Price and Volume Effects of a Devaluation in Developing Countries
Author:
Mr. Arend Kouwenaar
Search for other papers by Mr. Arend Kouwenaar in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

The IMF Working Papers series is designed to make IMF staff research available to a wide audience. Almost 300 Working Papers are released each year, covering a wide range of theoretical and analytical topics, including balance of payments, monetary and fiscal issues, global liquidity, and national and international economic developments.

Abstract

The IMF Working Papers series is designed to make IMF staff research available to a wide audience. Almost 300 Working Papers are released each year, covering a wide range of theoretical and analytical topics, including balance of payments, monetary and fiscal issues, global liquidity, and national and international economic developments.

I. Introduction

The theoretical literature on the relationship between the nominal exchange rate and domestic prices has emphasized that devaluation per se cannot permanently change the equilibrium real exchange rate, defined as the price ratio of tradable goods versus domestic goods consistent with external and internal equilibrium. It can only produce a temporary deviation of the actual real exchange rate from its equilibrium level. Under conditions of price and wage flexibility (and hence equilibrium in labor and domestic goods markets), a real exchange rate appreciation and external resource balance disequilibrium occur when there is excess domestic spending fed by bank or foreign borrowing, typically on the side of the government. For example, government deficit spending in part Leaks away directly in the form of higher imports, and in part drives up prices of domestic goods and thus raises import demand indirectly. Under these circumstances, the appreciation and resource balance disequilibrium, unsustainable for a given amount of reserves, can only be corrected by removing their cause, i.e., excess demand; a nominal devaluation can speed up the process of attaining equilibrium, but cannot have long-term real output effects (Edwards (1988); Khan and Lizondo (1987)). 1/

On the other hand, under conditions of nominal wage and price rigidity and less than full employment, a nominal devaluation can be instrumental in reducing the real wage, can shift the price ratio of tradable goods versus domestic goods toward its equilibrium level, and can have real output effects (Dornbusch (1974)). In the same vein, a devaluation can facilitate reductions in real government expenditure and increases in real government revenue, and thereby eliminate a cause of external disequilibrium, while avoiding the contractionary effect of deficit reduction.

The conclusion from the literature on the real exchange rate is that fiscal policies and the behavior of the nominal wage rate under a devaluation are crucial for the effects on real variables. Predicting these effects in practice minimally requires specifying the supply and demand relationships for tradable goods and domestic goods, the functioning of the labor market, the level of aggregate demand, and the fiscal policy stance.

In this paper a simple model is constructed to assess the medium-term effects on domestic price and output levels of a devaluation in developing countries. The formation of the wage rate and the stance of fiscal policies under a devaluation are critical for the outcome of the “pass-through” process, which is described by a simple dependent-economy model. The insertion of a few key parameters, available for most countries, into the reduced form of the model permits a quick and easy quantification of both price and volume effects. It also allows an examination of the sensitivity of the results to changes in key elasticities, wages, and aggregate demand and tax policies.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section II briefly reviews some empirical studies of the price impact of a devaluation. Section III presents the basic model and highlights the main policy instruments. Section IV considers empirical applications of the model; it shows simulations of exchange rate and accompanying tax, wage, and other policies under various assumptions for five African countries. 2/ Section V uses the model to estimate the degree of overvaluation of the real exchange rate vis-à-vis the equilibrium real exchange rate, that is, the rate consistent with external and internal equilibrium. Conclusions are presented in Section VI.

II. Empirical Studies of the Price Impact of a Devaluation

Empirical studies of the impact of a nominal devaluation on the domestic price level or the real exchange rate, 3/ are relatively few. They have focused on estimating a reduced-form equation explaining a domestic price or real exchange rate variable by the nominal exchange rate and a set of other structural and aggregate demand variables, such as terms of trade, foreign capital inflows, the government deficit, and domestic credit growth.

Edwards (1988 and 1989), using pooled time-series data for 12 developing countries, found that the nominal exchange rate, an excess demand variable (government deficit or credit supply), and the terms of trade had significant effects on the real exchange rate. From the estimated long-term elasticity of the real exchange rate with respect to the nominal exchange rate of about 0.6, he concludes that “…nominal devaluations can indeed be a quite powerful device to re-establish real exchange rate equilibrium […provided] that the sources of the original disequilibrium […] are eliminated.” (Edwards (1988, p. 338)). Greene (1989), in a study of African countries for the 1978-88 period, also found a significant effect of the nominal exchange rate on the consumer price index (CPI) in an equation controlling for the money stock and the government deficit. 4/ In another study, Canetti and Greene (1991) analyzed inflation in ten African countries for the 1978-85 period and found that exchange rate depreciation and monetary growth cause inflation, but suggested that a measure of overall macroeconomic policy stance as well as structural bottlenecks might be more important determinants of inflation in African countries.

Chhibber (1990) analyzed the pass-through coefficient of the nominal exchange rate in the domestic CPI for Ghana (1965-88) and Zimbabwe (1969-86). Controlling for real money supply, real GDP, unit Labor costs (for Zimbabwe only), and the nominal interest rate on six-month deposits, he found long-term elasticities of the CPI vis-à-vis the nominal exchange rate of 0.40 for Ghana 5/ and 0.14 for Zimbabwe. An unpublished Fund study for Mexico, using quarterly data for 1980-88, found an elasticity of domestic prices vis-à-vis the nominal exchange rate of 0.30, when controlling for the minimum wage and government interest payments.

The problems with this type of reduced-form estimates are simultaneity and correlation between independent variables. Moreover, the estimated coefficients do not usually permit a determination of the values of the parameters of underlying structural relationships, such as export supply, import demand, and labor demand and supply, or of government policy responses such as government fiscal and credit policies. Therefore, the coefficients will usually reflect a combination of parameter values, the impact of government policies, and the implicit wage rate determination. 6/ Given the method of the cited empirical studies, the domestic inflation attributed to the nominal exchange rate impulse can reflect completely different underlying transmission channels, depending on how (import and wage) cost increases affect supply, how real income and relative prices affect the demand for domestic goods, and how the government spends and sets tax rates under the devaluation.

As a result of country differences in both economic structure and policies, the devaluation experiences also vary widely between countries and the reduced-form estimates obtained from cross-country and time-series studies seem to be of limited use for other cases. In order to fully capture all the economic interactions determining the price effect of a devaluation, one would have to estimate a fully specified model based on plausible behavioral relationships, which, given data and time constraints, is often impractical. Instead, one can use available empirical evidence on key elasticities, and a priori knowledge about some other parameters to numerically evaluate the price and other effects of a devaluation, while specifying the assumptions about accompanying government, policies, the wage rate determination, and remaining parameter values. 7/ This practical approach is followed here with the help of a simple two-sector model.

III. The Model

This model is a simple version of the real exchange rate model developed recently by Edwards (1988), with the main simplification being the use of a consumption function that does not incorporate financial assets or intertemporal considerations. This could be justified by the lack of quantified knowledge on portfolio behavior in African countries. The model focuses on assessing the impact of exchange rate, tax, aggregate demand, and wage policies on the domestic price level and the actual real exchange rate. The model also addresses the issue of determining the equilibrium real exchange rate and its response to altered domestic policies and exogenous shocks. 8/ In assessing output effects, the model incorporates some features of recent, essentially Keynesian, models of a contractionary devaluation. 9/ However, while allowing for disequilibrium in the labor market and a devaluation-induced fall in real wages, the model is essentially neoclassical in that prices of domestic goods are determined by supply and demand (allowing for substitution in both) and not by a fixed markup on costs, as assumed in those Keynesian models.

Aggregate demand, a key variable in the trade-off between price and volume effects, has only two components in our simplified approach. Private consumption demand is specified as a function of disposable household income alone; all other domestic demand is considered to be the main policy instrument, under control of the government through its own expenditure and credit and other policies. The mechanisms through which the government affects private investment remain implicit. 10/ Monetary policy is assumed to be accommodating, i.e., consistent with the targeted level of domestic demand and the projected real growth and inflation rates.

The economy produces two goods—exportable goods and domestic goods—and imports a third, which is an imperfect substitute for domestic goods. Outputs in the sectors of exportables and domestic goods are produced with fixed (and immobile) capital, homogeneous (and mobile) labor, and imported inputs. Domestic goods output includes both nontradables and import substitutes and the supply elasticity represents the average for all domestic goods, ranging from nontradables to perfect import substitutes. 11/ Using a standard approach (such as nested, two-level CES functions), one derives the supply of exports (E) and domestic goods (X) as a function of output prices (PE and PD), the wage rate (W), and import costs (PM):

Output

( 1 ) E = E [ P E / c 1 ( W , PM ) ] ϵ E
( 2 ) X = X [ P D / c 2 ( W, PM ) ] ε X

where the superscript o indicates base-year values, ci (W, PM) denote cost functions, and εE and εX are supply elasticities vis-à-vis price/cost ratios. 12/

Demand for labor (LD) is determined simultaneously with the output decisions by labor productivity functions of output prices and the wage rate:

Labor demand

( 3 ) L D = 1 E ( P E / W ) σ 1 + 2 X ( P D / W ) σ 2

where ℓi, represents base-year unit labor costs and σi elasticity of substitution between capital and labor. 13/

For the supply of labor (LS) we use two alternative specifications: (a) a nonnegative function of the real wage (RW) for the case of labor market equilibrium with an endogenous real wage; and (b) perfectly elastic supply for the case of an exogenously given real wage:

Labor supply

( 4 a ) L S = L S ( R W ) ω

or:

( 4 b ) R W = R W ¯ = C P I ν 1 R W

where RW = W/CPI represents the real wage index and ω the labor supply elasticity. For the second alternative, the real wage is conveniently set by choosing a CPI correction factor or pass-through (ν). 14/

Prices of tradable goods and imported input costs are given in foreign currency terms, i.e., we make the small country assumption. Prices in domestic currency terms, defined as indexes vis-à-vis the base year are as follows:

Prices

( 5 a ) P E = PE ¯ NER TE price index of exportable goods
( 5 b ) P E = PE ¯ NER TM price index of imports
( 5 c ) W = RW CPI nominal wage index
( 5 d ) CPI = f c ( PD, PM, θ ) consumer price index
( 5 e ) P G = f g ( PD, PM, η ) other demand deflator
( 5 f ) P = f ( PD, PM, ζ ) total domestic demand deflator
( 5 g ) RER = f e ( PE ¯ , PM ¯ ) NER/PD real exchange rate

where NER indicates nominal exchange rate index, PE and PM denote (given) world price indices, TE and TM are indices of export and import tax factors (i.e., TE=(1te)/(1te)

and TM=(1+tm)/(1+tm) with te and tm implicit trade tax rates), and RER indicates real exchange rate. 15/ The base-year shares of domestic goods in private consumption (θ), in other demand (η), and in total domestic demand (ζ) are parameters in CES aggregates of domestic and import prices. 16/

Household income (Y) is the sum of sectoral value added after trade taxes and the government wage bill. Government wages (WC) are partially corrected for the devaluation-induced CPI increase reflected in a policy-controlled pass-through coefficient (ρ):

Income

( 6 ) Y = E PE ν 1 + X PD ν 2 + W G C P I

where ρ is the inflation correction for government wages and ν1, ν2 represent value-added shares in output, which for simplicity are assumed to be constant. 17/

Private consumption (C) is a function of disposable household income alone; real wealth and portfolio decisions only come in through changes in the average propensity to consume (C), which could depend on the level of real wealth, the interest rate, and specific savings policies. 18/ Domestic tax—direct and indirect—is expressed as a proportion of household income:

Private consumption

( 7 ) C = C ¯ Y T D

where TD = 1-td tax factor, with td being the ratio of net domestic taxes and transfers over household income. 19/

Other domestic demand (G) consists of government spending on goods and nonfactor services and private investment. For our purposes, this variable is set exogenously, reflecting the stance of aggregate demand policies; we abstract from private investment responses to changing profits, profit expectations, and interest rates, as well as from responses of government spending to the altered fiscal situation. 20/ To facilitate analysis, the policy instrument used here is the pass-through coefficient (ξ) for the devaluation-induced price increase of this expenditure category:

Other demand

( 8 ) C = G O P G ξ

where ξ represents the inflation correction for “other demand” and PG is the deflator for “other demand” from equation (5e).

Private consumption and other demand are allocated to domestic goods (including import substitutes) and imports according to a CES aggregation of imported and domestic goods from which the share of imports (μ) in domestic demand (D) derives as a function of relative prices:

Import share

( 9 ) D = C + G
( 10 ) μ = μ O [ P M / P ] ε M
( 11 ) D D = ( 1 μ ) D

where εM = 1 – σM is the price elasticity of import share in domestic demand and σM is the import substitution elasticity (>0). 21/

The stance of fiscal policy, seen as an important cause of resource balance deficit and RER appreciation, is likely to change as a result of changes in tax rates and in government spending on wages and goods and nonfactor services that accompany a devaluation; the larger the fall in the government deficit under a devaluation, the lower the inflationary impact. Since we focus on the price and volume effects of a devaluation, the size of the primary government deficit, but not its financing, is relevant here. Implicitly, the net foreign resource transfer (net borrowing minus interests) closes the investment-saving gap.

Equilibrium requires domestic demand for domestic goods (DD) and labor demand to equal supply of domestic goods and labor supply, respectively: 22/

Equi1ibrium

( 12 ) D D = X PD
( 13 ) LD = LS

The model equations in linearized form are described in Appendix I. The main endogenous variables are the price of domestic goods, the outputs of exportable and domestic goods, the real wage rate (under the first labor market closure), and imports. The main policy instruments are the nominal exchange rate, implicit tax rates, the real wage rate (under the second labor market closure), and the pass-through coefficients for government wages and “other demand” determining their changes in real terms. 23/ The nominal exchange rate acts as an indirect instrument to reduce real wages and the real government deficit when nominal wages and government expenditure are downwardly rigid. Key behavioral parameters, reflecting responses in the medium term (about five years), are the supply elasticities in the export and domestic goods sectors, the substitution elasticity of import demand, and the substitution elasticities between labor and other factors of production (under the first labor market closure). The structure of the economy is reflected in a set of value-added, demand, and import shares for the base year.

The model in linearized form is easily solved and permits a quick assessment of the medium-term price and volume effects of policy shocks after a new equilibrium is attained, i.e., when the lags in supply and demand responses—not modeled here—have worked out. The short-term effects and the time path to the new equilibrium are outside the scope of this analysis. The problem with linearization is that for large shocks it involves non-negligible errors, and in particular it over-estimates price, and underestimates volume, effects. 24/ This is sometimes neglected in the empirical literature that presents simulation results for linearized models. The shortcomings of the absence of lags and linearization can only be resolved by a dynamic nonlinear model. As a shortcut alternative, we have devised a method 25/ to reduce the linearization error, while maintaining the simplicity of the linearized model.

IV. Effects of a Devaluation: Simulation Exercises

To examine the price and volume response to a nominal devaluation under various accompanying policies, we assign realistic values to the model parameters for five African countries, based on the characteristics of their economies in 1989-90 and elasticity estimates from the empirical literature (Tables 1 and 2). The key parameters reflect the economic structure and vary greatly between countries. The shares of domestic goods in private consumption (Θ) vary between 80 percent and 90 percent, while for other (investment and government) demand (η) these figures are 60 percent and 80 percent. The shares of private consumption in total domestic demand (δ) range between 70 percent and 85 percent; a large share implies that the government cannot easily influence aggregate demand through its expenditure and credit policies. The shares of imported input costs determine the cost-push effect of a devaluation on the supply of goods. Firm data are unavailable for most countries in the sample, but estimates indicate that import costs represent between 8 percent and 15 percent of the value of production, and wage costs between 25 percent and 30 percent for both the export and domestic goods sectors. Mineral export sectors typically use substantial imported goods and services.

Table 1.

Structural Characteristics and Key Elasticities of Five African Economies

article image
Sources: Recent national accounts; and staff estimates.

Domestic final demand excluding government wage bill; the complement is import final demand.

Total value added at current market prices, excluding import taxes.

Import costs are the costs of intermediate imported goods, directly or indirectly used in the sector.

Other taxes net of domestic subsidies, transfers, and interest payments.

Excluding foreign interest payments and transfers.

Table 2.

Survey of Empirical Estimates of Price Elasticities

article image
Sources: Balassa, B., “Incentive Policies and Export Performance in Sub-Saharan Africa,” World Development (Oxford), Vol. 18 (March 1990), pp. 383-391. Behresn, J.R., International Commodity Agreements: An Evaluation of the UNCTAD Intergrated Commodity Programe (Washington: Overseas Development Council, October 1977). Bond, M.E., “Agricultural Responses to Prices in Sub-Sahnran African Countries,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 30 (December 1933), pp. 703-726. Bond, M.E., “An Econometric Study of Primary Commodity Exports from Developing Country Regions to the World,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 34 (June 19S7), pp. 191-227. Dervis, K., J. de Melo, and S. Robinson, General Equilibrium Models for Development Policy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982). DeRosn, D.A., “Protection and Export Performace in Sun-saharan Africa,” IMF Working Paper Wp/90/83, (Washington: IMF, 1990). Devarajan, S., and J. de Melo, “Adjusment with Fixed Exchange Rate: Cameroon, Gote d’lvoire, and Senegal.” The World Bank Economic Review (Washington), Vol. 1 (May 1987), pp. 447-587. Naque, N.D., K. Lahlri, and P.J. Montiel, “A Macroeconometric Model for Developing Countries” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 37 (September 1990), pp. 537-559. Khan, M.S., and CM. Reinhart, “Relative Price Responsiveness of Foreign Trade in Developing Countries,” (Unpublished: Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990). World Bank, Accelerated Development in Sub-Saharan Africa: An Agenda for Action (New York: Oxford University Press, 1981).

The export supply elasticities are long terms and defined with respect to the ratio of the export price in domestic currency and a deflator for domestic costs, commonly the CPI.

De Vries (1975) and World Bank (1981) reproduced in Bond (1983).

Askari and Currdngs (1977) reproduced in Bond (1987).

Behrman (1977).

Ford (1971) reproduced in Bond (1983).

Batemsn (1965) reproduced in Bond (1983).

Beherman (1968) reproduced in Bond (1933).

Oni (1969) and (1973) reproduced in Bond (1983).

Olayide (1972) reproduced in Bond (1983).

Balasen (1990), export-output ratio with respect to real exchange rate, period 1965-82, 16 countries.

Bond (1983).

Average calculated by Bond (1987).

World Bank: estimate.

UNCTAD (1974) reproduced in Bond (1987).

Arize (1986), reproduced in DeRosa (1990).

Shapouri and Rosen (1989), reproduced in DeRoea (1990).

Khan and Reinhart (1991), calculated compensated price elasticity of import demand.

Haque et al. (1990).

Based on Devarajan and De Melo (1987), and Dervis et al. (1982).

The elasticities of export supply with respect to the price-cost ratio (εE) are weighted averages of commodity-specific—sometimes country-specific—estimates from the empirical literature (Table 2). 26/ The country averages shown in Table 1 vary from less than 0.1 for mineral exporting countries to 0.8 for countries with manufactured exports or price-responsive agricultural products, such as cotton and livestock. The elasticities for the supply of domestic goods (εX) have been given plausible values near 1.0.

The balance of exports and imports of goods and nonfactor services varies from a deficit of 10 percent of GDP for countries that are highly dependent on imports and foreign aid, to a surplus of 15 percent of GDP for oil exporters. A further structural characteristic is the base-year composition of the government primary deficit in terms of tax and expenditure categories (Table 1).

The policy shocks examined in this section are meant to illustrate the method and not to reflect actual policy measures in the countries. They are (1) a 33 percent devaluation in domestic currency terms; (2) a change in average import and export tax factors; 27/ (3) a nominal wage policy which allows a reduction in the private sector real wage of about 10 percent; (4) a reduction in the real government wage bill of about 15 percent; and (5) a modest change in real nonconsumption expenditure on goods and services (government and investment).

Below, we report on three types of simulation exercises with numerical examples for each. The first exercise assumes an exogenously given reduction in the private sector real wage, i.e., the second labor market closure. It derives the analytical solution for the domestic price increase and examines the properties of the multiplier with respect to the nominal exchange rate change. The second exercise is done for both exogenous and endogenous real wages. It calculates the solution for all the endogenous variables, in particular domestic price level, sectoral outputs, and disposable income, using the linearized model. The third exercise, done for the second labor market closure, is an attempt to partly overcome the error made in using the linearized model.

1. The reduced-form multiplier for domestic prices, linearized model

In this exercise, we assume the labor market is in disequilibrium, and the real wage is determined by a pass-through coefficient for the CPI. The reduced-form multiplier for the domestic price level vis-à-vis the nominal exchange rate can then be expressed as a function of behavioral parameters and the inflation pass-through coefficients for private wages, the government wage bill, and “other demand”, reflecting realistic aggregate demand policies (equations (4b), (6) and (8)). This “black box” of the pass-through process is mathematically opened in Appendix II. 28/

The overall effect of a nominal devaluation (ner), and changes in trade tax rates (tm and te) is written as: pd = Φ1 ner + Φ2 tm + Φ3 te where Φi(ν, ξ, ρ, par.) denote functions of pass-through coefficients ν, ξ, ρ and other parameters in the linearized model. Table 3 shows the inflationary effects of a 33 percent parity change after response lags have worked out and a new equilibrium is attained.

Table 3.

Inflationary Impact of a Devaluation in Five African Countries: Reduced Form Linearized Model

article image

The impact on all variables is based on linearized expressions.

In domestic currency terms. Defined as the nominal exchange rate index over the domestic price index (NER/PD). The real exchange rate depreciation for the nonlinearized expression is shown in parentheses.

For realistic parameter values, a reduction in the real wage of some 10 percent, a cut in real “other demand” of about 1 percent, and small changes in trade tax rates, the impact of a 33 percent devaluation on prices of domestic goods is between 10 percent and 23 percent, depending on the country characteristics, whereas the CPI increases by 13-24 percent. The resulting improvement in the real exchange rate lies between 10 percent and 23 percent.

The reduced-form multiplier for the effect of the nominal exchange rate on domestic goods prices (Φ1) takes values between 0.4 and 0.7, i.e., domestic prices rise by 4-7 percent under a 10 percent devaluation. This result depends on the country’s structural characteristics, in particular, the import content in demand, the share of the export sector in value added and the pass-through of price increases into “other demand.” The reduced-form multiplier for the import tax rate Φ2 generally varies between 0.02 and 0.20, implying that a 10 percent reduction of the tax factor, or a 40 percent reduction of an average rate of 33 percent, reduces the domestic price level by between 0.2 percent and 2 percent. This multiplier takes negative values in cases when the income effects dominate the cost effects. The reduced-form multiplier for the effect of the export tax rate takes values between minus 0.2 and minus 0.6, reflecting the deflationary impact when devaluation-induced income gains are removed through taxation.

The sensitivity of the reduced-form multipliers with respect to the pass-through coefficients and structural parameters is explored next, with the help of the point derivatives of the nominal exchange rate multiplier (Φ1), also shown in Table 3. For example, if the pass-through coefficient for the nominal wage (ν) rises from 50 percent to 60 percent (compensation for the CPI increase), the nominal exchange rate multiplier increases by between 0.03 and 0.04, i.e., an additional domestic price increase of between 0.3 and 0.4 percentage point for a 10 percent devaluation. If the “other demand” pass-through coefficient rises from 90 percent to 100 percent (compensation for the demand deflator), the nominal exchange rate multiplier increases by between 0.03 and 0.04, i.e., between 0.3 to 0.4 percentage point is added to the domestic price increase under a 10 percent devaluation.

The multiplier is, for the given constellation of parameters, a positive function of the share of the export sector in value added and the share of consumption in domestic demand, both reflecting the income effects on domestic prices. The multiplier increases as the substitut-ability between domestic and imported goods improves (i.e., the elasticity of the import share in domestic demand takes a lower value), because demand shifts from imported to domestic goods. This is reflected in values of the derivative (∂ϕ1/∂εM) between minus 0.1 and minus 0.2. The multiplier is sensitive to the import share in domestic demand; for given pass-through coefficients, a 10 percentage points higher share of imports increases the multiplier by between 0.01 and 0.04, i.e., between 0.1 and 0.4 percentage points is added to the domestic price increase under a 10 percent devaluation. This somewhat counterintuitive result is explained by the stronger cost-push effect of nominal wages, which are adjusted for the stronger CPI increase, as well as by the bigger substitution possibilities when the import share is larger.

The point derivative of the multiplier vis-à-vis the supply elasticity of domestic goods production is relatively small, i.e., about minus 0.10, in most cases. Since part of the improved production response is matched by higher demand through income effects, an increase in the elasticity from 1.0 to 1.1 reduces the domestic price by 0.1 percentage point under a 10 percent devaluation.

The model has the property that, when real wages, real “other demand,” and tax rates are kept constant, a devaluation is neutral, i.e., has no volume effects and leaves the RER unchanged. An inflexible real wage is relevant in situations where the labor market is in equilibrium or the labor unions are strong. Simulating this case by setting all pass-through coefficients equal to unity, and assuming no changes in tax rates, gives the expected outcome, namely a unit multiplier and absence of any output effect, which result is independent of all other parameter values. 29/

2. Effects on prices, volumes, and income: solution of linearized model

a. Exogenous real wage

The second exercise involves the solution of the full linearized model (Table 4). We first maintain the assumption of an exogenous real wage (labor market in disequilibrium). 30/ The impact on domestic prices is the same as in the first exercise, i.e., between 10 percent and 23 percent, since the underlying models are identical. Real output growth varies between 0 percent and 13 percent for exports, and between 1 percent and 6 percent for domestic goods, depending in particular on supply elasticities and the pass-through assumptions for “other demand.” The output increase in the domestic goods sector is less strong than that in the export sector owing to a lower real wage reduction in terms of the output price somewhat offset by a higher supply elasticity. Real disposable income (when deflated by the CPI) rises by 0-7 percent. The import share in domestic final demand rises by 1-9 percent in most cases, reflecting the combined effect of an increase in import prices in domestic currency of about 30 percent and a reduction in import volumes, owing to substitution, of 20-29 percent.

Table 4.

Price, Volume, and Income Effects of a Devaluation in Five African Countries: Solution Linearized Model, Exogenous Real Wage

article image

After import tax; in domestic currency.

The real exchange rate depreciation for the nonlinearized expression is shown in parentheses.

Sectoral value added after trade taxes, before nontrade taxes; including government wage bill.

Increase (+), in percentage points, in the surplus in foreign currency at base-year exchange rate over base-year GDP.

Increase (+), in percentage points, in the government surplus in foreign currency at base-year exchange rate over base-year GDP.

Increase (+), in percentage points, in the government surplus/GDP ratio in current prices.

Shortcut measures of the impact on the external resource balance and government primary balance, 31/ measured in foreign currency at base-year exchange rate in terms of base-year GDP, show improvements of 1-3 percentage points and 0.6-5 percentage points, respectively. The improvement in the resource balance is highest in countries where price responses in foreign trade are high and the supply response in nontrad-able goods is not so large as to generate high income effects on imports. The improvement in the government primary balance is high in countries where the increase in the implicit export tax rate is large, and there is a substantial drop in real government expenditure on goods and services.

It is interesting to examine the reduced-form coefficients of the full model. To this end we reformulate the model slightly, by making the real growth rates of the private wage, the government wage bill, and “other demand” explicit policy instruments, i.e., we no longer use inflation pass-through coefficients. We then linearize the 12 equations in these and the other exogenous variables. Despite the model’s simplicity, the (12x8) matrix of reduced-form coefficients is a complicated function of many parameters and hard to interpret analytically. We therefore look at the numerical solution of the reduced-form matrices for Kenya and Ghana. The results in Appendix I, Table 1 show that the nominal exchange rate has a unit impact on all nominal variables, reflecting the linear homogeneity of the model. The real wage and real “other demand” appear to be the most powerful instruments through which the potentially inflationary impact of a devaluation can be mitigated, although they have opposite effects on output of domestic goods. Furthermore, lowering import tax rates reduces inflation and increases output in both sectors, whereas increasing domestic tax rates reduces both inflation and output in the nontradables sector, but increases exports. Raising export tax rates strongly reduces inflation, but affects both exports and nontradable output negatively.

The reduced form allows a decomposition of the domestic price effect, as illustrated in Table 5. The reduced-form impact on domestic prices of a 10 percent real wage reduction is between 7 percent and 10 percent and that of a 10 percent reduction in real “other demand” is between 7 percent and 8 percent. Similarly, 10 percent reductions of the import and export tax factors reduce domestic prices by 1-5 percent, and 5-9 percent, respectively.

Table 5.

Reduced-Form Multipliers for the Domestic Price Levelin Two African Countries

article image

b. Endogenous real wage

We next examine the alternative labor market closure, where an endogenous real wage equilibrates supply and demand in the labor market. The supply elasticity of labor with respect to the real wage has been set at 0.10 in all cases. As this simulation requires specifying labor demand functions (equation 3), we set the substitution elasticities and base-year employment shares at plausible values. 32/ The results are shown in Table 6. As the real wage cannot decrease without a loss of labor supply, real output in the export sector can only grow at the expense of employment (and hence output) in the non-tradables sector. The reduced-form multiplier is over 60 percent, i.e., a 33 percent devaluation raises domestic prices by 19-29 percent. With equilibrium maintained in the labor market, the real effect of the devaluation is entirely due to the change in tax rates and the less than full pass-through for government wages and “other demand.” For initial labor market equilibrium and positive labor supply elasticity, a devaluation accompanied by a reduction in the government deficit is contractionary, i.e., the reduction of real demand leads to a fall in output of domestic goods, which is only partly compensated by a rise in the export sector. The fall in total labor demand drives down the real wage. It is the devaluation-induced reduction in the deficit that achieves a shift in relative prices in favor of exports, and away from imports, as well as a fall in real income, thereby improving the external balance. Under these circumstances, the devaluation is highly inflationary and reduces total output and employment, but can still be instrumental in reducing real government expenditure and raising export taxes. When the labor supply elasticity is zero, total employment is constant, but output shifts toward exports only if the devaluation is accompanied by a reduction in the government deficit. Otherwise, domestic prices will rise at the same rate as the exchange rate, as will nominal wages, thereby keeping the real wage constant. 33/

Table 6.

Price, Volume, and Income Effects of a Devaluation In Five African Countries: Solution Linearized Model, Endogenous Real Wage

article image

After import tax; in domestic currency.

The real exchange rate depreciation for the nonlinearized expression is shown in parentheses.

Sectoral value added after trade taxes, before nontrade taxes; including government wage bill.

Increase (+), in percentage points, in the surplus in foreign currency at base-year exchange rate over base-year GDP.

Increase (+), in percentage points, in the government surplus in foreign currency at base-year exchange rate over base-year GDP.

Increase (+), in percentage points, in the government surplus/GDP ratio in current prices.

3. Effects on prices, volumes, and income: approximate solution of nonlinear model

The objective of this third exercise is to reduce the error involved in linearization. Although one can only solve this problem by specifying a dynamic nonlinear model, it seems useful to combine an error-approximation method with the analytical simplicity of the linearized model. The method used here, explained in Appendix III, can be characterized as midway between a linearized and a nonlinear model. The results show that linearization overestimates domestic price changes and underestimates most volume changes (Table 7). For the parameter sets used, the impact of a 33 percent devaluation on prices of domestic goods is overestimated by about 2 percentage points in the linearized case, the impact on output of domestic goods is underestimated by about 1 percentage point, and the nominal wage increase is overestimated by some 3 percentage points. The error that is due to linearization obviously becomes much larger when the amount of the devaluation is increased. For example, under a 50 percent devaluation the domestic price and nominal wage increases in Kenya would be, respectively, 35 percent and 26 percent with linearization, as against 32 percent and 20 percent with our alternative method.

Table 7.

Price, Volume, and Income Effects of a Devaluation in One African Country: Reducing the Linearization Error

(Exogenous Real Wage)

article image

Increase (+), in percentage points, in the surplus in foreign currency at base-year exchange rate over base-year GDP.

Increase (+), in percentage points, in the government surplus in foreign currency at base-year exchange rate over base-year GDP.

V. The Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate

The model is used to obtain an estimate of the equilibrium real exchange rate (ERER). We define the ERER as the real exchange rate (RER) which—for a target level of protection and a projected terms of trade—brings the external resource balance to a level that is compatible both with the sustainable level of foreign borrowing and transfers and with internal equilibrium. The latter is defined as the situation in which economic activity is at its potential, or full-employment, level and the government deficit is compatible with the sustainable level of foreign borrowing and transfers. Assuming that—necessarily somewhat subjective—estimates for the sustainable level of foreign borrowing and transfers and the degree of unemployment of resources are available, we simulate real wage and government deficit reduction policies—achieved through a nominal devaluation cum accompanying tax and expenditure policies—that permit the economy to attain both external and internal equilibria. The resulting real exchange rate depreciation is a measure of the degree of initial overvaluation vis-à-vis the ERER. Although the two global policy instruments suffice, in principle, to attain the two targets, the corresponding equilibrium domestic price level, and hence the ERER, depend on the choice of the tax and government expenditure measures. 34/ As a result, this method of measuring RER overvaluation vis-à-vis the ERER is sensitive both to the chosen definitions of external and internal equilibria and to the choice of policy instruments to attain them. 35/

The method is illustrated for the cases of Kenya and Madagascar (Table 8). For each country, we derive the target level of the external resource balance from a target public debt/GDP ratio, the projected interest payments on public debt and private factor payments, and the projected Levels of sustainable public and private transfers. 36/ The target external resource balance is compared with the actual resource balance in the base year after correction for exceptional circumstances in that year. In the same way, we obtain a target for the government primary balance, taking into account the desirable levels of foreign and domestic debt. The target increase in the level of economic activity follows from an analysis of the evolution of real output over the past ten years.

Table 8.

Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate in Two African Countries

article image

In foreign currency at base-year exchange rate in percent of base-year GDP.

Corrected for exceptional circumstances in the base year, such as sale of stocks. Corrected for effects of expected terms of trade change.

Obtained from the target debt/GDP ratio and a nominal GDP growth rate of 7 percent per year.

At present average borrowing conditions for the country.

Reduction in the average tariff rate on imports of goods and nonfactor services.

Increase in implicit export tax rate, defined as government revenue from exports over value of exports of goods and nonfactor services. The increase is achieved by allowing a less than 100 percent pass-through of the nominal exchange rate into producer prices and margins. See footnote 2/ in Appendix I on page 31.

Defined as the nominal exchange rate index over the domestic price index.

Weighted average of output increases in exports and domestic goods sectors.

The illustrative simulations 37/ show that the assumed targets for resource balance, government primary balance, and output could be obtained practically with policy packages, including nominal devaluations, which result in real exchange rate depreciations of 10 percent and 12 percent, respectively, for Kenya and Madagascar.

VI. Conclusions

In this paper we have developed a simple two-sector general equilibrium model for assessing the medium-term effects of a devaluation on domestic price and output levels in developing countries. It focuses on the formation of the wage rate and the stance of fiscal policy as the main determinants of the “pass-through” process. Although the model excludes intertemporal considerations from the household consumption function, and portfolio behavior, its simplicity and minimal parameter requirement make it an easily applicable tool to simulate policy packages including a devaluation.

Empirical studies have focused on estimating a reduced-form equation, which explains the domestic price level by the nominal exchange rate, structural variables such as terms of trade, and aggregate demand variables such as government deficit and credit supply. The main problem with this type of study is that the estimated coefficients will reflect a mixture of (1) the parameters of structural relationships, (2) the levels of policy variables, and (3) the implicit wage rate determination. Since devaluation-inflation pass-through estimates obtained from such studies are in our view of limited use for other cases, we have followed an alternative approach here. This consists in fully specifying a number of structural relationships, assigning estimated or plausible values to key structural and behavioral parameters, and making assumptions on essential policy variables. Data requirements are mainly the price elasticities of supply of exports and domestic goods, price elasticities of import demand, and the base-year structures of value added, domestic demand, and government balance. The solution of the linearized model reflects the medium-term impact of policy shocks, i.e., after lags in supply and demand responses have worked out.

The paper reports on illustrative exercises for a 33 percent devaluation for five African countries, for which data on base-year structural characteristics and key elasticities have been collected. The results strongly depend on the assumptions about the wage formation and the accompanying trade tax and government expenditure policies, and are also sensitive to the structural characteristics and behavioral parameters.

The price effects of a devaluation are most sensitive to what happens to real wages, i.e., to what extent nominal wages are indexed to the CPI. Under the assumption of unemployment and downward rigidity of the nominal wage, a devaluation is a tool to reduce the real wage toward its equilibrium level. For a 10 percent real wage reduction the medium-term impact of a 33 percent devaluation on domestic prices is between 23 percent and 25 percent, depending on country characteristics. Furthermore, a simultaneous reduction in the government real wage bill by 10 percent reduces the price impact by some 2 percentage points, whereas a reduction in the import tax factor and an increase in the export tax factor—by 1 percent each—further mitigate the inflationary effects of a devaluation by about 0.3 percentage point and 0.7 percentage point, respectively. Each percent reduction in real nonwage expenditure (mainly government) contributes to lowering the price increase by about 0.7 percentage point.

With respect to base-year characteristics and elasticities, the results are relatively sensitive to the share of the export sector in value added, the share of imports in domestic demand, and the price elasticity of import demand. The larger the share of the export sector in total value added, the larger the demand-pull effects from devaluation-induced income gains on the domestic price level. The larger the share of imports in demand, the larger the cost-push effect of nominal wages, which are adjusted for the higher CPI index (for a given reduction in the real wage), and the stronger the substitution of domestic for imported goods (for a given price elasticity of import demand). Finally, the higher the price responsiveness of imports, the higher the demand pressure on domestic production.

Real output in the export sector increases—by between 0 percent and 13 percent, depending on supply elasticities—mainly as a result of the reduction in the real wage in terms of the output price corrected for higher export taxation. Real output in the domestic goods sector increases less strongly—by 1-6 percent—owing to a lower reduction in the real wage in terms of the output price, which is somewhat offset by a higher supply elasticity in that sector.

In all countries, the reductions in the real wage and government deficit, combined with relatively conservative estimates of trade elasticities and a modest reduction in real nonconsumption demand, are sufficient to improve the external resource balance by between 1 percent and 3 percent of GDP (at base-year prices) in the medium term.

These results change drastically when the real wage is inflexible, i.e., when the labor market is initially in equilibrium or when labor unions are strong. In this case, the rate of the domestic price increase will tend to be the same as the rate of the devaluation without any output effects; however, when the devaluation induces a reduction in the government deficit, prices of domestic goods rise less quickly than the exchange rate does, resulting in a shift of production from domestic toward exportable goods, while leading to a fall in total labor demand.

In this paper, we have shown that the errors involved in solving the linearized model can be substantial and have developed an alternative shortcut solution procedure, which results in lower price and higher volume effects of a devaluation. Finally, the model is used to estimate the equilibrium real exchange rate, i.e., the rate that brings the external resource balance to a level that is compatible with a sustainable level of net foreign resource transfers and with full employment and a sustainable government deficit. We simulate policy packages aimed at attaining those targets through a devaluation, real wage reduction, and government tax and expenditure policies. The resulting real exchange rate depreciation is an estimate of the initial overvaluation vis-à-vis the equilibrium real exchange rate. Overall, the results of the simulations for five African countries are plausible and stress the crucial role of accompanying policies and key parameters in determining the “pass-through” of the devaluation into domestic prices.

Appendix I: The Linearized Model

Panel A gives the basic model equations in relative change with secondary effects neglected (lower case or dot denotes relative change).

After substituting equations (5a’-5c’) and (5e’-5f’) into the other ones, equation (13’) into (4a’) for the first labor market option, and after dropping equation (13’) for the second labor market option, we obtain a system of 12 linear equations in 12 endogenous variables (e, x, Id, rw, pd, cpi, y, c, g, μ˙, d, dd).

Let B represent the (12x12) coefficient matrix of the endogenous variables, A represent the (12x6) coefficient matrix of the exogenous variables, and y and x be the vectors of endogenous and exogenous variables. The solution is found by y = B–1 A x, where x consists of the relative changes in: nominal exchange rate, import tax factor, export tax factor, average propensity to consume, domestic tax rate, and real wage (only for the second labor market option).

The impact on resource balance and government balance in current prices is written as: 38/

( 14 ) d ( RB/Y ) = β 1 ( 1 + e + n e r ) M o Y o ( 1 + μ ˙ + d ) ( 1 + y ) E o M o Y o
( 15 ) d ( GSUR/Y ) = [ γ 1 ( 1 + tm + ner + m vol ) + γ 2 ( 1 + te + ner + e ) + γ 3 ( td + y ) γ 4 ( 1 + ρ cpi ) γ 5 ( 1 + Ψ + ξ cpi ) ( 1 + y ) ( GSUB o Y o )

where: MoYo,EoMoYo,CSURoYo represent the base-year shares in GDP of imports, the export-import balance, and the government surplus excluding foreign grants and interests, respectively; mvol is the growth rate of import volume; γ1, γ2 γ3 are, respectively, base-year shares in GDP of import tax, export tax, and other net tax and nontax revenue; γ4, γ5, are the base-year shares in GDP of government wage bill and other expenditure on goods and nonfactor services; ψ is the relative change in government share in “other demand”; and tm’, te’, td’ are relative changes in import, export, and domestic tax rates, respectively. 39/

Panel A Equations of the linearized model

( 1 ) e = ε E [ pe α 1 w ( 1 α 1 ) pm ]
( 2 ) x = ε X [ pd α 2 w ( 1 α 2 ) pe ]
( 3 ) ld = λ [ e + σ 1 ( p e w ) ] + ( 1 λ ) [ x + σ 2 ( pd w ) ] 40 /
( 4 ) ls = ω rw
( 4 b ) rw = rw ¯ = ( ν 1 ) cpi
( 5 a ) pe = ner te 41 /
( 5 b ) pm = ner + tm
( 5 c ) w = rw + cpi
( 5 d ) cpi = θ pd + ( 1 θ ) pm
( 5 e ) pg = η pd + ( 1 η ) pm
( 5 f ) p = ζ pd + ( 1 ζ ) pm
( 5 g ) rer = ner - pd
( 6 ) y = β 1 ( e + pe ) + β 2 ( x + pd ) + ( 1 β 1 β 2 ) ρ cpi 42 /
( 7 ) c = c ¯ + y - td
( 8 ) g = ξ pg
( 9 ) d = δ c + (1 - δ ) g
( 10 ) μ ˙ = ε M ( pm - p )
( 11 ) dd = - μ ˙ μ 1 μ + d
( 12 ) dd = x + p d
( 13 ) ld = ls

(σ1 – σ1) (1 – α1) (pm – w) + (σ2 – σ9) (1 – α2) (pm – w), where σi is the substitution elasticity between labor and imported inputs.

Let teo=(PE¯ER - C0)/PE¯ER be the base-year implicit tax rate, with CO representing total costs of producers and intermediators. Let the pass-through of the devaluation into costs be Φc. Then the new implicit tax rate is:

t e = PE ¯ ER ( 1 + er ) CO ( 1 + Φ c er ) PE ¯ ER ( 1 + er ) = ( 1 + er ) ( 1 t e o ) ( 1 + Φ c er ) ( 1 + er )

Note that te=teoforΦc=1, andte=(teo+er)/(1+er)forΦc=0.

vi=(1vi)vi(1vi)where(1vi) are the shares of imported inputs in production, in relative change:

( 1 ˙ v 1 ) = ( σ 1 1 ) ( pe pm ) + ( σ ¯ 1 σ 1 ) α 1 ( pm w )

(1˙v2)=(σ21)(pd pm)+(σ¯2σ2)α2(pm w) for the export and domestic goods sectors, respectively.

Panel B Base year shares and elasticities:

article image
Table 1.

Coefficient Matrix of the Reduced Form of the Linearized Model 1/

article image

The matrix is written as B–1, where B and A coefficient matrices of the endogenous and exogenous variables, respectively.

Appendix II: Derivation of Reduced-Form Multiplier for Domestic Prices 43/

Solving the linearized model of Appendix I through substitution gives the reduced-form multiplier (“black box”) for the nominal exchange rate:

( 1 ) Φ 1 = pd ner = { α 1 δ β 1 ε E ( 1 α 2 ) ( δ β 2 1 ) ε X ζ μ + δ β 1 ν ( 1 θ ) [ α 1 δ β 1 ε E + α 2 ( δ β 2 1 ) E X ] + ρ ( 1 θ ) δ ( 1 β 1 β 2 ) + ξ ( 1 η ) ( 1 δ ) } / { δ β 2 1 } ( ε X + 1 ) + ζ μ ε M ν θ [ α 1 δ β 1 ε E + + α 2 ( δ β 2 1 ) ε X ] + ρ θ δ ( 1 β 1 β 2 ) + ξ η ( 1 δ ) }

Simplified as:

( 2 ) Φ 1 = ( a + b ν + c ρ + d ξ ) ( e + f ν + g ρ + h ξ ) = numberator denominator

Except for very low values for the pass-through coefficients, is positive; it is unity for ν=ρ=ξ=1, i.e., for unchanged real wages and expenditure. For a plausible range of parameter values the signs of the first derivatives of Φ1 take the expected values:

Φ 1 ν > 0 , Φ 1 ρ > 0 , Φ 1 ξ > 0 , Φ 1 ε E > 0 , Φ 1 ε X < 0 ,
Φ 1 ε M < 0 , Φ 1 β 1 > 0 , Φ 1 δ > 0 , Φ 1 ( 1 ζ ) > 0

The reduced-form multipliers for the import and export tax factors are as follows:

( 3 ) Φ 2 = pd tm = [ ( 1 α 1 ) δ β 1 ε E ( 1 α 2 ) ( δ β 2 1 ) ε X ζ μ ε M ] ν ( 1 θ ) [ α 1 δ β 1 ε E + α 2 ( δ β 2 1 ) ε X ] + ρ ( 1 θ ) δ ( 1 β 1 β 2 ) + ξ ( 1 η ) ( 1 δ ) } / denminator
( 4 ) Φ 3 = pd te = δ β 1 ( ε E + 1 ) / denominator

The import tax multiplier can be positive or negative, depending on price, income, and supply effects, and increases with the share of imports in demand. The export tax multiplier is normally negative and quite high, i.e., the removal—through taxation—of some of the income increase in the export sector reduces domestic demand and inflation.

Appendix III: A Method to Reduce the Linearization Error

Let Y and X be vectors of endogenous and exogenous variables in absolute levels, so that f(Y, X) = 0 represents the system of equations that are nonlinear in Y and X. Formulating all variables in relative change (y, x) permits linearization up to a vector of residual terms:

( 1 ) B y = A x + r ( y , x )

where r is the residual term including all multiplicative effects, which are negligible for very small x; and B and A denote coefficient matrices of endogenous and exogenous variables containing base-year shares and parameter values. We assume adjustment takes place in one period, so that the coefficient matrices do not change; as a result this method does not address any error that is due to a nondynamic presentation.

The procedure is to iteratively approximate the residual term by evaluating the multiplicative term r at the values found for y in the previous iteration.

Step 0: Solve system (1) for r° = 0:

( 2 ) y = B 1 A x

Step 1: Evaluate r1 (y, x) for y° and solve system (1)

( 3 ) r 1 = r ( y , x )
( 4 ) y 1 = B 1 A x + B 1 r ( y , x ) = B 1 [ A | r 1 ] [ x 1 ]

This amounts to including a constant term in the exogenous variables ξ and augmenting the matrix A by a column r1, i.e., [A | r1] in equation (4).

The correction in equation (4) is, for any endogenous variable yj, calculated as the difference between the linear solution yio and the nonlinear expression for y¯io (denoted with a bar) from equation (1):

( 3 ) r i 1 = y ¯ i o y i o
where y i o = Σ j B i j 1 Σ k A j k x k solution step 0 y ¯ i o = f ( y j i o , x ) nonlinear equation evaluated for the solution of step 0.

The error term ri1 is included as a constant in the equation for the itn endogenous variable in the next round:

( 4 ) y i 1 = Σ j i B ij y j 1 + Σ k A ik x k + r i 1

Step 2

( 5 ) r 2 = r 1 + ( y ¯ 1 y 1 )
( 6 ) r 2 = B 1 A x + B 1 r 2

where equation (5) adds the calculated difference of the next step to the error term.

The two following examples illustrate that determining the error term, ri, involves calculating either a multiplicative term or the difference between the original nonlinear expression and the linearized form.

Equation (5c) for the nominal wage on page 6 is written in relative changes:

( 5 c ) W = RW CPI
( 5 c ) W = Δ W W = R W C P I [ ( 1 + rw ) ( 1 + cpi ) 1 ] R W CPI
w = ( 1 + rw ) ( 1 + cpi ) 1 = rw + cpi + rw cpi ( 5 c ) w =  rw + cpi

The error in going from (5c”) to the linearized form (5c’), i.e., rw cpi, can be quite large; for example, for rw=-25 percent, cpi=60 percent, the correct nominal wage in (5c’’) is 20 percent whereas (5c’) gives 35 percent.

As a second example, consider equation (5d) for the CPI on page 6, written in relative change:

( 5 d ) CPI = PD θ PM I θ
( 5 d ) cpi = Δ CPI CPI = ( PD θ PM 1 θ ) { ( 1 + pd ) θ ( 1 + pm ) 1 θ 1 } ( PD θ PM 1 θ )
( 5 d ) cpi = θ pd + ( 1 θ ) pm

The error in going from the correct relative change in (5d”) to the linearized form (5d’) is calculated as:

r = ( 1 + pd ) θ ( 1 + pm ) 1 θ 1 θ pd ( 1 θ ) pm

For example, with θ=0.7, pd=40 percent, and pm=100 percent, the error is r=-2.2 percent.

References

  • Canetti, E., and J. Greene,Causes of Inflation in African Countries: An Empirical Analysis,” IMF Working Paper No. WP/91/67 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chhibber, A.,Africa’s Rising Inflation: Causes, Consequences, and Cures,” PRE Working Paper No. 577 (Washington: World Bank, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, R.,Real and Monetary Aspects of the Effects of Exchange Rate Changes,” in National Monetary Policies and the International Financial System, ed. by R.Z. Aliber (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1974), pp. 6481.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, R.,PPP Exchange Rate Rules and Macroeconomic Stability,” Journal of Political Economy (Chicago), Vol. 90 (February 1982), pp. 158165.