Abstract
The paper examines the role of credibility in the conduct of exchange rate policy in developing countries, The analysis is based on a model in which policymakers are concerned about inflation and external competitiveness. Price setters in the nontraded goods sector of the economy adjust prices in reaction to anticipated fluctuations in the domestic price of tradable goods. This type of model is showm to generate a “devaluation bias” which undermines the credibility of a fixed exchange rate. The effect of reputational factors, signaling considerations, and joining a currency union as possible solutions to this bias is examined.
I. Introduction
Policymakers in developing countries typically face a dilemma when using the exchange rate as a policy instrument. Although a nominal depreciation may improve the trade balance and the balance of payments, it is usually associated with a rise in the price level, which may turn into inflation and ultimately erode external competitiveness. Conversely, maintaining the exchange rate fixed to stabilize prices in the presence of a large current account deficit is often not a viable option, if the country faces a foreign exchange reserves or external borrowing constraint. In spite of these controversial issues, however, the exchange rate has been increasingly used as a policy instrument to promote external adjustment. Since the mid-1970s a number of developing countries have moved away from pegging to a single currency to more flexible exchange rate arrangements, such as composite pegs (see Aghevli, Khan and Montiel, 1991). To a large extent, this occurred because of the extreme fluctuations among the major currencies in the post-Bretton-Woods years. Some countries have also opted for more flexible arrangements in order to “disguise” the occasional depreciation of the domestic currency, enabling them to avoid the political costs of announced devaluations.
Despite this notable evolution towards increased use of the exchange rate as a policy tool, there has recently been a variety of arguments proposed in favor of adopting a fixed exchange rate regime. 1/ The debate has recently focused on the role of the exchange rate as an anchor for the domestic price level and on the “credibility effect” that a fixed rate may attach to a disinflation program when the commitment to defend the parity is clearly established. Without central bank credibility, private agents will continue to expect a high inflation rate, and this will increase the cost of any attempt to stabilize domestic prices. Establishing credibility means convincing the public that the central bank will not deviate from its exchange rate or money supply target in order to attain any short-term benefits associated with surprise inflation. This requires that the public be convinced that the authorities have some incentive to refrain from introducing monetary surprises. It has been argued that by acting as a constraint on macroeconomic policies, a fixed exchange rate may enhance the credibility of the central bank’s commitment to maintaining a low and stable rate of money growth.
The purpose of this paper is to examine, in a developing-country context, recent arguments favoring a fixed exchange rate regime that are based on inflation problems caused by policymakers’ lack of credibility. The analytical framework draws on recent developments in macroeconomics, which have emphasized the strategic aspects of disinflation policies resulting from the interdependence between the behavior of private, forward-looking agents and centralized policymakers. In this context--which lends itself to a game-theoretic interpretation--credibility issues have been shown to emerge because of an incentive for policymakers to pursue a strategic advantage and seek short-run gains by reneging on previously announced policies, leading to time-inconsistent policies (Kydland and Prescott, 1977). 1/ The dynamic inconsistency literature has shown that, if feasible, precommitment to certain rules by monetary authorities could improve the behavior of the economy by securing a low-inflation equilibrium, without sacrificing other macroeconomic objectives. The paper focuses particularly on the role of reputational factors, signaling considerations, and adherence to a monetary union as possible ways to mitigate, or even eliminate, the time-inconsistency problem in exchange rate management.
Our basic results can be summarized as follows. In a typical developing-country setting, in which the nominal exchange rate can be used as a policy instrument directed at either an external competitiveness target or a price level target, the authorities’ intention to maintain a fixed exchange rate may not secure price stability. This is because private agents will be aware that the competitiveness target will create a temptation to devalue and will accordingly set prices higher in the expectation of devaluation, which the authorities will then find optimal to produce. This time-inconsistency problem arises because of the absence of a precommitment technology that can render the authorities’ intentions credible. We show, however, that several factors may mitigate the problem. First, if the authorities’ credibility depends on their past behavior, then “cheating” will incur a future penalty, Knowing this, the private sector will be more likely to expect adherence to announced intentions. Second, when the authorities’ true intentions are uncertain, today’s exchange-rate policy may help “signal” these intentions to the private sector, creating favorable future price expectations, and thus also supplying an incentive for adherence to an exchange-rate target. Third, crediblity problems may be mitigated by “tying one’s hands” by joining a monetary union (provided partner countries maintain themselves a low-inflation policy stance) or by giving up some discretionary power over exchange-rate adjustment to some supra-national authority.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II establishes the basic time-inconsistency proposition in the context of exchange rate policy in developing countries. Section III determines the degree of credibility of a fixed exchange rate by examining how the policymaker is induced to behave under alternative policy rules. Section IV focuses on how the “devaluation bias” generated by the time-inconsistency problem faced by the policymaker can be solved by building up “reputation”. Section V examines the costs and benefits of joining an international monetary arrangement in which the country surrenders the power to alter the exchange rate. The concluding section summarizes the main results of the paper, discusses possible extensions, and draws together the major implications of the analysis for exchange rate policy in developing countries pursuing a fixed exchange rate regime.
II. Time Inconsistency in Exchange Rate Policy
We examine in this section the time-inconsistency problem faced by a policymaker who must decide whether or not to maintain a fixed exchange rate, on the basis of potential gains and costs. The model we consider focuses on aspects of the economy that are relevant for developing countries, 1/ A key feature of the analysis is the assumption that policy announcements lack credibility, because the private sector is aware that the policymaker may have an incentive to renege on his commitment to an announced fixed exchange rate.
1. The framework
Consider a small open economy producing traded and nontraded goods. The economy’s exchange rate is determined by a policymaker who cares about external competitiveness and price stability. The foreign-currency price of traded goods is determined on world markets. Agents in the nontraded goods sector set their prices so as to protect their position relative to the traded goods sector, and to respond to domestic demand shocks. Prices are set at discrete intervals, while the exchange rate can be changed at very short notice. Agents in the nontraded goods sector are therefore assumed to set prices before the policymaker sets the exchange rate. 1/ Formally, the domestic rate of inflation, π, is given by
where ϵ denotes the rate of devaluation of the nominal exchange rate, πN the rate of increase in the price of nontradables,
The former objective reflects the assumption that the authorities are concerned with an improvement in competitiveness, which results from a depreciation of the real exchange rate. The rate of change of the real exchange rate enters the loss function linearly, because the authorities are assumed to attach a negative weight to a real appreciation relative to their target. 2/ The government’s overall objective is to minimize its loss function given by (2). 3/
Agents in the nontraded goods sector change prices in reaction to fluctuations in the (expected) domestic price of tradables goods, and to an exogenous demand disturbance to their sector, zN, which occurs at the beginning of the period and becomes known immediately. Their loss function is therefore taken to be:
where ɛa denotes the expected rate of depreciation of the exchange rate. The price setters’ objective is to minimize LP.
2. Discretion and precommitment
When the authorities decide whether or not to devalue the exchange rate, they know prices set in the nontraded goods sector. Substituting (1) in (2) and setting
Similarly, the optimal rate of inflation in the nontradable sector is determined by setting ∂Lp/∂πN = 0, which yields
In the non-cooperative Nash game implied by this behavior (in which each party optimizes, taking the other’s behavior as given), the equilibrium values of the nontradable inflation rate and the rate of devaluation, denoted by
where υ = δ/(1 - δ), Ω = υ/δ ≥ 1, and κ = αυ/λδ(1 - δ).
Equations (6a) and (6b) indicate that, in the absence of demand shocks, the optimal discretionary policy requires a positive rate of inflation in the nontradable sector. When demand shocks are present, that is, zN ≠ 0, whether the rate of devaluation
Substituting (6a) and (6b) in (1)-(3) yields the solutions for the overall inflation rate and the loss functions under discretion:
Equation (7a) indicates that the economy’s inflation rate is independent of the demand shock and increasing with the relative weight attached to competitiveness in the policymaker’s loss function, α/λ. Price setters achieve their target and bear no loss, Inflation is positive, because if it were zero, the policymaker would always have an incentive to devalue. Thus, the policymaker incurs a net loss unless zN takes on large negative values--which improve competitiveness and reduce the rate of increase in nontradable prices.
Consider now the case where the policymaker is able to commit himself to a predetermined exchange rate. Formally, this means that in minimizing its loss function, the policymaker takes into account the effect of its actions on private sector behavior, knowing it will not renege. In this case it can readily be shown that the policymaker will announce and maintain a fixed exchange rate--or a rate of devaluation
or, if
It is easy to verify from (7b) and (8) that L–g ≤ L –g. Thus, the no-devaluation equilibrium--the precommitment solution--gives a value of the loss function which is less than that obtained under the non-cooperative solution when zN = 0. This reflects the fact that the policymaker is not able to achieve the gain in competitiveness sought in the discretionary regime, because price setters simply increase nontradable prices accordingly. Thus, a binding commitment entails a gain in the form of a lower inflation rate with no loss in competitiveness. 2/
Consider now the case where the government announces at the beginning of the period its intention to maintain the exchange rate fixed (that is, ɛ = 0), but decides to deviate from this policy and to implement a discretionary change once price decisions are taken. Let
Once private agents in the nontraded goods sector have set their prices on the basis of the announced zero-devaluation policy, the policymaker has the incentive to renege on the declared strategy because a real exchange rate depreciation will improve external competitiveness, although this comes at the expense of an increase in inflation. The policymaker will devalue in a proportion such that the benefit of a higher rate of depreciation of the real exchange rate is just offset by the cost of a higher inflation rate. A fixed exchange rate policy is therefore time inconsistent; once it is announced and believed, the policymaker has an incentive to depart from it.
The minimized value of the policymaker’s loss function under this “cheating” regime is
where
For zN = 0, it can readily be verified that
The three different solutions are represented in Figure 1. 2/ In the πN –ϵ space, the locus PP, which reflects the objective of the private sector (given by equation 4), has a positive slope, while the policymaker’s reaction function under discretion (given by equation 5), depicted by GG, is negative. The non-cooperative equilibrium is located at the intersection of curves GG and PP, that is, at point A. The precommitment solution obtains at point 13, while the “cheating” solution obtains at point C. The discretionary solution is characterized by a “devaluation bias”. Private agents know that once they set prices of nontradables, the policymaker has the incentive to devalue so as to depreciate the real exchange rate and improve the balance of payments. They therefore set prices at a higher level, to the point where they believe the authorities are unwilling to trade off a higher inflation rate for a more depreciated real exchange rate. The precommitment solution, although not the best possible, provides a better outcome than the discretionary alternative. This provides an argument in favor of a fixed exchange rate--assuming the commitment can be made binding and perceived as such by price setters.
3. Seignorage and the incentive to devalue
It has often been observed that, to a greater extent than in industrial economies, in developing countries revenue from seignorage provides an incentive to produce inflation (see Spaventa, 1989). Bruno (1990), Cukierman (1991, Chapter 4) and Kiguel and Liviatan (1990a) for instance, have examined the time-inconsistency issue in a model in which seignorage yields a positive utility to the policymaker because it reduces the need for distortionary taxation. 1/, 2/ In a similar perspective, it may be asked whether a fixed exchange rate regime, by lowering the equilibrium level of inflation, is optimal for a policymaker who needs to rely on the inflation tax. To examine this issue in the above setting, we modify the policymaker’s loss function to
where m(.) ≥ 0 denotes the demand for real cash balances, and πa the expected inflation rate. πm measures the flow of seignorage, under the assumption of money market equilibrium. As for nontradable prices, real money holdings are chosen at the beginning of the period, on the basis of the expected inflation rate, which depends on the anticipated exchange rate policy. Therefore,
A comparison of equations (4) and (4’) shows that, at each point in time, the rate of devaluation is higher by an amount proportional to the value that the policymaker attaches to seignorage. Once agents have determined their holdings of cash balances, there is an incentive for the policymaker to depreciate the exchange rate--or raise the inflation rate--in order to increase seignorage revenues. In Figure 1, equation (4’) is represented as G’G’, with the corresponding Nash equilibrium given by point A’ where the two reaction functions intersect. 3/ The equilibrium rates of devaluation and nontradable inflation under discretion are both higher than in the previous case. It is easy to verify, however, that none of the above conclusions--in particular the ranking of policies when zN ≡ 0--are affected by this extension. 1/ We will, therefore, retain specification (2) in what follows.
Several papers have recently focused on strategic aspects of exchange rate policy. Andersen and Risager (1991), Cukierman (1991), and Horn and Persson (1988) examine the existence of a devaluation bias in a model where nominal wages are set by a trade union at the beginning of each period based on its price expectations and a real wage target. 2/ In Cukierman’s model, dynamic inconsistency explains why nominal devaluations fail to improve the current account and only cause inflation. Under discretion, the public knows in advance that the policymaker is willing to tolerate devaluations and inflation in order to improve the balance of payments. Since the policymaker is not bound by any commitment, private agents know that once nominal wage contracts have been concluded, the authorities have an incentive to devalue. They, therefore, ask and obtain higher nominal wage rates to start with. Once contracts are set, the government indeed devalues at the expected rate. However, relative to a situation without a devaluation and no expectation of a parity change, such action has no impact on the current account, since the prior actions of the public have neutralized such an effect. By precommiting exchange rate policy, the authorities can avoid this inefficient outcome. In the presence of a credible peg, unions would rationally expect no inflation and would have no reason to ask for nominal wage increases --provided the current nominal wage is, to start with, at the level that produces the desired real wage.
In the model developed here, the time-inconsistency problem is qualitatively similar to the one described in the above papers: a fixed exchange rate policy is time-inconsistent because the policymaker has an incentive to deviate from it when agents expect it to be followed, The mechanism stressed here, however, does not rely on a specific Lucas-type supply function in which only unanticipated inflation matters. Moreover, it does not rely on the assumption of a monolithic union, which has been criticized as being at variance with the institutional features of labor markets in highly developed countries (Blackburn and Christensen, 1989). 1/ The key distinctive feature of the model, however, is that the inflation rate is an endogenous variable, resulting from the behavior of both private agents (who set the price of nontradables) and the policymaker (who sets the exchange rate). As a consequence of this formulation, the optimal policy in the discretionary regime may call for a revalution of the nominal exchange rate--a feature which is absent in existing strategic models of exchange rate policy. Overall, the model developed here may provide a more realistic setup for analyzing the time-inconsistency problem in exchange rate management, particularly for small open developing economies.
III. Credibility of a Fixed Exchange Rate
In the framework described above, a fixed exchange rate policy is time-inconsistent because the authorities may gain by devaluing the nominal exchange rate so as to depreciate the real exchange rate and improve competitiveness. The policymaker’s attempt to alter the real exchange rate, however, will not be successful if the public is aware of the authorities’ temptation to deviate from a preannounced exchange rate commitment. In the resulting discretionary (or consistent) equilibrium, the rate of depreciation of the real exchange rate is zero but the rate of devaluation is inefficiently high, in the sense that it generates a costly positive rate of inflation without an offsetting gain in competitiveness.
In order to avoid this discretionary equilibrium, it has been argued above that the authorities may decide to commit themselves to a preannounced zero-devaluation rule. However, precommitment can be successful only if the authorities would incur some penalty if they deviate from their rule. One form that this penalty can take is that if the policymaker were to deviate from the preannounced rule, the public would not believe its announcements in the following period(s), so that the economy reverts to the discretionary equilibrium. In this context, a zero-devaluation rule--which is, of course, a fixed exchange rate target--is credible if the temptation to deviate from the rule is less than the discounted value of the “punishment” associated with reversion to the discretionary equilibrium, In such circumstances, it is rational for the public to believe that the rule will not be broken. Following Barro and Gordon (1983b), we use in what follows the difference between the present value of the punishment and the temptation as an indication of the degree of credibility of a fixed exchange rate regime.
Assume that, unlike in the previous Section, private agents and the government expect that their interaction will be of infinite duration. Both groups will then mimimize the discounted sum of their loss functions (2) and (3), or
As shown in the previous Section, the period-by-period loss for the policymaker when the zero-devaluation rule is expected and is actually followed,
is lower than the loss from any alternative strategy. 1/ Similarly, the total loss incurred when the policymaker “cheats” in period t and adheres to the discretionary policy thereafter is given by
Since
that is,
Equation (13) has first been derived, in a similar context, by Born and Persson (1988). The quantity
or, substituting equations (7b), (8), and (10) in (14),
For zN ≡ 0, it is easily shown that a necessary condition for the degree of credibility of a fixed exchange rate to be positive is
Equation (15) indicates that a fixed exchange rate can be credible only if the inflation rate that would obtain in a discretionary regime is high enough to “discourage” any attempt to devalue. Using (7a), it can be shown that (15) requires, in turn, γ ≥ 0.5. The initial level of credibility can therefore be equal to zero (in which case the temptation equals the punishment) or may even be negative if future losses are heavily discounted. 1/ In such circumstances, the policymaker will pursue an active exchange rate policy, and will be expected to. 2/
When the discount factor is greater than one-half, the authorities should maintain the exchange rate fixed. For zN ≡ 0, this is consistent with a zero inflation rate and a constant real exchange rate. A fixed exchange rate, under perfect information about the policymaker’s preferences, is the optimal strategy provided that the future costs of higher inflation are not sufficiently discounted so as to fall short of the current gain from a depreciation of the real exchange rate resulting from a devaluation. The potential loss of credibility, or reputation, motivates the policymaker to abide by the zero-devaluation rule; the short-term benefits from a nominal devaluation are foregone in order to secure the gain from low inflation over the long term.
Finally, it can be noted that using (15), the effect of changes in the structural parameters on the degree of credibility can be readily analyzed. For instance, since both the temptation and the punishment are increasing in α, the net effect of a change in a on credibility is a priori indeterminate, and depends on the curvature of the loss function. An increase in the degree of “openness” (as measured by a fall in δ) reduces the temptation to devalue, since it increases the effect of exchange rate changes on overall inflation, and thus increases the punishment. The net effect on exchange rate credibility of an increase in openness is therefore unambiguously positive.
IV. Incomplete Information and Exchange Rate Commitment
In this Section, we examine how reputational factors and signaling considerations may help mitigate the time inconsistency problem faced by the policymaker when choosing an exchange rate policy. The analysis is based on an extension of the model developed in the previous sections, but we now assume that agents are uncertain about the “type” of policymaker (that is, the structure of his preferences) in office.
1. Reputation and uncertain preferences
Let us assume that there is a continuum of types of policymakers which differ with respect to the cost incurred from reneging on a fixed-exchange rate commitment. 1/ The policymaker’s horizon is fixed at T periods. 2/ Formally, the government loss function can be written as
where
where
If the policymaker chooses to devalue in period t, he will do so at the optimal, discretionary rate
Assume for the moment that expectations are exogenous and are fixed at the beginning of period 0. The discounted loss incurred by the policymaker when adhering to the fixed exchange rate from periods 0 to t-1 and selecting the discretionary policy from periods t to T is given by, setting Θ ≡ 0,
or
Equation (18’) shows that sticking to a zero-devaluation rule during (0, T) yields a present-value loss equal to
while adhering to a fixed exchange rate until period T-1 and devaluing at T yields
Equation (19) shows that if the reneging cost
Consider now the behavior of expectations, As shown by equation (17), private beliefs are updated as time proceeds on the basis of observed exchange rate policy: the longer the policymaker sticks to a fixed exchange rate, the lower will be the expected rate of devaluation. But if the policymaker abandons the fixed exchange rate, private agents will raise devaluation expectations (to the discretionary level) and will adhere to such beliefs until period T, Formally, such a process of gradual learning can be formalized by assuming that private beliefs evolve according to a Bayesian rule. As shown by Rogoff (1887, 1989), a sequential process of this type leads agents to revise continually upwards the threshold level of cost below which they assume the government has an incentive to renege--provided, of course, that no devaluation occurs. As a result, devaluation expectations tend to fall over time. Although agents may never discover the “true” value of the cost attached to reneging by the policymaker, the behavior of expectations creates an incentive to commit to a fixed exchange rate rule. “Reputation”, in this context, is viewed as a mechanism which translates into a progressively lower expected rate of depreciation. 2/ Rogoff’s (1987, 1989) analysis suggests that a government which faces a relatively low cost of reneging may be tempted to devalue very early in its term in office. But if the time horizon T is long enough, (or if the discount rate is high enough) the temptation to devalue is lowered because of the costs resulting form high devaluation expectations.
The major implication of the above analysis is that even policymakers that are concerned about a balance-of-payments target may tend, at the start of their term in office, to act as if they do not in order to maintain the impression, among private agents, that inflation is the primary target and reduce expectations. Such policymakers, nevertheless, may devalue near the end of their term in office in an attempt to increase competitiveness. A nominal devaluation will “work”, in this context, as long as the policymaker has a reputation of being a “pegger”, or as long the cost of reneging on the exchange-rate commitment is not “large”. The critical element on which this result rests is the public’s lack of information about the policymaker: even if the authorities are committed to maintaining a fixed exchange rate, private agents cannot know this with certainty. Complete credibility in this context is impossible to achieve. 1/ This analysis also shows, however, how reputational factors can help overcome the time-inconsistency problem. A policymaker who is more concerned about a balance-of-payments target has nevertheless an incentive to avoid the discretionary outcome early in his term in office because doing so secures more favorable price behavior on the part of private agents.
2. Signaling and discretionary policy
We now consider a situation where there are only two types of policymakers which differ in the relative weights they attach to the “internal” target (inflation) and the “external” target (the real exchange rate). Using a variant of the terminology developed by Vickers (1986) and used as well by Horn and Persson (1988), we call the first type D-policymakers (“devaluers”) who attach a value to both low inflation and to a more depreciated real exchange rate. The second type, called P-policymakers (“peggers”), attaches a lower weight to the real exchange rate in its loss function. Price setters do not know the type of policymaker in office, but they have a prior probability that the policymaker is of type P. As time proceeds, private agents observe the exchange rate policy and revise their assessment of the policymaker’s type.
In the presence of imperfect information about policymakers’ preferences, even a government that cares relatively more about inflation (i.e. a P-type policymaker) may have an incentive to devalue less that it would otherwise find optimal, in order to signal its preferences to the public. As shown by Vickers (1986), a policymaker who cares relatively more about inflation can signal his preferences to the private sector by inducing a temporary recession. 2/ Policy-makers with relatively greater concern about output and employment are unwilling to bear this cost, so the signal successfully conveys the policymaker’s intention to disinflate. In the context of the above analysis, Vicker’s analysis suggests that one way for the P-type policymaker to reveal his identity might be to select an exchange rate policy which is such that the D-type policymaker would not find optimal to replicate. Such a policy would not, of course, be without cost for the P-type policymaker, but could be a credible signalling device under some circumstances. In what follows, we show that, under imperfect information about its preferences, an anti-inflation government may devalue by less than it would find otherwise optimal, in order to signal unambiguously its policy goals to price setters and its commitment to price stability.
For simplicity, we consider a two-period game. In period 1, only the policymaker acts, and sets
From equation (3), with zN ≡ 0,
while from (2), with πN (1) = 0,
so that
As indicated above, agents do not know the type of the policymaker in office. They only have a probability ρ of having a P-policymaker in office. 2/ They also know, however, that the P-policymaker puts a lower weight on the real exchange rate target, and sets 0 ≤ αP < αD. In period 1, the D-policymaker pledges to refrain from a large depreciation (it mimics the P-type) because he hopes to deter agents from raising nontradable prices too rapidly in period 2. If, however, agents do increase prices, the D-policymaker will renege on his commitment to a low depreciation rate in the second period--assuming that reneging does not entail prohibitive costs--and will devalue so as to offset the loss in competitiveness, as shown in equation (22).
From (20) and (22), the non-cooperative solution obtained when agents can identify unambiguously the type of policymaker in office is given by
where κi = αiυ/λδ(1 - δ), and κp < κD. Equations (23) basically replicate the time-inconsistency result derived in Section II. 1/ For both types of policymakers, a fixed exchange rate is the optimal policy
Equations (23) also show that both types of policymakers have a well-defined strategy in the second period--under rational expectations
The solution to this problem is as follows. When price setters observe the exchange rate signal in period 1, they do not know precisely the type of policymaker in office, They recognize, however, that there is a possibility that both types may be sending the same signal (that is,
If the two types send separate signals, however, private agents will be able to distinguish between the P-policymaker (and will accordingly set
which shows that, since κp < κD, the higher the probability of having a P-policymaker in office (the higher ρ), the lower the rate of increase in nontradable prices and, from (23), the lower the rate of depreciation of the exchange rate.
We focus in what follows on separating equilibria, in which the first-period action reveals the policymaker’s type. 2/ In this case, the P-type government separates itself from the D-type by setting
For a separating equilibrium to exist, there must clearly he no incentive for the D-policymaker to choose
Intuitively, the conditions for the existence of a separating equilibrium mean that the P-policymaker’s gain resulting from lower nontradable prices in the future must outweigh the immediate loss incurred by depreciating the exchange rate by less than the optimal perfect-information amount, whereas for the D-policymaker, the loss associated with an initially lower rate of depreciation must exceed the immediate benefit of getting a lower price reaction in the next period. The first inequality in (26) sets an upper bound on ɛ1, while the second leads to a lower bound on ϵ1. equations (20)-(26), The following ranges are obtained: 1/
where
The above result provides an interesting argument in support of an exchange rate freeze in stabilization programs, of the type that has been observed recently in many Latin American countries and Israel (see, for instance, Kiguel and Liviatan 1990b). Fixing the exchange rate (or more generally lowering the rate of depreciation of the exchange rate) may prove successful in signaling the anti-inflationary commitment of the policymaker, and will therefore enhance the credibility of a stabilization program, 2/ Indeed, an extension of the argument suggests that it may ultimately be beneficial for a government to revalue its currency to convey unambiguous information about its policy preferences. Chile, for instance, revalued its currency twice in 1977, in an attempt to demonstrate the government’s resolve to fight inflation. An argument along these lines has also been presented by Winckler (1991) to explain the decision of the United Kingdom to enter the Exchange Rate Mechanism of the EMS at an appreciated exchange rate on October 8, 1990.
There are, however, situations in which signaling considerations are incapable of mitigating the time-inconsistency problem. For instance, both types of government may have a high rate of time preference, in which case the optimal solutions under perfect information and uncertain preferences may not be very different from each other. Intuitively, this is because D-type policymakers have a reduced incentive to masquerade as a P-type. Since price setters are aware of this, the signal that must be sent by the P-policymaker to separate himself from the D-type need not be as “strong”. 3/ Another situation (which may prove particularly relevant for developing countries) may be that, when implementing a disinflation strategy, countries are faced with a large current account deficit and a financing constraint--which render a “high” rate of depreciation inevitable. Formally, this is reflected in the weight a which, if sufficiently large, eliminates the region in which separating equilibria may be obtained. Finally, there are other ways for a P-type policymaker to send signals that would enable the public to clearly identify his preferences: signals may be sent via the removal of capital controls, a drastic cut in the budget deficit, the appointment of a “conservative” central banker, etc. An interesting extension to the present analysis would be, therefore, to examine in a more detailed model the benefits and costs of alternative signaling strategies.
V. Credibility Effects of Monetary Unions
An alternative way to attach credibility to a fixed exchange rate regime (and signal the policymaker’s commitment to a stable parity) would be for the authorities to surrender the power to alter the exchange rate. This could be achieved, for instance, by forming a monetary union under which a group of countries adopt a common currency and fix their parity against a major currency--for developing countries, the CFA Franc Zone or the East Caribbean Currency Area provide examples of such an arrangement. A less rigid arrangement would probably be more similar to the European Monetary System, under which the exchange rate can be adjusted periodically, although such adjustments are subject to international scrutiny. The credibility argument has indeed been presented as an important consideration favoring EMS membership, especially among small high-inflation European countries. One way for a government to establish credibility for an anti-inflationary policy is to appoint a conservative central banker, who is highly averse to inflation (Rogoff, 1985). It has been argued that EMS membership plays an equivalent role: it allows member countries, in effect, to appoint a German central banker, establishing credibility by linking the country’s monetary policy to the strong anti-inflationary preferences of the Bundesbank. 1/ By “tying their hands” when joining a fixed- exchange rate arrangement, therefore, policymakers can combat inflationary expectations more effectively. 1/ In these circumstances, it may be desirable for the authorities to adopt an institutional arrangement that imposes large--political or otherwise--costs to reneging on such precommitment. The important and general point emphasized in this line of reasoning is that, to be credible, such monetary arrangements have to be based on institutional features that make it costly to alter the exchange rate.
There are, however, costs associated with foregoing the use of the exchange rate as a policy instrument, particularly in the presence of large external shocks. The credibility of a country’s commitment to the “rules of the game” of a monetary union--and thus the extent to which membership in a union can overcome time-inconsistency problems--must depend on the nature of such costs. This section examines these issues by extending the model developed previously so as to capture the institutional and macroeconomic constraints imposed by an international monetary arrangement.
1. Credibility and political costs
Consider a country which has to decide whether or not to join an international monetary union. By joining, it incurs a fixed domestic political cost of cj, per period as long as it adheres to the fixed-exchange rate agreement, but enjoys full credibility for its declared parity. If it decides to join and then reneges on its commitment, it incurs a fixed (international) political cost of cL. 2/,3/ If the country commits itself at period t = 0, the present discounted value of the costs incurred by joining the union forever is given by
Similarly, the present discounted value of the costs of leaving the currency arrangement forever--assuming, for simplicity, that at t = 0 the country is already a member of the union--is given by 1/
The degree of credibility of a fixed exchange rate, as previously defined, must accordingly be modified to reflect the existence of political costs, Adding (28) to (11) and (29) to (12) and solving as before yields, for credibility to be positive, 2/
Equation (30) indicates that the higher the political cost of leaving a currency union relative to the cost of joining the arrangement, the less stringent the condition that must be satisfied by the discount factor to ensure credibility. By choosing to precommit its exchange rate policy to a zero-devaluation path as a member of a currency union, the government incurs an additional domestic political cost in each period. This requires that future losses be subjected to a smaller discount rate (or a higher γ) if credibility of the fixed exchange rate is to be ensured. By contrast, an increase in the cost incurred by the policymaker when he reneges on his fixed-rate commitment within the currency union lowers the requisite discount rate. This is because the short-term benefit resulting from a discretionary exchange rate change is reduced by an additional cost which is incurred over a longer term. Political costs may therefore have an enforcement effect which can alleviate the institutional deficiency behind the devaluation bias.
2. The optimality of “tying one’s hands”
Consider now a country which has to decide whether or not to maintain its exchange rate fixed within the framework of a monetary union with its major trading partner. Suppose, moreover, that inflation in the partner country is positive, or that there is a positive shock to the price of tradables, that is,
which yields an overall inflation rate equal to
and a rate of change of the real exchange rate
If the authorities decide to maintain the nominal exchange rate fixed, and if such a policy is believed by price setters,
the loss function is equal to
A comparison of equations (33) and (35) shows that the loss under a (credible) commitment to maintain the exchange rate fixed is higher than under discretion when
The analysis suggests therefore that, for a government possessing a loss function which trades off inflation and competitiveness, the desirability of “tying one’s hands” as a solution to the time- inconsistency problem depends on whom one’s hands are tied to. If joining a monetary union subjects a country to large nominal shocks, the credibility gain may be outweighed by the cost of lost autonomy. When the economy is not subjected to large adverse nominal shocks (that is, when union members have stable, low inflation rates), a case can be made for the authorities to precommit to a fixed exchange rate as a means of demonstrating their resolve to maintain financial discipline. But when the economy is subject to large nominal shocks, it may be optimal to alter the exchange rate. Thus, while it may be desirable for policymakers to attach a greater weight to price stability than that perceived by society as a whole (Rogoff, 1985), this weight should not be so large that the exchange rate is never moved.
In practice, exchange rate arrangements involving a peg typically incorporate an “escape clause” or a contingency mechanism which allows members to deviate from the declared parity under exceptional circumstances. 1/ To examine this issue in the above setting, suppose that
The expected rate of depreciation of the exchange rate will therefore be given by
or, using (2),
where
which is lower than (31b), since devaluation expectations are lower. An implication of equation (38) is that the higher q is--or, equivalently, the lower μ is--the more effective is a contingency mechanism in mitigating the devaluation bias of a discretionary regime
The actual (ex post) rate of depreciation of the real exchange rate is determined by the size of the foreign price shock. If the realized value of
which is in general indeterminate. The point, however, is that in “normal circumstances”, a high probability of using the contingency mechanism has a negative effect on competitiveness. This suggests, therefore, that if this type of mechanism is to be considered as part of an exchange-rate arrangement, q should not be “too high”, that is, the threshold above which a discretionary adjustment of the exchange rate is allowed should not be too “low”.
Finally, having shown the pros and cons for a small country of avoiding time-inconsistency problems by joining a monetary union in which the exchange rate is kept unalterably fixed, we can show that time-consistency problems could also be mitigated--and countries be made better off--by considering a more “flexible” type of monetary arrangement in which countries commonly manage the exchange rate, through a supra-national entity with discretionary powers. 1/ Essentially, this is because the supra-national entity always chooses a rate of devaluation that is less than would have been chosen by the domestic country if it acted alone, because it takes into account the induced adverse effect of an exchange rate depreciation on the competitiveness of the foreign country. Again, a fixed exchange-rate arrangement can be viewed as a “solution” to the time-inconsistency problem--in the sense of representing a compromise between the benefits of complete flexibility and the need for precommitment--only when the economy is not subjected to large, external shocks. When, on the contrary, foreign price disturbances are large, the cooperative solution in which a supra-national entity determines the “optimal” rate of depreciation of the exchange rate may yield a more favorable outcome.
VI. Concluding Remarks
The purpose of this paper has been to examine the time-inconsistency problem in the conduct of exchange rate policy which creates incentives for policymakers to “cheat” on fixed-exchange rate announcements, and the role that reputational factors, signaling considerations, and adherence to a currency union may play to alleviate it. The analysis has been based on a model in which the interactions between price-setting behavior in the nontraded goods sector and concerns over the behavior of the real exchange rate create a temptation for the policymaker to pursue an active exchange rate policy. In this setting, inflation arises because price setters rationally fear that the authorities will try to devalue in order to depreciate the real exchange rate. The analysis also shows that a binding commitment to a fixed exchange rate, if feasible, would result in lower inflation with no loss in competitiveness. If commitment is not feasible--or not credible--the outcome is biased towards an inflationary process resulting from exchange rate devaluations, even in the absence of demand shocks. The incentive structure under a pegged arrangement thus may not be conducive to the adoption of an immutably fixed exchange rate (with attendant financial discipline) but rather to periodic devaluations.
The degree of credibility of a fixed exchange rate has been analyzed under the general assumption that a no-devaluation rule is credible only if it is rational for the public to believe that the authorities have the incentive to adhere to it. Credibility can be achieved if the policymaker worries enough about his reputation and balances future losses of credibility against immediate prospective balance-of-payments gains. Alternatively, when the preferences of the policymaker are uncertain, eschewing devaluation may provide a valuable signal to the private sector, thus increasing the incentives for the authorities to adhere to an announced exchange rate target. The analysis has also focused on the rationale for joining an international monetary arrangement which is intended to lead to permanently fixed exchange rates. Following Giavazzi and Pagano (1988), it has been argued that one could view an exchange rate union as a mechanism that enhances the pegging government’s credibility by raising the cost of inflationary policies. Governments can make binding commitments to the rules in the zone while they cannot precommit to macroeconomic rules outside the system because there are significant costs to the option of dropping out: these costs are related to the gains from macroeconomic cooperation that member countries would forego by going it alone. Finally, we have examined how international serveillance over exchange rate movements--in the limit by surrendering the discretionary power to alter the exchange rate to a supra-national authority--can enhance the credibility of an exchange-rate target by weakening the incentives for competitive devaluations.
There are several extensions of the present analysis that would be worth investigating. 1/ First, the paper has not examined the role of budgetary and monetary policies in supporting a credible exchange rate policy. The relationship between fiscal policies and the credibility of the commitment of a country to price stability is, however, crucial. More generally, the analysis of credibility developed here is partial in the sense that it focuses only on exchange rate management. In practice, credibility should be assessed in the context of a model where several other policy instruments are available, and where their overall consistency with policy goals is deemed important. In that regard, an important issue would be to examine under what conditions an announced fixing of the nominal exchange rate might be preferable to a money supply target as a nominal anchor for tight financial policies. 1/
Second, the analysis does not deal with the intertemporal aspects of the government budget constraint in a fixed exchange rate regime, and its implications for the credibility and viability of a fixed parity. 2/ Third, the analysis could be extended to consider the effect of credibility on balance-of-payments crises. When agents perceive that the authorities’ commitment--and ability--to maintain a fixed exchange rate is weak, speculative attacks may occur. If successful, a speculative attack will be self-fulfilling in the sense that it will lead to a devaluation--or a realignment of the currency within an exchange rate union. Such an attack may occur when the competitiveness of a high-inflation country has been eroded by holding the nominal exchange rate parity. This will, therefore, generate speculation that the currency will be devalued which may lead to an eventual exhaustion of the authorities’ foreign exchange reserves and their external borrowing capacity, forcing them to devalue. Such a situation may be exacerbated if price setters incorporate the possibility of a devaluation in their pricing behavior, thereby adding further inflationary pressure.
Nevertheless, independently of how useful these extensions might prove to be, the central implication of the analysis developed here is likely to remain unaltered, In countries where policymakers can use the nominal exchange rate so as to alter the degree of competitiveness or to affect prices, simply fixing the exchange rate will not in general be sufficient to ensure financial and price stability. Additional institutional mechanisms must be enforced to convince a skeptical public of the authorities’ commitment to adhere to its stated policy.
References
Aghevli, Bijan B., Mohsin S. Khan, and Peter J. Montiel, “Exchange Rate Policy in Developing Countries: Some Analytical Issues,” Occasional Paper No 78 (International Monetary Fund: March 1991).
Andersen, Torben M., and Ole Risager, “The Role of Credibility for the Effects of a Change in the Exchange-Rate Policy,” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 41 (January 1991), pp. 85-98.
Backus, David, and John Driffill, “Inflation and Reputation,” American Economic Review, Vol. 75 (June 1985a), pp. 530-38.
Backus, David, and John Driffill, “Rational Expectations and Policy Credibility Following a Change in Regime,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 52 (April 1985b), pp. 211-21.
Barro, Robert J., “Inflationary Finance under Discretion and Rules,” Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 16 (February 1983), pp. 1-16.
Barro, Robert J., Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy with Incomplete Information,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 17 (March 1986a), pp. 3-20.
Barro, Robert J., ”Recent Developments in the Theory of Rules versus Discretion,” Economic Journal, Vol. 96 (March 1986b), pp. 23-37.
Barro, Robert J., and David B. Gordon, “A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91 (August 1983a), pp. 589-610.
Barro, Robert J., and David B. Cordon, “Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12 (July 1983b), pp. 101-21.
Blackburn, Keith, and Michael Christensen, “Monetary Policy and Policy Credibility: Theories and Evidence,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 27 (March 1989), pp. 1-45.
Bordo, Michael D., and Angela Redish, “Credible Commitment and Exchange Rate Stability: Canada’s Interwar Experience,” Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 23 (May 1990), pp. 357-80.
Bruno, Michael, “High-Inflation and the Nominal Anchors of an Open Economy,” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No 3518, Cambridge Mass. (November 1990).
Canzoneri, Matthew, and Dale Henderson, “Is Sovereign Policymaking Bad?,” in Stabilization Policy and Labor Markets, ed. by Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series, Vol. 28, North-Holland (Amsterdam: 1988).
Calvo, Guillermo A., “On the Time Consistency of Optimal Policy in a Monetary Economy,” Econometrica, Vol. 46 (November 1978), pp. 1411-28.
Cho, In-Koo, and David M. Kreps, “Signalling Games and Stable Equilibria,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 111 (May 1987), pp. 179-221.
Cukierman, Alex, Central Bank Behavior, Credibility, Accomodation and Stabilization, mimeo, April 1991. Forthcoming, MIT Press (Cambridge, Mass).
Cukierman, Alex, and Allan H. Meltzer, “A Theory of Ambiguity, Credibility, and Inflation under Discretion and Asymmetric Information,” Econometrica, Vol. 54 (September 1986), pp. 1099-1128.
Driffill, John, “Macroeconomic Policy Games with Incomplete Information: Some Extensions,” Discussion Paper No 159, Center for Economic Policy Research (London: February 1987).
Fischer, Stanley, “Exchange Rate versus Money Targets in Disinflation,” in Stanley Fischer, Indexing, Inflation and Economic Policy, MIT Press (Cambridge, Mass.: 1986).
Fischer, Stanley, and Lawrence H. Summers, “Should Governments Learn to Live with Inflation?,” American Economic Review, Vol. 79 (May 1989), pp. 382-87.
Flood, Robert P., and Peter Isard, “Monetary Policy Strategies,” Staff Papers (International Monetary Fund), Vol. 36 (September 1989), pp. 612-32.
Friedman, James W., Game Theory with Applications to Economics, Oxford University Press, 2nd ed. (New York: 1990).
Genberg, Hans, “Exchange Rate Management and Macroeconomic Policy: A National Perspective,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 91 (June 1989), pp. 439-69.
Giavazzi, Francesco, and Alberto Giovannini, “Interpreting the European Disinflation: The Role of the Exchange Rate Regime,” in Limiting Exchange Rate Flexibility, ed. by Francesco Giavazzi and Alberto Giovannini (Cambridge, Mass.: 1989).
Giavazzi, Francesco, and Marco Pagano, “The Advantage of Tying One’s Hands: EMS Discipline and Central Bank Credibility,” European Economic Review, Vol. 32 (June 1988), pp. 1055-82.
Grossman, Herschel I., and J. B. Van Huyck, “Seignorage, Inflation, and Reputation,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 18 (July 1986), pp. 21-31.
Horn, Henrik, and Torsten Persson, “Exchange Rate Policy, Wage Formation and Credibility,” European Economic Review, Vol. 32 (October 1988), pp. 1621-36.
Joshi, Vijay, “Exchange Rate Regimes in Developing Countries,” in Public Policy and Economic Development, ed. by Maurice Scott and Deepak Lal, Clarendon Press (Oxford: 1990)
Kamin, Steven B., “Exchange Rate Rules in Support of Disinflation Programs in Developing Countries,” Federal Reserve Board of Governors, Wasington DC, mimeo (February 1991).
Kiguel, Miguel, and Nissan Liviatan, “Some Implications of Policy Games for High Inflation Economies,” PRE Working Paper No 379 (the World Bank: March 1990a).
Kiguel, Miguel, and Nissan Liviatan, “The Business Cycle Associated with Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilization,” PRE Working Paper No 513, the World Bank (October 1990b).
Kreps, David M., and R. Wilson, “Reputation and Imperfect Information,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 27 (August 1982), pp. 253-79.
Kydland, Finn E., and Edward C. Prescott, “Rules rather than discretion: the Inconsistency of Optimal Plans,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 85 (June 1977), pp. 473-91.
Lane, Timothy, and Liliana Rojas-Suarez, “Credibility, Capital Controls, and the EMS,” Working Paper No 89/9, International Monetary Fund (January 1989). Forthcoming, Journal of International Economics.
Meltzer, Allan H., and Alex Cukierman, “A Theory of Ambiguity, Credibility and Inflation under Discretion and Asymmetric Information,” Econometrica, Vol. 54 (September 1986), pp. 1099-128.
Mino, Kazuo, and Shunichi Tsutsui, “Reputational Constraint and Signalling Effects in a Monetary Policy Game,” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 42 (July 1990), pp. 603-19.
Obstfeld, Maurice, “A Model of Currency Depreciation and the Debt Inflation Spiral,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 15 (January 1991a), pp. 151-77.
Obstfeld, Maurice, “Destabilizing Effects of Exchange-Rate Escape Clauses,” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No 3603 (January 1991b).
Persson, Torsten, “Credibility of Macroeconomic Policy: An Introduction and a Broad Survey,” European Economic Review, Vol. 32 (March 1988), pp. 519-32.
Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini, Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics, Harwood Academic Publishers (London: 1989).
Rogoff, Kenneth, “The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 100 (November 1985), pp. 1169-89.
Rogoff, Kenneth, “Reputational Constraints on Monetary Policy,” in Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 26, North- Holland (Amsterdam, 1987).
Rogoff, Kenneth, “Reputation, Coordination, and Monetary Policy,” in Modern Business Cycle Theory, ed. by Robert J. Barro, Harvard University Press (Cambridge, Mass.: 1989).
Spaventa, Luigi, “Seignorage: Old and New Policy Issues,” European Economic Review, Vol. 33 (March 1989), pp. 557-63.
Vickers, John, “Signalling in a Model of Monetary Policy with Incomplete Information,” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 38 (November 1986), pp. 443-55.
Winckler, Georg, “Exchange Rate Appreciation as a Signal of a New Policy Stance,”, Working Paper No 91/32, International Monetary Fund (March 1991).
The author would like to thank, without implication, Alex Cukierman, Paul Masson, Steven Kamin, Mohsin Khan and Anna Lennblad for helpful discussions and comments on successive drafts. Particular thanks are due to Peter Montiel, who was involved at all stages in this project.
These arguments relate to the role of exchange rate stability in the promotion of trade flows, foreign investment, etc. See Genberg (1988) and Joshi (1990) for a recent review of the literature on the choice of an exchange rate regime.
The dynamic inconsistency literature in macroeconomics has been almost exclusively concerned with the alleged inflationary bias of macroeconomic policy. For surveys of this literature, see Barra (1986b), Blackburn and Christensen (1989), Cukierman (1991), and Persson (1988). Papers that have specifically focused on exchange rate policy are discussed below.
Although the paper attempts to highlight particular policy considerations deemed relevant for developing countries, the major implications of the analysis are also relevant for small, industrialized countries.
This assumption, which reflects price stickiness, is important because without it there would be no incentive for the authorities to adjust the exchange rate. If policy is implemented before nontradable prices are set, the issue of time-inconsistency is irrelevant because the government policy is revealed when it is announced.
Note that the real exchange rate target could he expressed in level form; the rate of change formulation used here is simply easier to work with analytically.
More general loss functions are considered, for instance, in Fischer and Summers (1989). Stochastic preferences are examined in Cukierman and Meltzer (1986).
Note that equation (4) would not be independent of ⊖ if the cost of deviations from the real exchange rate target in the loss function (2) were quadratic. This would occur if the policymaker were concerned not only with competitiveness of the tradable sector, but also with the beneficial effects of an appreciation of the real exchange rate. For instance, a real appreciation can benefit the economy by stimulating employment when wages are indexed to the price level, or by lowering the cost of imported intermediate goods, Thy, major implications of the analysis would not, however, be qualitatively altered by this extension.
That is, when λ is “high”, when α is “low”, or more generally when
However, the government would still be subject to the same credibility problem as in the discretionary equilibrium if it merely announces a fixed exchange rate. To work, the commitment must be binding. We assume this can be achieved for the moment, and will return to this issue below.
However, if the effect of the demand shock on nontradable prices is large enough, the loss under precommitment can exceed that obtained under discretion, that is,
For positive demand shocks, the loss under cheating will always be less than that obtained under discretion
Suppose the authorities are mainly concerned with the balance-of-payments objective. An alternative way to formulate the cheating solution is then to assume that a fixed exchange rate is announced, but that they actually devalue so as to maintain ϵ - πN = 0. If the private sector acts on the basis of the announcement, πN = ΦzN = π. The loss function becomes
The Figure assumes that α/λ > δ(1- δ)ΦzN, which ensures that
The analysis in Bruno, Cukierman and Kiguel-Liviatan is based on an earlier paper by Barro (1983). Calvo (1978) provides a general analysis of the time-inconsistency problem based on seignorage considerations. In his model, however, the policymaker attaches no cost to inflation, so that there is no well-defined solution under discretion. See also Grossman and Van Huyck (1986), who examine the role of reputational factors in Calvo’s model.
Inflation itself has distortionary effects, which is one way to explain the negative utility associated with deviations from price stability in the model above.
In equilibrium, expectations are rational. An explicit solution can be derived by taking a linear approximation of m(πa).
The qualitative features of the solutions noted above remain also unaffected when zN ≠ 0.
In Andersen and Risager (1991) and Horn and Persson (1988) the policymaker’s loss function is assumed to depend on inflation and the level of employment. Cukierman (1991), however, explicitly considers the current account deficit as a policy target in addition to the rate of increase of prices.
The assumption of synchronized price setting in the nontradable sector may, however, be subject to the same type of criticism, although it may appear more defensible.
This type of behavior represents a “trigger strategy” discussed for instance by Friedman (1990), and used by Barro and Gordon (1983b), and Horn and Persson (1988), among others. However, such a process is not the only rational process possible leading to “perfect” equilibria. The problem of multiple solutions to intertemporal games is well known; Rogoff (1987, pp. 151–53) gives an example of another consistent set of strategies.
This assumption of an “infinite” punishment interval follows Horn and Persson (1988) and is justified below.
Note that in this certainty setting a reputational equilibrium is possible only if the horizon of the policymaker it infinite. Otherwise the policymaker would be sure in the last period to produce the discretionary outcome whatever the behavior of the private sector is, and working backwards would be expected to do the same in the first period. This is so because the policymaker will always find it optimal to choose the discretionary outcome in period r if he is expected to do so in period t+1, since in this case there would be no reputation gain from eschewing such behavior in period t.
A similar result is derived by Horn and Persson (1988). A possible reason for a high discount rate might be an exogenous institutional constraint, such as the need for the government to seek re-election periodically.
If the credibility loss lasted only one period, the policymaker would devalue further in every succeeding period because he is faced with the same decision each time. This would occur despite the fact that in this model the choice of a current rate of devaluation implies no direct constraints on future choices.
The issue of uncertain preferences was first examined in the context of models of monetary policy in a closed economy developed by Backus and Driffill (1985a, 1985b) and Barra (1986a), whose work has been extended to consider exchange rate policy by Horn and Persson (1988), and Andersen and Risager (1991). The methodology used in these papers rely on the theory of incomplete information games developed by Kreps and Wilson (1982). The analysis that follows here relies, in part, on Rogoff (1987, 1989).
The value of T is common knowledge and may be related to the term of office of the government. More generally, it may be assumed that the government believes that its actions will not affect the credibility of future governments beyond period T.
In models of exchange-rate policy such as those of Andersen and Risager (1991) or Horn and Persson (1988), in which there are no (contemporaneous) cost of reneging on an exchange-rate commitment, a policymaker who is more concerned with a “real” target is certain to devalue in period T because there is no incentive to invest in “reputation” beyond T.
In Barro’s (1986) analysis, as well as in Horn and Persson (1988), reputation is explicitly defined in probabilistic terms, However, Barro’s approach has the unattractive feature of involving a phase of randomizing strategy. Mino and Tsutsui (1990) consider, as is done here, a model with a continuum of policymakers, which differ by the relative weight attached to the “real” target in the government loss function.
Driffill (1987) considers the case where private agents are unable to monitor perfectly the policymaker’s actions due to exogenous disturbances.
See also Cukierman (1991) for a useful exposition of Vickers' model.
Since prices are fixed at the beginning of every period, they cannot respond to the signal sent by the current, effective devaluation rate. As a result, the assumption of πN (1) = 0 does not have much bearing on the analysis that follows.
ρ can be taken as determined by factors such as the fraction of governments which historically have turned out to maintain a fixed exchange rate during their terms, the appearance and personality of the elected politicians, etc.
Note that, as a result of the rise in nontradable prices in period 2,
This is important because it implies that the “cost” of signaling the anti-inflation stance of the P-policymaker will not persist beyond period 1.
The assumption of rational expectations rules out any “cheating” strategy by the policymaker, and ensures a time-consistent outcome.
Vickers (1986) shows that practically all pooling equilibria can be eliminated in this type of problem, by appealing to several refinements to solution concepts, in particular the Cho-Kreps (1987) intuitive criterion. See also Cukierman (1991).
The inequalities (26) yield the polynomials
where, for i = P, D,
Solving for the roots of P(ϵ1) and D(ϵ1) yields equations (27).
It can be seen from (27a) that an increase in a increases the optimal range for signaling behavior for the P-policymaker. From (27b), an increase in αD reduces the range for the D-type.
A sufficient condition for the intersection of the sets defined by (27a) and (27b) to be non empty is
a condition which is always satisfied, since Ψ > 0 and q > 1.
This requires recourse to a restriction which eliminates “weakly dominated strategies.” Essentially, the closer is
An alternative view on this issue relates to Kamin’s (1991) discussion of “front-loading” in exchange rate management--a deliberate over-depreciation of the nominal exchange rate in the initial phase of a stabilization program, so as to “undervalue” the real exchange rate and provide room for possible future policy slippages, The above discussion suggests, however, that over-depreciation may send the “wrong” signal in the context of a disinflation program.
Formally, one needs to consider the effect of a change in γ on Dmin, which yields
See Giavazzi and Giovannini (1989), and Giavazzi and Pagano (1988). Lane and Rojas-Suarez (1989) have questioned the “credibility effect” attached to EMS membership by arguing that such a view is inconsistent with the existence of exchange rate bands within the system. However, such fluctuation bands may be viewed as a response to the trade-off between exchange rate flexibility, required for stabilization and competitiveness, and fixity, required to enhance credibility.
Italy, for instance, is thought to have been able to solve its precommitment problem by tying the lira to the mark (Canzoneri and Henderson, 1988). The annual inflation differential vis-à-vis Germany has been brought down from an average of 12 percentage points in 1979–83 to nearly 3 percentage points in 1988–90, while the lira’s average annual rate of depreciation vis-à-vis the mark declined from over 6 percent to 1 percent over the same period. However, this “solution” to the credibility issue has been criticized by Canzoneri and Henderson (op. cit.). An announcement about an exchange rate target is not necessarily more binding than an announcement about a money supply target, This issue is further discussed below.
c J itself could be made a function of the length of the period during which the country maintains its exchange rate fixed in the arrangement, while cL could depend on the size of the exchange rate change--should the country decide to devalue. These extensions would not, however, alter the basic implication of the analysis.
The international exchange-rate arrangement could be such that it also reduces the member countries’ discretionary power by imposing a committment to a higher weight on inflation in the domestic policymaker’s loss function. This would work just as if the country were agreeing to appoint a “conservative” central bank (as suggested by Rogoff, 1985), since it would induce less inflationary price setting behavior (note from (6b) that
Note that since cL is constant, it does not matter for the expression in (29) whether the government chooses the cheating solution or the discretionary outcome when it decides to alter the exchange rate.
We assume that the political cost differential is such that the condition γ ≤ 1 holds, or that (cJ - c L) < α κ/2.
A case in point is the Bretton Woods system, The optimality properties of monetary policy rules which combine discretionary elements and state-contingent mechanisms have been discussed by Flood and Isard (1989). See also Obstfeld (1991b) and Persson and Tabellini (1989).
This could represent, for instance, an extreme case of international surveillance over exchange-rate changes exercised by a multilateral financial agency. A formal analysis of this issue in the context of a two-contry model is developed in an earlier version of this paper, available from the author on request.
The design of empirical methods to evaluate the degree of credibility of a fixed exchange rate regime is only just beginning and constitutes an important part of the research agenda in this area; see Bordo and Redish (1990) for a recent attempt which focuses on Canada’s interwar experience.
For a discussion of alternative nominal anchors for an open economy, see Fischer (1986) and Bruno (1990).
See Obstfeld (1991a) for a recent attempt to examine this issue.