The Flow-of-Funds Accounts, the United Nations' System of National Accounts, and the Developing Countries
Author:
International Monetary Fund
Search for other papers by International Monetary Fund in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

This paper considers flow-of-funds accounting and analysis in relation to the forthcoming revision of the United Nations’ System of National Accounts (SNA), with emphasis on the problems faced by developing countries in this area. After a survey of the uses of flow-of-funds data, we conclude that these accounts should continue to have a central place in the SNA. Next, conceptual relations between the SNA and the flow-of-funds accounts are explored as well as the question of harmonization with the Fund’s statistical systems. Finally, the feasibility of these accounts for developing countries is demonstrated by a sketch of appropriate estimation procedures.

Abstract

This paper considers flow-of-funds accounting and analysis in relation to the forthcoming revision of the United Nations’ System of National Accounts (SNA), with emphasis on the problems faced by developing countries in this area. After a survey of the uses of flow-of-funds data, we conclude that these accounts should continue to have a central place in the SNA. Next, conceptual relations between the SNA and the flow-of-funds accounts are explored as well as the question of harmonization with the Fund’s statistical systems. Finally, the feasibility of these accounts for developing countries is demonstrated by a sketch of appropriate estimation procedures.

I. Introduction

Our purpose is to survey flow-of-funds or national financial accounting in the context of the forthcoming revision of the United Nation’s System of National Accounts (SNA) and with special emphasis on the potential of flow-of-funds analysis for developing countries. The task has been divided into three main sections.

We begin in Section II with a consideration of the analytical uses of the flow-of-funds accounts, utilizing simple data matrices of the sort that could be available in most of the countries of the world. A key scheme for the analysis of financial fluctuations is presented, the saving-investment process, and this scheme is related to the data matrix. The data are also related both to financial policy problems that are commonly faced by developing countries and to more sophisticated types of projections and programming. In all, we emphasize the substantial usefulness of flow-of-funds data in the formation and execution of public policies in the financial area.

In Section III we examine the conceptual relations between the flow-of-funds accounts and the SNA. This is done by examining the evolution of certain key features of the SNA standard accounts as these features have evolved in the successive revisions of the SNA, and, in particular, the representation of finance in the SNA. This latter evolution is pushed ahead to envision how financial data should be portrayed in the forthcoming SNA revision—labeled SNA 1990. Section III also considers the closely related matter of the harmonization of the statistical systems of the Fund with the SNA as well as the technical problem of relating financial flows and balances in the accounts.

Finally, Section IV considers the procedures to be used in the estimation of flow-of-funds accounts in the developing countries. It is demonstrated that an effective flow-of-funds system can now be implemented quickly and easily by most of these countries. However, the data problems these countries face are seen to have implications for the design of SNA 1990.

II. Analytical Uses of the Flow-of-Funds Accounts

The broad purpose of the flow-of-funds accounts, or the sector capital finance accounts as they appear in the UN’s System of National Accounts (SNA), is to facilitate analysis of the operations of the financial system. That is, these accounts aim at interpreting the transactions in financial markets carried out by the various economic sectors and at relating these transactions to the behavior of the nonfinancial economy. To this end the sector accounts record for each sector its capital formation, its gross saving (that is, its operating surplus), and its acquisitions of various types of claims (financial uses of funds) and the incurrence of various types of liabilities (financial sources of funds). In the sectoring scheme, financial institutions are separated out in order to distinguish their functional role. Finally, the whole can be presented as a technically interlocking matrix with balancing cross and down totals. Tables 1 and 2 present simple examples of this type of matrix format that could be currently produced by most of the nations of the world.

Table 1.

Financial Flow Matrix I

article image
Table 2.

Financial Flow Matrix II

article image

The analytical power of the flow-of-funds system of accounts—like that of the income and product accounts—stems fundamentally from the interlocking character of the system—from the cross and down totals that balance for every period. Social accounting consistency requires that a flow change in any matrix cell be accompanied by corresponding changes in at least three other cells. For example, if increased government capital formation is to be financed by government debt issues, some sector must absorb the issues. To do so that sector must have larger sources of funds or must reduce other acquisitions. By making use of this feature in various forms, it is often possible to trace the impact of each sector’s financial behavior on the others and eventually on the nonfinancial economy, or vice versa.

In the following four parts of Section II, we shall try to indicate the range of different forms of flow-of-funds analysis. The level of detail would naturally depend on the sector and transaction detail available in the accounts, but we shall focus here on quite condensed matrices of the sort that many countries would be able to construct. It should also be borne in mind that, although our descriptions will focus on structures which are best revealed by the matrices, substantive work would be largely expressed as time series analysis.

1. Saving-investment process analysis

Perhaps the most pervasive structure used by flow-of-funds analysts is the saving-investment process. This is the process by which saving is transformed into ultimate lending, whence it passes through various financial channels to ultimate borrowing, and then into real investment. An important feature of the scheme is the insertion of financial institutions in the center between ultimate lending and ultimate borrowing in order to portray their role as financial intermediaries.

The way in which the details of the process are worked into the scheme will vary with the analyst. One such scheme is shown in Chart 1, which is designed to reveal the domestic financing process. 1/ Private saving appears at the right of the chart and as the arrows indicate is either placed internally into real investment or is placed into ultimate lending (that is, used to acquire claims). This claims acquisition may take any of three major forms. They can be claims of financial institutions, thus placing funds with these institutions; they can be private credit instruments, thus passing funds directly through these markets to finance private ultimate borrowing; they can be federal securities, thus advancing funds in this market. In turn, financial institutions (bank or nonbank), in lending out the funds placed with them, must acquire either federal securities or private claims. Finally, private ultimate borrowing assembles the borrowing from banks, nonbanks, and ultimate lenders, which together with internal financing provides the funds to finance real investment.

Chart 1
Chart 1

Saving-Investment Process Scheme

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1989, 095; 10.5089/9781451950267.001.A001

Note: Codes for all flows refer to cells in Exhibit IIIB1/ (C 1) + (D 1) + (E 1)2/ (A 2) - (C 1) - (D 1) - (El)3/ (E 4) - (C 3) - (D 3)

Federal ultimate borrowing in Chart 1 also assembles the lending of the various sectors and provides the financing for the federal deficit. Here, however, there is also a “feedback” arrow at the top of the chart. This is a somewhat awkward expression of the fact that governments often borrow not to finance the government deficit, narrowly defined, but to on-lend the funds. In developing countries this is a key form of finance for government enterprises. In this way general government becomes a kind of financial intermediary.

We note that, in effect, on Chart 1 the saving-investment account is split down the middle, its two halves separated to the right and left, and the financial system inserted between. As a result, we see the placement of saving and the financing of investment as two distinct activities. But they necessarily articulate; whatever saving is placed with the financial system necessarily provides the financing of investment. Further, because saving and real investment are both nonfinancial variables, the financial markets are linked to the real economy at each end of the scheme.

This scheme is tied closely to flow-of-funds data because the various flow arrows can be measured by the cells in a flow-of-funds matrix. In this case the corresponding matrix is presented in Table 3. The codes on the various Chart 1 arrows refer to the rows and columns of Table 3. We observe that each of the (underlined) major flows oh the matrix is represented in the scheme. The saving-investment process scheme thus provides a means of interpreting the flow movements in the matrix over time.

Table 3.

Condensed Flow-of-Funds Matrix

article image

Households, nonprofit, enterprises, provincial and local government, and rest-of-world.

Central bank, commercial banks, treasury monetary funds.

Currency and demand deposits, time and saving accounts, saving via life insurance and pension funds.

In using the scheme we often find the causation moving from left to right, counter to the arrows. For example, it is often the case that fluctuations in real investment or the federal deficit will result in fluctuations in various forms of borrowing. Chart 1 indicates how the impact of these borrowing fluctuations on financial institutions and markets can be traced. We see the advantage of having available in the flow-of-funds accounts the immediate forms of borrowing by each sector and not just the ultimate “financing” of the saving figures. With added detail the scheme can become a very effective vehicle for our understanding of how capital formation or the federal deficit is financed.

2. Policy problem analysis in developing countries

We shall here pose some key financial planning problems regularly faced by developing countries and shall briefly indicate their relationship to the flow-of-funds accounts. (1) Will there be an adequate amount of foreign exchange? In the first instance, of course, this question implies an analysis of the rest-of-world account. Given the balance of payments current deficit (rest-of-world saving), the foreign exchange balance is protected by foreign borrowing. To judge its extent an analysis of the domestic borrowers’ financing is needed (private and public enterprises, financial institutions, and general government). (2) How will the central government deficit be financed? The government deficit (gross capital formation less gross saving) plus its lending will be financed by the issue of government debt. The placement of these issues is analyzed by moving horizontally across the flow-of-funds matrix. Estimating the other sectors’ capacities to absorb the issues requires sector analysis of the major debt buyers. And the absorption by the banking system may imply further money supply expansion or the crowding out of private borrowers. (3) How will the major government enterprises be financed and by whom? Government enterprise capital formation will be financed first by the enterprises’ own saving (that is, their operating surpluses). Beyond this their major sources of funds will be government loans, borrowing from abroad, and borrowing from commercial banks. The volume of this last is of special interest because of the possibility again of crowding out private borrowers.

In all three of these policy questions we note that answers require an impact analysis on various sectors and/or types of transaction. It is the articulation of the accounts within the flow-of-funds matrix that enables us to seek and judge the answers.

3. Financial projections and programming

The essence of a flow-of-funds projection is a matrix for some future time period. Such projections can be used for a variety of purposes. One would be to test the consistency of a number of separately prepared sector or market forecasts. Another would be to develop a consistent view of the financial flow implications of a particular set of assumptions about future events. A third might be used by the planners in a developing country to examine the implications of parts of an economic plan.

For example, consider a projection of Table 1. A developing country might have sector capital formation and saving data from a tentative plan formulation. It might then impose certain constraining balance of payments estimates. The interior of the matrix could be projected under these constraints in order to work out the implications for domestic finance. The projection might well be able to identify certain types of credit shortages or the amount of necessary monetary expansion.

The projection of a more elaborate matrix—of some 10 sectors and 20 or more financial transaction types—has for many years been a regular part of monetary and credit policymaking at the central bank in the United States. In a series of iterations, the judgmental forecasts of numerous financial market and national account specialists in the research division are used to modify an extrapolated matrix. At the same time, monetary policy implementation and impact are gradually worked into the projection. In the end the exercise provides a detailed statistical picture of future financial flows that is closely integrated with the prepared policy position to be placed before the governing board.

A sophisticated illustration can be drawn from the type of financial programming engaged in by the Fund in the design of adjustment programs. The policy packages of these programs aim primarily at establishing a viable balance of payments position over the medium term. An important element of this type of programming is an analysis that traces major credit demands to a focus on the banking system, even on the central bank itself. First, a balance of payments target is established and the implications of projected imports, exports, and foreign borrowing for foreign exchange reserves are calculated. The pathway of balance of payments impact is via the movement in the foreign exchange reserves to the banking system. And because the central bank is assumed to be the residual buyer of government debt, public finance needs can ultimately also be traced to the banking system. Given an independent estimate of the appropriate currency and deposit expansion, the credit extension available to the private domestic sector can be calculated residually and its adequacy can be judged in the light of financing needs. Iterations of this analysis lead to the firming of the various policy objectives. Until now, financial programming has generally been done without the help of formal flow-of-funds projections, but it is evident that they would be a useful complement to the analysis.

4. Long-run development of financial institutions

Flow-of-funds projections need not be merely short-run; they can cover 5-year plan periods or even 15- to 20-year financial developments. In this latter case the projection may reveal, or be required to take into account, various institutional developments in the financial system. Thus, shifts in the main sectors carrying out capital formation will be accompanied by changes in the types and composition of claims that the financial system will be asked to absorb. Similarly, as some households become more affluent and sophisticated, the supply of funds moving into the various financial markets will alter. Wealthy households may wish to deal regularly in equity share markets or to place funds into life insurance and pension saving. These changing borrower and lender needs will be pressures for change in the financial institutions and the markets that are their financial channels. An efficient group of financial institutions is one that can comfortably absorb the varieties of instruments offered to it by borrowers and can offer a suitable variety of claims to meet the needs of lenders. The long-run changes in these borrower and lender needs will thus suggest appropriate institutional growth, and policies can be designed for its promotion.

One or two examples from developing countries may provide illustrations. We should keep it in mind that well-organized open markets for financial instruments may not be common in developing circumstances. A country may wish to place more of its government debt issues domestically and/or less with its banking system. The situation may be appropriate for the design of a small-saver instrument that can be widely distributed and that would carry a very high rate of return in the interest of saving mobilization. Or we might consider a country in which liquid business deposits are stored in foreign assets. Such accumulation represents lending to the rest-of-world and may be part of a pattern in which the rest-of-world is being treated as a financial intermediary, accepting short-term funds and lending back long-term funds. It may be desirable to attract the short-term flow to the domestic economy. What is suggested is the need for a secure, liquid financial instrument—for example, a treasury bill—with an attractive enough return to compete with foreign instruments. The flow-of-funds projection can incorporate such new growth patterns into its flows and can help us to judge their impact on other markets and sectors.

In concluding this section, it is only fair that we raise a question. Given all these promising applications, why has flow-of-funds analysis not become more prominent during the past 30 years? We can only speculate. On the academic side, for some reason, flow-of-funds analysis—unlike input/output analysis—seems not to have developed a strong tradition. And, on the other hand, many applied economists have apparently not sensed how they might make use of the system. Or, perhaps, much flow-of-funds analysis is so informal as to remain hidden, as in much of the Fund’s work. Nevertheless, given the growing importance of financial problems for most of the countries of the world, we believe the system’s potential remains great.

We turn, in the next section, to an examination of the relation of flow-of-funds accounts to the SNA, and, finally, in Section IV, to a demonstration that flow-of-funds matrices such as Tables 1 and 2 are within easy grasp of the nations of the world.

III. The Conceptual Relationship of Flow-of-Funds Accounts to the System of National Accounts (SNA)

1. Finance and the evolution of the SNA

As background to a consideration of the relationship between the flow-of-funds accounts and the SNA, it will be useful to briefly review the evolution of the SNA itself over the last 35 years. For this purpose we propose to comment on the so-called standard accounts as they first appear in the 1953 version (SNA 1953), 2/ then as they appear in the 1968 version (SNA 1968), 3/ and finally as they might appear in the revision under consideration which we label SNA 1990. We shall discuss several key features of each phase of the evolution.

a. SNA 1953

The standard accounts as initially laid out in SNA 1953 (see Appendix I) focus centrally on the circular flow of product and income. Accounts 1 and 2 present on one side the sale of the final product, the gross domestic product (GDP), and on the other side the income and other payments generated in producing the GDP—a total we may refer to as the gross domestic income (GDI). Accounts 3 through 6 are the accounts that receive the GDI and, taking account of the various transfer and financing operations, use it in purchasing the GDP. This portrayal of the income circuit in the accounts thus separates the activity of production from all other activities engaged in by the institutional sectors of the economy—the activities we later come to associate with income/outlay and capital finance. The foundation of the SNA 1953 system is a cross-classification of the economy: once by activity and once by institution. This first key feature is an obvious and familiar one.

The second key feature is that these standard accounts consist of a set of balancing and interlocking accounts. One part of the analytical power of the system stems from the fact the each account balances conceptually, that each is a selection of receipt items which provides the finance for its corresponding group of disbursement items; each is a balancing sources and uses of funds statement. Another part of the system’s analytical power stems from its interlocking character. That is, each disbursement (use of funds) item in one account can be matched to an equal receipt (source of funds) item in a different account. The system is technically a quadruple entry system: a change in any one item implies a change in at least three other items. These are characteristics that greatly facilitate the tracing of intersectoral economic impacts.

In connection with this interlocking feature it is necessary to consider Account 6, External Transactions (rest of the world account). The treatment of this account in SNA 1953—and in SNA 1968, as well—is somewhat ambiguous with respect to the point of view represented by the account.

On one hand, the title and wording of the account imply that it is an assembly of the domestic sector records of international transactions—as in a balance of payments account. Thus, we have an external transactions account, an account derivable by consolidating all the domestic sector accounts—Accounts 1 through 5. Such an account records transactions from the viewpoint of the domestic sectors (for example, “receipt” implies received by a domestic sector). In this view the account reflects one kind of domestic sector activity and the rest-of-world is not an institutional sector in a system of national accounts.

On the other hand, if the accounts are to be considered as a complete system of interlocking accounts, Account 6 must be viewed as recording the transactions of the rest-of-world (for example, a domestic sector receipt in Accounts 1 through 5 must be matched by a rest-of-world disbursement in Account 6). In SNA 1953, this view is implied both by the interlocking coding of account items and by the consistency with which the accounts elsewhere record sources of funds on the right and uses of funds on the left. In this view the right side of Account 6 should be labeled (Rest-of-world) Receipts rather than (Domestic Sector) Disbursements. It would seem desirable to remove this ambiguity in SNA 1990. And if the interlocking feature of the system is as important as we assert, it would seem that the External Transactions account should become unambiguously a rest-of-world account and the rest-of-world should become an institutional sector in a closed social accounting system.

We turn now to a third key feature of SNA 1953—the analytical significance of the system. This feature was unquestionably a central motivator for the statistical development of the accounts. First of all, Western economic analysis had universally accepted the circular flow of product and income as a central organizing concept. Further, the GDP, or some variant of it, was becoming widely accepted as an important measure of overall economic performance. In addition, the Keynesian hypothesis that the GDP is determined by the aggregate demand remains even today as the key practical hypothesis in macro-analysis. In SNA 1953, aggregate demand is prominently set out in Account 1. These accounts, particularly the sector accounts, also contain a judicious selection of other important variables—for example, household income and saving, the general government current deficit (saving), the economy’s external surplus on current account. And, as was noted above, all the variables are related via the balancing and interlocking feature. Finally, although the SNA 1953 accounts are somewhat cluttered with items of minor importance for many countries, the scheme is simple enough to be analytically manageable. While our list of such characteristics could be extended, suffice it to say here that the scheme was nicely designed and timed to catch on as a tool for economic analysis.

Finally, since our ultimate purpose is to relate the SNA to finance, we consider the portrayal of finance in these standard accounts. At first sight we appear to have in Account 3 a capital formation account for the whole economy, showing domestic capital formation together with its methods of finance. But items 3.7 and 3.8, despite their labels as “finance,” are imputed items measured as types of real capital formation. However, if we consolidate the three capital reconciliation accounts (for households, etc.; general government; and the rest of the world) with Account 3 we end up with an account for capital formation together with the elements of sector saving which ultimately finance it (items 4.6, 5.5, and 6.6) (see SNA 1953, Standard Table V). Because this consolidated “saving and investment” account was in practice substituted for Account 3, and the reconciliation accounts were never developed, our best sense of finance in SNA 1953 is to see the system as presenting the sector surpluses that ultimately finance real investment but as not presenting any information about the flows in financial assets and liabilities by which the saving moves through the financial system into investment. These flows in financial claims have in effect been consolidated out.

An alternative view is to see the capital reconciliation accounts as primitive capital finance accounts (items 4.12 and 5.13 being converted into capital formation components) and Account 3 (by netting items 3.7 and 3.8) as applying only to corporate enterprises. This approach, in effect, deconsolidates the Domestic Capital Formation account. When we do this the financial claim items (items 3.6, 4.18, 5.19, and 6.11) are retained and finance remains explicitly in the system. 4/ It will be appropriate to pursue this viewpoint when we discuss SNA 1968.

b. SNA 1968

We now move forward 15 years to the next stage in the evolution of the standard accounts to SNA 1968 (see Appendix II). We actually find here three different systems of standard accounts. The first consists of the four consolidated accounts for the nation (Accounts 1, 3, 5, and 6). This system is then deconsolidated in two quite separate ways. One method deconsolidates the GDP and expenditure account (Account 1) in the direction of detailed production analysis. Since our concern is finance we will not pursue this path. The other deconsolidates the national income and outlay account (Account 3) and the national capital finance account (Account 5) into five domestic sectors each. When we put these ten accounts together with the GDP and external accounts (Accounts 1 and 6) we have a 12-account version of SNA 1968. This is the standard system we shall examine as SNA 1968.

How have the various key features that we sketched for SNA 1953 fared in this revision? The SNA 1968 focuses even more sharply on the circular flow of income and product than did its predecessor. We note that the first two accounts in the previous system, the Domestic Product and National Income accounts, have here been consolidated into a single GDP and expenditure account (Account 1). Thus, all of the GDP expenditure flows go to Account 1 and all of the equal income flow—what we have called gross domestic income—flows out of the same account.

With respect to the balancing and interlocking features, the former is clearly present. But in the sector accounts the parenthetical references that specified the interlocking character of the previous system have disappeared. The SNA 1968 system is nevertheless interlocking, but in a somewhat different sense. It should be understood as a matrix of accounts with balancing cross totals (total sources and uses for each transaction type), and also as balancing down totals (total sources and uses for each account). For example, the sum of the final consumption expenditure items as disbursements equals, conceptually, final consumption expenditure as receipts; and total property income receipts should equal property income disbursements. The analytical power of the quadruple entry system is in this way preserved.

From the viewpoint of financial analysis, this 12-account system takes two crucial steps forward. While the consolidated capital finance account (Account 5) remains similar to the earlier capital formation or saving-investment account in that it presented only the ultimate origins of the finance of investment, the deconsolidated sector capital finance accounts each present, as well, the immediate financial sources and uses: that is, these accounts show us details of the net incurrence of liabilities and the net acquisition of financial assets as well as the sectors’ saving (income and outlay surplus) and capital formation. Furthermore, these financial flows are for the first time defined (other than residually) and classified. As we have indicated, such data can enable us to do a very useful and straightforward analysis of how a sector finances itself and how it contributes to the finance of other sectors.

The second crucial step forward occurs by virtue of the separate sectoring of financial institutions in the SNA 1968 domestic sector breakdown. As was pointed out in SNA 1953, the separate sectoring of financial institutions is necessary if we are to do a meaningful analysis of the financial flows. This is because of the intermediary role played by financial institutions in providing finance to governments and to the enterprise and household sectors. We should add that this role is characteristic of developing as well as developed economies; almost all countries have important central bank and commercial banking institutions.

It is when we come to the matter of analytical significance that questions begin to arise about this 12-account SNA 1968 system: it appears to be far more complex than the 6-account SNA 1953 system. The question is, how much more analytically effective is the newer system? Is the added detail worth the effort to collect it? On one hand, we have argued that at least some sector detail is necessary in order to facilitate intersectoral impact analysis. And we have also argued that separate sectoring of financial institutions is essential for effective financial analysis. Thus, it is hard to see how we could accommodate ourselves to less than, say, four domestic sectors. 5/

But proliferation of sectors is not in fact the main source of added complexity. This stems primarily from added transaction type detail in the income and outlay accounts and the capital finance accounts. 6/ We believe that these classification schemes could be substantially condensed with little analytical loss for the purposes of standard national accounts. Furthermore, with respect to the financial transaction detail presented in the sector capital finance accounts, effective financial analysis requires not only less detail but a different sort of detail. Our proposal in this respect will appear in our discussion of SNA 1990. Suffice it to say here that a standard system containing well-designed sector capital finance accounts would be capable of producing financial system analysis far beyond the capability of SNA 1953.

c. Types of national accounts data presently submitted

It is time to pause in our evolutionary survey of the standard SNA systems—before we project forward to SNA 1990—and address a somewhat different question. We have been tracing the UN schemes of what was desirable in social accounting data. We need also to observe what has been happening in practice over the past 35 years. One way of doing this is to look at what types of data the countries of the world are able to submit for the UN’s compendium of national accounts. 7/ Table 4 summarizes a recent such survey.

Table 4.

Major Types of National Accounts Data Reported in United Nations Compilation for 1983 1/

(146 Countries Reporting in accordance with UN-SNA.)

article image

From United Nations, National Accounts Statistics: Main Aggregates and Detailed Tables, 1983. All tables for which more than 50% of the countries reported either current or back data are included here.

We see in Table 4 strong evidence that the early SNA 1953 scheme has taken hold in practice. Almost all of the 146 reporting countries are producing a GDP account (GDP, 1.1, and income, 1.3), although it is true that for many countries these data are not yet current. Most also provide the GDP by industry (1.10) and in constant prices (1.2 and 1.11). More than half are able in time to add current accounts for general government (1.4) and the rest-of-world (1.7), and also a capital formation (saving-investment) account (1.8). These four accounts are four of the five needed for the closed SNA 1953 system referred to above in which the capital reconciliation accounts are merged with the domestic capital formation account to form a saving-investment account. About a quarter of the reporting countries are able to add a household income and outlay account (not shown in table) and form the complete system.

Table 4 reports 1983 data, but its source compendium was published in 1986—more than 15 years after the publication of SNA 1968. Do we find evidence of its impact? The reporting scheme does not include SNA 1968 Account 3: National Disposable Income and Its Appropriation (the consolidated income and outlay) or Account 5: Capital Finance (the consolidated capital finance). So, apparently, the four “Consolidated Accounts for the Nation” as a standard scheme did not take hold. If we inquire about the deconsolidated 12-sector scheme, we find that only a handful of countries—perhaps 10 percent and largely in Europe—are able to report sector income and outlay accounts at the level of detail of SNA 1968, and a still smaller handful—perhaps 5 percent—are able to report detailed sector capital finance accounts. We are thus forced to conclude that SNA 1968 is not widely used as a system of standard accounts.

d. Implications for SNA 1990

As we project the SNA forward to formulate SNA 1990, it is important to consider why SNA 1968 has had so little impact. Our data suggest an important clue: while 57 percent of the countries reporting could submit a summary general government current receipts and expenditures account, only 11 percent could submit one at the level of detail required by the standard system; for the external account, the corresponding figures are 73 percent and 11 percent. We might infer that SNA 1968 is too complicated and detailed for most countries to produce at present. We should like to add that in the author’s view SNA 1968 is too complicated and contains too much insignificant detail for straightforward policy analysis. These suggestions underscore the objective in the current revision process of presenting a simpler standard set of accounts.

2. The flow-of-funds representation in the SNA

What, then, is the upshot of our vision of the about-to-be-created SNA 1990 standard accounts? If we are right about the main lesson of SNA 1968, the new accounts should not be far ahead of the current statistical accomplishment of most countries. To be serviceable, the new accounts should be feasible next steps in statistical development. In addition, our analysis has stressed the need to maintain sector accounts in the standard central system. And for effective financial analysis we must have sector capital finance accounts and the separate sectoring of financial institutions. Are these objectives compatible? We believe so.

In sketching a suggested new system, let us begin where a good many countries presently are: they have a gross product and income account, income and outlay accounts for the rest-of-world, general government, and households (including within it nonprofit institutions), and a consolidated capital formation (saving-investment) account. Let us move toward the SNA 1968 12-account scheme but keep in mind, at the same time, the need for simplification.

First, we envision a vertical extension of the rest-of-world account to derive its capital finance account and a similar extension for general government. The development of full balance of payments and government finance data for most countries during the past few decades should make this a relatively easy step. 8/

Three capital finance accounts remain: for nonfinancial enterprises, for financial institutions, and for households, etc. (including nonprofit institutions). Let us imagine them lumped together into a single residual capital finance account. For analytical purposes it is essential to estimate and break out an account for at least a large share of financial institutions. For many countries this can be done via an account for the monetary and banking system alone. And these basic data are available for almost all countries. As we shall note below, it is analytically less essential to break nonfinancial enterprises away from households, etc., but such a step would in any event have to await the compilation of balance sheet data for substantial groups of enterprises. If SNA 1990 wishes to emphasize feasibility, a first-stage version of it might contain (1) a monetary and banking system capital finance account and (2) a catch-all other domestic sector capital finance account.

Let us consider the types of financial transaction to be used. We have suggested that much of the difficulty in producing sector capital finance accounts may stem from the complexity of the classification scheme for financial claims. For SNA 1990 we suggest first a greatly condensed scheme consisting of four broad financial categories:

A. Foreign assets

B. Currency and deposits

C. Bills, bonds, and loans

D. Other claims.

The existing thirteen-claim categories can, of course, be allocated to these headings. 9/ Our purpose here is only in part simplification. In many applications foreign assets (category A), properly defined, will consist largely of net foreign exchange. And currency and deposits (category B) is closely related to money, broadly defined. So these categories are likely to be of analytical use.

To understand why category C as a whole might not be very useful, let us consider such an item on the various SNA 1968 capital finance accounts. Each of the sectors might accumulate and each of them might issue these instruments. In these circumstances it would generally not be possible to identify who is acquiring from whom (that is, who is financing whom). And we are probably no better off if we narrow the category to bonds, long-term. On the other hand let us consider the category of central government bond issues. Here we have only one sector issuing the instrument. In the absence of secondary market transactions, we know the acquiring sector is financing the government. Even with secondary market transactions, there is a much better chance with government bond issues of being able to identify who is financing whom. And that is the central objective in financial flow tracing. To generalize, the most useful financial transaction types will be those designed so as to have only one or two sectors issuing or only one or two sectors acquiring the instrument. Category C needs to be broken down.

This discussion of the most useful categories of financial transaction types for a flow-of-funds matrix is related to Table 24 in SNA 1968 (see Appendix III). There we find the same 13 types of claim that appear in the sector capital finance accounts, but within each of the 13 types we also find institutional sector detail to indicate sectors bearing the liabilities for that particular claim. 11/ The line for a subcategory such as 5iii (bonds, long-term, liability of the central government) would have a single issue figure under central government off to the right and figures for the various sector acquisitions off to the left. Given such detail, it is clear that the category central government debt could be assembled as the sum of 4iii, 5iii, 7iv, and 8iii—that is, the sum of all the central government liability components we wish to define into central government debt. Alternatively, if we wished to build up data for the 13 basic claim types we would have to reverse this process, allocating central government debt to the Table 24 subcategories. The Table 24 analysis thus shows us how we can conceptually relate the 13 basic claim types both to basic data sources and to analytically significant categories.

Perhaps the simplest effective breakdown for the bills, bonds, and loans that comprise Category C would be into central government debt, bank loans, and other, but most countries should consider at least the following:

C. Bills, bonds, and loans

  1. Central government debt

  2. Central government loans

  3. Central bank advances

  4. Financial institution loans and advances

  5. Other debt.

This or a similar list should be adopted for the SNA 1990 standard accounts to suggest the type of detail that countries would find analytically useful. It will be remembered that these are the types of claims in Tables 1 and 2, above, that we used to indicate inter-sectoral tracing of financial flows.

Let us summarize our position in regard to the financial transaction types presented in the SNA 1968 sector capital finance accounts. To produce these accounts as presented requires a high level of financial detail—detail at the level of the subcategories of Table 24, which is generally available only in the most statistically advanced countries. Further, the transaction types in these accounts are not very effective in financial flow analysis: they provide little sector-to-sector identification of flows. The alternative classification that we have presented is simpler and, as we shall show in Section IV, below, can be derived directly from data available in almost all countries. And it is a scheme that is demonstrably useful in financial flow analysis.

In conclusion, we feel that the flow-of-funds accounts should be represented in SNA 1990 by a closed set of condensed capital finance accounts. We have suggested such accounts for the rest-of-world, general government, the monetary and banking sector, and the other domestic sector. To form a standard system we could add to these four capital finance accounts a gross product and income account and three income/outlay accounts (rest-of-world, general government, and households, etc., including nonprofit institutions). 11/ These eight accounts could form a closed, interlocking system—a system that in its condensed form is achievable for most countries in the next decade or so. This system could be a standard first stage leading to a later more detailed standard system.

If financial analysis is to have an improved social accounting data base, increased statistical effort must focus on the sector capital finance accounts. To help in this effort these accounts must have a prominent place in the simplest, most central, UN standard accounts formulation.

3. Flow-of-funds accounts, the Fund’s GFS, BOP, and MBS, and the harmonization issue

We have taken the view that the hope for an early statistical realization of sector capital finance accounts rests importantly on early development of such accounts for the government, the rest-of-world, and the monetary and banking sectors. In order to serve the social accounting purpose, they must, of course, fit into a matrix. This means that at the technical level there must be consistent sector coverage and consistent accounting treatment of transactions within and (especially) across sectors. This is our understanding of what harmonization means. Harmonization among the three Fund systems: government finance statistics (GFS), balance of payments statistics (BOP), and money and banking statistics (MBS), and between each of these and SNA 1990, becomes an issue because GFS, BOP, and MBS (or closely related country data) are likely to be basic source material for the new flow-of- funds accounts.

Each of the three Fund systems has had international comparability as a goal. Each has provided useful compilations of data. In this process some member countries have altered their accounts in the direction of the respective Fund conventions. To the extent that the Fund’s standard systems are not harmonized, such alterations may make the local articulation of these accounts more difficult. There is to some extent an inherent conflict between international comparability and local articulation of sector accounts, but this is especially so if the international standards are not harmonious.

If GFS, BOP, and MBS had been developed for systematic social accounting purposes, their instruction manuals might well now provide uniform and consistent measurement conventions. However, these systems did not come about in this way. They were created within the Fund over a. considerable period, each guided by the analytical needs of a particular group of specialists. It is true that steps toward harmonization were taken as the later systems were developed and the earlier ones revised. But differences remain, and now that the differing measurement conventions have taken hold among analysts both within and outside the Fund, changing them will be difficult. Perhaps over time the analytical advantages of a social accounting approach may be persuasive in moving toward harmonization: after all, the problems dealt with by the Fund usually deal with the interrelationships among these three sectors. But at present the differing needs of each system’s primary users may continue to impede a true harmonization.

SNA 1990, on the other hand, is constrained to build full consistency into its system. In this situation, what is to be done? Of course we should harmonize to the extent possible. But wisdom may suggest stressing the construction of standard reconciliation or bridge tables linking the key time series in the four systems to permit analysts to move from one system to another in both estimation and analysis. We understand such an effort to be under way. It should be given urgent priority because such tables could greatly facilitate the construction of SNA by individual countries.

Curiously, the single most important harmonization issue for the SNA seems likely to be overlooked entirely. In order to comprise a closed system, all the sector accounts of that system must be in the same unit of account, the same currency. Thus, it is essential to SNA that the rest-of-world account be expressed in the local currency. But this in turn means that there must be a balance of payments account in the local currency as a data source. The increasing trend throughout the world is to do balance of payments analysis in some international currency such as U.S. dollars. The loss of any analytical connection with domestic sector data is apparently less important than the fact that payments to abroad must be made in an international currency. In countries without local currency balance of payments data, or where such data are of low quality, the Fund could aid the development of the SNA accounts by assuring the early compilation or improvement of these data. 12/

We shall not here deal with the many technical aspects of the harmonization issue, but we shall try to offer an approach to these problems, one that suggests a rough ordering of priorities. We suggest that attention first be focused on the definitions of sector coverage for the major domestic sectors and the rest-of-world. The remaining issues here are relatively minor and, with compromise, true consistency should be achievable. And complete harmony on major sector definitions would greatly simplify the conversion of BOP, GFS, or MBS data into the corresponding SNA capital finance accounts.

Our second priority for harmonization would be toward standardization of the financial/nonfinancial line in each sector account for the four systems. Conceptually, entries indicating the exchange of goods, services, and transfers lie above this line in each sector account, and entries recording the exchange of claims (including cash balances) lie below this line. In SNA 1968 the line is marked by the net lending item in each capital finance account, which, broadly, equals the difference between gross saving and gross capital formation for each sector. 13/ In this harmonization we would be trying to standardize the definition of the deficit/surplus of each sector; conceptually, the algebraic sum of these items across all sectors (including the rest-of-world) should be zero. Drawing this line is an essential feature of flow-of-funds accounts.

For example, in GFS, although lending minus repayments is separated out from other government expenditure and revenue, it is for analytical purposes located above the overall deficit/surplus line (that is, as part of the net aggregate that is to be financed by government debt issue). Although this practice cannot be accepted by SNA, the separate identification of the item makes the shift of these financial transactions to below the deficit line simple. This applies, of course, providing the technical specifications for the lending minus repayments total are in harmony with those for the other sectors. This harmonization is an example of our second priority focus.

Finally, we approach the complexities of the harmonization of the various types of financial transactions. Here, too, we suggest a “closing in on the area” strategy. We urge first the standardization across sectors of broad groups of claims such as the four groups we suggested by way of simplifying the capital finance account (see Section III.2). In this way there are far fewer borderlines to define. Beyond this we can only urge the wisdom of the view that in these matters it is necessary to have some agreed upon convention; which particular convention is less important. And where agreement is not possible, we should take on the obligation of providing reconciliations.

Let us consider just one key example in this category. It is our hope that harmonization can be effected in the area of foreign exchange, and, in particular, the area of international reserves. The flow in these net foreign assets appears only in the monetary sector and the rest-of-world sector accounts. The analytical purpose of the identification of these reserves—a key part of the means of payment for international transactions—is broadly the same for users of both BOP and MBS. Furthermore, both estimates generally rely on the same (monetary sector) sources for data. To a practitioner there would seem to be no reason for differences in these flows where they are expressed in the local currency unit. At minimum, we should have a clear reconciliation.

4. Balances, flows, and valuation changes

About a decade ago the standard accounts of SNA 1968 were extended in the Guidelines 14/ to add a system of balance sheet and reconciliation accounts to the capital finance accounts. The construction of national and sectoral balance sheets and reconciliation accounts is in general envisioned as a stage beyond the construction of sectoral capital finance accounts (that is, flow-of-funds accounts). Nevertheless, because flow estimates are often derived from balance sheet increments, the two areas appear to have a substantial overlap and it is this overlap that we here wish to explore.

From an accounting viewpoint, asset and liability balances change either as a result of transactions, which are encompassed in the flow measure, or as a result of revaluations—that is, write-ups or write-downs of the asset or liability valuations. This principle is embodied in the definition of the reconciliation accounts which include all the differences between opening and closing balance sheet accounts that are not covered by the flows in the capital finance accounts. That is, the reconciliation accounts will consist largely of revaluations of balance sheet items. 15/

In general, the Guidelines call for nonfinancial assets on the balance sheets to be valued at current market values. This rule makes large annual revaluations of tangible assets highly likely; and since the companion entry to every revaluation is a corresponding change in the transactor’s net worth, we are assured of large and frequent revaluations in sector equities. The situation differs dramatically, however, when we consider financial assets. With only three exceptions, the Guidelines call for these assets to be valued at nominal or face values. And these financial assets—so-called fixed-claim assets—are similarly valued as liabilities. The upshot of these rules is that much of the array of claims on the flow-of-funds matrix is not subject to regular revaluations owing to asset price changes.

The exceptions to the use of nominal values for financial assets are made in the cases of: (1) gold, (2) long-term bonds, and (3) corporate equity securities. Current market valuations are proposed for all three of the above. Market valuations are also proposed for long-term bonds and corporate equity securities on the liability side of the balance sheet. Thus, revaluations are to be expected in these three items. The Guidelines also allow for another important type of revaluation. The foreign assets category will be subject to revaluation if the local balance sheet convention is to show the local currency equivalent of the foreign exchange that is receivable or payable on the claim. In all, we are alerted to three types of flow-of-funds claims in which revaluations are likely to play a role in the balance sheet/reconciliation account scheme: (1) corporate equity securities, (2) long term bonds, and (3) foreign assets (including gold). 16/

Let us now return to the situation of the implementation not of balance sheets and reconciliation accounts but merely of the capital finance accounts themselves. Our problem will be reduced to removing revaluations that we pick up when we estimate flows from balance sheet increments. To consider it we must anticipate some of the results of our discussion below of estimating procedures. Of the main sectors we will estimate first only the accounts for the financial sectors will be estimated from balance sheets. And the valuation conventions on these balance sheets will be near enough to face values so that the increments will be good approximations of the actual flows for most items. However, if long-term bonds are a substantial portfolio item, and the balance sheets value them at market values, removal of the revaluations will be in order. Finally, we may have difficulty reconciling the flow in net foreign exchange, to the corresponding flow as shown in the balance of payments. And valuation changes may be at the heart of this matter. This last is the harmonization issue that we referred to above.

At a later stage in the implementation, balance sheets of enterprises—both government and private—will be used as sources. Revaluations of fixed assets as well as other items on the balance sheet are to be found here and can probably be avoided in flow estimates only by a case-by-case scrutiny of the accounts. In addition, large revaluations in the corporate stock account are so likely that this item should not be used to estimate the cash inflow derived from net cash stock issues if at all possible. In most cases, this flow is small and, luckily, plays a minor role in the flow-of-funds matrix.

Overall, our review of the problems involved in the overlap of flow-of -funds estimation and the revaluation of balance sheet items has indicated that the overlap is not large. Experience indicates that at present most of the errors that are due to unidentified revaluations being mixed into the flows are small errors in relation to classification problems and other data shortcomings.

IV. Feasible Flow-of-Funds Accounts and the Developing Countries

Most of the 160 or so countries of the world are developing countries. And one of the features of a developing country is a developing statistical system. Unfortunately, SNA 1968 did not take into account the fact that a great many countries have only the most limited capacity for producing new and improved data. One surmises that this was one key reason why SNA 1968 has been, as we concluded above, too complicated and detailed for most countries to produce during the past 20 years; the goals were set too far ahead of the possibilities.

In presenting its full set of standard accounts arid supporting tables, the only concession SNA 1968 made to development was a suggested order in which the full accounts should be implemented.17/ The developing countries were not offered any intermediate targets leading up to the full system. In particular, they were not offered simpler versions which, while within their statistical capabilities, would offer the analytical advantages of a social accounting system (that is, of a closed set of interlocking accounts). Our objective in this section is to demonstrate a simplified system in the flow-of-funds area that is presently feasible for almost all countries and that can lead in steps to the SNA 1968 system of sector capital finance accounts and/or a complete flow-of-funds system. It is, in effect, a design for a series of intermediate systems leading toward complete implementation; it thus embodies its own suggestions for statistical priorities.

1. Getting the initial estimates

Our method of presentation will be to describe the statistical implementation of a simplified flow-of-funds matrix using the sort of statistical base found in the least developed countries in, let us say, the 1970s. This will enable us to enumerate the bare statistical necessities for such an undertaking. We shall then move on to describe the successive stages of statistical elaboration of the matrix in the movement toward a full system. For this exercise we shall assume that BOP, GFS, and MBS are not available to use as data sources.

Table 1 (see p. 4) presents an illustration of the format we use for the earliest stage flow-of-funds matrix. 18/ It contains a very simple sectoring scheme of 5 sectors: the central government, the central bank, the commercial banks, the rest-of-world, and a catch-all other domestic sector which includes enterprises, households, and a variety of smaller sectors including provincial and local government and other financial institutions. And the classification for types of financial claims follows closely the scheme we advocated above. In Table 1, financial institution loans and advances is divided between central bank advances and other loans and advances which in our simple sectoring becomes entirely commercial bank loans and advances. It is to be noted that several of the key claims we have selected for enumeration are claims attributable to the sectors we have selected, so that if data are available for these sectors they will in general be available for these claims. We note also that in laying out sector accounts we do not suggest government as a whole or financial institutions as whole. Each of these more aggregative sectors contains subsectors whose data are not likely to be available at the earliest stage.

a. Preliminary considerations

As a primary matter, we must consider the time reference that is to be standard for all sectors. We may find that our local data sources deal with the central government on a fiscal year basis while the banking data and balance of payments are on calendar years. Which time reference we use will depend on the ease of conversion. If an insufficient amount of quarterly or semiannual data is available to permit conversion and, hence, uniformity where it does not exist, then probably flow-of-funds implementation should be deferred. Financial flows are simply too volatile for the average of two calendar years to be representative of a fiscal year, or viceversa.

A second primary requirement is the existence of balance of payments data on a local currency basis. As we have suggested above, moving from dollar or SDR figures to a local currency basis with a single exchange ratio can sometimes give unsatisfactory results. However, the most critical data are those for the current account balance and the items above it. Since local currency figures here are necessary for the income and product accounts, it is likely that even for less developed countries a local currency balance of payments will be available or can be estimated. If it is not possible to obtain it, however, the flow-of-funds effort should be deferred.

As a final preliminary we may raise the question of how current the basic data are. The data are likely to be reasonably current in our directly estimated sectors because they are all tied to areas of current public policy decision-making. And in fact at the start we need not aim to assemble a very recent year. We would be well-advised to move back in time to a year in which definitive rather than preliminary or revised data are available. Once we are successfully producing the system with a lag of a few years we can then use the more recent, more preliminary, more fragmentary sources to carry the system toward current data production.

b. The matrix

We now proceed to the matrix itself, referring to Table 1. The totals data at the right of the table for the first two lines—gross capital formation and gross saving—will come from the national income and product (NIP) data. It is on these first two lines that the flow-of-funds construction ties in with the income/outlay accounts that lie above the capital finance accounts in SNA. The key central government/other breakdown of capital formation is usually available in the NIP source. The saving breakdown is generally more troublesome. The NIP source will have a rest-of-world saving figure which is (minus) the surplus of the nation on current account, but NIP is unlikely to have central government saving. This figure may well have to be derived as an operating surplus from the central government data. Given the central government/other domestic saving breakdown, we have the surplus or deficit of each sector 19/ (shown in Table 1 as net lending), which is to be analyzed into the incurrence of liabilities (financial sources of funds in Table 1) and the acquisition of financial assets (financial uses in Table 1) in the lower section of the matrix.

At this point we shall consider the initial derivation of each of the directly estimated sector accounts from its basic sources. For the central government, two basic sources are generally available: the data associated with the budget-making process and the data associated with the auditing process. Each will contain past actuals for income, outlay, and financing—the budget source often being more up to date but less detailed. The quality of either source may be much better than the other. It is better to stick to one source if possible, since each reflects a whole system of accounts and tables.

The worksheet task is to transcribe the balancing account and supporting detail so that the account can be rearranged and condensed to yield a first approximation to the Table 1 sector account. We shall focus first on deriving a nonfinancial surplus or deficit (net lending) from the revenue and expenditure figures. The main difficulty will be the removal of financial transactions from the expenditures and revenues. 20/ Expenditures are likely to contain new loans and/or equity advances made and also repayments of government debt principal, while receipts will probably contain some types of debt issues and repayments of principal on loans. These financial entries are to be assigned below the line to complete the estimates for the net increases in government debt and government loans. It is useful to keep the balance in the account during this process of netting, reclassification, and condensation, making use of a miscellaneous, or other sources, net item. Finally, if necessary, the nonfinancial surplus control figure from the government finance data can be combined with the capital formation figure from the income and product data to obtain a residual estimate for central government gross saving.

As this process proceeds, classification decisions will be made. If ways and means advances from the central bank can be identified in these data they can be assigned either to the bank loans or government debt category, according to local policy usage. For flow-of-funds purposes, where they are assigned is not critical; the key point is to make the same assignment in the central bank account.

In broad outline, the estimation of the rest-of-world account from the balance of payments data is a simple affair. 21/ The debits and credits are reversed to shift to a rest-of-world viewpoint and the current account is netted down to a single gross saving figure. In the transforming of the capital account, it is essential that the basic data separate asset items from liability items so that financial uses can be separated from sources. The capital flow to the official sector is an estimate of the rest-of-world’s acquisition of government debt, and that to the private sectors is an estimate of its acquisition of other domestically issued debt. All the rest-of-world liabilities are assembled into the claim category of foreign assets. To the extent that these are held by the central bank or the commercial banks, they become foreign exchange; other domestic sector holdings are generally small. It is sometimes analytically desirable to present the foreign exchange of the two banking sectors on a net basis, and that convention is followed here. In principle, then, the rest-of-world’s foreign exchange entry is the sum of the net foreign exchange held by commercial banks and by the central bank. These entries are the bulk of the foreign Assets line.

The flows for both the central bank and the commercial banks in Table 1 are derived as balance sheet increments. The basic process is again straightforward. Balance sheet transcriptions are taken from the basic banking statistics; they are reclassified into flow-of-funds format and increments are taken. To ensure that the currency and deposits liabilities of the banking sectors reflect the entire quantity of money, a small accounting adjustment is sometimes made (as in MBS), transferring any monetary accounts of the central government into the central bank account.

Whenever financial flows are being estimated, as here, via balance sheet increments, the question arises as to whether these increments reflect only the transactions in the instrument or also reflect book write-ups or write-downs. 22/ Conceptually, the revaluations should be removed so that the flow portrays only the transactions. Practically, the matter hinges on the size of the revaluation in relation to the flow, and indeed whether the data availability makes the removal possible. Fortunately, for developing countries, experience indicates that the problem is not serious in the banking sectors as far as the domestic assets and liabilities are concerned. 23/ As we have noted, it is most likely to arise in foreign assets and with respect to net foreign exchange. For example, it has become somewhat conventional for central bank balance sheets to revalue for balance sheet purposes their monetary gold stocks. Since the international transactions in gold are likely to be small, the flow will be overwhelmed in the balance sheet increment by a revaluation of the stock, and a removal adjustment will be essential.

With respect to commercial banks, the sector coverage will be governed by the basic aggregation in the banking statistics. It is very important for effective sector articulation that the data used be as of the actual year end and not, for example, as of the end of the last business week of the year. In the account for this sector, it is useful to accept pro tem. the definition of bank loans that is found here (interbank loans eliminated). Further, we shall take the bank loan portfolio figures as the statistical control total for the bank loans (other loans and advances) category. With the Table 1 matrix, the only institutional sector breakdown of bank loans that is required is that for central government/other, and the usual balance sheet will provide it. But, to anticipate, a bank loan classification by institutional sector (loans to local governments, government enterprises, other financial institutions) will at a later stage be very useful.

Once we have completed preliminary sources and uses of funds accounts for the four sectors, the assembly of the other domestic sector in Table 1 is simply a matter of calculating the residuals to balance the cross totals. In this process, any items in the discrepancy columns not involving the other domestic sector should be taken as given. In fact, the discrepancy columns should be treated as if they comprise an institutional sector, with a residual estimate at the bottom to force the total net sources to zero.

It is to be understood that the matrix at this stage is a fairly rough affair. It is essential now to examine and tighten the articulation of the sector accounts. This is best done by focusing “cross-wise” on the transaction type accounts or the level version of these accounts, which we may call debt distribution tables. For example, let us suppose that the banking statistics offer us a table breaking down the government debt holdings by sector; or that we have such data for portions of it such as treasury bills or government bonds. The assembly of such tables may well have involved adjusting the technical basis of the various sector records into uniformity and may thus enable us to do so as well. 24/ Most important, this process should enable us to make progress on our likely main inconsistencies at this stage—that is, in the coverage of our types of transaction. Borderline transactions need to be treated in the same way by all sectors across the matrix. For example, if the Treasury carries an overdraft we must consistently assign it either to deposits or to bank loans.

In the end we shall have arrived at a matrix of substantial usefulness both as a way of conceptualizing important relationships and as a source of substantive analysis. We have already indicated in Section II a number of types of analysis that are available even with so condensed a matrix. If it is urged that a residually estimated other domestic sector is not a very firm basis for economic policy, then the reply must be that these estimates are inferred from data for the central government, the banking system, and the balance of payments that are routinely used as the basis for policy. We may as well see clearly what they imply for the other domestic sector. Finally, as we hope this description has made clear, we have an instrument that is feasible and inexpensive to create—easily done by one social accountant in, perhaps, two months.

2. Tightening the system

One of the great advantages of the above initial flow-of-funds implementation is its launching of a very creative stage for the statistical system of a developing country. Broadly, the condensed flow-of-funds matrix provides the incentive and points out the direction for a number of substantial improvements in financial statistics. We shall now try to indicate the nature of these developments.

Table 1 might have very few entries in the discrepancy columns. If this is the case, we would understand this to be not because of the high quality of our estimates, but rather because of the necessity for residual estimates for the other domestic sector. In effect, many of our discrepancies will be transferred to and incorporated in the estimates for this sector. Now, we can conceive of these discrepancies as arising from the existence of two differing estimates for one flow-of-funds matrix cell—estimates from two differing statistical sources. For example, figures for bank reserve deposits usually appear in the balance sheets of both the central bank and the commercial banks. If the figures differ, and if, rather than selecting one as the basis for both bank reserves flow estimates, we retain both flow estimates—each in its respective sector—then we have identified a discrepancy which will appear in the discrepancy column. It is very important in flow-of-funds work to make such identifications wherever possible and to have them appear in the discrepancy columns, for if the discrepancies are large and involve key policy variables, we want them out in the open so that they can be dealt with.

The estimates we have so far assembled have involved three (largely) separate data sources. Thus it is likely that this sort of discrepancy will already have been encountered and that the differences will turn out to be recalcitrant (that is, the estimates cannot be reconciled by modest efforts). We suggest five possibilities for such discrepancies which might well be significant: (1) central government borrowing from abroad (central government versus balance of payments data), (2) central government cash balance (central government versus banking data), (3) change in foreign exchange reserves (balance of payments versus banking data), (4) central government gross saving (central government versus national, income and product data), and (5) government debt issue (central government data versus data compiled in the central bank).

In order to gain a sense of why the exploration of these discrepancies has creative possibilities, we must visualize the typical statistical “system” of many developing countries. The data sources we have been considering will to some extent correspond to different data producing organizations. Perhaps there will be a bureau of statistics producing the national income and product data. Probably the central bank will supervise banking data and the assembly of the balance of payments data, and the treasury (or auditor general) will generate the central government data. In the developing country situation these organizations may well generate their respective data with a minimum of technical communication with respect to statistical methods and/or detailed breakdowns. Coordination and cooperation among governmental agencies may not yet have developed. The point is that a detailed reconciliation effort of the sort required to reduce the flow-of-funds discrepancies requires the kind of technical consultation that can become an important force for coordination.

Organizationally, flow-of-funds also needs a home. Some single organization needs to be responsible for its generation: an interagency committee will not have sufficient authority to be successful. Probably the central bank will have closest access to the major necessary data sources and eventually to analytical users. The latter is desirable because users will press for continuous, current generation of the data and for needed types of further detail.

3. Expanding the system

The strategy for expanding our condensed matrix, either toward the SNA 1968 sector capital finance accounts scheme or toward a still fuller flow-of-funds system, is the same simple one: to break down the other domestic sector—that is, to proceed to make direct estimates for subsector accounts and in turn break each subsector account out of the other domestic sector, leaving, each time, a smaller and more homogeneous residually estimated other domestic sector. This procedure implies that added sector detail is more useful analytically than transaction detail at this point. And this will continue to be true until the main parts of the enterprise sector can be separately shown.

If a country has a substantial system of economic planning, an appropriate statistical direction would be toward a public sector account (that is, to estimate accounts for provincial and local government and for government enterprises). Provincial and local governments themselves (or at least the large ones) should be able to provide income, outlay, and financing data in budget documents. If necessary, earlier actuals can be carried forward on the basis of budget figures. Or it may be possible to assemble a synthetic account from planning ministry data if the plan covers provincial and local government capital formation and financing. And perhaps the banking data can provide figures for bank loans to this sector. As we enter this sector into the matrix, we will be defining and allocating the components of provincial and local government debt issues. There may be security issues (perhaps assigned into other domestic debt), borrowing from the central government (into central government loans), bank loan borrowing (into other loans and advances), and, perhaps, borrowing from abroad (into other domestic debt).

Next we consider nonfinancial government enterprises. Let us suppose that the central government or planning data do not provide the detail we need in order to assemble a capital finance account, and so a new compilation must be made. The initial task will be to transcribe the balance sheet and the appropriate income statement items 25/ for each enterprise from published annual reports or reports filed with regulatory agencies or with the registrar of companies. If there are many such enterprises, a sample of the largest may be advisable; often, a surprisingly small number of government enterprises can comprise 80 percent or more of the sector. Given the transcriptions, a standard balance sheet format must be designed—one as close as possible to the flow-of-funds classification but still one into which all the enterprise statements can be transformed in order to permit compilation. If the accounts have been audited by auditing companies, the balance sheet formats will be surprisingly similar. At this point in the derivation of the flow-of-funds account from these data, rough estimates of some items will no doubt be necessary. Finally, either the sample or blown up estimates for the universe may be used for the flow-of-funds sector.

Another subsector that will be quite easy for most developing countries to assemble is that of the nonbank financial institutions. In the early development of a financial system, there are generally few such institutions. The procedure is as outlined above for government enterprises.

The expansions of the condensed matrix that we have considered so far are illustrated by Table 2 (see p. 3). The sectors in the matrix at this stage are similar to the full flow-of-funds scheme, except that private corporate enterprises are not yet separated out of the other domestic sector. 26/ For many developing countries, this will be as far as the flow-of-funds implementation can be taken, assuming only a modest commitment of resources. An assembly of basic financial data for private corporations is not likely to already exist, and such a compilation may be beyond the capability of a small statistical shop. Thus, the final stage in this case will await the compilation from tax files, official financial reports, or company reports of aggregate balance sheets and income statements for a significant sample of private companies. Still, these data are important for many uses and the compilation task will not be an enormous one. 27/

Throughout our description of the breaking down of the other domestic sector, we have paid little attention to the expansion of transaction type detail. But the financial transaction coverage has been slowly expanding. Each new directly estimated subsector picks up new claims in its liabilities or its portfolio that were not previously in the matrix because, in effect, they were washed out when the subsector was a consolidated part of the other domestic sector. That sector is de facto a consolidated one because of its residual derivation. Thus, perhaps the greatest increase in the system’s coverage of private claims will occur when private corporations can be finally separated from households.

A final commentary relating SNA 1990 to the implementation process as we have described it should be made. As the developing countries set out to disaggregate the national capital finance account into sector capital finance accounts, their data sources do not permit them first to estimate such an account for general government as a whole and then break it down further into central, provincial, and local government, or to estimate such an account for all financial institutions and then break this down for the central bank, commercial banks, and other financial institutions. As we have seen, the process is rather the reverse. Accounts are first estimated for the key subsectors—those in fact of policy importance—and these are later added to in order to assemble government or financial institutions or nonfinancial enterprises as a whole. This suggests that perhaps SNA 1990 should present a sequence of standard systems, a developmental sequence that would guide countries toward the implementation of a full SNA system.

V. Conclusions

Looking back over the main sections of this paper, we may summarize our conclusions as follows. First, our survey of the applications of flow-of-funds accounts concluded that analysis based on these data could be of considerable use to many nations of the world. These accounts are an especially effective data organization for the key public policy problems in the financial area. And the techniques can vary according to need from crude flow tracing, to the use of the saving-investment process scheme, to highly sophisticated programming models. If our case for the usefulness of flow-of-funds accounts is correct, we may infer that these accounts should have a central place in the standard United Nations’ System of Accounts.

In examining the representation of finance in SNA 1953 and SNA 1968 and the forthcoming revision, we arrived at a number of conclusions that are perhaps best set down in tabular form:

  1. For the proper articulation of national accounts as a system, the rest-of-world needs to be cleanly treated as an institutional sector.

  2. The path taken in SNA 1968 of deconsolidating the national capital finance account and separately sectoring financial institutions was correct. In effect, the comprehensive set of sector capital finance accounts becomes the flow-of-funds system of accounts.

  3. However, the 13-claim financial transaction classification in SNA 1968 is not well designed for analysis. It should contain at least key elements of the “three-dimensional classification” identifying creditor and debtor sectors, as is completely done in SNA 1968 Table 24 (Appendix III). At the same time, the standard classification needs to be much simpler, at least for developing countries.

  4. From the viewpoint of the many developing countries, the standard accounts should emphasize three main capital finance accounts—those for the rest-of-world, for general government, and for the monetary and banking system. This may imply at least initially a catch-all other domestic sector account.

Because the Fund’s statistical systems (BOP, GFS, and MBS) will provide basic financial data for the estimation of the key capital finance accounts, for SNA purposes these systems need to be harmonized. But the issue is a difficult one because of the independent life of these systems within the Fund. The compromise position is to provide for reconciliation among the systems. If harmonization fails, reconciliation should be made an urgent priority. In pursuing harmonization we suggest concentrating first on sector articulation and second on a uniform definition of the sector deficit/surplus.

We also considered the relations among flows, balances, and valuation changes. In estimating flows from balances in order to derive capital finance accounts the difficulties posed by valuation changes involve only the estimates for (1) corporate equity securities, (2) long-term bonds, and (3) foreign assets (including gold). And in practical terms, especially for developing countries, these difficulties do not appear to be great.

A simple but analytically effective form of the flow-of-funds system can now be implemented quickly and easily even by most developing countries. To demonstrate this statistical feasibility, we described the process by which these accounts can be derived. In doing so we were able to see the developmental or evolutionary path of such implementation, the movement of the estimates from the simplest loose matrix toward a tighter more detailed formulation.

A number of elements in our analysis have suggested that the new SNA design should take an evolutionary view of the development of national accounts. We saw evidence that much of SNA 1968 has not been implemented by most countries, and indications that SNA 1968 is too complex to be a feasible next step in statistical development for many countries. And we have just noted that the actual process of flow-of-funds estimation necessarily has an evolutionary character. We conclude that the new SNA might wish to present both simpler and more complex standard systems, a sequence that would provide developing countries with a useful immediate system and at the same time provide guidance in achieving the full SNA system.

Appendix I

A System of National Accounts and Supporting Tables

article image
Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1953 (page 18).

A Standard Accounting Structure

article image
Note: An asterisk denotes “part of” item listed. Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1953 (page 19).

Appendix II: ANNEX 8.2 The standard accounts

article image
article image
article image
Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 152).
article image
Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 153).
article image
Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 152).
Table 8.3.

Consolidation of Accounts II or III to Accounts I

(in the case of the II Accounts, “A” or “C” preceding the summation sign and “n” following it indicate summation over all the accounts of each of the two classes of II Accounts. In the case of the III Accounts, “N” following the summations sign means summation over all the accounts in which the given transaction appears; and “n” at the end of the expression means summation over all categories of the given class of transactions.)

article image
Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 154).
article image
Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 155).

Notes To The Accounts I And Table 8.3

Indirect taxes and subsidies

8.91. In certain instances an international body may receive indirect taxes from, or pay subsidies to, the industries of a country directly. In order to keep national income valued to include net indirect taxes equal to the sum of the gross domestic product less consumption of fixed capita! plus net factor income received from abroad, it is desirable to route these flows to the international body (the rest of the world) through the general government sector of the country. The flows in question are then to be classed first as indirect taxes received (item 3.3.4), and subsidies paid, (item 3.3.5) by the general government sector and second as the sector's current transfers n.e.c. to, and from, the rest of the world (items 6.9.2. and 6.10.2 in Account III C 3). In the case of the consolidated accounts of the nation, these current transfers are to be covered in item 3.6.23 in Account 3 and items 6.6.22 and 6.6.21 in Account 6. If the alternative of routing the flows in question directly to the rest of the world were to be adopted, the transactions would of course be shown as indirect taxes and subsidies (items 6.3.4 and 6.3.5, respectively) in Account 16. In this case items 6.3.4 plus 3.3.4 would be equal to item 1.3.4; and items 6.3.5 plus 3.3.5 would be equal to item 1.3.5.

II. Production consumption expenditure and capital formation accounts

article image
Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 156).
article image
Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 157).
article image

Notes To The Accounts II

Classification of Accounts II A and C

8.92. The number of categories of industries and their characteristic products used in Accounts II A and C should be limited. For international purposes the categories should be kept to the minimum number that is required for purposes of annual summary data on the sources of demand for broad classes of commodities. The minimum list suggested is: (i) agriculture, hunting, forestry and fishing, (ii) mining and quarrying, manufacturing and electricity, gas and water, (iii) construction, (iv) wholesale and retail trade, restaurants and hotels, (v) transport, storage and communication and (vi) services. It may be desirable to separate mining and quarrying from other industrial activities because of the important role of this activity in the case of a number of developing countries.

Valuation

8.93. Commodities are to be valued at producers’ values in the Accounts II. As is indicated earlier in this report, this mode of valuation enhances the analytical values of the data for such purposes as correlating the supply of. and demand for, commodities. Decomposing in Accounts II A, the purchasers’ value of commodities disposed of to the various categories of demand into producers’ values and distributive trade and transport margins is most practicable when the commodity-flow approach is used in estimating these series.

8.94. When, however, estimates of the dispositions of commodities are mainly based on statistics in respect of the various categories of demand, it is most practicable to use purchasers’ valuation only. The use of purchasers’ values is appropriate for purposes of studying the experience and behaviour of purchasers and co-ordinates the data in Accounts IIA directly with the series on final consumption expenditure in tables 4, 5 and 6 and the data on gross capital formation in table 7. If purchasers’ value only were to be used in these accounts, distributive trade and transport margins would be shown as debits in each Account II A, rather than entirely in Account II A on distributive-trade and transport services. As is indicated in chapter IV, the Accounts II A will then differ from the structure of the corresponding part of the system.

Memorandum item in respect of consumption of fixed capital

8.95. In the case of Accounts II C, D and E, which concern the production and cost-structure of industries and the producers of government and private non-profit services, it will be valuable to add memoranda items to the accounts in respect of the figures of the consumption of fixed capital recorded in the books of the producers. These figures will in general differ from the estimates of the consumption of fixed capital which should be used in the national accounts. The character of these differences is of interest in analysing data on the operating surplus of industries and the cost-composition of government and private non-profit services and purposes.

Treatment of producers of private non-profit services in certain circumstances

8.96. Some countries may find it necessary to combine private non-profit bodies serving households with households during the early stage of introducing the new system. They may not have data on the intermediate consumption, sales to household, and other aspects of the production of private non-profit services. The modifications which it may then be necessary to make in Accounts II A, B and E might be as follows.

(a) A Accounts: Combine entries 1.2.3 “Intermediate consumption, producers of private non-profit services to households” and 2.2.4 “Final consumption expenditure in the domestic market, households”; and disregard entry 1.1.3 “Commodities from producers of private non-profit services to households”;

(b) B Accounts: Consolidate the transactions of the private non-profit services and households in respect of the output and disposition of services and goods. Thus, omit entry 1.1.6 “Non-commodity sales of producers of private non-profit services to households” from Account II B a but add a debit entry in respect of the total value of the primary inputs of producers of private non-profit services. Account II B c is to be eliminated and Account II B d is to show private final consumption expenditure;

(c) E and F Accounts: Combine the two accounts; and give the primary inputs of the producers of private non-profit services as their cost-structure and output. Limit the cost structure and output to the primary inputs of the private non-profit institutions; in other words, omit entries 1.2.3 “Intermediate consumption”, 1.1.6 “Non-commodity sales” and 1.1.3 “Commodities produced”.

8.97. In any case, fraternal, sport, neighbourhood, etc. clubs which engage the equivalent of less than two full-time employees are to be included among households. Any data which may be available concerning their activities should be dealt with in the accounts as is indicated above.

III. Income and outlay and capital finance accounts

A. Non-Financial Enterprises, Corporate And Quasi-Corporate

Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 159).

B. Financial Institutions

Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 160).

C. General Government

Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 161).

D. Private Non-Profit Institutions Serving Households

Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (page 162).

E. Households, Including Private Unincorporated Non-Financial Enterprises

Source: The Standard Accounts, SNA 1968 (pager 163).
d56967290e9599
d56967290e9599
d56967290e9599
d56967290e9599
d56967290e9599

Appendix III

Table 24.

Financial transactions of the detailed sub-sectors

article image
article image
Source: Table 24, SNA 1968 (page 200).

Privately owned and/or controlled.

Publicly owned and/or controlled.

The sub-division of the categories of claims according to sector of debtor relates to transactions in respect of all types of financial assets. The aub-dlvlslon of the categories of claims according to sector of creditor relates to transactions In currency and transferable deposits, other deposits and snort-term and long-tern loans only.

The definitions of international reserves and of offsets to these reserves are those of the International Monetary Fund and the collection Internationally of these data is the responsibility of the fund.

References

  • United Nations, A System of National Accounts and Supporting Tables, Studies in Methods, Series F, No. 2 (New York, 1953).

  • United Nations, A System of National Accounts, Studies in Methods, Series F, No. 2, Rev. 3 (New York, 1968).

  • United Nations, National Accounts Statistics, Studies in Methods, (New York, annual).

  • United Nations, Provisional International Guidelines on the National and Sectoral Balance-Sheet and Reconciliation Accounts of the System of National Accounts, Statistical Papers, Series M, No. 60 (New York, 1977).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
*

A background paper for the Expert Group Meeting on Financial Flows and Balances, September 6-15, 1988, Washington, D.C. The author, Professor of Economics, Grinnell College, Grinnell, Iowa, is grateful for helpful comments by Michael Brimble, Vicente Galbis, and Kevin O’Connor on an earlier draft. This paper is scheduled for publication in a forthcoming book of essays on the Fund’s statistical systems and the revision of the SNA by the Fund.

1/

Rest-of-world saving, lending, and borrowing could easily be shown separately in another variant.

2/

United Nations Statistical Office, A System of National Accounts and Supporting Tables, Studies in Methods, Series F, No. 2 (New York, 1953).

3/

United Nations Statistical Office, A System of National Accounts, Studies in Methods, Series F, No. 2, Rev. 3 (New York, 1968).

4/

Ibid., 14. Paragraph 285, points out that “no further classification of these [net changes in financial assets and liabilities] flows is undertaken in the system since, to produce meaningful results this would require a greater number of sectors including, in particular, a separate sector for banks and other financial intermediaries.”

5/

Private nonprofit institutions serving households need not be a separate sector in the standard accounts.

6/

When social accountants try too hard for conceptual neatness, complexity is sometimes the result.

7/

United Nations, National Accounts Statistics, (New York, annual).

8/

We comment below on the necessity for the balance of payments data to be in the local currency.

9/

The allocation is straightforward except for Category 1. Foreign assets consist of all rest-of-world liabilities held by domestic sectors as financial assets. However, in the cases of the central bank and the commercial banks, it is somewhat customary to assign to this category (by netting against their foreign assets) certain of their short-term deposit liabilities held by the rest-of-world. In this way, the foreign asset holdings of these two banking sectors become net foreign exchange—the balances used to effect international transactions.

10/

To simplify this discussion we neglect here the subclasses indicating sectors holding the particular claim.

11/

We would propose as a simplification not to have separate income/outlay accounts for nonfinancial enterprises or financial institutions. The latter is analytically insignificant and the former greatly overlaps in content the gross product and income account. In effect, these two income/outlay accounts could be merged with the larger account without loss of analytical power.

12/

Technical readers will be aware that for multiple exchange rate countries the conversion of the account from local currency to dollars or vice versa cannot be satisfactorily done with the use of a single conversion ratio.

13/

We here neglect the minor items: purchases of land, net; purchases of intangible assets n.e.c., net; and capital transfers, net.

14/

United Nations, Provisional International Guidelines on the National and Sectoral Balance-Sheet and Reconciliation Accounts of the System of National Accounts, Statistical Papers, Series M No. 60 (New York, 1977).

15/

The reconciliation entries will also include some non-revaluation elements, such as changes that are due to asset items not included in the capital finance accounts and statistical discrepancies and discontinuities.

16/

In principle we may also find revaluations that are due to exchange rate response in the case of debts held by foreigners, but such cases seem uncommon.

17/

We may note that the chapter in SNA 1968 devoted to developing countries was devoted to how the full system, presumably once that system was achieved, could be adapted to the development situation.

18/

We urge use of this format not only for countries with the least developed statistical systems but also as the starting flow-of-funds format for countries at a more advanced statistical stage.

19/

These lines for the banking sectors may be assumed zero as a first approximation.

20/

Other technical problems may involve the removal of internal transaction entries and the adjustment of accrual items.

21/

We assume here that the figures for the balance of payments current account surplus from the balance of payments data and the rest-of-world saving from NIP data are equal, apart from sign reversal.

22/

The issue here is not affected by whether the gain or loss is realized but, rather, whether balance sheet valuations reflect them, realized or not. The sale of a financial asset that realizes and records a gain should be viewed as a book revaluation followed by a transaction.

23/

We assume here that the commercial banks’ long-term bond holdings are small.

24/

The major origins of discrepancies may be listed as differences in (1) sector coverage, (2) transaction classification, (3) basis of valuation, (4) timing of recording, and (5) degree of netting or of consolidation.

25/

Gross saving can be approximated by the sum of retained profit plus the depreciation charge from the income statement. Gross capital formation can be approximated by the increment in gross fixed assets.

26/

The other domestic sector also still includes local government and the government enterprises and nonbank financial institutions lying outside their respective samples.

27/

Far off on the horizon the question might arise of whether to split a noncorporate business sector away from a remaining household sector, as is done in some full flow-of-funds systems. Even assuming that data are available, such a split would be highly arbitrary in the institutional context of most countries. It would seem wisest for SNA 1990 to leave noncorporate business sectored within households except for the quasi- corporate portion.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
The Flow-of-Funds Accounts, the United Nations' System of National Accounts, and the Developing Countries
Author:
International Monetary Fund