A Model of Adjustment and Growth
An Empirical Analysis
Author:
International Monetary Fund
Search for other papers by International Monetary Fund in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

This paper develops a model merging the monetary approach to the balance of payments and a neoclassical growth model into a unified framework in which inflation, growth, and the balance of payments are simultaneously determined. The empirical part of the paper presents estimates of the key parameters of the model for a sample of seven diverse developing countries and tests the validity of a subset of the theoretical assumptions. The estimated model is then used for a variety of comparative static exercises, including the effects of fiscal and monetary policy changes, and devaluation.

Abstract

This paper develops a model merging the monetary approach to the balance of payments and a neoclassical growth model into a unified framework in which inflation, growth, and the balance of payments are simultaneously determined. The empirical part of the paper presents estimates of the key parameters of the model for a sample of seven diverse developing countries and tests the validity of a subset of the theoretical assumptions. The estimated model is then used for a variety of comparative static exercises, including the effects of fiscal and monetary policy changes, and devaluation.

I. Introduction

The concept of “growth-oriented adjustment”, or the notion that economic growth is essential for the achievement of the twin goals of a sustained reduction in inflation and a viable balance of payments, has recently received the attention of policymakers and academics alike. Indeed, growth-oriented adjustment is considered a key characteristic of the policy packages that make up Fund-supported programs. Examples of the blossoming literature on the subject of growth-oriented adjustment can be found in Corbo, Goldstein, and Khan (1987). 1/

Any analysis of the effects of policies on the multiple targets of growth, inflation, and the balance of payments requires a consistent and unified framework. Further, because this issue is particularly relevant for developing countries, it is desirable that this framework be sufficiently simple so as to allow its application to countries in which data availability is limited, and at the same time be general enough to ensure its applicability to a diverse set of countries. The model developed by Khan and Montiel (1988), which merges a variant of a neoclassical growth model with the monetary approach to the balance of payments, is one example of such an integrated framework. 2/

While simplicity makes a model more tractable from an operational standpoint, it nonetheless has several drawbacks due to the necessarily restrictive assumptions it employs. This paper assesses the usefulness of this model for policymaking by examining empirically the tradeoff between its simplifying assumptions and its ability to fit reality. This tradeoff can be assessed by applying the model to a variety of countries. For each country considered it is possible to ask the following questions: (a) Are the key parameters of the model stable? (b) How sensitive are the policy multipliers to these parameter estimates —that is, how robust are the policy implications? and (c) Are some target variables more vulnerable to forecast errors than others?

This paper examines these questions for a diverse sample of seven capital-importing developing countries and, in doing so, attempts to reach some conclusions about the usefulness of the model to help in designing policy. The countries considered here are: Burma, Chile, Ghana, Honduras, Korea, Pakistan, and Tanzania. The sample thus includes low- and middle-income countries, manufacturing- and primary-exporters, as well as service and remittance countries, and one heavily-indebted country. This diversity makes the sample reasonably representative of developing countries in general.

The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows: Section II provides a brief outline of the theoretical framework and examines its properties. The estimates of the key parameters of the model are described in Section III and the stability of a subset of these parameters is tested. Special attention is given to the adequacy of the model’s specification of output determination, the demand for money, and private savings behavior. Section IV contains some comparative static exercises dealing with a variety of exogenous and policy-induced shocks, given the estimated parameter values. The shocks that are considered are at the center of most adjustment programs: devaluation, changes in domestic credit, and changes in government spending. 3/ This section concludes with an analysis of the “robustness” of the policy implications of the model under varying parameter values. The final section reviews the key results, discusses the limitations of the approach followed in this paper, and highlights some of the directions in which the theoretical and empirical work could be extended.

II. Summary of the Theoretical Framework

1. The key relationships

The model outlined in this section, which follows Khan and Montiel (1988), will serve as a benchmark for the subsequent empirical application. The model merges a growth block similar to that employed by the World Bank 4/ and a monetary block that is central to the monetary approach to the balance of payments associated with Fund-supported adjustment programs. 5/

The framework describes a small open economy, representative of a developing country, that maintains a fixed exchange rate. Equations (1) through (7) define the basic identities of the model, as well as the budget constraints for the private and public sectors. The private budget constraint:

( 1 ) Y t T t C t S p t 0 ;

The allocation of private savings:

( 2 ) S p t P D t d k t + d M t d d D p t ;

The government budget constraint:

( 3 ) e t d F t + d D g t G t + i t e t F t T t T B t ;

The sources of changes in the money stock:

( 4 ) d M S t e t 1 d R t + d D t ;

The composition of changes in domestic credit:

( 5 ) d D t = d D g t + d D p t ;

Interest earnings on foreign reserves transferred to the government:

( 6 ) T B t = i t e t R t ; and

Gross national product:

( 7 ) Y t = Y t i t e t ( F t R t ) .

In order of appearance, the variables are defined as:

article image
article image

The “d’s” denote changes from time t-1 to time t, i.e., dxt=xt-xt-1.

The centerpiece of the growth block of the model is a neoclassical production function. Capacity, or potential growth, depends on increases in total factor productivity, changes in the size of the labor force, and in the capital stock. Combining technologically-driven productivity changes and changes in labor supply into one exogenous variable 6/, the production function takes the following form:

( 8 ) d y t = α 0 + α 1 d k t

where the lower case letters denote real magnitudes. The coefficient of investment, α1, is the marginal product of capital, and the constant term, α0, denotes the combined effects total factor productivity and the change in the size of the labor force. This production function specification is a more generalized version of the “incremental capital output relationship” (ICOR). 7/

The second behavioral relationship in the growth block describes private savings. It is assumed that real private savings is proportional to real disposable income:

( 9 ) S p t = S ( y t ) t ; 0 < S < 1

where s is a constant representing both the marginal and average savings rate.

The third building block of the growth model links savings identically to investment. Substituting the definition of the money stock, the government’s budget constraint, and the savings function into (2), we obtain the following expression for the change in the capital stock:

( 10 ) d k t = s ( y t ) t + [ t t g t ie ( F R P D t ) ] + e ( d F-dR P D t ) t

where the first term represents real private savings, the second real public saving, and the third is the real current account deficit (real foreign savings).

Since yt = yt-1 + dyt, and PDt = PDt-1 + dPDt, we can express capacity growth as a function of domestic prices, reserves, and the exogenous variables and parameters:

( 11 ) d y t = ( 1 s α 1 ) 1 { α 0 + α 1 [ s ( y t 1 t t ) + ( t g ) t + e ( d F d R i [ F R ] ) t P D t 1 + d P D t ] }

The monetary block is also defined by three relationships 8/ starting with the flow supply of money:

( 4 ) d M S t = e t 1 d R t + d D t

The second relationship is the flow demand for money, here simplified by the assumption that velocity is constant: 9/

( 12 ) d M d t = ν P t d y t + ν y t 1 d P t

where P is the aggregate price level, defined below, and ν is the inverse of the income velocity of money.

The last relationship in the monetary block determines money market equilibrium:

( 13 ) d M d t = d M S t

Defining the change in the aggregate price level, dPt, as a weighted average of the change in the price of importables, dPzt, and the change in the price of domestic output, dPDt, with weights θ and (1-θ), respectively, we can write:

( 14 ) d P t = θ d P z t + ( 1 θ ) d P D t

Assuming that θ and the foreign-currency price of importables are constant, initial conditions are set so that, e0 = Pz0 = PD0 = 1 and that the law of one price holds, we obtain:

( 15 ) d P z t = P D * d e t t = d e t .

Using (14), (15), and the definitions of flow money demand and supply, and substituting these back into the money market equilibrium condition (equation (13)), we arrive at an expression for the change in domestic prices as a function of output, reserves, the exogenous variables, and the parameters of the system:

( 16 ) d P D t = { ν ( 1 θ ) [ y t 1 + d y t ] } 1 { d R t ν d y t ν θ y t 1 d e t ν θ d e t d y t + d D t } .

2. The merged model

Combining the growth block, equation (10), with the monetary block, equation (16), does not close the system, as we have two equations in three unknowns, dyt, dPDt, and dRt. The additional relationship that enables this system to be fully determined is the balance of payments identity:

( 17 ) d R t = X t Z t i ( F-R ) t + d F t ,

where Xt and Zt are the foreign currency value of exports and imports. Defining the trade balance in foreign currency terms, Bt = Zt - Xt, it is assumed that:

( 18 ) B t = B 0 a ( e t / P D t 1 ) + b d y t

where a and b are positive constants; B0 is constant whose sign is undetermined. Equation (18) implies that the trade balance improves in foreign currency terms when the real exchange rate depreciates (e/PD>1) or when real output falls. 10/ Recalling that Ft = Ft-1 + dFt and, similarly for Rt, equations (17) and (18) yield an expression for the change in reserves:

( 19 ) d R t = ( d F t B 0 ) + a ( e t / P D t 1 ) b d y t i ( F t 1 R t 1 ) ,

where a=a/(1-i), b=b/(1-i), i=i/(1-i), and B0=B0/(1-i).

Having obtained an expression for reserves, equation (19), the system can be solved in terms of equation (10), which summarizes the growth block, and equation (16), which summarizes the monetary block.

From the substitution of (19) into (10) we obtain:

( 20 ) d y t = [ 1 s α 1 α 1 b e t / P D t ] 1 { α 0 + α 1 { s ( y t 1 t t ) + ( t g ) t + e t P D t [ B 0 a ( e t / P D t 1 ) ] } } .

Graphically, the growth block traces out the locus in Figure 1 that has been labelled GG. Its slope evaluated at dyt = dPDt = 0 is:

( d P D ) ( d y ) | G G = β / α 1 η
Figure 1
Figure 1

Macroeconomic Equilibrium

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1989, 032; 10.5089/9781451979572.001.A001

where,

η = B0 - a

and

β = 1 - α1(S + b) > 0

If η is negative, the GG schedule is upwardly-sloped as depicted in Figure 1.

Similarly, substituting out reserves in the equation representing the monetary block, equation (16), we obtain:

( 21 ) d P D t = { ν ( 1 θ ) ( y t 1 + d y t ) } 1 { [ d F t B 0 i ( F t 1 R t 1 ) + d D t ] } ( b + ν ) d y t ν θ y t 1 d e t ν θ d e t d y t + a ( e t / P D t 1 ) } .

Equation (21) traces out a negatively-sloped locus, labelled MM in Figure 1. The slope at dyt = dPDt = 0 is given by:

( dP D ) ( dy ) | MM = ( b + ν ) / γ < 0 ,

where γ = a + ν(1-θ)y0 > 0.

The intersection of the GG and MM schedules in Figure 1 depicts the equilibrium values of output changes and domestic inflation.

3. Parameters to be estimated

The model outlined above is applied to a sample of seven countries. Table 1 lists the parameters that must be estimated in order to make it operational.

Table 1.

Parameters of the System

article image

III. Estimating the Parameters of the System and Testing the Underlying Assumptions

1. General comments

To test the empirical validity of the model outlined in the previous section, we proceed to apply the model to a set of seven diverse developing countries. The list of developing countries included in the sample, and the time period relevant for each., are: Burma (1969-87), Chile (1976-87), Ghana (1969-87), Honduras (1969-87), Korea (1969-87), Pakistan (1976-87), and Tanzania (1969-87).

The common approach to evaluating a model’s empirical performance involves a two-step process: the first step is the estimation of the model as a system; the second step uses the estimated system to generate either in-sample forecasts, out-of-sample forecasts, or possibly both; and the final judgement on the model’s performance is based on a comparison between the “fitted” values and the actual values—the forecast errors.

One problem with the above approach is that it generally provides little or no direct information about what particular assumptions of the model are inappropriate, or what equations were misspecified. The approach followed here, although similar to the one outlined above, varies in some important ways. The first step still involves obtaining estimates for the seven parameters that characterize the system. However, this was accomplished by estimating each behavioral equation separately using either ordinary least squares (OLS) or generalized least squares (GLS), as dictated by the data. The individual equation approach was preferred over the alternative approach—estimating the model as a system—as it allowed more efficient use of limited data availability, particularly in the cases where the available time series for the same country had uneven starting points. The sample period covered by the empirical work for the individual equations was the maximum allowed by the availability of the data.

To assess not just the general fit of the model, but to be able to pinpoint where the specification weaknesses lie, another intermediate step was added to the evaluation process—the validity of a subset of the individual theoretical assumptions was tested. Particular attention was devoted to the specification of output growth, savings behavior, and money demand, as it is the parameters in these equations that are central to the analysis.

Finally, since the model was not estimated as system, and because we wanted to highlight the effects of certain policies, the methodology adopted in this paper does not involve a direct comparison of the actual and fitted values of the endogenous variables. Instead, the estimated parameter values are used to construct reduced form policy multipliers for each of the endogenous variables. The range of values these multipliers take, as the parameter values are allowed to vary, provide useful information on the “robustness” of the model’s policy implications. With the exception of the production function, which includes a proxy for the labor force, the subsequent empirical work includes as explanatory variables only those variables dictated by the theoretical model. However, in general, the specifications of the estimation equations did allow these explanatory variables to appear with a richer lag structure than that suggested by the theoretical model. In each case the data determined the relevant lag pattern for the explanatory variables. The specific details for each equation and for each country are outlined in the remainder of this section.

2. How well can a production function explain output growth?

To obtain estimates for the marginal product of capital, α1, and the combined effects of changes in the size of the labor and total factor productivity, α0, we began by estimating a simple growth model that is derived from an aggregate neoclassical production function. As in Robinson (1971), IMF (1988), and Khan and Reinhart (1989), the growth function estimated takes the form:

( 8 a ) D y t = α 0 + α 1 ( d k t / y t 1 ) + α 2 D L t

where the upper case Ds indicate rates of change and L denotes the labor force, here proxied by population. Because the data was allowed to determine the lag pattern for the investment-output ratio, the particular form that (8a) assumed for each country is presented in Appendix II. The estimates presented in Table 3 were obtained by applying OLS to an equation such as (8a) and imposing constant returns to scale, so that α2=(1-α1).

Table 2.

Production Functions: How Well Can These Explain Output Growth?

article image

The investment-output ratio has been de-trended.

Table 3.

The Savings Rate 1/

article image

The sample period is 1963-86, except for Chile in which a 1973-86 sample is used.

This exercise has a twofold purpose: first, it yields the relevant parameter estimates; second, it serves as a “test” of the usefulness of an aggregate production function in explaining actual output growth. As Table 2 highlights, the estimates for the marginal product of capital are reasonable in sign and magnitude across countries, averaging about 0.29 11/ (these are the parameter values that will be used in the subsequent comparative static exercises). Unfortunately, however, a neoclassical production function does not explain much of the variation in actual output. One possible explanation for the large proportion of output variation that remains unexplained is that, in effect, the specification traces out a production possibility frontier—in reality, a significant number of countries, particularly developing countries, are not operating at full capacity. As such, a host of macro- and microeconomic factors, not embodied in the production function, can push actual output growth towards or away from its potential. While this variation of the ICOR meets the criteria of simplicity, which makes it applicable even in countries with limited data availability, it has the considerable drawback of being unstable over time. Projections of output growth based on variants of a production function are routinely subject to large and variable errors and, yet, a neoclassical production function is one the key relationships of the “growth block” of the theoretical framework.

Given the empirical inadequacy of the “full capacity” assumption, one possible route for future research would be to incorporate the existence of persistent excess capacity (present in varying degrees in most developing countries). By so doing, the theoretical model would allow domestic and foreign “demand” variables to play a greater role in output determination. Empirically, this extension should help reduce the share of output fluctuations that remains unexplained.

3. Savings behavior—Is the savings rate constant?

The second behavioral relationship in the model’s growth block is the specification of the personal savings rate. The theoretical model assumes that real private savings is proportional to real disposable income. Variables that proxy the private sector’s rate of time preference are not included in this specification. Similarly, other scale variables, such as wealth, are also omitted. 12/

The presence of negative levels of private savings for some of the countries in the sample for a subset of the years in which the data is available ruled out estimating a log linear savings function. Furthermore, the problem of hetereoskedastic errors makes the use of levels inappropriate.

Equation (9), however, implies that the marginal and average savings rates are equal. We proceed to use the average private savings rate, reported in Table 3, as our measure of s. 13/ While this average provides numerical values for the savings parameter, it says nothing about the adequacy of assuming a constant stable savings rate. To assess the properties of savings behavior, in particular its stability, given the aforementioned obstacles, we focused on consumption behavior. Table 4 reports the results of an equation of the form:

( 21 ) D c t = c 0 + c 1 D ( y t ) t

where c represents real private consumption, c0 is a constant term, c1 is the average propensity to consume, and the D’s indicate rates of change. The results of (21) were used to test the assumption of a constant savings rate. If the savings rate is constant, then the null hypothesis of c0 = 0 and c1 = 1 should hold in the data. In other words, to maintain the savings rate constant, income and consumption would have to increase at equal rates. This test of stability was preferred over the more traditional approaches, such as the Chow test, because in many instances splitting the sample was not advisable, given the limited number of observations available.

Table 4.

Velocity Behavior

article image

The results of an F-test comparing the residuals of the unconstrained, (21), and constrained equations indicate that only in one out of the seven countries in the sample was the savings rate found to be variable, making the assumption of a constant and stable savings rate reasonable for most instances. In effect, the constrained equation imposes the condition that the savings rate is stable while the unconstrained does not. If the savings rate is indeed unstable, then imposing the constraints would generate large errors relative to the errors of an unconstrained specification and this would be apparent in the F-tests that compare the two versions of (21). The drawback of this test is that, even if the savings rate is found to be unstable, as in the case of Honduras, this result could stem from misspecification—in particular the omission of the real rate of interest, not from behavioral instability. If the interest rate belongs in the savings function, as several studies would suggest, 14/ then the constant term in a specification such as (21) could simply be picking up the systematic influence of the omitted variable.

4. Money demand—Is velocity constant?

Having obtained estimates for the three parameters that describe the “growth block” of the model and having evaluated the relative merits of the assumptions that underscore that portion of the merged model, we proceed to do the same for the monetary sector. The key behavioral relationship is the specification of money demand. As equation (14) indicates, it is assumed that opportunity cost variables do not affect the demand for money, hence the income velocity of money is taken to be a constant. 15/

As with the savings parameter, the historical averages of the ratio of money to income are used to approximate ν, the inverse of the income velocity of money. These averages for both narrow and broad definitions of money are reported in Table 4.

To “test” the validity of the constant velocity assumption, we begin with a generalized version of (14) which: (a) includes a constant term, (which under the null hypothesis of constant velocity should be insignificantly different from zero); and (b) does not restrict the coefficients of output and prices to be identical, allowing for the presence of economies of scale in cash balances. This generalized specification is equation (14a),

( 14 a ) D M t = d 0 + d 1 D y t + d 2 D P t

where d0 is a constant term that represents D(1/ν), the rate of change in income velocity. This equation was estimated over the seven countries in the sample (using both narrow and broad definitions of money) with and without imposing the restriction that d1=d2. The results are presented in Table 5. At one end are Korea and Chile with an insignificant constant term in all specifications indicating that our null of no change in velocity cannot be rejected. At the other end of the spectrum, for Ghana and Pakistan all specifications indicate that velocity is not constant. More generally, it appears that it easier to reject the null hypothesis of constant velocity for broad definitions of money (five out of seven countries) than for narrowly defined money (only two out of seven). 16/ The almost uniform poor fit of (14a) is another indication of the variability of velocity changes since, in the cases where the rate of change in velocity is constant, (14a) would be an identity.

Table 5.

Approximating the Weight of Import Prices In the Aggregate Price Level

article image

As with the savings rate these results must be interpreted with care. The above results do not imply widespread instability in the demand for money, but rather suggests that a specification such as (14) is likely to be too restrictive. In particular, it seems reasonable to expect that a developing country, becoming increasingly monetized over time, would show secular changes in the income velocity of money. The significance of the constant term in many of the specifications presented in Table 5 may well arise from these institutional changes as well as from omission of other explanatory variables such as the nominal interest rate, inflationary expectations, and exchange rate changes. However, the results do indicate that future extensions to the theoretical and empirical work should include more comprehensive specifications of money demand. In summary, the assumption of constant velocity, like the assumption of fully employed resources in the growth block, appears to be a weak link in the unified model.

The remaining parameter in the monetary component of the model is θ, the weight of import prices in the general price level. This parameter was approximated by average share of imports in total (public plus private) consumption and is reported in Table 5.

5. The trade balance

Two external-sector relationships close the system: the balance of payments identity, equation (17), and the trade balance responses to output and real exchange rate changes, equation (18). These two remaining parameters (in the trade balance equation) to be estimated link the “real” and “monetary” sectors. The remainder of this section outlines how estimates for the parameters a and b were obtained. Because the trade balance changes in sign across countries and across time, a log-linear version of (18) cannot be estimated. Also to avoid the problem of hetereoskedastic errors, the use of levels was deemed inappropriate. Instead, the trade balance was decomposed into its components—exports and imports. The relative price and income elasticities of import demand and export supplies were estimated using some variant of:

( 22 ) log ( z t ) = δ 0 + δ 1 log ( y t ) + δ 2 log ( P z t / P D t )

for imports; and

( 23 ) log ( x t ) = ϵ 0 + ϵ 1 log ( y f t ) + ϵ 2 log ( P x t / P D t ) 1 /

for exports. In the export demand function, yf denotes real GDP of the industrial countries. The specific form equations (22) and (23) assumes for each country varies according to the lag pattern the data reveals. These details are relegated to Appendix II.

Proxies for a and b were constructed by weighting the “disaggregated” parameter estimates (obtained by applying GLS to the above equations) by the sample period averages of imports and exports, respectively. The results of the estimation of import demand and export supply as well as the derivation of the relevant weights are reported in Appendix II, while the “weighted” estimates for a and b are reported in Table 6. In all seven countries, the real exchange rate elasticity, -a, has the correct sign (negative), and in all cases, an increase in domestic income worsened the trade balance—i.e., b is positive.

Table 6.

The External Sector Parameters

article image

To make the weighted elasticities comparable across countries these were scaled by the size of the external sector, here measured as the sum of average imports and exports (see Appendix).

Having obtained estimates for all the parameters that characterize the theoretical model and highlighted the weaknesses of some of the key assumptions, we proceed to evaluate the policy implications of the model and assess the robustness of those implications.

IV. Comparative Statics and Sensitivity Analysis

1. Summary of findings in the cross-country comparisons

Parametrizing the model is useful in comparing it’s ability to fit diverse circumstances, but is only an intermediate step in evaluating the model’s usefulness for policymaking. The purpose of this section is to construct the policy multipliers associated with the estimated parameter values and address two related issues. First, we examine the sensitivity of these multipliers to varying parameter values—the policy robustness question; second, we assess the relative precision of the forecasts for the target variables.

Table 7 summarizes the point estimates of the parameters of interest, and it is these values that generate the “core” set of policy multipliers. However, as Table 8 shows, only limited confidence can be placed on these point estimates since some of the parameters are unstable. Even in the instances in which the hypothesis of stability cannot be rejected, the precision of these point estimates tends to be quite low (i.e., the standard errors tend to be large). This suggests that, for any analytical purposes, a band of parameter values must be considered. The upper and lower bounds of such a band were calculated by respectively adding and subtracting one-half a standard error to the point estimates.

Table 7.

Cross-Country Comparison of the Key Parameters

article image

Uses the broad definition of money, money plus quasi-money.

Table 8.

Testing the Assumptions of the Model

article image

Figure 2 illustrates the configuration of the real and monetary sectors that the averages from our sample suggest. The actual numerical values of the slopes of the GG and MM schedules (and the range defined by the parameter band) are presented in Table 9 for the sample countries. The remainder of this section considers three policy exercises: an increase in domestic credit; an increase in government spending; and a devaluation. Since the model is static, we evaluate the effects of policy by comparing the pre-shock and post-shock steady states—that is, we calculate the relevant policy multipliers.

Figure 2
Figure 2

The Parametrized System

Citation: IMF Working Papers 1989, 032; 10.5089/9781451979572.001.A001

Table 9.

The Graphics of the Empirical Model

article image

In all cases considered, we assess the sensitivity of these multipliers to changing parameter values. The policy implications of the model are said to be robust if the range of values assumed by the multiplier remains narrow despite changes in the parameters. This section concludes with a discussion of the relative predictability of the target variables.

2. An increase in domestic credit

An increase in the rate of domestic credit expansion (here we assume that the increase in credit goes entirely to the private sector) creates a flow excess supply of money on impact. In Figure 2, this shifts the MM schedule upward. At the initial level of output, this induces an increase in the price level which, in turn, increases money demand. However, for a given level of import prices, the domestic price rise also produces a real exchange rate appreciation and a worsening in the current account deficit. The worsening current account is mirrored in an increase in foreign savings and an increase in investment and output growth. Ultimately inflation rises, output growth increases, and the balance of payments worsens. 17/

More formally, the increase in inflation is given by:

( dPD ) ( dD ) = ( Ω γ ) 1 > 0
Ω = 1 α 1 η ( b + ν ) β γ > 0

and as before,

β = 1 α 1 ( s + b ) > 0
η = B 0 a

The change in output growth is:

( dy ) ( dD ) = η α 1 β ( Ω γ ) 1 > 0

and the change in the balance of payments is:

( dy ) ( dD ) = ( b α 1 η a ) β ( Ω γ ) 1 < 0

Using the estimated parameter values and the corresponding parameter bands, the multipliers for the three target variables are reported in Table 10. As an example, in the sample average case, a ten percent increase in the rate of growth of credit increases inflation by about 15 percent (the range is 12 - 19 percent), increases output growth by two percent, and worsens the balance of payments by six percent.

Table 10.

A Ten Percent Increase in Domestic Credit 1/

(Percent)

article image

The upper and lower bounds refer to adding and subtracting (respectively) one-half a standard deviation to the underlying structural parameters—not to the multipliers themselves.

∂(dPD)/∂(dD)

∂(dy)/∂(dD)

∂(dR)/∂(dD)

Note the large discrepancy between the inflation multipliers, which are highly variable in most instances, and the relatively close values for multipliers for growth and the balance of payments. This suggests that the usefulness of the model, and/or the desirability of using credit as a policy instrument, will depend, to a large degree, on the form of the policymakers’ objective function. If the primary objective of policy is to meet an inflation “target”, then this framework of analysis, given the underlying parameter values, may not be the best to employ. If on the other hand the primary policy objective is a balance of payments or growth target the model is more useful.

3. An increase in government spending

An increase in government spending, maintaining taxes and the rate of change in domestic credit at initial levels, shifts the GG schedule in Figure 2 to the left. The rise in fiscal spending translates into a higher deficit and, therefore, less public savings. The decline in savings reduces capital accumulation and output growth. As output growth falls, reducing the flow demand for money and creating an excess supply, inflation must rise to ensure the money market clears. With output falling and prices rising, the impact of the fiscal expansion on the balance of payments is theoretically ambiguous and must be determined by the data. The effects of a change in real government spending on inflation growth and the balance of payments are listed below while Table 11 summarizes the relevant set of policy multipliers.

Table 11.

A Ten Percent Increase in Government Spending 1/

(Percent)

article image

The upper and lower bounds refer to adding and subtracting (respectively) one-half a standard deviation to the underlying structural parameters—not to the multipliers themselves.

∂(dPD)/∂(g)

∂(dy)/∂(g)

∂(dR)/∂(g)

( dP D ) g = Ω 1 α 1 ( b + ν ) β γ > 0 ,
( dy ) g = Ω 1 α 1 / β < 0 ,

and

( dy ) g = α 1 β Ω 1 [ b a ( b + ν ) γ ] > < 0

Once again the fiscal multipliers for output and the balance of payments are bounded by a fairly narrow range. In the case of a change in credit—a monetary shock—the bulk of the adjustment fell on the nominal variable (inflation) with output growth and the balance of payments remaining relatively unaffected. This result is not surprising, given the very steep GG schedules that the estimated parameter values trace out. What is more surprising is that a change in government spending—a real shock, also has a greater impact (and more variable) on inflation than on the real variables. It was also found that for all seven countries the balance of payments improved after the shock, indicating that the contractionary output effect dominated the relative price effect.

4. Devaluation

A devaluation is both a real and nominal shock, and consequently shifts both schedules in Figure 2. At the initial price of domestic goods, a devaluation increases the aggregate price level via an increase in the price of imports. This increases the flow demand for money. At the same time, the shift in relative prices induces lower consumption of the importable and higher production of the domestic good, leading to an improvement in the balance of payments and an expansion in the flow supply of money. If substitution effects are dominant then the increase in the flow supply of money more than accommodates the rise in demand and the MM schedule shifts to the right—this effect is expansionary. In the “real” sector the foreign component of savings is lower, due to the improvement in the balance of payments, this reduces capital formation shifting the GG schedule to the left—a contractionary effect. As shown in Khan and Montiel (1988), the latter effect dominates and output falls. Table 12 presents numerical multipliers of a devaluation, the partial derivatives are listed below:

( d P D ) ( de ) = ( Ω γ ) 1 [ a ν Y 0 θ α 1 η ( b + ν ) / β ] > 0
Table 12.

A Ten Percent Devaluation 1/

(Percent)

article image

The upper and lower bounds refer to adding and subtracting (respectively) one-half a standard deviation to the underlying structural parameters—not to the multipliers themselves.

∂(dPD)/∂(de)

∂(dy)/∂(de)

∂(dR)/∂(de)

for growth:

( d y ) ( de ) = α 1 η β ( Ω γ ) 1 ν Y 0 < 0

and the balance of payments

( d R ) ( de ) = ( a b α 1 β η ) ( Ω γ ) 1 ν Y 0 > 0

Two general characteristics are worth noting: first, the multipliers of a devaluation are relatively low when compared to those associated with credit and fiscal changes, suggesting it takes large devaluations to impact the target variables in any meaningful way; second, as with monetary and fiscal policy, although not quite as pronounced, the effects of a devaluation on inflation are greater than the output or balance of payments effects, indicating that the desirability of either employing this framework, using devaluation as a policy tool, or both, will depend on the relative importance of the inflation target in the overall objective function of the policymakers.

V. Conclusions

The objective of this paper was to apply to a diverse group of developing countries a model that, in principle is: (a) simple enough to be used operationally in countries where data availability is limited and, (b) comprehensive enough to enable a useful analysis and evaluation of growth-oriented policies to be undertaken.

The first step of this evaluation process was to estimate the model and test its underlying assumptions. The estimated parameter values were in accordance with the theoretical priors, but we identified two weak building blocks in the framework: that output is assumed to expand at a technology- and endowment-determined rate, and, that the income velocity of money is assumed to be constant. The low explanatory power of a neoclassical production function suggests that future extensions to this framework should attempt to incorporate the presence of excess capacity, which characterizes most developing countries. Similarly, the empirical variability in velocity indicates the need for a less restrictive specification of money demand that allows for the secular effects of monetization in developing economies as well as for the impact a variety of opportunity cost variables. Lastly, the model is static and consequently, does not incorporate the possibility of slow adjustment and the role of expectations in the analysis.

The second part of the evaluation process involved using the estimated parameter values to construct reduced form multipliers and analyze the effects of a variety of policy exercises. Here, we found that the robustness of the model’s policy implications depend heavily on two factors.

First, “robustness” depends on which of the target variables are being considered—for output growth and the balance of payments the range for multipliers is narrow, despite sizable variation in parameter values. For inflation, the range of values the policy multipliers assume are quite broad. This suggests that, more likely than not, the forecast errors are bound to be large if this model is employed to forecast the effects of policy changes on inflation. So, in effect, the usefulness of this model for policymaking (given the parameter values) will depend crucially on the policymaker’s objective function. In general, the model is less useful if the primary objective of policy is to meet an inflation target. If on the other hand, the balance of payments or growth are the principal targets, then the projected outcomes suggested by this model are more useful.

Second, the reliability of the policy implications depends on the policy instrument being considered. From the multipliers calculated in the paper, it is evident that effects of a devaluation (on all target variables) are less sensitive to parameter changes than the multipliers of changes in credit or fiscal policies.

While some possible extensions to the theoretical framework have already been mentioned, there are a number of ways in which the empirical work can be enriched. In particular, when maintaining a consistent methodology across countries is not a binding constraint, as it was in this paper, more efficient use can be made of the greater data availability in some countries. This would allow for more rigorous tests of parameter instability. It would also enable the estimation of the model as a system and a more formal assessment of forecasting errors.

In conclusion, the present model is a useful starting point for the design of growth-oriented policies, although its usefulness across countries is by no means uniform. There are countries where none of the theoretical assumptions appear to be adequate—Honduras—and where, consequently, the effects of macroeconomic policies suggested by the model are subject to a large degree of uncertainty. There are countries where the assumptions appear to have greater empirical validity—Korea and Chile—and the policy implications are relatively more robust. In general, this analysis would indicate that a reasonable next step in enhancing the operational usefulness of basic model would be to relax some of the more rigid assumptions, while attempting to keep the added degree of complexity to a minimum.

APPENDIX I: Data Definitions and Sources

a. IMF, International Financial Statistics; and

b. IMF, World Economic Outlook.

The definition of the variables used in the estimations are, in order of appearance:

article image

APPENDIX II: 1. Specification of the Production Function

The specification of (18a) for Tanzania and Honduras took the form of:

( 18 a 1 ) Dy = α 0 * + α 1 ( dk/y 1 ) + ( 1 α 1 ) DL.

For the remaining countries, lagged values of the investment-output ratio were included along the lines outlined below:

( 18 a 2 4 ) Dy = α 0 * + Σ i=0 n α i [ ( dk/y ) i ] + ( 1 Σ i=0 n α i ) DL.

For Burma and Chile; n, the number of lags included equals 1.

For Korea; n=2.

For Ghana and Pakistan; n=3.

2. Import and Export Demand Specifications

The generalized version of the estimated import demand equation is given by:

( 22 ) log ( z ) = δ 0 + δ 1 log ( y ) + δ 2 log [ ( P z / P D ) i ]

For Pakistan, Korea, and Chile; i=0—no lag.

For Honduras; i=1.

For Burma; i=2.

For Tanzania and Ghana; i=3.

The generalized version of the estimated export supply equation is given by:

( 23 ) log ( x ) = ϵ 0 + ϵ 1 log ( yf ) + ϵ 2 log [ ( P x / P D ) i ]

For Honduras and Chile; i=0.

For Ghana and Pakistan; i=1.

For Tanzania, Korea, and Burma; i=2.

Equation (23) also includes a time trend for Tanzania.

3. Deriving the Weights

To construct the price and income elasticities of the trade balance, B, from the estimates obtained by estimating import demand and export demand individually we proceeed as follows:

Since dB = z dz z x dx x , d [ log ( z ) ] = dz z , d [ log ( x ) ] = dx x ,

and recalling that the terms of trade, Px/Pz, is assumed constant in the theoretical model (and equal to one at t=0), we obtain,

dB = z δ 1 dy y x ϵ 1 dy f yf [ z δ 2 + x ϵ 2 ] d ( P z / PD ) ( P z / PD ) .

As usual the estimated elasticities are unit free, however, the relevant weights, z and x, are not. To make these weighted elasticities comparable accross countries the above was divided by the sum of imports and exports, z+x.

dB z+x = z z+x δ 1 dy y x z+x ϵ 1 dy f yf [ z z+x δ 2 + x z+z\x ϵ 2 ] d ( P z / PD ) ( P z / PD ) .
Table A1.

Trade Parameters: Estimation Results

article image

References

  • Balassa, Bela,Exports and Economic Growth: Further Evidence,Journal of Development Economics (June 1978), pp. 18189.

  • Chenery, Hollis B., and Alan M. Strout,Foreign Assistance and Economic Development”, American Economic Review (September 1966), pp. 679-733.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corbo, Vittorio, Morris Goldstein, and Mohsin Khan (eds.), Growth-Oriented Adjustment Programs (Washington, D.C.: IMF and the World Bank, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fry, Maxwell J.,Terms of Trade Dynamics, An Analysis of National Savings and Domestic Investment to Terms of Trade Changes in 14 Asian LDCs”, Journal of International Economics Vol. 5, March 1986.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments (Washington, D.C.: IMF 1977).

  • International Monetary Fund, Theoretical Aspects of the Design of Fund-Supported Adjustment Programs, IMF Occasional Paper No. 55 (Washington, D.C., IMF, September 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook. (April 1988).

  • Haque, Nadeem U., and Peter Montiel, Ricardian Equivalence, Liquidity Constraints, and the Tarai-Blanchard Effect: Tests for Developing CountriesReview of Economics and Statistics (1989). forthcoming.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., and Malcolm D. Knight, Fund-Supported Adjustment Programs and Economic Growth, IMF Occasional Paper No. 41 (Washington, D.C., IMF, November 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., and Malcolm D. Knight, Peter Montiel, and Nadeem Haque, Adjustment with Growth: Relating the Analytical Approaches of the World Bank and the IMF”, World Bank, Development Policy Issues Series Discussion Paper (October 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., and Malcolm D. Knight, Peter Montiel,Growth-Oriented Adjustment Programs: A Conceptual Framework”, IMF Working Paper Series No. 64 (July 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., and Malcolm D. Knight, Peter Montiel, and Carmen M. Reinhart,Private Investment and Economic Growth in Developing Countries,IMF, unpublished (March 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robichek, E. Walter,Financial Programming as Practiced by the IMF”, World Bank, unpublished (January 1985).

  • Robinson, Sherman,Sources of Growth in Less Developed Countries: A Cross-Section Study”, Quarterly Journal of Economics (August 1971), pp. 391-406.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rossi, Nicola,Government Spending, the Real Interest Rate, and the Behavior of Liquidity Constrained Consumers in Developing Countries”, IMF Staff Papers (March 1988). pp. 104-140.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sato, Kazuo,International Variations in the Incremental Capital-Output Rates”, Economic Development and Cultural Change. July 1971.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tyler, William G.,Growth and Export Expansion in Developing Countries: Some Empirical Evidence,Journal of Development Economics (March 1981), pp. 121-30.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wai, U. Tun,A Study of ICOR in Developing Countries”, Finafrica Savings and Development. Vol. IX, No.3, 1985.

*

The author is grateful to Mohsin Khan, Carlos Medeiros, Peter Montiel, and Vincent Reinhart for helpful comments and suggestions.

1/

See the references contained therein, particularly Michalopolus. Khan (1987) also provides a broad survey of this literature.

2/

For a more detailed discussion of the building blocks of this model, see Khan, Haque, and Montiel (1986).

3/

See, for instance, Khan and Knight (1985).

5/

See IMF (1977), (1987).

6/

These are combined for simplicity in the theoretical model (as in Khan and Montiel, 1988). In the empirical work this assumption is relaxed.

9/

The underlying specification is Mdt = νPtyt, with ν constant. This type of restrictive assumption is not essential to the model, as the analysis carries through with a more general specification.

10/

Because imports (Z) decline in the latter case.

11/

This average is higher than the 0.2 value obtained by Khan and Reinhart (1989) for a cross-section sample of 24 developing countries, but in line with Tyler (1981), who obtained a value of 0.25. Balassa (1978) found the marginal product to be about 0.16.

12/

For example, the role of wealth in consumption is emphasized in Haque and Montiel (1989).

13/

The construction of this variable is explained in Appendix I.

15/

This is, of course, an extreme assumption.

16/

We reject when both restricted and unrestricted versions coincide.

17/

The use of the relative price of exports, Px/Pn, in this specification in lieu of the real exchange rate, Pz/PD, is justified by the assumption of constant terms of trade in the theoretical model.

18/

See Khan and Montiel (1988) for a detailed discussion.

  • Collapse
  • Expand