Abstract
In this paper it is argued that the willingness of debtors to make external debt-service payments reflects, in part, their inability to credibly and permanently suspend debt service. The benefits of a credible debt-service suspension would include increased private investment. But this would, in turn, tend to create conditions in which it would then be optimal for the government to resume payments. Thus, debt remains a threat even after the announcement of suspension of debt service. It follows that the expected benefits of such a suspension are limited and may be offset by penalties imposed by creditors.
I. Introduction
A fundamental question about the behavior of debtor countries has been their willingness to make substantial net transfers to creditors in the face of very difficult economic circumstances. Although it is common for debts to be renegotiated, debtor countries have made substantial net real transfers to creditors and have, for the most part, reached contractual agreements to finance remaining debt-service obligations. For problem debtors 1/ real debt-service payments to private creditors from 1983-1989 were sufficiently large so that the entire real interest expense was paid; additional interest payments resulted in a fall in the real value of debt to private creditors of about 4 percent. 2/
Historical experience and theoretical arguments suggest that penalties imposed on defaulting countries by creditors are likely to be small and temporary. In this note it is argued that continued debt service may be optimal because debtor countries cannot credibly and permanently suspend debt-service payments. Since any announced suspension of payments would be regarded by the private sector as potentially temporary, investment in the debtor country would remain depressed. It follows that the benefits of default to the debtor country might be quite limited. For this reason even small costs of default might be sufficient to offset the limited benefits.
A suspension of payments that was permanent, and was believed to be permanent, might provide substantial benefits in terms of increased private domestic investment in the debtor country. Investment would tend to increase because a default is, in effect, a promise not to tax new investors in order to pay existing creditors. However, creditors have no incentive to extinguish the debt, and any announced default could turn out to be temporary. 3/
Investors would expect a default to be temporary if a rise in investment and income in the debtor country made it optimal for the debtor government to eventually renew debt-service payments. In the next section, a plausible example of such behavior is provided. The debtor government is expected to “default on the default” because, at higher levels of domestic income, the marginal costs of resuming payments are lower as compared to the benefits of avoiding penalties. Thus, the debtor government’s announced policy of a permanent suspension of debt service may not be “time consistent” and, therefore, not credible to private investors. 1/
This lack of credibility suggests that it may not be possible to convince investors that a default is permanent. In the interim, the benefits of increased investment and growth are lost. Moreover, the debt will continue to grow in the form of interest arrears, and there is no incentive for creditors to forgive this additional debt.
II. The Costs of Default
If the benefits from default are limited, it follows that even mild penalties might be sufficient to explain the reluctance of debtors to adopt this policy. The theoretical literature and historical analysis of the costs of default suggest that penalties are indeed likely to be both temporary and mild.
The theoretical literature has focused on the loss of access to credit and losses in gains from trade as the likely costs of default. 2/ Access to credit markets is valuable in order to smooth consumption. However, as Bulow and Rogoff (1986) point out, a debtor country could divert debt-service payments to accumulate assets that could subsequently be drawn’ down and replenished in order to smooth consumption. At some point in time the debtor will face the choice of making a large payment in order to preserve access to credit markets or acquiring an asset that would provide a large and growing amount of insurance against a temporary fall in income. Looking forward it would be difficult to rule out the self-insurance option, and it follows that a loss of access to credit markets may not be an effective penalty.
A recent collection of papers examining the experience of defaulting countries in the 1930s casts further doubt on the hypothesis that default results in loss of access to credit markets. Eichengreen and Lindert (1989) conclude that “there is remarkably little evidence that defaulting countries acquire a reputation for unwillingness to pay, which in turn hinders their ability to borrow.”
The logical case for trade restrictions is also suspect. Clearly, trade restrictions injure residents of creditor countries as well as residents of the debtor country. While it is rational for the government of the creditor to threaten trade sanctions in the event of default, it may not be rational to actually carry out the threat. Moreover, important interest groups in creditor countries that depend upon trade can only lose by supporting sanctions favored by creditors. Eichengreen and Portes (1986), for example, conclude that efforts by creditors to restrict trade or trade credit for defaulting countries in the 1930s were generally successfully resisted by residents of creditor countries.
In this note, small but positive costs for default are taken as a working hypothesis. It is argued, however, that debtor countries have not necessarily made payments that exceed what would be consistent with this cost structure. Even these relatively low costs can be sufficient to deter debtors from announcing defaults because time consistency considerations tend to limit the gains from default.
III. An Example
To illustrate the argument, suppose the debtor government maximizes utility, U(y), from income after debt repayment, y, less costs, C(x), of the amount of default, x. (We assume positive and decreasing marginal utility, and positive and increasing marginal cost. Uy > 0, Uyy < 0, Cx > 0, and Cxx > 0.)
Income after taxes used for debt repayment equals y = (1-τ)αI, where τ is the tax rate, I (0 ≤ I ≤
The amount of default is x = R
For a given tax rate and a given investment level, the government’s net utility level can be written
Investment is determined on a competitive world capital market. Investors require an after-tax rate of return, (1-τ)α, at least equal to the given world rate of return, R*. As a consequence, equilibrium investment is a function, I(r), of the tax rate, such that
where the critical tax rate τ* equals 1 - R*/a (assumed positive). (For τ - τ*, investors are indifferent to the level of investment. For simplicity, we assume that they then choose the maximum level
The government chooses the tax rate so as to maximize the net utility level (1), given that investment by (2) depends on the tax rate.
Suppose the government chooses a tax rate larger than τ*. Then investment and income after tax will be zero, y = 0, and the amount of default will be maximal, x = R
Hence the government chooses τ to maximize V(τ,
with equality if
The first-order conditions are illustrated in Figure 1. As the tax rate falls, after-tax income rises, and the marginal utility of consumption, Uy, falls so that Uy has a positive slope. As the tax rate falls, the amount of default rises. Then the marginal cost imposed on the debtor increases so that Cx has a negative slope.
Marginal utility and marginal cost are equal for τ = τ1. If the critical tax rate τ* exceeds τ1,
Suppose now that we allow the government to re-optimize after international investors have committed themselves to
The lesson is that, even if the government promises to increase the amount of default (promises to set a low tax rate), they will be tempted to reverse this decision (raise the tax rate) once the investment is in place. This is a simple application of the familiar time-consistency argument.
Rational investors will anticipate the increase in tax rate ex post, and choose not to invest at all. The government is caught in the worst possible outcome, zero investment and maximum default.
A slightly more complicated model can be utilized to show that in cases where the debtor government cannot credibly default, the low investment equilibrium might involve very high tax rates. In this example, it is assumed that a minimum level of income, Y, is generated in the debtor country and that investment adds to that level. Then income after tax is y = (1-τ)(
The first-order conditions are more complicated in this case. For tax rates less than the critical rate τ ≤ τ*, investment is maximal, and we have
with equality if the constraint is not binding. For tax rates above the critical rate, τ > τ*, investment is zero, and we have
The left-hand side of (5a), marginal utility with high investment, is shown on the top panel in Figure 2, as the curve ABA’. Only the portion left of τ* is relevant, AB. The right-hand side of (5a), marginal cost with high investment, is curve EFE’, where only EF is relevant.
The middle panel shows investment, equal to
The left-hand side of (5b), marginal utility with low investment, is shown as D’CD. It lies above ABA’ since marginal utility is higher with lower investment and lower income. Only the portion CD is relevant. The right-hand side of (5b), marginal cost with low investment, is shown as H’GH, where the position GH is relevant. It lies above EFE’ since marginal cost is higher with low investment and higher default.
The total marginal utility curve is ABCD, with a vertical portion BC. The total marginal cost curve is EFGH, with a vertical portion FG.
The total net utility curves for high and low investment are shown in the bottom panel. V(τ,
If the government could commit to τ* investment would be set at
Positive investment, and the associated payoff for the debtor country, is attainable if the high investment curve EFE’ in Figure 2 could be shifted to the left or the high investment curve ABA’ shifted to the left so that τ1 was less than or equal to τ*.
The most direct way to accomplish this would be to reduce
IV. Conclusion
A suspension of debt-service payments to external creditors may not allow a debtor country to break out of a low growth, low investment equilibrium. Such a policy accelerates the growth of external debt as interest arrears are added to the stock of debt. Moreover, the debtor government may not be able to credibly insulate new domestic investment from taxation. The dilemma is that if new investors believe the debtor governments promise not to tax their returns in order to service existing debt, the new investment can create the conditions under which it will be optimal for the government to break that promise.
The potential benefits of moving to the high investment and growth equilibrium are substantial. Policies that improve the probability that such a move will be possible include improved economic performance as well as policies that limit the growth in debt. The latter include interest payments as well as debt reduction operations. An extension of this analysis might consider the option value of current debt-service and debt-reduction expenditures. Such expenditures may be valuable to the debtor because they increase the debtor’s ability to move to a high investment and growth equilibrium in the future.
References
Blejer, Mario I., and Alain Ize, “Adjustment Uncertainty, Confidence, and Growth: Latin America After the Debt Crisis,” IMF Working Paper, WP/89/105 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1989).
Borensztein, Eduardo, “Debt Overhang, Credit Rationing and Investment,” IMF Working Paper, WP/89/74 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1989).
Bulow, Jeremy I., and Kenneth Rogoff, “A Constant Recontracting Model of Sovereign Debt,” NBER Working Paper No. 2088 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, December 1986).
Bulow, Jeremy I., and Kenneth Rogoff, “The Buy-Back Boondogle,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 2, (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1988).
Calvo, Guillermo, “On the Costs of Temporary Policy,” Journal of Development Economics. Vol. 27 (Amsterdam, October 1987).
Calvo, Guillermo, “Controlling Inflation: The Problem of Non-Indexed Debt,” IMF Working Paper, WP/88/29 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, March 1988).
Cohen, Daniel, and Jeffrey Sachs, “Growth and External Debt Under Risk of Debt Repudiation,” European Economic Review. 30 (1986), 529–560.
Corden, Max, and Michael P. Dooley, “Issues in Debt Strategy: An Overview,” in J.A. Frenkel, M.P. Dooley, and P. Wickham, eds., Analytical Issues in Debt. (Washington, International Monetary Fund, 1989), 10–37.
Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos, “Stories of the 1930s for the 1980s,” in P. Aspe Armella, R. Dornbusch, and M. Obstfeld, eds., Financial Policies and the World Capital Market: The Problem of the Latin American Countries. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983).
Dooley, Michael P., and Peter Isard, “Country Risk, International Lending and Exchange Rate Determination,” International Finance Discussion Papers No. 221, (Federal Reserve Board of Governors, May 1983).
Dornbusch, Rudiger, “Notes on Credibility and Stabilization,” NBER Working Paper No. 2970 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, December 1988).
Dornbusch, Rudiger, “Economic Reconstruction of Latin America,” (unpublished, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, November 1989).
Eaton, Jonathan, and Mark Gersovitz, “Debt with Potential Repudiation: Theoretical and Empirical Analysis,” Review of Economic Studies. 48 (1981), 289–309.
Eaton, Jonathan, Mark Gersovitz, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, “The Pure Theory of Country Risk,” European Economic Review. 30 (June 1986), 481–513.
Fishlow, Albert, “Lessons from the Past: Capital Markets during the 19th Century and the Interwar Period,” in Miles Kahler, ed., The Politics of International Debt. (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1986).
Eichengreen, Barry, and Richard Portes, “Debt and Default in the 1930’s: Causes and Consequences,” European Economic Review. 30 (1986), 599–640.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Richard Portes, “Settling Defaults in the Era of Bond Finance,” The World Bank Economic Review (May 1989).
Eichengreen, Barry, Richard Portes, and Peter H. Lindert, The International Debt Crisis in Historical Perspective. (Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press, 1989).
Froot, Kenneth, and Paul Krugman, “Market-Based Reduction for Developing Countries: Principles and Prospects,” (unpublished, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, January 1990).
Guttentag, Jack M., and Richard J. Herring, “What Happens When Countries Cannot Pay Their Bank Loans? The Renegotiation Process,” Journal of Comparative Business and Capital Market Law. 5 (1983), 209–231.
Kaletsky, Anatole, The Costs of Default (New York: Priority Press, 1985).
Kletzer, Ken, “External Borrowing by LDC’s: A Survey of Theoretical Issues,” Yale University Economic Growth Center, Discussion Paper No. 523 (December 1986).
Krugman, Paul, “International Debt in an Uncertain World,” in Gordon W. Smith and John T. Cuddington, International Debt and the Developing Countries. (Washington: IBRD, 1985), 79–100.
Kydland, F.E., and E.C. Prescott, “Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans,” The Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 85, No. 3 (June 1977).
Lindert, Peter, and Peter J. Morton, “How Sovereign Debt Has Worked,” in Jeffrey Sachs, ed., Developing Country Debt and Economic Performance. Vol. 1 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988).
We are grateful to our colleagues and to the participants in a Research Department workshop who provided us with useful comments.
The 65 countries described as countries with recent debt-service problems in the IMF’s World Economic Outlook, April 1988.
See Corden and Dooley (1989) for a discussion of the inflation accounting and the data. In a recent paper Lindert (1989) argues that only a handful of debtors have made “major” net repayments to creditors during the 1980s. It is clearly the case that payments have varied among debtor countries, but in our view the balance of payments data and the price adjusted debt stock data support the view that debtors have made major net transfers to their private creditors. The fact that a part of these transfers was financed by net official credits does not explain debtors’ willingness to make such payments.
Even if the debt is sold to a new creditor at a discount, the new creditor would attempt to collect the contractual value of the debt.
See Kydland and Prescott (1977) for other examples of inconsistency in government policies :
See Eaton, Gersovitz, and Stiglitz (1986) for a comprehensive review of the theoretical literature. See Eichengreen and Lindert (1989) for a collection of papers reviewing historical experience.