Output Fluctuations and Monetary Shocks
Evidence From Colombia
Author:
Mr. Vincent Reinhart https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Mr. Vincent Reinhart in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
and
Ms. Carmen Reinhart https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Ms. Carmen Reinhart in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Using annual data for Colombia over the last thirty years and a new battery of econometric techniques, we test opposing theories that explain macroeconomic fluctuations: The neoclassical synthesis, which posits that, in the presence of temporary price rigidity, an unanticipated monetary expansion produces output gains that erode over time with increases in the price level; and an alternative explanation, which focuses on “real” technological or preference shocks as the sources of output changes. The coefficients from these systems are used to examine two basic propositions: the long-run neutrality of nominal quantities with respect to permanent movements in the money stock; and the short-run sensitivity of output to inflation.

Abstract

Using annual data for Colombia over the last thirty years and a new battery of econometric techniques, we test opposing theories that explain macroeconomic fluctuations: The neoclassical synthesis, which posits that, in the presence of temporary price rigidity, an unanticipated monetary expansion produces output gains that erode over time with increases in the price level; and an alternative explanation, which focuses on “real” technological or preference shocks as the sources of output changes. The coefficients from these systems are used to examine two basic propositions: the long-run neutrality of nominal quantities with respect to permanent movements in the money stock; and the short-run sensitivity of output to inflation.

I. Introduction

Any macroeconomic model makes a judgment—explicit or implicit—concerning the correlations among money, income, and prices. The neoclassical synthesis, represented by models combining forward–looking agents planning their spending decisions in the face of temporarily rigid prices, predicts that an unexpected monetary relaxation will be associated with an elevated level of real output at first, but that the output gain erodes over time with increases in the price level. 1/ On the other hand, an influential group of researchers have offered nonmonetary frameworks that explain observed correlations among real variables in terms of real impulses, such as technological or preference shocks. Money enters the picture after the important decisions are made, with nominal quantities settling at levels reflecting an endogenous provision of money balances. 2/

This paper, taking advantage of a new battery of econometric techniques, tests these opposing macroeconomic theories against the annual data for Colombia over the last thirty years. Colombia, with a history of moderate to high rates of price increase, offers a range of variation of the basic time series without the pathologies inherent in hyperinflations. The basic strategy is to estimate a compact reduced form system explaining the predictable comovements among the nominal money stock, the price level, and real income. The coefficients from this system are used to examine two basic propositions: the long–run neutrality of nominal quantities with respect to permanent movements in the nominal stock of money; and the more short–run sensitivity of output to inflation (which proved troublesome for Barro, (1979)). The unexplained portion of the movement in these variables is then given a structural interpretation by imposing identifying assumptions on the pattern of correlation among the residuals, as in Adams (1990) and Blanchard (1989), thus providing some insight on the nature of the underlying shocks and the economy’s propagation mechanism. Our goal is not to impose strict theoretical priors on the macroeconomic time series, but rather capture the key set of empirical regularities that any reasonable theory, at a minimum, must capture.

The empirical linkage between monetary policy and inflation has been documented for Colombia by Barro (1979), Clavijo and Gomez (1988), Edwards (1984), Fernandez Riva (1988), and Leiderman (1984), among others. These papers commonly find evidence of a positive and statistically significant relationship between monetary growth and inflation. Indeed, a majority indicate the presence of a causal linkage running from money to output and prices, thus favoring the neoclassical explanation of macroeconomic fluctuations. However, these studies have not typically examined the time–series behavior of the variables of interest. There has been a growing realization that neglecting to account for basic time series properties of the variables that enter a behavioral relationship can cloud inference.

As Yule (1926) showed sixty five years ago, an ordinary least squares regression between two variables that are highly autocorrelated is bound to find a measure of “significance,” independent of any deeper behavioral link. Subsequently, Granger and Newbold (1974) emphasized the pitfalls inherent with series with even more persistence—series that behaved as random walks. That intuition has been codified with a set of tests to determine if a series behaves like a random walk, as well as new limiting distributions to define a level of statistical significance among such variables (including the important work of Dickey and Fuller (1981), Engle and Granger (1987), and Phillips (1987)). Using U.S. data, Stock and Watson (1987) have shown that much of the disagreement among results concerning the causal linkage between money and prices traces to differing specifications of the underlying variables. Their moral is that care must be taken at the outset in defining the unit of observation and the basic specification—i.e., whether to use levels or rates of change of each variable appearing in a regression and whether that regression should include a constant and time trend.

The starting point of our analysis is to establish the time series properties of the variables of interest. Subsequently, we follow Liederman (1982), by using an unrestricted reduced form to assess the interrelationships among inflation, output growth, wage changes, and the policy variables—various measures of the nominal money stock, the exchange rate, and the minimum wage. The resulting dynamic explanation of the inflation process resembles, in many ways, the theoretical derivation of Khan (1980). Moreover, the contemporaneous correlation among these variables allows a more detailed investigation of the sources of shocks than has been available previously.

Beside assessing the central issue of whether monetary shocks induce output and price fluctuations or whether it is the other way around, this technique can address the debate over the lever through which monetary policy may influence the economy. Traditionally, researchers assign one instrument to the central bank, modelling policy as working by varying the stock of a money or credit aggregate or by pegging an interest rate. Recently, Calvo and Vegh (1990a and b) have suggested that, when assets are imperfect substitutes, the conduct of monetary policy can have elements of both money—stock and interest–rate rules. In our framework, this reduces to an empirical issue concerning the source of the contemporaneous variation in money and interest rates.

The next section details the specification search, first examining the time–series properties of an array of macroeconomic variables. From that set, varying combinations of explanatory variables are considered to arrive at a compact, reduced–form model of the Colombian economy. This simple framework yields some insights as to the systematic comovement of money and inflation. However, it is not a complete system until, in Section III, the observed contemporaneous correlation is attributed to primitive shocks. That section also examines alternative decompositions to reflect the range of opinions in the theoretical literature. Section IV offers concluding comments.

II. The Time–Series Properties of Inflation and Money Growth

1. Time–series preliminaries

Most economic time series exhibit substantial comovement, but for policy analysis it is critical to distinguish a correlation that owes to a shared trend from that associated with an underlying causal relationship. Granger and Newbold (1974) showed that, when the dependent and independent variables have unit roots, traditional estimation methods using observations on the levels of those variables will likely find a statistically significant relationship, even absent a meaningful “economic” linkage. For example, the simplest case of a process with a unit root is the random walk, written here for the variable xt,

X t  = α  + ρ X t 1  + e t , ( 1 )

where et is an independent disturbance and ρ equals one. Since ρ equals one, a shock to et is incorporated permanently into the level of xt. The constant “α” represents a drift, which allows for a secular movement in xt. Granger and Newbold’s insight was that two variables that behaved like equation (1) will be correlated, independent of any common element to their respective shocks. 3/

To avoid erroneous inference, the data were subject to a variety of tests to establish their univariate time series behavior in order to determine the basic unit of observation—that is, whether the subsequent estimation should use the level or first difference of each time series. The tests include the Dickey–Fuller (D.F.), augmented Dickey–Fuller (A.D.F.), and Durbin–Watson (D.W.) statistics, explained in Engle and Granger (1987), Phillips (1987), and Bhargava (1987), and are given in Table 1. In effect, these statistics test whether ρ equals one, which implies that the steady—state level of xt (as well as its variance) is not well defined, or whether ρ is less than one, which implies that xt gravitates toward some steady—state level. In practice, each statistic tests for significant deviations from the assumed null hypothesis of nonstationary behavior. However, a complication arises because the form and distribution of any of these statistics depend on the exact null hypothesis, varying according to the presence or absence of a drift term (that is, what is assumed about the coefficient α).

Table 1

Time-series Properties of the Macroeconomic Variables 1960 to 1987

article image

The first three columns record statistics based on the assumption that there is no drift, while the last three columns posit a significant drift. The top panel tests for the presence of a single unit root, while the bottom panel tests for the presence of two unit roots. As is clear, the evidence suggests that real and nominal quantities in Colombia have one unit root. That is, each xt behaves like equation (1), requiring that it be differenced to achieve stationarity. Further, according to the D.F. and D.W. tests, the evidence suggests that first differencing is sufficient, or that the variables do not have two unit roots. However, interest rates are the important exception. These tests indicate that the real interest rate and, most likely, the nominal interest rate are stationary time series. As a result, measures of the interest rate will appear in levels, while all other variables appear as rates of change.

2. The specification search

The goal is to explain the joint movement of the price level, real output, and the nominal stock of money, in the expectation that this explanation sheds light on the relative merits of competing macroeconomic theories. However, researchers have found that observed relationships depend importantly on the other variables included in the estimation scheme. For example, using U.S. data, Sims (1980b) found that movements in the money stock reliably preceded movements in output. But, after including a nominal interest rate in his system, that explanatory power evaporated. Our strategy is to cast a wide net at first, estimating systems purporting to explain a long list of variables. We then winnow that list as the data dictate, ending with a compact system relating money, income, prices, and whatever else may be needed.

Ideally, a structural model would link observations on the set of endogenous variables in terms of their own current and lagged behavior, as well as the exogenous variables. In generic terms, such a model could be written in matrix form as:

[ Δ M t Δ Y t Δ P t ] A  = [ Δ M t 1 Δ Y t 1 Δ P t 1 ] B ( L )  + [ Δ X 1 t Δ X 2 t ] C ( L )  + [ e t M e t Y e t P ] ( 2 )

A is a 3x3 matrix of coefficients with ones on the diagonal;

  • B(L) is an 3x3 matrix of polynomials in the lag operator, which shifts a series back in time, i.e., Lwt = wt-1; and,

  • C(L) is a 2x3 matrix of lag polynomials.

The variables X1 and X2 stand for explanatory variables found to be significant in the specification search, while the Δ’s denote the first difference of a variable, which the univariate results of the previous section suggested were appropriate. Equation (2) can be solved to find a set of three equations in terms of predetermined variables,

[ Δ M t Δ Y t Δ P t ]  = [ Δ M t 1 Δ Y t 1 Δ P t 1 ] B ( L ) A 1  + [ Δ X 1 t Δ X 2 t ] C ( L ) A 1  + [ u t M u t Y u t P ] ( 3 )

where the vector of reduced—form residuals, ut’ = (utM, uty, utp), depends on the structural errors, et’ = (etM, ety, etp), and the relationship among the endogenous variables, A. Specifically,

u t  = e t A 1 . ( 4 )

This reduced form can be estimated by ordinary least squares, yielding consistent predictions and estimates of the compound terms, B(L)A-1 and C(L)A-1. A researcher concerned about the structural parameters—the individual elements of A, B, and C—then needs to solve the identification problem. Identification requires using economic theory (and common sense) to limit the number of parameters being estimated. Typically, this takes the form of exclusion restrictions, or the assumption that not every variable appears in every equation, placing zeros in the coefficient matrices. With enough a priori restrictions, the individual elements of the parameter matrices can be calculated given estimates of the reduced form. However, a researcher confident about those identifying restrictions should impose them at the outset, as that information permits more efficient estimation techniques. Indeed, much of the agenda in econometrics until the 1970s was filled with formalizing the identification problem and detailing efficient means of estimating systems given by equation (2).

However, as there are competing paradigms to be tested with vastly different implications for the structural parameters, we impose at the outset as few priors as possible. The result is that efficiency is traded off in favor of flexibility. This “unstructured” approach finds support in the failure of large–scale models to explain the sea change of the 1970s and Lucas’s theoretical explanation of why that should not have been surprising. Vector autoregressions (VARs) are the simple alternative to the increasingly complicated—and sometimes arbitrary—use of exclusion restrictions, particularly attractive to researchers unattached to a specific economic theory. Essentially, the VAR methodology advocates manipulating estimates of the reduced form, equation (3), to characterize the comovements of the endogenous variables. The presence of lagged variables implies that a shock to one equation potentially traces complicated dynamics in all three variables. Also, forecast errors in one equation over time contributes to explain the variability of prices, output, and money.

Such VARs were used as a tool to analyze the dynamic responses among output, prices, various monetary aggregates, interest rates, the exchange rate, both general wages and the minimum wage, and the price of coffee.4/

All variables were treated as potentially endogenous. This step in the specification search allowed the data to determine which set of variables would define our macroeconomic framework and determined the extent to which each policy variable was subject to feedback from other variables—that is, how truly “exogenous” those policy variables were.5/ The data also determined the optimum lag length: no priors were imposed on the lag profile and a variety of selection criteria were calculated.

The major facts that emerged from these regressions, which are omitted to conserve on space, were:

1. Leiderman (1984) found in a system consisting of prices, money, and output, that no lagged variables were significant in explaining the dynamic behavior of Ml—suggesting exogeneity in the Granger sense. Broadening the system to include the interest rate, exchange rate, and wages did not alter his result.

2. There was no evidence of a lagged relationship between the inflation rate and export coffee prices. (There was also no evidence of a contemporaneous relationship.) This runs counter to the positive relationship posited by Edwards (1984), who argued that a boom in coffee prices would lead to an accumulation of reserves which, unless sterilized, would result in faster money growth and inflation.

3. Past fluctuations in inflation, money growth, as well as its own history helped predict the exchange rate. This evidence of the “endogeneity” of the nominal exchange rate in Colombia’s crawling peg system suggests a (possibly time–varying) feedback rule on the part of policy makers, or the presence of a policy that targets the real exchange rate.6/

4. The inertia in wages was greater than the inertia in prices. Once money is included in the system, lagged values of inflation were insignificant in the price equation. Wage dynamics, however, continue to depend on their own history, as well as on other lagged nominal variables (i.e. money and the exchange rate).

5. Our results using annual data on rates of change parallel those of Sims (1980), who studied higher frequency level data for the United States. Movements in money reliably preceded movements in output but, after including a nominal interest rate in the system, that explanatory power disappears.

3. The reduced form model

In the end, we settled on a six–variable system using the growth rates of the narrow monetary aggregate, Ml, real income (GDP), consumer prices, (CPI), average wages in manufacturing, and the nominal exchange rate, and the level of the. nominal interest rate. As there is no obvious criterion for selecting lag length, Table 2 reports the four measures used frequently in this literature, the Akaike, Schwartz, and Hannan and Quinn criteria and the logarithm of the final prediction error. 7/ All these statistics are concerned with minimizing the value of the determinant of the covariance matrix of the residuals, but differ according to the penalty attached to increasing the number of estimated parameters. Not surprisingly, these measures offer conflicting advice, varying from the harshest critic of free parameters (the Schwartz criterion), which suggests using only a constant term in the estimation, to the Akaike and FPE criteria, which would allow us to consume almost all the available degrees of freedom. Given the limited sample, we opted for a parsimonious specification, using one lag of each variable and no exogenous variable other than a constant.

Table 2

Criteria for Selecting Lag Length1/

article image

The model selected by each criterion is underlined.

The results of this estimation are summarized in Table 3 (see also Table A.2), with each column representing an equation of the model. As the entries in the (a) panel attest, the model explains a significant fraction of the variability of the series, doing best for inertial macro variables such as wage growth and the policy–controlled nominal interest rate, surprisingly well for the change in the exchange rate, and least well for the growth of the nominal money stock. The latter may witness to the varying pace of financial innovation, as well as to changes in the policy goals of the Colombian authorities over the course of the sample period.

Table 3

Summary of Results Model Estimated from 1960 to 1987 with 1 lag and 21 d.f. per equation

article image
Note: An asterisk denotes a departure from the null hypothesis that is significant at the 10 percent level.

The (b) panel presents F–tests of exclusion restrictions, where the (i,j) element tests whether the ith variable appears in the jth equation. For example, reading down the third column detailing results for the CPI relationship, only lagged changes in money and wage growth have any significant impact on inflation. The pattern of significance among the variables determines how shocks to any one equation are propagated through the dynamic system.

Figure 1 attempts to make plain these relationships. Each box represents one variable in the system, with an arrow depicting the direction of a statistically significant impact. For example, the three lines connected to the CPI box show that the growth rates of Ml and wages enter importantly in the CPI equation (those arrows point inward), while inflation effects the rate of change in the exchange rate (that arrow points outward). The figure suggests three important dynamic properties of the Colombian economy. First, since movements in Ml predictably influence other variables but no previous movements in other variables predictably influence Ml, the nominal money stock is exogenous in the Granger sense. Thus, this nominal aggregate predictably influences domestic nominal magnitudes—prices, wages, and the exchange rate. Second, the significant feedback among nominal magnitudes, the changes in consumer prices, wages, and the exchange rate, may produce complicated dynamics: any perturbation to one of those relationships will feed through the entire price sector, suggesting a sluggishness in pricing decisions familiar in the literature on the wage–price spiral, a result that is not surprising given the pervasiveness of long—lived contracts in the Colombian labor market where the average contract length in the private sector is two years. Third, income appears at the bottom of any Granger–causal ranking, as it influences no other variable, even as it is influenced by the nominal interest rate. Thus, any comovement among income and money predicted by this model, for example, would not owe to the systematic effect of past movements in income on Ml, casting some doubt on the reverse–causation argument of the real business cycle theorists, at least for the Colombian economy.

Figure 1
Figure 1

The causal relationships among the variables

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1991, 035; 10.5089/9781451978353.001.A001

The flow chart in Figure 1 speaks only to the statistical significance of the relationships among the variables, not to the magnitudes of the responses. Since money growth appears exogenous in the system, we can consider any arbitrary path for Ml. In the exercise reported in Table 4, a one percentage point increase in money growth lasting one year was allowed to feed through to the other five variables in the system. In this example, we have, but did not use, an equation explaining money growth over time, but, instead, enforced an exogenous path for money. The resulting effects on rates of change then were cumulated to calculate the multipliers reported in the table. Those multipliers suggest approximate long-run monetary neutrality, as income is virtually unchanged, while the domestic price level increases about one percent, after a permanent one percent increase in the level of Ml. However, this exercise also suggests that long-lived external consequences are felt by domestic workers. The nominal exchange rate depreciates by half the increase in the CPI, and, invoking the small–country assumption that there is no feedback to foreign prices, there is a permanent real exchange rate appreciation. Thus, a change in the nominal exchange rate is also reflected in a change in the real exchange rate, similar to Mussa’s findings in his exhaustive examination of nominal and real exchange rates in developing countries (Mussa, 1986). More recently, Lizondo and Montiel (1991) argue that a nominal shock (in their case a nominal devaluation) may be nonneutral even in the long run if the fiscal adjustment that accompanies that shock changes the aggregate demand for nontraded goods. With foreign competitiveness impaired, domestic workers see a decline in their real wage, as the nominal wage increases by only about 85 percent of the increase in domestic prices.

Table 4

Monetary Policy Multipliers Implied by the Estimated Coefficients

(percent difference of the level of each variable from baseline)

article image

Percentage point difference from baseline.

The bottom of Table 4 also illustrates the effects of a 25 basis point increase in the nominal interest rate lasting one year, a shock of similar magnitude to that considered in the upper panel. With inflation largely predetermined at a point in time, the increase is, in effect, a real one. By contrast to the monetary shock, the interest rate increase has larger and longer–lived output consequences. Output falls at most over the near term but even nine years after the shock output remains below its initial level. With the nominal wage adjusting more gradually than other prices, the real wage first rises (possibly contributing to the output loss) then falls. Prices are higher. Indeed, the price level increases by more than the nominal money stock, lowering real balances in line with the lower level of real output. The foreign sector proves more puzzling in this simulation: both the nominal and real exchange rate depreciate. This result may simply be highlighting the limitations of these simulation exercises, as they are drawn by the patterns of temporal significance among the variables. If the exchange rate is as influenced by contemporaneous factors as it is by lagged determinants, then we may well see significant revisions to these results. What we next do is examine the within–year relationships among the variables to detail a complete description of temporal and contemporaneous effects.

III. A “Structural” Model of the Colombian Economy

1. General considerations

The multiplier results of the previous section, however, should not be interpreted too finely, as they reflect a partial solution to the model, using five of the six equations and taking no effort to explain the substantial contemporaneous correlation among the prediction errors. Indeed, returning to Table 3, the (d) panel shows that errors in some of the equations share a high degree of common movement. The structural model gives a good reason for this correlation, namely equation (4). Reduced form errors will be correlated to the extent that endogenous variables appear in more than one equation of the structural system. The notion of a forecast error, the heart of the VAR methodology, becomes problematic. A uM shock, for example, could represent either an independent monetary disturbance or the within–period monetary response to an income or price shock.

In the end, the econometrician cannot escape using theory. In the VAR world, this is addressed with a “causal ordering,” or a set of assumptions that allows the researcher to parse the observed contemporaneous correlation in the reduced form errors to unobserved structural errors. In our price–output–money example, the structural errors could be reclaimed by assuming:

u t M  = e t M ;
u t Y  = f 1 e t M  + e t Y ;
u t P  = f 2 e t M  + f 3 e t Y  + e t P .

where the f’s are constants. This imposes the theoretical restriction that money shocks are independent, output shocks respond to within–period money shocks, and inflation owes its variability to both money and output shocks. Alternatively, an accommodative money rule might imply,

u t M  = e t M  + f 1 e t Y  + f 2 e t P ;
u t Y  = e t Y ;
u t P  = f 3 e t Y  +  e t P ,

where the f’s represent new constants. Indeed, there are six possible orderings that can explain the observed correlation in reduced–form errors.

In the general case, a causal ordering amounts to assuming that the endogenous variables enter the system in a triangular fashion, with the first equation containing one endogenous variable, the second two variables, the third three variables, and so on, giving a specific form to the A matrix. The reduced form errors are written as a similar triangular sum of independent errors, or “innovations.” Bernanke (1986) and Blanchard (1987), moving the VAR methodology closer still to structural estimation, have noted that the exclusion restrictions do not have to be so precisely distributed. Rather, the zeroes can be interspersed through the identifying matrix, as long as the number of unknowns are kept equal to the number of equations (and no linear dependencies are introduced).8/ Simple algebra allows a VAR to be given a structural interpretation, directly specifying the form of A and using reduced form results to completely detail the model. Indeed, an identification scheme may place even more zeroes in the A matrix, with the nonzero coefficients estimated by a maximum likelihood technique. Such a decomposition would not exactly replicate the correlation matrix of the residuals, with the extent of the shortfall providing a measure of the identification scheme’s inadequacy.

After experimenting with a variety of possible A matrices, we report two alternative representations, each using 11 parameters to proxy for the 15 free parameters in the correlation matrix standing in for competing macroeconomic paradigms.

2. The Neo–Keynesian structure

The first set of priors imposed on errors captures a traditional transmission mechanism. The money stock, set by policy, is only affected by its “own” shocks, so that any correlation among money and the other variables owes to the independent influence of money on those variables. A traditional money demand relationship characterizes the interest rate equation, while the output equation has the interpretation of an IS schedule. Prices are marked up over wages, which in turn are described by a Phillips curve. Lastly, the nominal exchange rate reflects a policy feedback rule. As detailed below, an equation in the ordering is subject to Its own shocks and some fraction of the shocks to other equations in accordance with this set of theoretical priors. Omitting lagged endogenous variables and constant terms, our version of the neoclassical system can be summarized by:

an exogenous money stock,

Δ M t  = e M t ,

the demand for money,

i t  = a 21 Δ M t  + e i t  + a 23 Δ Y t  + a 25 Δ P t ,

an IS schedule,

Δ Y t  = a 31 Δ M t  + e y t  + a 35 Δ P t ,

a Phillips curve,

Δ W t  = a 43 Δ y t  + e W t ,

a markup equation,

Δ P t  = a 54 Δ W t  + e P t ,

and, lastly, a feedback rule for the exchange rate,

Δ E t  = a 61 Δ M t  + a 62 i t  + a 63 Δ y t  + a 65 Δ P t  + e E t .

Using this ordering permits a full simulation of the model that exploits the temporal and contemporaneous relationships among the variables. Six such simulations are given in the panels of Table 5. Each panel reports the effect on the levels of all the variables of a one standard deviation shock to a particular equation. In the top set, that translates to a 4.2 percent increase in Ml in the first year, which results in increase in income and the other nominal domestic variables, as well as a decline in the exchange rate. In turn, those shocks feed through the economy over time.

Table 5

Impulse Response: A Traditional Ordering

(percent difference of the level of each variable from baseline)

article image

Percentage difference from the baseline.

Given a complete simulation of the model, the evidence on the neutrality of money is more mixed. The 6.4 percent increase in Ml over time produces higher interest rates and lower income. With the demand for real balances presumably lower, the price level increases by more than the nominal money stock. Wages lag slightly behind prices so that the real wage falls. As explained in Blanchard (1987), this procyclical movement in wages is a common occurrence in developed countries, confounding the predictions of most sticky wage models. The other simulations reveal that positive real or nominal shocks are not accommodated in the money stock. In the long run, the money stock is lower after independent shocks to income or inflation, while it is only slightly higher after a shock to wages.

The response of the system to a nominal exchange rate shock (a depreciation) also makes evident other nonneutralities. A devaluation initially increases prices—but reduces wages. 9/ The combination of a lower real wage and increased exports could possibly explain the increase in output. While the stimulative short–run consequences of a devaluation are frequently addressed in the literature, the more surprising result is that this nominal shock appears to have long–lived effects, as output continues to increase and the real wage decline persists.

An ordering also permits a decomposition of the forecast errors over any horizon into the parts attributable to specific structural errors. Such a decomposition is provided in Table 6 for the six dynamic variables. As the first column of the first panel indicates, the within–year forecast of money growth has a standard error of about 4-1/2 percent. Quite reasonably, forecasts made further ahead have relatively larger standard errors. 10/ With this ordering, most of that variability can be attributed to money shocks, (since about 70 percent of the variance is traced to its own shocks) not the influence of other shocks on money.

Table 6

Variance decompositions at different horizons: A Traditional Ordering

(percent explained by each variable)

article image

level

Significantly, the sizable variation in the policy–directed short–term interest rate owes to its own shocks, as well as Ml shocks. This suggests, supporting the Calvo–Vegh thesis, that the interest rate should be thought of as an independent instrument of policy, rather than the automatic outcome of the control of the nominal money stock. 11/ With this in mind, the two instruments of monetary policy explain a large share of the variability in nominal magnitudes—over 28 percent of inflation variability and 24 percent and 29 percent of the uncertain part of wage inflation and the change in the exchange rate, respectively. Real activity is also similarly effected.

The estimated structural coefficients are interesting in their own right, as they speak to the substantial within–year movement among the key macroeconomic variables. Consider the coefficients of the A matrix significantly different from zero at the 90 percent level:

Δ M t  = e M t
i t  = .74 Δ P t  + e i t
Δ Y t  = .11 Δ M t  -  .05 Δ P t  + e Y t
Δ W t  = e W t
Δ P t  = e p t
Δ E t  = .54 Δ M t  - e E t

Several features are worth noting. First, contemporaneous money and prices are significant in the output equation, indicating that output depends positively on real balances and thus according monetary shocks a role in the business cycle. Second, prices and wages do not appear to be affected by any contemporaneous shock (other than their own), suggesting a significant predetermined component in these variables. Lastly, only contemporaneous inflation appears as significant in the interest rate equation—neither income nor money shocks have a significant effect. The absence of the latter suggests that interest rates may be a “separate” instrument.

3. A real business cycle structure

A growing literature asks that movements in real variables be interpreted as the outcome of real shocks. Such impulses then alter the rate at which households trade current for future consumption, leading to allocative reshuffling fully reflected in prices. In the end, the nominal money stock endogenously adjusts as the banking system accommodated a changed demand for a transactions media. One ordering consistent with the real business cycle approach would be:

a cash–in–advance constraint,

Δ M t  = e M t  + a 13 Δ y t  + a 15 Δ P t  + a 16 Δ E t ,

a Fisher equation for the nominal interest rate,

i t  = e i t  + a 23 Δ Y t  + a 25 Δ P t ,

technology–determined output,

Δ Y t  = e Y t ,

a real wage equation,

Δ W t  = a 43 Δ Y t  + e W t  + a 45 Δ P t ,

a markup equation,

Δ P t  = a 54 Δ W  + e P t ,

and, the real exchange rate,

Δ E t  = a 62 i t  + a 63 Δ Y t  + a 65 Δ P t  + e E t .

This ordering allows a different and unique partitioning of the correlation among variables and, accordingly, results in different simulations and variance decompositions, which are presented in Tables 7 and 8. This new ranking accords real shocks more important and long-lasting effects on the economy with the income shock apparently embodying a permanent productivity shift. The shock to income persists and is also associated with an increase in the real wage.

Table 7

Impulse Response: Real Business Cycle Ordering

(percent difference of the level of each variable from baseline)

article image

Percentage difference from the baseline.

Table 8

Variance decompositions at different horizons: Real Business Cycle Ordering

(percent explained by each variable)

article image

level

Despite the radically different ordering, the lessons for monetary policy are similar. First, there is no evidence that real or nominal shocks are accommodated. In the long run, the money stock is lower after shocks to real income, the CPI, and the exchange rate, and only 1–1/2 percent higher after a near 9 percent wage shock. Second, approximate domestic neutrality holds, as the increase in the CPI about matches the increase in the money stock after a purely monetary disturbance. Indeed, as the variance decomposition in Table 8 shows, monetary indicators still provide important information about the behavior of domestic prices. The short–term nominal interest rate and the stock of money accounts for about 23 and 27 percent of the CPI and exchange rate forecast errors, respectively (a similar percentage as in the previous ordering), suggesting that debate over the transmission mechanism should not cloud the central bank’s ultimate responsibility for nominal magnitudes.

The response of the system to a nominal exchange rate depreciation has some common elements with its Neo–Keynesian counterpart. As before, the exchange rate shock is associated with a long–lived real wage decline and an increase in output. Under both scenarios real balances increase, in tandem with the higher level of income and the slightly lower nominal interest rate. The implications for prices and the real exchange rate, however, are markedly different. In this ordering the nominal devaluation is accompanied by an even larger price decline so that the real exchange rate appreciates.12/

Considering only structural coefficients significantly different from zero at the 90 percent confidence level, three of the six equations become indistinguishable from their counterparts in the traditional ordering.

Δ M t  =  .34 Δ P t  + e M t
i t  =  .81 Δ P t  + e i t
Δ Y t  = e Y t
Δ W t  = e W t
Δ P t  = e P t
Δ E t  = 1.63 Δ Y t  + e E t

As before, the coefficient estimates indicate that prices and wages are largely predetermined (see also Table A.2) and only affected by their own shocks, while the interest rate equation is also unchanged. Output fluctuations now enter significantly in the exchange rate equation, apparently substituting for money, which had been significant in the traditional ordering. The distinctions between the two orderings mainly lie in the output and money equations. In the case of the former, the exogeneity restrictions result in a loss of information, as the correlations of output fluctuations with money and inflation shocks, apparent in the data, are lost in the estimated structural coefficients. In the case of the latter, the estimates suggest that neither output nor exchange rate shocks affect money directly. while only price shocks turn out to be significant.13/

These competing orderings each use 11 parameters to estimate the 15 distinct off–diagonal elements of the correlation matrix, but with quite distinct identification restrictions (the exception is the inflation equation). A reasonable way of assessing the adequacy of the competing models is to compare the results of a likelihood ratio tests for overidentification, which assess if the estimated coefficients can efficiently reproduce the actual correlation matrix of the reduced form errors. A model’s success is gauged by the extent that important information is not lost by restricting the number of parameters, which suggests that the zeroes in the identification matrix were placed judiciously. This test statistic is distributed as a χ2 with degrees of freedom equal to the number of overidentifying restrictions, in our case four. With our arbitrary real business cycle ordering, we confidently reject the null hypothesis that the estimated coefficients can reproduce the actual covariance matrix at any level of significance. For the traditional ordering the results are better, with less evident loss of information associated with the identifying restrictions—the null hypothesis cannot be rejected at the 90 percent level.14/

IV. Conclusion

Using annual data for Colombia over the last thirty years and a new battery of econometric techniques, we test opposing theories purporting to explain macroeconomic fluctuations: The neoclassical synthesis, which posits that in the presence of temporary price rigidity an unanticipated monetary expansion produces output gains that erode over time with increases in the price level and an alternative explanation focusing on “real” technological or preference shocks as the sources of output changes. The estimates of both the temporal linkage (the VARs) and the contemporaneous relationship (the estimates of the off–diagonal elements of the covariance matrix) present evidence that, in the case of Colombia, a neoclassical–Keynesian framework describes the dynamics of output better than an alternative that accords no role to monetary shocks.

Tests for overidentifying restrictions indicate that the results for the traditional ordering are better, with less evident loss of information associated with the identifying restrictions. Having said this, however, care must be taken not to over interpret the test results, since they crucially depend on an arbitrary ordering. It is quite possible that an alternative representation of the real business cycle framework can explain a higher proportion of the covariance matrix than the ordering presented here.15/

This relatively atheoretical approach to the macroeconomic time series highlights several empirical regularities for this small partially open economy:

First, the sizable variation in the policy–directed short–term interest rate owes to its own shocks, as well as Ml shocks. This suggests, supporting the Calvo–Vegh thesis, that the interest rate should be thought of as an independent instrument of policy, rather than the automatic outcome of the control of the nominal money stock.

Second, a complete simulation of the model, irrespective of the ordering used, presents mixed evidence on the neutrality of money. An increase in Ml over time produces a small increase in interest rates and a slight decline in output. With the demand for real balances presumably lower, the price level increases by more than the nominal money stock. Wages lag slightly behind prices so that the real wage falls. As explained in Blanchard (1987), this procyclical movement in wages is a common occurrence in developed countries. A change in the nominal exchange rate is also reflected in a change in the real exchange rate, similar to Mussa’s findings in his exhaustive examination of nominal and real exchange rates in developing countries (Mussa, 1986).

Third, the behavior of the money stock does not lend support to models where money is an endogenous “passive adapter”. In a temporal sense, money is independent of lagged values of any variable but important in influencing the subsequent development of nominal variables. Variance decompositions show money to be largely determined by its own shocks, while other simulations reveal that positive real or nominal shocks are not accommodated in the money stock. In the long run, the money stock is lower after independent shocks to income or inflation, while it is only slightly higher after a shock to wages.

Lastly, our results highlight the important role institutional arrangements play in shaping the relationships among macroeconomic time series. The pervasiveness of long–term labor contracts is obviously instrumental in according monetary shocks a role in the determination of output fluctuations. The relative “exogeneity” of the money stock must be the byproduct of the limited extent of capital mobility in the Colombian.16/ Similarly, the complex and differentiated system of reserve requirements and directed credit can to a large extent account for the “separability” of interest rates and money stock. However, this is not a new lesson in the literature on the correlation between money and economic activity. As Cagan (1988) described this tradition:

“A broad historical analysis goes beyond a narrow dependence on time series regressions. It draws on a wide–ranging examination of the institutional environment and economic events in a series of historical episodes.”

This paper attempted to efficiently characterize the comovements of an important set of macroeconomic variables so that such institutional detail and the key channels of monetary transmission would show more clearly.

Appendix

Table A.1

Variable List and Sources

article image

Breaks in the IFS data were filled by applying the M1 growth rate reported by Banco de la Republica to the IFS level.

Table A.2

Vector Autoregressions: 1960 to 19871/

article image

Standard errors are in parentheses.

References

  • Adams, C.,Trends and Cycles in the U.S. Economy,” IMF Working Paper Number WP/90/72, (1990).

  • Barro, R.J.,Money and Output in Mexico, Colombia, and Brazil,” in J. Behrman and J.A. Hanson, Short–term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Co.), (1979), pp. 177200.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bernanke, B.S.,Alternative Explanations of the Money–Income Correlation,” Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series on Public Policies 2, (1986), pp. 49100.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhargava, A.,On the Theory of Testing for Unit Roots in Observed Time Series,” Review of Economic Studies 53, (1986), pp. 369384.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, O.J.,Why Does Money Affect Output?NBER Working Paper no. 2285, (1987).

  • Blanchard, O.J.,A Traditional Interpretation of Macroeconomic Fluctuations,” American Economic Review 79, (1989), pp. 11461164.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cagan, P.D.,Money–Income Causality—A Critical Review of Literature Since the Monetary History,” Columbia University Discussion Paper no. 373, (1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, G.A.,Staggered Contracts in a Utility–Maximizing Framework,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, (1983a), pp. 383398.

  • Calvo, G.A. and C.A. Vegh,Interest Rate Policy in a Small–Open–Economy: The Predetermined Exchange Rate Case,” IMF Staff Papers 37, (1990a).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, G.A. and C.A. Vegh,Money Supply and Interest Rate Policy in a New–Keynesian Framework,” IMF Working Paper Number WP/90/119, (1990b).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clavijo, S.V. and H.J. Gomez, “Selección y Control de los Agregados Monetarios Optimos,” Ensayos Sobre Politica Economica, (1988).

  • Dickey, D.A. and W.A. Fuller,Likelihood Ratio Tests for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root,” Econometrica 49, (1981), pp. 10571072.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, S.,Coffee, Money, and Inflation in Colombia,” World Development 12, (1984), pp. 11071117.

  • Engle, R.F. and C.W. Granger,Dynamic Model Specification with Equilibrium Constraints: Co–integration and Error–correction,” Econometrica 55, (1987), pp. 251276.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fernandez Riva, J., “Inflación y Dinero: Un Repaso,” Debates de Coyuntura Económica, 9, (1988).

  • Granger, C.W. and P. Newbold,Spurious Regressions in Econometrics,” Journal of Econometrics 2, (1974), pp. 111120.

  • Khan, M.Monetary Shocks and the Dynamics of Inflation,” IMF Staff Papers. (1980), pp. 250284.

  • King, R. and C. Plosser,Money, Credit, and Prices in a Real Business Cycle,” American Economic Review 74, (1984), pp. 363380.

  • King, R. and C. Plosser,Money as the Medium of Exchange,” Journal of Monetary Economics 17, (1986), pp. 93115.

  • Kydland, F. and E. Prescott,Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Econometrica 50, (1982), pp. 13451370.

  • Leiderman, L.,On the Monetary–Macro Dynamics of Colombia and Mexico,” Journal of Development Economics, 14, (1984), pp. 183201.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lizondo, J.S. and P.J. Montiel, “Fiscal Policy and the Dynamics of Devaluation for a Small Country with Optimizing Agents,” mimeo, (1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lukepohl, H.,Comparison of Criteria for Estimating the Order of a Vector Autoregressive Process,” Journal of Time Series Analysis 6, (1985), pp. 3552.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mondino, G. and R. Renhack,Capital Mobility and Monetary Policy in Colombia,” IMF Working Paper WP/88/77, (1988).

  • Montiel, P.J. and J. D. Ostry,Macroeconomic Implications of Real Exchange Rate Targeting in Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper WP/91/ (1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mussa, M.,Sticky Prices and Disequilibrium Adjustment in a Rational Model of the Inflationary Process,” American Economic Review 71, (1980), pp. 10201027.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ohanian, L.E.,The Spurious Effects of Unit Roots on Vector Autoregressions: A Monte Carlo Study,” Journal of Econometrics 39, (1988), pp. 251266.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Phillips, P.C.B.,Time Series Regression with a Unit Root,” Econometrica 55, (1987), pp. 277301.

  • Sims, C.A.,Macroeconomics and Reality,” Econometrica 48, (1980a), pp. 148.

  • Sims, C.A.,Comparison of Interwar and Postwar Business Cycles,” American Economic Review 70, (1980b), pp. 250256.

  • Small, D.H. and R.D. Porter,Understanding the Behavior of M2 and V2,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, 75, (1989), pp. 244254.

  • Stock, J. and M. Watson,Interpreting the Evidence on Money–Income Causality,” Journal of Econometrics 40. (1989), pp. 161181.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Yule, G.U.,Why Do We Get Nonsense Correlations Between Time Series?,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 89, pp. 164.

*

Respectively, International Monetary Fund and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. The authors are grateful to Charles Adams and Paulo Leme for helpful comments and suggestions; the views expressed do not necessarily reflect those of the International Monetary Fund or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve.

1/

The reasons for the sluggishness of prices include nominal contracting, as in Calvo (1983) and Calvo and Vegh (1990a and b), adjustment costs, as in Mussa (1980), and asynchronous price setting, as in Blanchard (1987).

2/

Examples of this work include Kydland and Prescott (1982) and King and Plosser (1984 and 1986). For a critical survey, see the summer 1989 issue of Journal of Economic Perspectives.

3/

Ohanian (1988) generalizes the problem to the multivariate setting considered in the paper.

4/

The list of variables considered are presented in Table A.1.

5/

In our case the policy variables considered were the monetary aggregates, the nominal interest rate, and the nominal exchange rate.

6/

For a model that illustrates the endogeneity of the nominal exchange rate and its response to a variety of shocks under a policy that targets the real exchange rate see Montiel and Ostry (1991).

7/

Lutkepohl (1985) provides simulation evidence on the efficacy of these criteria.

8/

In formal terms, the system must be just identified.

9/

The reduction in the real wage may perhaps be explained by considering the relative labor–intensiveness of the traded and non–traded sectors. If the latter is more labor intensive, as is usually thought, then the wage decline could be the outcome of a sectoral reallocation of factors towards the traded goods sector.

10/

Here, it is important to remember the time–series properties of each variable. Forecasts of the level of the money stock compound each intervening year’s variance of the forecast of the growth rate of the money stock. Thus, the standard error attached to a forecast of the level of the money stock expands as the forecast horizon lengthens, so that it is unbounded in the limit—the level of the money stock has a nonstationary distribution. Only the interest rate, which is estimated in levels, has a well defined long–run limiting distribution.

11/

In the case of Colombia the explanation for this “separability” may lie in the highly differentiated and active system of reserve requirements as well as a fairly complex system of directed credit.

12/

This outcome resembles a case considered by Lizondo and Montiel (1991), where the nominal devaluation is accompanied by an increase in government spending on nontraded goods. Their model predicts that the combined effect of the devaluation and fiscal adjustment produces a steady–state real appreciation and increased values of private wealth and expenditure.

13/

Note, however, that in this ordering the nominal exchange rate does explain a significant share of the total variation in money (Table 8).

14/

The χ2 statistics for the real business cycle and traditional orderings are 19.344 and 5.655, respectively, with accompanying significance levels of .0007 and .23.

15/

For this number of parameters we did not find such an ordering.

16/

See, for instance, Renhack and Mondino (1988).

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Output Fluctuations and Monetary Shocks: Evidence From Colombia
Author:
Mr. Vincent Reinhart
and
Ms. Carmen Reinhart