Abstract
This paper reviews recent developments in the theoretical and empirical analysis of balance-of-payments crises. A simple analytical model highlighting the process leading to such crises is first developed. The basic framework is then extended to deal with a variety of issues, such as: alternative post-collapse regimes, uncertainty, real sector effects, external borrowing and capital controls, imperfect asset substitutability, sticky prices, and endogenous policy switches. Empirical evidence on the collapse of exchange rate regimes is also examined, and the major implications of the analysis for macroeconomic policy discussed.
I. Introduction
The literature on balance-of-payments crises examines the consequences of incompatible monetary, fiscal and exchange rate policies for the balance of payments of a small open economy. In a seminal paper, Krugman (1979) showed that under a fixed exchange - rate regime, domestic credit creation in excess of money demand growth leads to a gradual loss of reserves, and ultimately to a speculative attack against the currency that forces the abandonment of the fixed exchange rate and the adoption of a flexible rate regime. This attack always occurs before the central bank would have run out of reserves in the absence of speculation.
Krugman’s analysis draws on the Salant and Henderson (1978) model of a stabilization scheme in which the government uses a stockpile of an exhaustible resource to stabilize its price—a policy that eventually ends in a speculative attack in which private agents suddenly acquire the entire remaining government stock. 1/ Due to the nonlinearites involved in his model, however, Krugman was unable to derive explicitly a solution for the time of collapse in a fixed exchange rate regime. Later work by Flood and Garber (1984b) provided an example of how such a solution is derived in a linear model, with or without arbitrary speculative behavior.
A considerable literature has developed in recent years that amended or extended the original Krugman-Flood-Garber insight in various directions: the nature of the post-collapse exchange regime; uncertainty regarding the credit policy rule and the level of reserves that triggers the regime shift; real effects of anticipated crises (on both output and the current account, through the real exchange rate); external borrowing and capital controls (both temporary and permanent); imperfect asset substitutability and sticky prices, and endogenous policy switches. This paper reviews these extensions and advances, highlights their policy implications, and examines areas that may warrant further attention.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section II reviews recent experiences of certain countries — both developed and developing—which faced exchange rate and balance - of-payments crises. Section III sets out a single-good, full-employment, small open-economy model which specifies the basic theoretical framework used for this type of analysis. Section IV examines various extensions of this framework. Section V reviews empirical work, while Section VI examines some recent perspectives for future research. Finally, Section VII draws together the major policy implications of the existing literature for macroeconomic policy under a fixed-exchange rate regime.
II. Recent Experiences with Exchange Rate Crises
Numerous examples of exchange - rate and balance-of-payments crises occurring both in developed and developing countries have been documented in the literature. This section briefly reviews six such recent experiences: those of Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Mexico, France and Italy. 2/, 3/
The Argentine experience has been well documented by several authors recently, including Connolly (1986) and Cumby and van Wijnbergen (1990). In December 1978, the Argentine authorities adopted a stabilization program aimed at containing soaring inflation (in excess of 300 percent annually) and an enormous public sector deficit (amounting to approximately 17 percent of GDP). A key aspect of the program was exchange-rate policy. Specifically, the exchange rate was to follow a pre-announced declining rate of crawl—the now well-known “tablita” experiment. Following a year of success, a series of bank failures in early 1980 touched off a financial crisis. The rate of increase of credit to the financial sector increased sharply in early 1980 thereby undermining confidence in the exchange rate regime. Large and increasing reserve losses coincided with the increase in domestic credit (Figure 1). The loss in confidence was reflected in a sharp increase in interest rates on peso deposits relative to foreign rates adjusted for the announced rate of devaluation. At the same time, the period prior to the collapse was marked by a steep rise in the parallel market premium (beginning in early 1981), very high inflation rates and a sustained appreciation of the real exchange rate (Figure 1). These events were the precursor of the collapse of the crawling peg policy in June 1981 when a dual exchange rate regime was temporarily adopted.

ARGENTINA Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001

ARGENTINA Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
ARGENTINA Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
The Brazilian cruzado crisis occurred in October 1986, some eight months after the Cruzado Plan was launched in February of that year (see Claessens, 1991). The Plan attempted to fix all prices, including the nominal exchange rate. As in other instances, however, domestic credit increased rapidly throughout the pre-collapse period. Through 1986, domestic credit expanded by more than 40 percent while Central Bank foreign reserves again declined at an increasing rate (Figure 2). Net foreign reserves declined by some $5.8 billion during 1986. The Cru2ado Plan was abandoned in October 1986 with a devaluation of the cruzado. The parallel market premium increased steadily from around 30 percent in March 1986 to more than 100 percent in the month preceding the devaluation (Figure 2).

BRAZIL Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001

BRAZIL Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
BRAZIL Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
The Chilean peso crisis occurred in June 1982 and, as in the case of Argentina, may have been precipitated by a series of banking failures (see, for instance, Velasco, 1987). The Central Bank of Chile responded to the failures by sharp increases in the rate of domestic credit creation, which reached nearly 100 percent in the last quarter of 1981. The acceleration of domestic credit expansion coincided with an appreciating real exchange rate and increasing foreign reserve losses by the Central Bank for some months prior to the actual exchange rate collapse on June 15, 1982 (Figure 3). The eroding confidence in the exchange rate regime was reflected in a continually widening spread between spot and forward rates for the Chilean peso as well as a rising parallel market premium prior to the day of collapse.

CHILE Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001

CHILE Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
CHILE Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
The collapse of the Mexican peso which occurred in February 1982 was accompanied by a sharp devaluation of 28 percent against the U.S. dollar. Again, the turbulence in the exchange market was preceded by sharp increases in the rate of central bank credit creation and an increasing rate of reserve loss for some months prior to the collapse (Figure 4). Penati and Pennacchi (1989) report that quarterly reserve losses of the Central bank amounted to 39 billion pesos, 44 billion pesos, and 140 billion pesos, respectively, in the last three quarters of 1981. At the same time, the percentage spread between the spot and forward peso rates began to widen appreciably during the final quarter of 1981 with the widest spread, not surprisingly, being attained immediately prior to the collapse. The gradual acceleration in the domestic inflation rate (which rose on a month-to-month basis from 1.4 percent in June 1981 to 1.9 percent in November of that year and to 4.9 percent in January 1982) led to a steady appreciation of the real exchange rate (Figure 4). On February 12, 1982, the Mexican authorities abandoned the quasi-fixed exchange rate system and allowed the exchange rate to float freely. Continuing capital outflows, however, led to a 67 percent depreciation of the peso vis-à-vis the US dollar by the end of February 1982. In August 1982, with the Central Bank virtually out of reserves, a dual exchange rate regime was put in place.

MEXICO Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001

MEXICO Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
MEXICO Reserves, Parallel Market Premium and the Real Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
The French and Italian experiences were similar in many respects to those of the developing countries. The collapse of the French franc in March 1983 can again be traced to a prior period of expansionary domestic credit policy (Figure 5). However, official data on French official reserves disguises the pressure on the central bank. This is because French authorities intervened heavily prior to the collapse by utilizing foreign exchange borrowed by various public sector entities. This intervention was, however, insufficient to relieve the pressure on the franc, as evidenced by a growing spread between spot and forward rates which emerged in August 1982. Interest rates rose dramatically during the first few months of 1981 and remained above 15 percent until the beginning of 1982, reflecting sustained devaluation expectations (Figure 5). Finally, on March 21, 1983, with the forward market premium at its peak—and a short-term interest rate spread with respect to Germany equal to nearly 7 percent on an annual basis—the franc was devalued by 8 percent against the deutsche mark.

FRANCE Credit, Interest Rates and the Trade Balance
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001

FRANCE Credit, Interest Rates and the Trade Balance
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
FRANCE Credit, Interest Rates and the Trade Balance
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
The Italian crisis of January 1976 was preceded by a period of heavy reserve losses beginning in November of the preceding year. As with the other cases discussed above, this coincided with an increasingly rapid growth in domestic credit (Figure 6). During the last quarter of 1975, Central Bank credit to the Italian Treasury grew at an annual rate six times higher than its growth rate over the first half of that year. On January 21, 1976, with less than $0.5 billion left in official reserves and with the parallel market premium at a peak, the official foreign exchange market was closed. It remained closed until March 1, 1976 at which time the lira was allowed to float.

ITALY Credit, Interest Rates and the Trade Balance
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001

ITALY Credit, Interest Rates and the Trade Balance
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
ITALY Credit, Interest Rates and the Trade Balance
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
This brief review of recent empirical evidence suggests the existence of strong similarities in the process leading to an an exchange-rate crisis, among both developed and developing countries. First, in the periods leading to the crisis, domestic inflation is high—and sometimes rising—while international reserves tend to fall at an increasing rate, reflecting the over-expansionary credit policy and heightened perceptions of the ultimate collapse of the regime. Second, anticipations of a crisis translate into a forward premium (in developed countries) or a parallel market premium (in developing countries) which may rise to extremely high levels in the periods immediately preceding the regime collapse. Domestic interest rates, as a result, tend to rise to very high levels in the periods immediately preceding the exchange-rate crisis. Third, there are important real effects associated with balance-of-payments crises. The real exchange rate tends to appreciate (and the current account to deteriorate) in the transition period. The behavior of the real exchange rate, as well as the behavior of interest rates tend to affect domestic output. The analysis in the next sections will examine the nature of these different effects.
III. A Basic Analytical Framework
We now develop a simple continous-time, perfect-foresight model of balance-of-payments crises. 4/ The model is a log-linear formulation which allows us to solve explicitly for the time of occurence of the crisis, by assuming initially that the exchange rate is allowed to float permanently in the post-collapse regime. Our framework allows us to present in a simple setting the basic insights of the literature, which have been shown to carry through in more complex models. 5/
Consider a small open economy whose residents have perfect foresight and consume a single, tradable good whose domestic supply is exogenously fixed at
Formally, the model is defined by
All variables, except interest rates, are measured in logarithms, denotes the nominal money stock, Dt domestic credit, Rt the book value in domestic currency of gross foreign reserves held by the central bank, st the spot exchange rate, pt the price level, i* the foreign interest rate (assumed constant) and it the domestic interest rate. 6/ Et denotes the expectation operator conditional on information available at time t, and a dot over a variable indicates a time derivative, that is, ṡt ≡ ds/dt.
Equation (1) defines real money demand as a positive function of income and a negative function of the domestic interest rate. Equation (2) is a log-linear approximation to the identity linking the money stock to reserves and domestic credit, which grows at the rate μ (equation (3)). Purchasing power parity and uncovered interest parity are defined in equations (4) and (5) respectively.
Under perfect foresight, Etṡt = ṡt. Setting Ῡ= i* =0 and combining equations (1), (4) and (5) yields
When the exchange rate is fixed (at
and, using (3).
Equation (8) shows that if domestic credit expansion is excessive (that is, if it exceeds the fixed demand for money given in (6) with St = 0), reserves are run down at a rate proportional to the rate of credit expansion. Any finite stock of foreign reserves will, therefore, be depleted in a finite period of time.
Assume that the central bank announces at time t that it will not continue to defend the current fixed exchange rate after reserves reach a lower bound,
To calculate the time to transition to a floating rate regime, we use a process of backward induction, which has been formalized by Flood and Garber (1984b). In equilibrium, under perfect foresight, agents can never expect a discrete jump in the level of the exchange rate, since a jump would provide them with profitable arbitrage opportunities. As a consequence, arbitrage in the foreign exchange market fixes the exchange rate immediately after the attack to equal the fixed rate prevailing at the time of the attack. Formally, the time of the collapse is found at the point where the “shadow floating rate”, reflecting market fundamentals, is equal to the prevailing fixed rate. The shadow floating rate is the exchange rate which would prevail if Rt = 0 and the exchange rate were allowed to float freely. 9/ As long as the fixed exchange rate exceeds (that is, is more depreciated than) the shadow floating rate, the fixed rate regime is safe; beyond that point, the fixed rate is not sustainable.
If the shadow floating rate is below the prevailing fixed rate, speculators would not profit from purchasing the government’s entire international reserve stock and precipitating the adoption of a floating rate regime since these speculators would experience an instantaneous capital loss on their reserve purchases. Symetrically, if the shadow floating rate is above the fixed rate then speculators would experience an instantaneous capital gain. Neither anticipated capital gains or losses at an infinite rate are compatible with a perfect foresignt equilibrium. Speculators will compete with each other to remove such opportunities. Such opportunities lead to an equilibrium attack, which incorporates the arbitrage condition that the pre-attack fixed rate should equal the post-attack floating rate.
A first step, therefore, is to find the “shadow” floating rate, which can be expected to take the form 10/
Taking the rate of change of (9) and noting from (2) that under floating ṁt = γḊt yields
In the post-collapse regime, therefore, the exchange rate depreciates steadily and proportionally to the rate of growth of domestic credit. Substituting (10) in (6) yields
Comparing equations (11) and (9) yields
Noting that Dt = D0 + μt = mt/γ we obtain
The fixed exchange rate regime collapses when the prevailing exchange rate
or, since, from equation (2),
where R0 denotes the initial stock of reserves.
Equation (13) indicates that the higher the initial stock of reserves, or the lower the rate of credit expansion, the longer it will take before the collapse occurs. Without speculation, α = 0 and the collapse occurs when reserves are run down to zero. 12/ The larger the (semi-) interest rate elasticity of money demand, the earlier the crisis. Finally, the larger the initial proportion of domestic credit in the money stock (the higher γ), the sooner the collapse. 13/
The analysis implies therefore that the speculative attack always occurs before the central bank would have run out of reserves in the absence of speculation. To determine the stock of reserves just before the attack (that is, at
where
Using equation (13) yields
Combining (14) and (15) finally yields
Figure 7a portrays the behavior of reserves, domestic credit, and the money stock during the period surrounding the regime shift while Figure 7b displays the behavior of the exchange rate, which is also the price level in this model. Prior to the collapse at tc the money stock is constant, but its composition varies, since domestic credit rises (at the rate μ) and reserves decline at the rate μ/θ. An instant before the regime shift, a speculative attack occurs and both reserves and the money stock fall by μα/θ. Since reserves are exhausted by the attack, the money stock is equal to domestic credit in the post-collapse regime. In Figure 7b, the exchange rate remains at

Reserves, Credit, Money and the Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001

Reserves, Credit, Money and the Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
Reserves, Credit, Money and the Exchange Rate
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
IV. Extensions to the Basic Framework
The basic theory of balance-of-payments crises presented above has been refined and extended in several directions. We examine, in this section, major areas in which the analytical literature has developed. We first consider alternative assumptions regarding the post-collapse exchange regime. Secondly, we consider the introduction of uncertainty in the above framework. The role of perfect asset substitutability and sticky prices is then assessed. The real effects of an (anticipated) exchange rate crisis are subsequently examined in a model with endogenous output, sticky forward-looking wages and external trade, with particular attention being devoted to the effect of a potential crisis on the behavior of the real exchange rate. The role of foreign borrowing and the imposition of controls as policy measures undertaken to postpone the occurence of a balance-of-payments crisis form the focus of attention in the fourth subsection. Finally, the issue of policy switches (that is, changes in the macroeconomic policy mix) as a means to avoid a collapse is examined.
1. Alternative post-collapse regimes
It has been assumed in the foregoing discussion that the exchange rate regime that follows the fixed rate’s collapse is a permanent float. 15/ Although the focus of the theoretical literature has been on the transition from a fixed exchange rate to a post-collapse floating exchange rate, various alternative scenarios are suggested by actual experience. For instance, the central bank can devalue the currency (Blanco and Garber, 1986) or can decide to adopt a crawling peg regime following the breakdown of the fixed rate system (Dornbusch, 1987). 16/ A particularly interesting case—often observed in practice, as in the case of Mexico described earlier—corresponds to a situation in which after allowing the currency to float for a certain period of time, the central bank once again returns to the foreign exchange market with the objective of fixing—at a depreciated level—the exchange rate. As a rule, one would expect the timing of a crisis to depend on the particular exchange arrangement agents expect the central bank to follow after a run on its reserve stock.
The model developed above can be modified to consider the case, as in Obstfeld (1984), of a (perfectly anticipated) temporary post-collapse period of floating followed by a new peg, and to study the effect of the length of this period on the time of occurence of the crisis. 17/ In what follows, we study this case as an illustration of the type of modifications of the basic structure needed for an analysis of alternative post-collapse regimes. To begin with, suppose that the length of the transition period of floating, denoted by τ, and the level
Recall that in the last section, when the central bank’s policy was assumed to involve abandonment of the fixed rate and floating indefinitely thereafter, the shadow floating rate was given by equation (11). Now, under a transitory floating regime, the shadow rate is given by
where A is a constant to be determined. The complete solution must, therefore, specify values for both t and A. These solutions are obtained by imposing the conditions
where
Equation (18a) indicates that the collapse time is linked to the magnitude of the expected devaluation (
2. Uncertainty and the timing of a collapse
In the basic model developed above, it has been assumed that there is some binding threshold level, known by all agents, below which foreign reserves are not allowed to be depleted. The attainment of this critical level implies a permanent shift from a fixed exchange rate regime to a floating rate regime. In practice, however, agents are only imperfectly informed of central bank policies. They may not not perfectly know the threshold level of reserves which triggers the regime shift. If uncertainty about current and future government policy is prevalent, the assumption of perfect foresight may be inappropriate.
An implication of the perfect-foresight model developed above, which is contradicted by experience, concerns the behavior of the domestic nominal interest rate. In the model, the nominal interest rate stays constant until the moment the attack occurs—at which point it jumps to a new level consistent with the post-collapse regime. Uncertainty over the depreciation rate, as modeled below, may help to account for a rising interest rate in the transition period. Indeed, while specific results are sensistive to arbitrary assumptions regarding distributional assumptions of random terms, only stochastic models are consistent with the large interest rate fluctuations observed in actual crises.
Uncertainty in the theory of balance-of-payments crises has been introduced in various forms, but has focused on two aspects: first, uncertainty regarding the reserve limit that triggers the crisis; and second, uncertainty regarding domestic credit growth.
In practice, investors are uncertain about how much of its potential reserves the central bank is willing to use to defend its fixed exchange rate target. Uncertainty about the reserve level that a policymaker is willing to use to defend the exchange rate was first examined by Krugman (1979), who pointed out the possibility of alternating crises and recoveries of confidence that such uncertainty may entail. 22/ A general result, however, seems to be that speculative behavior is quite sensistive to the specification of the process which produces the critical level of foreign reserves. Depending on whether the threshold level is stochastic, or fixed but unknown to agents, currency speculation reveals itself as, respectively, a speculative outflow distributed over several periods of time or a sudden speculative attack on the currency (Willman, 1989).
Uncertainty about domestic credit growth was first introduced by Flood and Garber (1984b), in a discrete - time stochastic model. In their framework, credit is assumed to depend on a random component. 23/ In each period, the probability of collapse in the next period is found by evaluating the probability that domestic credit in the next period will be sufficiently large to result in a discrete depreciation, should a speculative attack occur. In the Flood-Garber framework a fixed rate regime will collapse whenever it is profitable to attack it. The condition for a profitable attack is, as in the model developed above, that the post-collapse exchange rate, st be larger than the prevailing fixed rate
The specific form of the process driving St will determine the exact form of tπt+1. 24/ From equation (19), the expected rate of depreciation of the exchange rate is given as
where
The expected rate of exchange rate depreciation given by (20) will change as the value of the variables forcing st change. The expected rate of change of the exchange rate increases prior to the collapse because both tπt+1 and
The Flood-Garber stochastic approach has given rise to a number of empirical applications, which are examined below. 26/ The introduction of uncertainty in collapse models has several implications for the predictions of these models, beyond being consistent with a rising interest-rate differential prior to the crisis. First, the transition to a floating regime is stochastic, rather than certain. The collapse time becomes a random variable and cannot as before be determined explicitly, since the timing of a potential future speculative attack is unknown. Second, there always exists a non-zero probability of a speculative attack in the next period, 27/ a possibility which, in turn, produces a forward discount on the domestic currency—a phenomenon known as the “peso problem” (Krasker, 1980). The evidence discussed in Section II suggests indeed that the forward premium—or, as an alternative indicator of exchange-rate expectations, the parallel market premium—in foreign exchange markets tends to increase well before the regime collapse. Third, the degree of uncertainty about the central bank’s credit policy plays an important role for the speed at which reserves at the central bank are depleted (Claessens, 1991). In a stochastic setting, reserve losses exceed increases in domestic credit because of a rising probability of regime shift, so that reserve depletion accelerates on the way to the regime change. Thus, uncertainty can help explain the pattern of reserves described in Section II.
3. Asset substitutability and sticky prices
Extensions of the theory of balance-of-payments crises to a world of sticky prices and imperfect asset substitutability have been discussed by Flood and Hodrick (1986), Blackburn (1988) and Willman (1988). 28/ A simple way to introduce sluggish price adjustment in the basic framework developed above requires dropping the assumption of perfect substitutability between domestic and foreign goods (which yields the purchasing power parity condition (4) and implicitly implies an instantaneously cleared goods market) and specifying a Dornbusch-type price equation of the form 29/
in which aggregate demand is inversely related to the real exchange rate and the real interest rate. The parameter A measures the speed of adjustment of prices to excess demand. Using equations (1)-(3), (4’) and (5) and setting as before i* = Ῡ = 0 yields, under floating exchange rates and perfect foresight, a non-homogeneous differential equation system in st and pt :
The two eigenvalues of this system are given by
It is easy to verify that provided that (1 - λΨ) > 0, the system (21) is saddle-point stable, with one negative root (denoted by ρ) and one positive root. 30/ Solving for the particular solutions yields
where A is an arbitrary constant which can be determined by imposing an initial condition on the predetermined output price. 31/
The solution value for st can be used to determine the timing of the crisis, which occurs, as before, at the point where the shadow exchange rate equals the prevailing fixed rate. Although an explicit solution cannot be derived analytically here, the collapse time can be determined graphically at the intersection of the curve Aeρt and the straight line
The effect of price flexibility on the collapse time derived above has also been highlighted by Blackburn (1988). In addition, Blackburn also examines the role of imperfect asset substitutability in the collapse process. His analysis shows that the higher the degree of capital mobility, the earlier the crisis occurs. As in Willman’s (1988) model, imperfect substitutability between domestic and foreign bonds implies that it is essentially the accumulating trade balance deficit which leads to depletion of foreign reserves and eventually causes the balance - of - payments crisis. Because of the potential impact of government spending on external deficits, it is therefore not just monetary policy, but rather the fiscal-monetary mix which is of importance in the analysis of the collapse process.
4. Output, the real exchange rate and the current account
The early literature on balance-of-payments crises focused on the financial aspects of such crises and ignored the real events occuring simultaneously. The evidence examined in Section II suggests, however, that balance-of-payments crises are often associated with large trade balance and current account movements during the periods preceding, as well as during the periods following, such crises. Typically, large current account deficits tend to emerge, as agents adjust their consumption behavior (and not only the composition of their holdings of financial assets) in anticipation of a crisis. The evidence regarding the experiences of Argentina and Mexico reviewed above shows how important the movements in the real exchange rate and the current account have been in these countries in the periods preceding exchange-rate crises. Such movements may provide an additional argument to explain why (in addition to uncertainty, discussed above) runs on reserves rarely occur abruptly but are generally preceded by a period during which official foreign reserves are lost at increasing rates. 34/
The real effects of a potential exchange rate crisis have been investigated by Flood and Hodrick (1986) in economies with sticky prices and contractually predetermined wages, and by Willman (1988) in the context of a simple model with endogenous output and foreign trade. 35/ Following Willman, we can assume that—as in equation (4’)—domestic output is demand-determined, positively related to the real exchange rate, and inversely related to the real interest rate. The trade balance depends also positively on the real exchange rate, but is negatively related to domestic output. A crucial feature of Willman’s model is the existence of forward-looking wage contracts, as in Calvo (1983). Under perfect foresight, an anticipated future collapse will affect wages, which, in turn, will influence prices, the real exchange rate and therefore output and the trade balance. The behavior of these variables is represented in Figure 8.36/ At the moment the collapse occurs, the real interest rate falls because of the jump in the rate of depreciation of the exchange rate. Output therefore increases, while the trade balance deteriorates. If nominal wages were fixed or backward-looking, output would be “flat” before the collapse occurs, since there are no anticipatory movements. But since wage contracts are forward-looking, anticipated future increases in prices are discounted back to the present and affect current wages. As a result, prices start adjusting before the collapse occurs. The real interest rate falls gradually, and experiences a downward jump at the collapse time, resulting from the upward jump in the rate of inflation. The decline in the (ex post) real interest has an expansionary effect on domestic activity before the collapse. However, output also depends on the real exchange rate. The steady rise in domestic prices is associated with an appreciation of the domestic currency and a negative impact on economic activity which may outweigh the positive output effect resulting from a lower real interest rate. In Figure 8, the net impact of an anticipated collapse on output is shown to be negative—a likely outcome if relative price effects are strong. The continuous loss of competitiveness, unless it is associated with a fall in output, implies that the trade balance deteriorates in the pre-collapse fixed exchange rate regime. The trade deficit increases further at the moment the crisis occurs, and returns gradually afterwards to its steady-state level.

Output, Real Interest Rates, the Real Exchange Rate and the Trade Balance
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001

Output, Real Interest Rates, the Real Exchange Rate and the Trade Balance
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
Output, Real Interest Rates, the Real Exchange Rate and the Trade Balance
Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 099; 10.5089/9781451852189.001.A001
In the model described above, the real exchange rate appreciates until the collapse time, at which point it starts depreciating smoothly. This feature of the model seems to account fairly well for the steady real appreciation and subsequent depreciation observed during crisis episodes in countries such as Argentina in 1980-81. By contrast, in the models developed by Calvo (1987) and Connolly and Taylor (1984), the real exchange rate experiments a downward jump at the time of the crisis—a feature of the collapse process which appears difficult to rationalize in a perfect foresight world. In Connolly and Taylor’s model for instance, the price of traded goods is fixed at the time of a speculative attack. It cannot jump because the exchange rate is continuous (as a result of the asset-price continuity assumption) and the world price of traded goods is assumed constant. Consequently, a sharp real depreciation at the time of the crisis must be attributed, under perfect foresight, to a substantial fall in the nominal price of nontraded goods—an assumption which implies an implausible degree of downward price flexibility for most economies.
5. Borrowing, controls, and the postponment of a crisis
A common feature in countries experiencing balance-of-payments difficulties has often been recourse to external borrowing to supplement the available amount of reserves, or the imposition of restrictions on capital outflows to limit losses of foreign exchange reserves. In the basic model developed above, it has been assumed that there is a critical level, known by everyone, below which foreign reserves are not allowed to be depleted. In practice, however, it is doubtful whether any such binding threshold exists. A central bank facing a perfect capital market can—at least in principle—create foreign reserves by borrowing. Thus negative (net) reserves are also feasible. 37/
Pressing the argument a little further suggests that perfect access to international capital markets implies that, at any given point in time, central bank reserves can become (infinitely) negative without violating the government’s intertemporal budget constraint. Such access to unlimited borrowing could, in principle, indefinitely avoid a regime collapse. The rate of growth of domestic credit cannot, however, be indefinitely maintained above the world interest rate, because it would lead to a violation of the budget constraint (Obstfeld, 1986a). In this sense, an over-expansionary credit policy still leads to the collapse of a fixed exchange - rate regime. A similar point has been emphasized by van Wijnbergen (1988, 1991). 38/
Moreover, even with perfect capital markets, the timing of borrowing matters considerably for the nature of speculative attacks. Suppose that the interest cost of servicing foreign debt exceeds the interest rate paid on reserves. If borrowing occurs just before the exchange rate regime would have collapsed absent borrowing, the crisis is likely to be postponed. If borrowing occurs long enough before the exchange rate regime would have collapsed in the absence of borrowing, the crisis would occur earlier. The reason why the collapse is brought forward is, of course, related to the servicing cost of foreign indebtedness on the fiscal deficit, which raises the rate of growth of domestic credit (Buiter, 1987).
In practice, most countries face borrowing constraints on international capital markets. The existence of such constraints has important implications for the behavior of inflation in an economy where the government—like private agents—is subject to an inter-temporal budget constraint. Consider, for instance, a country which has no access to external borrowing and in which the central bank transfers to the government its net profits. If a speculative attack occurs, the central bank will lose its reserves and its post-collapse profits from interest earnings on foreign assets will drop to zero. As a consequence, net income of the government falls and the budget deficit deteriorates. If the deficit is financed by increased domestic credit (a typical situation if access to external borrowing is limited) the post-collapse inflation rate will exceed the rate that prevailed in the pre-collapse fixed exchange - rate regime, raising inflation tax revenue so as to compensate for the fall in interest income (van Wijnbergen, 1988, 1991).
Another policy measure aimed at postponing a regime collapse which has been used to limit losses of foreign exchange reserves relates to capital controls. Restrictions of this type have been imposed either permanently or temporarily after significant losses. 39/ A simple way to introduce permanent controls in the above setting is to re-write equation (5) as
This equation states that deviations from the domestic interest rate from uncovered interest parity are accounted for by the existence of capital controls, which are modelled here as a proportional tax on foreign interest earnings. 40/ Using (5’) and solving the model as before, the collapse time is now given by
Equation (13’) indicates that the higher the degree of capital controls (the higher ρ), the longer it will take for the regime shift to occur.
The impact of temporary capital controls on the timing of a balance-of-payments crisis has been studied by Bacchetta (1990), Delias and Stockman (1988), and Wyplosz (1986). In Wyplosz’s model the domestic country expands credit excessively. Capital controls are in force, and residents are not allowed to hold foreign currency assets (or to lend to non-residents), but non-residents are free from restrictions. There are only two assets, domestic money and foreign money. Non-residents monitor reserve levels, provoking a “crisis” when reserve levels equal non-resident holdings of domestic currency. The currency is then devalued, setting off a new cycle. The analysis shows that in the absence of capital controls, a fixed rate regime would be viable only if the monetary authorities maintain a sufficient degree of uncertainty so as to force risk-averse speculators to commit only limited amounts of funds in anticipation of a crisis. 41/
It has been argued, however, that even with perfect foresight the regime might still be viable if interest rates are endogenous—a feature which is absent in Wyplosz’s model (Giavazzi and Pagano, 1990). Interest rates have an equilibrating role that eliminates the incentive for a run on reserves. For instance, if the public anticipates a devaluation, it will shift out of domestic money. The authorities accomodate the public, say, by bond sales at interest rates that reflect these expectations; such bond sales avert the need to shift into foreign assets. The implication of the analysis, however, is that without capital controls interest rates are likely to display substantial variability. 42/
Restrictions on foreign transactions also have real effects, as shown by Bacchetta (1990) who examines the effect of anticipated temporary capital controls in the process of a balance of payments crisis. The anticipation of controls affects the behavior of agents as soon as they are announced—or as soon as agents realize the inconsistency between the fiscal policy and the fixed exchange rate—and usually translate into a current account deficit, as capital out- flows are substituted by increased imports. A speculative attack may, however, occur just before the controls are imposed. Such an attack may therefore well defeat the very purpose of capital controls. 43/
6. Policy switches and the avoidance of a collapse
Early models of balance-of-payments crises have beeen generally limited to the consideration of an “excessive” rate of credit creation. 44/ The apparently inevitable character of a regime collapse that such an assumption entails runs into a conceptual difficulty, namely, why is it that the authorities do not attempt to prevent the crisis by adjusting their fiscal and credit policies? 45/ Moreover, there is nothing in the model which requires the central bank to float the currency and abandon the prevailing fixed exchange rate at the moment reserves hit their critical lower bound; instead, the monetary authority could as well change change its monetary policy rule to make it consistent with the fixed exchange rate target. Some recent models of balance-of-payments crises have considered this type of endogenous changes in monetary policy. For instance, in Drazen and Helpman (1988) the assumption that the authorities choose to adjust the exchange rate instead of altering underlying macroeconomic policy that is inconsistent with the existing exchange parity, can only provide a temporary solution. But ultimately, if the new exchange rate regime is inconsistent with the underlying fiscal policy process, there will be a need for a new policy regime. A similar argument has been made in the context of developing countries (Edwards and Montiel, 1989).
In the context of a model of the Gold Standard, Flood and Garber (1984b) showed that an attack on a price-fixing scheme can be self-fulfilling. This self-fulfilling aspect was applied to exchange-rate fixing by Obstfeld (1986b). A collapse, in these models, results from an indeterminacy of equilibrium that may arise when agents expect a speculative attack to cause an abrupt change in government macroeconomic policies. Suppose, for instance, that a country fixes its exchange rate and maintains a stable credit policy in “normal times”. In the event a speculative attack occurs, however, the country will cease fixing the exchange rate and will increase the rate of growth of domestic credit. Evidently the private sector can be in equilibrium with either policy. If an attack never occurs, the fixed exchange rate will survive indefinitely. If there is an attack the system may collapse. The indeterminacy arises because the authorities’ credit policy is not exogenous to the collapse.
Uncertainty about the post-collapse credit rule can also cause a fixed exchange-rate regime to collapse—just as arbitrary speculative behavior (or noneconomic extrinsic factors which private agents may believe to trigger a crisis) would. Formally, a simple way to introduce policy uncertainty in the basic model developed above is to allow two possibilities with respect to the credit policy rule (Willman, 1987): there is a probability q that the monetary authority will maintain the existing rule given by (3) and float the currency from the moment the stock of foreign exchange reserves has been depleted to zero, and a probability (1 - q) that the authorities will adopt a zero-growth rule consistent with the fixed rate regime, that is
Using (3’) and solving as before, the collapse time can be shown to be now equal to
The earlier result (equation 13) corresponds to a probability equal to one. If the probability is zero, a speculative attack never occurs and the system collapses “naturally”. The smaller q—the greater the probability that the monetary authorities alter the credit policy rule (3)—the longer it takes before the collapse occurs.
An alternative way to formalize the effect of a possible future policy switch is as follows. Suppose that the process driving domestic credit is given by (3’) instead of (3),
where dzt is a standard Wiener process, and a is a constant. 46/ To derive the solution for the flexible exchange rate in the post-collapse regime, set Rt = 0 in (2) and use (4), (5) in (1) to get
Suppose that speculators expect the central bank to alter its credit rule (3’) in the future—even while allowing the exchange rate to float initially. 47/ More precisely, the central bank may decide to again fix the exchange rate, if a higher limit on domestic credit
where
The collapse date tc is now a stochastic variable which can be determined by using the “first-passage” probability density function, given for instance in Feller (1966, pp. 174-75).
V. Models of Exchange Rate-Crises: Empirical Evidence
Speculative attacks and devaluation crises have come to be associated with developing countries and historical applications to now-developed countries. We examine in this Section some formal econometric applications of the speculative attack model to such foreign exchange crises. Specifically, we focus on three cases: Mexico (1973-82), Argentina (1978-81) and the United States (1894-96). 50/
In the preceding sections explaining the theory of speculative attack models, arbitrary assumptions needed to be made concerning the policy to which a government would switch following a speculative attack. The assumption that the government allows its foreign exchange reserves to be exhausted and then switches to a floating exchange rate is often made for analytical convenience and needs to be modified for empirical application. Precise modifications depend on the particular application since government policies differ. The analytical literature does, however, offer a basic lesson: the “shadow exchange rate”, as derived in the theoretical literature, allows the development of a lower bound on the probability of a policy switch. The reason is simple—any exchange rate that does not equal or exceed the shadow rate will be profitably attacked by speculators. This lesson is robust to a wide variety of policies followed by the government.
Blanco and Garber (1986) in their study of recurrent devaluations of the Mexican peso offer the first empirical application of the speculative attack model. 51/ The Mexican authorities did not follow the theory scenario and completely abandon the fixed rate policy. Instead, in the midst of a speculative attack, the Mexican authorities devalued the peso against the U.S. dollar. While such a policy switch does not exactly match the switch to a floating exchange rate usually posited in the theory literature, a devaluation that terminates a speculative attack must move the exchange rate to a position where it equals or exceeds the shadow floating rate, where the shadow floating rate is the exchange rate that would prevail if the foreign exchange authority had exhausted its stock of international reserves and allowed the exchange rate to float freely. A successful devaluation must take the shadow floating rate as a lower bound since any fixed rate below the shadow floating rate would be instantly and profitably attacked.
The development of the shadow floating rate is thus important in empirical application and this development requires a model of a flexible exchange rate. Blanco and Garber center their exchange-market model on the domestic money market and augment that market with uncovered interest rate parity and a relation between Mexican-peso goods prices and U.S.-dollar goods prices. In their model, if international reserves were exhausted and if the exchange rate were allowed to float freely afterwards, then the following equilibrium condition follows:
where ht is the exchange-market forcing variable that would prevail if the switch were made to a floating rate after the exchange authority had exhausted its international reserves and s is the shadow floating exchange rate. In Blanco and Garber’s analysis, ht is assumed to be exogenous to the exchange rate and it is assumed to follow a particular linear stochastic process that is invariant to the exchange rate regime. Thus one can solve in the usual way for the reduced form function relating st to ht.
The shadow exchange rate is assumed to play a role in the devaluation rule. In particular, Blanco and Garber assume that a devaluation will occur if and only if
where
where
Condition (27) determines the devaluation. Indeed, the probability that the currency will be devalued next period, tπt+1, probability based on time t information that condition (27) will hold next period;
Blanco and Garber assume ft = Eet+1 + εt, where ft is the forward exchange rate and εt a shock (a forecast error), which allows them to turn equation (29) into an estimating equation.
The empirical strategy of Blanco and Garber is built around the facts that neither st nor ht is directly observable. According to the theory, however, ht is a linear function of observable money market variables and the level of international reserves at which the monetary authority would abandon the fixed rate regime if attacked,
Estimation proceeds in several stages. In the first stage, they estimate parameters from the money market. In the second stage they use an initial guess of
The output of the estimation is a set of structural parameter estimates and a constructed time-series for st and tπt+1. These time-series are generated by combining the mean values of the estimated parameters with the time series for the state variable, ht. The striking feature of their work is that the estimated probabilities of devaluation in the next quarter, which range from highs of more than twenty percent in late 1976 and late 1981, to lows of less than five percent in early 1974 and late 1977, reach local peaks in the periods of devaluation and reach local minima in the periods following devaluation as predicted by the theory.
Cumby and van Wijnbergen (1989) applied a similar speculative attack model to the stabilization program in Argentina, which included the period from December 1978 to April 1981. Exchange-market aspects of the program were built around the “tablita”, which was a pre-announced table of daily exchange rates. The speculative attack model is relevant here because tension may arise between government financing needs and the “tablita”. For example, if government finance should demand more revenue from money creation than would be consistent with the “tablita”, then agents may conjecture that the “tablita” would collapse.
The predetermined “tablita” exchange rate acts like the fixed exchange rate in the previous literature. Cumby and van Wijnbergen use the same model as Blanco and Garber, but they implement it somewhat differently. Whereas Blanco and Garber aggregate all money-market influences into one variable and then fit a stochastic process for that variable, Cumby and van Wijnbergen assume that the forcing variables in the money market are appropriately modeled in a disaggregated way with different time series processes appropriate for the money demand disturbance, foreign interest rates, domestic credit growth and are unable to reject simple stochastic processes in place in Argentina from January 1979 through December 1980.
The distribution function appropriate to increments of the shadow exchange rate is thus more complex than in Blanco and Garber’s study because of the disaggregation of the forcing variable. More importantly, it is more complex because Cumby and van Wijnbergen treat the minimum level of reserves as a stochastic variable, unknown to agents in the model, which has its own distribution and is independent of other variables in the forcing process. Blanco and Garber treated the minimum quantity of reserves as a variable that is known to agents but in unknown to the researcher. Thus in deriving the probabilities of devaluation, they did not include a model of agents’ uncertainty about minimum reserves.
The econometric estimates of the collapse probabilities by Cumby and van Wijnbergen indicate that the sharp increase in domestic credit growth in the second quarter of 1980 undermined agents’ confidence in the crawling peg regime. Credibility of the exchange rate regime fell gradually in the ensuing periods. The one-month-ahead collapse probability rose to nearly 80 percent immediately prior to the abandonment of the crawling peg arrangement in June 1981.
Grilli (1990) applies the speculative attack model to the episode of foreign exchange market pressure on the dollar from 1894 through 1896. 52/ The distinguishing contribution of Grilli’s study is the implementation of a model of government reserve borrowing, which ties together the speculative attack literature with the optimal contracting literature (see, for instance, Harris and Raviv, 1981). In the framework used by Grilli the probabilities of speculative attack are measured in the standard way, but the government is assumed to structure borrowing contracts in order to minimize this probability subject to a set of constraints.
The constraints proxy the government’s degree of commitment to the fixed exchange rate system and lead to the development of an optimal government borrowing contract, which is compared in a case study manner with aspects of the Belmont-Morgan contract. 53/ The previous literature postulated an exogenous and possibly unknown minimum level of reserves; an important contribution of Grilli’s study is to begin to endogenize this variable and thus take more seriously the degree of the government’s commitment to the fixed exchange rate regime.
VI. Some Research Perspectives
The literature on speculative attacks has been growing steadily. There is, undoubtedly, a risk in trying to identify areas that may prove fruitful for future developments. We believe, however, that attention should be focused on the following topics: the analysis of speculative attacks in a target zone, the resolution of the “Gold Standard Paradox”, the role of reputational factors as a deterrent to speculative attacks, and the testing of collapse models—particularly in the context of developing countries.
1. Speculative attacks on a target zone
The literature on fixed exchange rates has usually modeled the policy of fixing the exchange rate by having the policy authority adopt a particular number for the exchange rate and by standing willing to buy or sell foreign exchange to maintain this price. In actual practice, such as in the Bretton Woods system or the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) in the European Monetary System, the exchange rate commitment involves announcing a range for the exchange rate and intervening to preserve this range. Such a policy has been termed a target zone for the exchange rate and a large literature has grown recently studying the behavior of the exchange rate in a target zone regime.
One of the important insights of the target zone literature has been that a credible target zone would stabilize exchange rate movements within the zone. This was Krugman’s (1990) “honeymoon effect”. More recently Krugman and Rotemberg (1990) studied target zones that were less than perfectly credible because the reserves committed to defense of the zone were limited. In the Krugman-Rotemberg scenario an exchange rate target zone might collapse exactly as the theoretical fixed rate regime collapses in a final speculative attack and a return to a flexible exchange rate.
In their example, Krugman and Rotemberg show that limited reserves and the possibility of a speculative attack weaken the “honeymoon” effect. With a speculative attack a possibility, agents are not certain of an effective forthcoming intervention to preserve the zone. Therefore agents’ expectations are less dogmatic than in a zone of certain permanence. In a permanent zone, agents always expect the exchange rate to be moved back toward the center of the zone when the rate drifts toward the edges. Such rationally regressive expectations are responsible for the “honeymoon” effect—a shock, which in the absence of the credible zone would move the exchange rate (say) up by 10 percent has a smaller effect on the exchange rate in a credible zone because the shock sets into motion the expectation of the return of the exchange rate toward its initial level. Once the zone is not perfectly credible however, the expected return of the exchange rate is dampened and so the “honeymoon” effect is less powerful.
2. The “Gold Standard Paradox”
Suppose that a small country is operating under a fixed exchange rate and that the country’s demand for money is rising secularly faster than the domestic credit component of its money supply. The country can expect to gain international reserves over time and it might expect its fixed rate to be indefinitely viable. But suppose also that the country experiences a temporary downward disturbance in money demand which is large enough to exhaust its stock of reserves. In the long run, the country’s fixed rate is still viable but in the short run, since reserves are exhausted, the country may have to abandon the fixed rate regime. When the country switches to a flexible exchange rate, the long-term expected increase in the excess demand for money implies that the currency will be stronger in the forward market than in the spot market, or that domestic interest rates will fall below world interest rates. The reduction in domestic interest rates following the abandonment of the parity will therefore increase money demand and appreciate the domestic currency as compared with the fixed rate. The “Gold Standard Paradox” refers to a situation where the fixed rate system would collapse and that following the collapse the domestic currency would become more valuable.
Two “resolutions” to this paradox have been offered in the literature. The first is the Buiter-Grilli (1989) solution, which works only in a zero-interest environment. The second type of solution is the Salant (1983) price-fixing rule as applied by Krugman and Rotemberg (1990). This “solution” consists in a change in the rules of the game, that is, the implementation of a rule which sets a floor on the domestic currency price of reserves and ensures the impossibility of a speculative attack when the price of reserves falls at the instant of an attack. However, analytical solutions have so far been obtained only in cases where fundamentals follow some simple stochastic processes.
3. Reputation as a deterrent to speculative attacks
In line with recent developments in the macroeconomic policy game literature, another potentially fruitful line of enquiry could be to examine the effect of exchange rate credibility on balance-of-payments crises. 54/ A fixed exchange rate regime will, in general, never carry full credibility. Official pronouncements notwithstanding, there is always a risk that when official reserves are being run down, a country will opt to alter its exchange rate rather than its monetary and/or fiscal policy. When agents perceive that the authorities’ commitment—and ability—to maintain a fixed exchange rate is weak, speculative attacks may occur. Such attacks may occur when the competitiveness of a high-inflation country has been eroded by adhering to the nominal exchange rate parity. This will typically reduce the degree of confidence in the existing exchange rate and will raise expectations that the currency will be devalued. A speculative attack can therefore be self-fulfilling because it may lead to an eventual exhaustion of the authorities’ foreign exchange reserves, leaving the authorities with little choice but to devalue (see Wood, 1991). Such a situation may be exacerbated if price setters incorporate the possibility of a devaluation in their pricing procedures, thereby adding further inflationary pressure. An important issue, in this context, is the extent to which reputational factors (such as the appointment of a “conservative” central banker for instance, as suggested by Rogoff, 1985) may mitigate the credibility problem and ensure the viability of a fixed-rate regime.
4. Econometric testing of collapse models
As discussed in the previous section, most empirical studies on balance-of-payments crises have been conducted in a developing-country context. The existing literature has, however, typically ignored the critical role often played in these countries by the parallel market for foreign exchange in diffusing speculative pressures on the official parity—a mechanism which has been formally examined by Agénor (1990) and Agénor and Delbecque (1991). 55/ If foreign exchange is rationed in the official market, an expansionary credit policy will depreciate the parallel exchange rate. The resulting increase in the premium will raise prices, appreciate the real exchange rate, and encourage diversion of export proceeds from the official to the parallel market—consequently accelerating the rate of reserve losses and precipitating the collapse of the official exchange rate. A devaluation entails a fall in the premium in the short-run, 56/ but the parallel rate will continue to depreciate if credit policy remains expansionary. As in the standard model of balance-of-payments crises, a fixed-exchange rate system is viable only if the authorities are able to maintain fiscal and monetary discipline. This analysis suggests that future empirical research on balance - of-payments crises in developing countries should aim at explaining simultaneously the behavior of the parallel market premium and foreign exchange reserves.
VII. Concluding Comments
The purpose of the paper has been to provide an overview of recent theoretical and empirical developments in the literature on speculative attacks in foreign exchange markets and balance-of-payments crises. The first part of the paper has examined the recent experience of some developed and developing countries with balance-of payments difficulties and exchange rate crises, and has highlighted empirical regularities observed during these episodes. In the second part of the paper, a simple analytical model which describes the process leading to such crises has been developed. The analysis has shown that under perfect foresight about the policy rule pursued by the monetary authorities, an exchange rate regime shift from a fixed to a floating regime is preceded by a speculative attack on the currency. Moreover, the timing of such attacks is entirely predictable. Intertemporal arbitrage ensures that the regime shift occurs “smoothly”. Its timing has been shown to depend on the stock of foreign reserves committed by the central bank to the defense of the fixed exchange rate regime.
The third part of the paper dealt with various extensions to the basic analytical model. Empirical evidence on the collapse of exchange rate regimes has been the focus of the fourth part, while the fifth part has discussed various perspectives for future research, notably the role of reputational factors as a deterrent to speculative attacks, and the link between models of balance - of-payments crises and the recent literature on target zones.
The major policy implications of the analysis for macroeconomic policy under a fixed-exchange rate regime are as follows. Balance-of-payments crises may be the equilibrium outcome of maximizing behavior by rational agents faced with inconsistent monetary and exchange rate policies, rather than the result of exogenous “shocks”. Measures such as foreign borrowing and capital controls, may temporarily enhance the viability of a fixed exchange rate, but will not prevent the ultimate collapse of the system if fundamental policy changes are not implemented. 57/ In the process leading to an eventual collapse, speculative runs are likely to occur recurrently, reflecting alternative periods of confidence and distrust in the ability of the central bank to defend the official parity. The more delayed fundamental policy measures are, the higher will be the potential costs (in terms of lost output, for instance) of a regime collapse. Morevover, viability of a fixed exchange-rate regime does not only depend on credit growth but will more generally be affected by the overall consistency and sustainability of the macroeconomic policy mix, which in turn will depend on the nature of the inter-temporal budget constraints faced by the government and private agents.
An important aspect of the recent literature on balance-of-payments crises is the emphasis on real effects of an anticipated collapse. Such effects can be quite pronounced, and may imply dramatic fluctuations in real interest rates and the real exchange rate. Such features have often been observed in high-inflation economies implementing stabilization programs based on an exchange-rate freeze. Collapse models may therefore provide important insights in understanding why some exchange - rate based stabilization programs have failed in their objectives. 58/