables and one jump variable, and therefore requires two negative roots and one positive root to ensure saddlepath stability. Sufficient conditions are therefore that the determinant of the coefficient matrix in (38) be positive and that the trace of the coefficient matrix be negative.27/ We assume in what follows that these two conditions hold.
The steady-state solution of the model implies an important property for the unemployment rate in the traded goods sector. Using the specific effort function defined earlier and assuming that
which indicates that the "natural" rate of unemployment in the traded goods sector is always positive in equilibrium
Consider, as before, a permanent, unanticipated reduction in the devaluation rate. The initial position of the economy is assumed to be such that the marginal utility of wealth is falling, and the rate of accumulation of foreign assets as well as the flow of workers migrating towards the traded goods sector are both positive. The behavior over time of the marginal utility of wealth, the efficiency wage and labor supply in the traded goods sector, consumption of traded goods, the real exchange rate, and the stock of foreign assets is shown in Figure 8. In general, whether or not the adjustment path of the economy differs from what obtains in the case of perfect labor mobility depends on whether the speed of adjustment of labor to changes in expected payoffs (the coefficient k) is small or large. When ic is large, the behavior of all variables is qualitatively similar to what obtains in the case of perfect labor mobility examined previously—except that now labor supply in the traded goods sector rises continuously over time (see Figure 8). The reason, of course, is the mono tonic increase in the efficiency wage in that sector before mnd after the policy shock, which maintains a positive payoff differential during the transition to the new steady state. In addition, at the moment the rate of devaluation is reduced, there is an increase in the flow of workers entering the traded goods sector. It can also be shown that, using the effort function described earlier, a permanent reduction in the devaluation rate reduces temporarily the unemployment rate in the traded goods sector—an unconventional result. In the long run, endogenous adjustment in labor supply and labor demand is such that, as shown in equation (39), the unemployment rate depends only on the efficiency coefficient.
Dynamics with Imperfect Labor Mobility
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1993, 079; 10.5089/9781451850161.001.A001
When the speed of adjustment of labor to changes in expected payoffs is small, changes in the flow of labor supplied in the two segments of the labor market will have a more limited effect on movements in wages in both sectors, and will dampen fluctuations in employment and output. At the same time, however, the transitory fall in the unemployment rate in the traded goods sector resulting from a reduction in the devaluation rate will also be dampened. The net welfare effect is thus ambiguous. But to the extent that workers’ productivity may also depend on the perceived risk of being unemployed—a relation that features in several efficiency-wage models—the effect of a low degree of mobility on the unemployment rate may be compounded by a reduction in output and labor demand.
V. Summary and Conclusions
The purpose of this paper has been to examine the implications of efficiency considerations and imperfect labor mobility for the short-run dynamics associated with macroeconomic policy shocks. The analysis was based on a two-sector optimizing model of a small open economy with segmented labor markets. While firms in the traded goods sector determine both wages and employment, wages in the nontraded goods sector are determined by the equilibrium condition between supply and demand. In addition, labor productivity in the traded goods sector depends on the attractiveness of opportunities—measured by real wages—that workers face inside and outside the sector. The equilibrium solution of the model indicates that firms in the traded goods sector always set the real wage above the level that prevails in the nontraded goods sector. In contrast to many existing models, sectoral real wage rigidity is thus not postulated but explicitly derived from optimizing conditions. Moreover, the formulation adopted here leads to an explicit specification of the interactions between wages in the different sectors of the economy.
We first considered the case where labor is homogeneous and perfectly mobile across sectors. The analysis showed that a permanent, unanticipated reduction in the devaluation rate leads to a drop in real wages in the traded goods sector, and an instantaneous reallocation of labor away from the nontraded goods sector. In the latter part of the paper, we considered the case where workers' movements across sectors occur gradually. The behavior of the economy with imperfect labor mobility was shown to be qualitatively similar to what obtains in the previous case when the speed of adjustment of labor to changes in expected payoffs is large, except that unemployment will typically emerge in equilibrium. However, a deflationary policy may not necessarily lead to an increase in unemployment in the short run. In the model developed here—as in standard efficiency wage models—firms in the traded goods sector do not reduce wages in the face of persistent sectoral unemployment because to do so would reduce productivity. When the speed of adjustment of labor is small, fluctuations in wages, employment and output are dampened but the transitory fall in the unemployment rate associated with a reduction in the devaluation rate will also be attenuated.
Beyond the specific results obtained here, two general lessons can be derived from the analysis. First, the issues of labor market segmentation and sectoral labor mobility deserve more attention than they have so far received in analytical and policy-oriented discussions on short-run macroeconomic adjustment. Shocks that lead to labor reallocation across sectors may have important aggregate effects that should be accounted for in the design of macroeconomic programs. Second, efficiency wage considerations provide a coherent explanation of sectoral real wage rigidity in an open economy as well as a logical framework for examining “spillover” effects that take place across markets. Accounting for alternative opportunities available to workers is crucial to understanding the interactions between different segments of the labor market and the ultimate effects of macroeconomic policy shocks on the level of unemployment.
References
Akerlof. George A., and Janet yellen, “Introduction,” in Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor Market, ed. by George A. Akerlof and Janet Yellen, Cambridge University Press (Cambridge: 1986).
Beladi, Haraid, and Amar K. Parai, “Sluggish Intersectoral Factor Movements and Alternative Trade Policies,” Southern Economic Journal. Vol. 59 (April 1993), pp. 760–67.
Bhandari, Jagdeep S., Nadeem Ul Haque, and Stephen J. Turnovsky, “Growth, External Debt, and Sovereign Risk in a Small Open Economy,” Staff Papers (International Monetary Fund), Vol. 37 (June 1990), pp. 388–417.
Brecher, Richard A., “An Efficiency Wage Model with Explicit Monitoring, Unemployment and Welfare in an Open Economy,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 32 (February 1992), pp. 179–91.
Bulow, Jeremy, and Lawrence H. Summers, “A Theory of Dual Labor Markets with Application to Industrial Policy, Discrimination, and Keynesian Unemployment,” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 4 (July 1986), pp. 376–414.
Carmichael, H. Lome, “Efficiency Wage Models of Unemployment,” Economic Inquiry, Vol. 28 (April 1990), pp. 269–95.
Casas, Francisco R., “Imperfect Factor Mobility: A Generalization and Synthesis of Two-Sector Models of International Trade,” Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 17 (November 1984), pp. 747–61.
Corden, W. Max, and Richard Findlay, “Urban Unemployment, Intersectoral Capital Mobility and Development Policy,” Economica, Vol. 42 (February 1975), pp. 59–78.
Copeland, Brian R., “Efficiency Wages in a Ricardian Model of International Trade,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 27 (November 1989), pp. 221–44.
Demekas, Dimitri G., “Labor Market Segmentation in a Two-Sector Model of an Open Economy,” Staff Papers (International Monetary Fund), Vol. 37 (December 1990), pp. 849–64.
Djajic, SLobodan, and Douglas D. Purvis, “Intersectoral Adjustment and the Dynamics of Wages,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archives, Vol. 123 (June 1987), pp. 216–31.
Edwards, Sebastian, “Terras of Trade, Tariffs and Labor Market Adjustment in Developing Countries,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 2 (May 1988), pp. 165–85.
Edwards, Sebastian, and Alejandra Cox Edwards, Monetarism and Liberalization: the Chilean Experiment, Ballinger (Cambridge, Mass.: 1987).
Feenstra, Robert C., “Functional Equivalence between Liquidity Costs and the Utility of Money,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 17 (March 1986), pp. 271–91.
Haley, James, “Theoretical Foundations for Sticky Wages,” Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 4 (April 1990), pp. 115–55.
Harris, John, and Michael P. Todaro, “Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two-Sector Analysis,” American Economic Review, Vol. 60 (March 1970), pp. 126–43.
Hill, John K., and Jose A. Mendez, “Factor Mobility and the General Equilibrium Model of Production,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 15 (August 1983), pp. 19–25.
Klundert, Th. van de, “Wage differentials and Employment in a Two-Sector Model with a Dual Labor Market,” Metroeconomica, Vol. 40 (October 1989), pp. 235–56.
McDonald, Ian, and Robert Solow, “Wages and Employment in a Segmented Labor Market,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 100(November 1985), pp. 1115–141.
Neary, Peter J., “On the Harris-Todaro Model with Intersectoral Mobility,” Economica, Vol. 48 (August 1981), pp. 219–34.
Rosenzweig, Mark, “Labour Markets in Low-Income Countries,” in Hollis Chenery, and T. N. Srinivasan, eds., Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. I, North Holland (Amsterdam: 1988).
Solow, Robert M., “Another Possible Source of Wage Stickiness,” Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 (December 1979), pp. 79–82.
Stiglitz, Joseph E., “Alternative Theories of Wage Determination and Unemployment: the Efficiency Wage Model,” in The Theory and Experience of Economic Development, ed. by Mark Gersovitz et al., Allen and Unwin (London: 1982).
Wilson, John D., “The Optimal Taxation of Internationally Mobile Capital in an Efficiency Wage Model,” in Taxation in the Global Economy, ed. by Assaf Razin and Joel Slerarod, University of Chicago Press (Chicago, 111.: 1990).
We would like to thank, without implication, Joshua Aizenman, Alejandra Cox-Edwards, Dimitri Demekas and Donald Mathieson for helpful discussions and comments on a preliminary draft.
Edwards (1988), for instance, examines the relationships between terms of trade disturbances, import tariffs, and the labor market, under alternative assumptions about wage formation and sectoral labor mobility.
Demekas (1990) provides one of the few studies that attempts to examine the implications of labor market segmentation in a general equilibrium framework. The issues he focuses on are, however, substantially different from those considered here.
The source of wage rigidity in the traded goods sector is left deliberately unspecified. A common rationale is the existence of a minimum wage imposed by government fiat, which typically covers only the manufacturing sector in developing countries. An alternative rationale, based on efficiency considerations, is provided in the model presented below.
In turn, the expected wage in the traded goods sector is defined as the product of the actual wage in that sector times the probability of being hired, which is measured by the employment ratio. A similar formulation has been used by Neary (1981), Demekas (1990) and Edwards (1988), among others, in a multi-sector open economy framework.
We abstract from induced effects of the shock on nontraded goods prices and, for simplicity, assume that the position of the curve
Note that the existence of unemployement in the situation depicted in figure 3 may be a short-run phenomenon only; if labor can adjust over time, the long-run outcome might be similar to what obtains in Figure 2.
There is now a voluminous literature in developed countries that views involuntary unemployment as the result of productivity-linked or efficiency wages. See Akerlof and Yellen (1986), Haley (1990) and, for a more critical view, Carmichael (1990). Two-sector efficiency wage models have been developed by Bulow and Summers (1986), Brecher (1992), Copeland (1989), McDonald and Solow (1985), Wilson (1990) and van der Klundert (1991). In Brecher's model, unemployment emerges because wages in all sectors of the economy are set on the basis of efficiency considerations.
This formulation captures the existence of a “country risk” associated with a small, developing economy, and is conceptually similar to the approach used in the literature on sovereign debt risk. See, for instance, Bhandari, Haque, and Turnovsky (1990).
Except otherwise indicated, partial derivatives are denoted by corresponding lower-case letters, while the total derivatives of a function of a single argument are denoted by primes.
Strictly speaking, firms in the traded goods sector set wages on the basis of the expected behavior of wages in the nontraded goods sector. However, since the model assumes perfect foresight, for simplicity we do not distinguish between actual and anticipated values.
A sufficient condition for h' > 0 is
Since the model is cast in continuous time, the adjustment process described below should be viewed as continuous rather than discrete.
An alternative formulation would be to introduce money directly in the instantaneous utility function (14), or to specify a transactions technology whereby holding money reduces transactions costs. Feenstra (1986) discusses the conditions under which these different approaches are functionally equivalent.
This implies that the central bank does not offset capital gains or losses on its foreign assets by changing the stock of credit to the government.
Equivalently, equation (25) can be interpreted as indicating that government spending on nontraded goods and net transfers to households minus interest income on reserves must be financed by the inflation tax. This assumption eliminates Ponzi games.
Note that since the equilibrium values of wages in the traded and nontraded sectors have been substituted out, equation (29) imposes simultaneously equilibrium in the markets for labor and nontraded goods.
Assuming that
The determinant of the coefficient matrix in equation (32) is equal to
Note that if
The real depreciation reduces the real wage (measured in terms of traded goods) in the nontraded goods sector, which has a positive effect on output. However, as assumed above, the direct effect of a change in the real exchange rate is assumed to dominate the indirect effect, so that the net impact of a real depreciation on output of nontraded goods and the demand for labor in that sector is negative.
Trade models with imperfect factor mobility have been developed by a number of authors, including Beladi and Parai (1993), Casas (1984), and Hill and Mendez (1983). Note that in the model developed above, perfect mobility of labor in the long run is not sufficient to establish the equality between sectoral wage rates.
The analysis could be extended to consider the possibility of wage inertia in the secondary sector, and therefore the possibility of generalized excess labor supply in the economy. The assumption of flexible wages in the nontraded goods sector appears, however, more in line with the evidence available for developing countries.
The absence of a forward-looking component in wage expectations may be justified by the existence of large costs associated with search, and by the lack of sophistication of the labor force.
Note that, since
The first condition is also necessary, and requires that
Under the above assumptions on