Abstract

The global crisis has highlighted the need to attach greater importance to systemic risk in policy analysis and incorporate a macroprudential perspective in policymaking. This need is especially relevant under external financing conditions conducive to financial and economic excess (asset price bubbles, credit exuberance, and demand booms). Latin American countries already have been using prudential tools for macroprudential purposes and authorities are actively engaged in analyzing systemic risks and deciding on policies incorporating a macroprudential perspective. Despite the emerging agreement on the need to adopt a macroprudential approach, thinking on policy design is still evolving and its implementation will be challenging. This chapter reviews the Latin American experience with macroprudential policies and discusses some general considerations to help guide their use and integration into existing policy frameworks.

The global crisis has highlighted the need to attach greater importance to systemic risk in policy analysis and incorporate a macroprudential perspective in policymaking. This need is especially relevant under external financing conditions conducive to financial and economic excess (asset price bubbles, credit exuberance, and demand booms). Latin American countries already have been using prudential tools for macroprudential purposes and authorities are actively engaged in analyzing systemic risks and deciding on policies incorporating a macroprudential perspective. Despite the emerging agreement on the need to adopt a macroprudential approach, thinking on policy design is still evolving and its implementation will be challenging. This chapter reviews the Latin American experience with macroprudential policies and discusses some general considerations to help guide their use and integration into existing policy frameworks.

The global crisis has highlighted the potential force of financial and real sector interactions. This calls for attaching greater importance to systemic risk in policy analysis and incorporating a macroprudential perspective in policymaking. Current macroeconomic and microprudential frameworks have limitations in identifying and managing systemic risk.1 They may fail to identify or appropriately handle financial excesses or adverse shocks that pose a risk to the financial system and the economy as a whole (for example, excessive risk taking, overly abundant capital inflows). In this regard, tackling systemic risk represents a new priority for policymakers, with the Lehman collapse as a clear reminder of its potentially non-self-evident nature.

Furthermore, the traditional policy toolkit may be too blunt or lead to difficult policy trade-offs.2 For instance, very high policy interest rates may prick a bubble, but in the process create a sharp recession or, in some cases, even exacerbate the source of the imbalance (e.g., capital inflows). In this regard, macroprudential instruments may allow a targeted policy intervention, offering finer alternatives to the use of traditional macroeconomic policies, which are more akin to “broad spectrum antibiotics.” Because of this, authorities in Latin America have resorted to complementing the usual policy toolkit with other instruments.3 Looking ahead, the challenge will be how to set in place a broader framework that assesses and manages systemic risk and its potential amplifying effects in the financial sector, to help smooth the financial and economic cycle.4

Embedding a macroprudential perspective in the policy framework has particular importance under external financing conditions conducive to financial and economic excess (asset price bubbles, credit exuberance, and demand booms). The financial systems in the region weathered the recent global financial crisis better than in the past. This was partly the result of improved prudential policies, which were well adapted to country circumstances, including the stage of financial development, and enhanced in light of lessons learned from past financial crises. But improved macroeconomic policies in the region and resilient terms of trade were also important factors; mitigating the severity of the shock to financial systems.5 Hence, future financial resilience cannot be taken for granted on the basis of the recent experience.

The current economic cycle in the LA region, South America in particular, may prove challenging given the strong economic rebound that may be increasingly accompanied by large capital inflows (see Chapter 2). More specifically, excesses could arise not only through the banking sector (the core of the financial system in the region), but also through other developing markets (e.g., bond or derivatives markets) that may not be under full oversight (see Chapter 3). Therefore, it will be important to incorporate to the extent possible analysis of systemic risk in policymaking to ensure financial and macro stability. International discussions are still evolving about the design of an eventual macroprudential framework, including its perimeter.

This chapter briefly reviews the ongoing international debate on macroprudential policies, including the concept of systemic risk and objectives of these policies. It gives some examples about the international experience with these measures, particularly in Latin America, and concludes with a discussion of the challenges ahead from a Latin American perspective.

Systemic Risk and Macroprudential Policy—An Ongoing International Debate

What is systemic risk? Systemic risk can be defined as “the risk of disruption to financial services that is caused by an impairment of all or parts of the financial system and has the potential to have serious negative consequences for the real economy.”6 It comprises two dimensions: a cross-sectional and a time dimension.7 The first takes into account the distribution of risk across the financial and economic system and therefore accounts for externalities across the system (for example, common exposures, interconnectedness). In this regard, information asymmetries about counterparty exposures are at the core of contagion during periods of financial stress, as the recent financial crisis clearly demonstrated.8 The second dimension considers how system-wide risk evolves and is accumulated over time, along with the two-way links between the financial system and the real business cycle. It accounts for the usual procyclicality of the financial system.9,10

From a Latin American perspective, addressing procyclicality is a major policy priority given the prospect of large capital inflows,11 but attention should also be paid to the lessons of the crisis in advanced economies, particularly on how to assess and tackle common exposures and interconnectedness in the financial system. Moreover, supervision of currency and liquidity mismatches, including those in the corporate sector, remain crucial for the management of systemic risk.

What is macroprudential policy? Macroprudential policy helps promote financial and macroeconomic stability by reducing systemic risks. For the cyclical dimension, one could think of it as a combination of a set of rule-based tools and limited discretion that helps manage the role of the financial system as a source of shocks and amplifier of economic cycles. It aims to reduce the cyclicality of financial services by leaning against the buildup of risk in the economic upswing and against deleveraging during the downswing to support economic activity. Buffers would act as economic and financial stabilizers. For the cross-sectional dimension, it aims to reduce spillovers generated within a closely interconnected financial network. This requires addressing not only the “too-big-to-fail” problem, but also identifying systemic institutions (from a financial substitutability perspective). In this case, the calibration of prudential tools is institution-specific and requires assessing the systemic significance of individual institutions (i.e., their contribution to overall risk).

How to measure systemic risk? A macroprudential approach requires measuring and identifying the source and extent of systemic risk. The task is far more complex than in other policy areas, where a specific indicator can serve as a target. In particular, it is unlikely that a summary indicator will be able to say whether systemic risk is too high or too low, or whether imbalances will arise or not down the road.12 Therefore, authorities have to rely on a broad set of indicators that examine the different dimensions of the problem and combine them with doses of judgment to assess the vulnerability of the system.13 Identifying systemic risk will also require enhanced transparency and greater information disclosure, to limit contagion in times of stress.14 However, one must keep in mind that this indicators-based approach is imperfect and can fail to take into account key vulnerabilities. A concern is that such a set of indicators may give a positive assessment of the health of the financial system precisely when the system is most vulnerable.

What is the relationship between macroprudential and microprudential policies? The distinction between the micro- and macroprudential dimension of financial stability is best drawn in terms of the objectives (Borio, 2009; Persaud, 2009; and Crocket, 2000). Microprudential policy aims to reduce the probability of default of individual institutions, taking systemic risk as given, whereas macroprudential policy aims at containing risks for the financial system as a whole, to prevent the economic and social costs of systemic financial distress, considering the feedback effects that the behavior of individual institutions have on each other, and on the whole economy. What could be enough to safeguard a particular institution from a narrow perspective (say, by limiting its credit to improve its capital adequacy ratio) might not be enough (or excessive, depending on circumstances) once spillovers to the economy and other players are considered. The distinction between macro- and microprudential policies has less to do with the type of instruments involved. However, the granularity of the former need not be as much as that of the latter (see below).

Proposed instruments. Ongoing international discussions have identified a set of potential tools that could be used to deal with systemic risk. In July 2010, the Group of Governors and Heads of Supervision have reached broad agreement on the Basel Committee capital and liquidity reform package.15,16 Although Basel III, to a large extent has focused on microprudential concerns, some proposals address macroprudential issues. For instance, in dealing with procyclicality, the proposed tool is a countercyclical capital buffer to be imposed when excess aggregate credit growth is judged to be associated with a buildup of system-wide risk. On forward-looking provisioning, the International Standards Accounting Board (2009) published its proposals for replacing the current incurred loss impairment methodology with an expected loss (or cash-flow) approach. To address cross-sectional risk, discussions have focused on strengthening capital requirements for counterparty credit risk exposures (for example, from derivatives, repos, securities financing). The BCBS also continues to review specific proposals to address the risks of systemic banking institutions, which include a “guided discretion” approach for a systemic capital surcharge in combination with other mitigating regulatory and supervisory measures.17 On liquidity, the main proposals are (i) a net stable long-term funding ratio to address liquidity mismatches and provide incentives for banks to seek stable sources of funding over a one-year horizon; and (ii) a short-term liquidity coverage ratio that promotes resilience to potential liquidity disruptions.

What are the benefits and costs of macroprudential policies? Benefits are associated with reduction in the probability of financial crises and broader economic dislocations, and reduction in the amplitude of the financial and economic cycle during noncrisis episodes (BCBS, 2010). Costs arise due to distortions that can affect aggregate credit (for example, lower lending volumes and higher spreads) and economic activity during the transition when banks adjust their capital and liquidity to the new standards, as well as in the long term. An illustration is offered by evidence gathered for the microprudential proposals currently being discussed. The general assessment recently reported by the Financial Stability Board (FSB) and BCBS (2010) is that net benefits of adopting tighter capital and liquidity ratios remain positive for a wide range of capital and liquidity ratios.18 In the end, for macroprudential purposes, the precise outcome is uncertain, in part because of lack of an adequate analytical framework to assess the benefits of reducing macroeconomic volatility.

Recent Country Experiences with Macroprudential Tools

Country experience with macroprudential measures suggests that policymakers have used a broad range of instruments and applied those to deposit-taking institutions on a discretionary basis. They have used macroprudential instruments mainly to limit financial exuberance and the fallout from the global financial crisis. Countries have taken a pragmatic approach, targeting measures to specific markets or financial channels that were a cause of concern for financial stability. In a survey of macroprudential instruments and frameworks prepared by the Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS, 2010), central bankers viewed these measures as those aimed at reducing system-wide financial risks, including traditional microprudential instruments applied to the system as a whole; fiscal measures such as financial transaction taxes; and central bank tools used for system liquidity management (for example, reserve requirements).19 These measures are usually seen as complements to monetary policy.20 Table 4.1 lists instruments that have been used recently for macroprudential purposes as well as their main channels of operation (e.g., whether they operate on the asset side or liability side of financial intermediaries).

Table 4.1:

Selected Examples of Macroprudential Tools

article image
Sources: IMF Staff Review Note (June 2010) and authors’ compilation, based on national sources.

In the run-up to the global crisis, countries in the region used prudential tools for macroprudential purposes, and recently have started to redeploy them. Latin America authorities have relied not only on traditional prudential tools (for example, leverage ratios, limits on currency and maturity mismatches, limits on credit growth to specific sectors), but also have put in place dynamic loan-loss provisioning systems (see Box 4.1), actively managed marginal reserve requirements (see Box 4.2), and have imposed capital controls or limits on the net foreign exchange position of banks.21

Many countries in the region are proactively thinking about ways to analyze interconnectedness, evaluate systemic importance of financial institutions, adjust capital requirements, and implement countercyclical capital buffers in line with the international discussions.22 Furthermore, authorities in the region already recognize the complexity of macroprudential objectives, including the matter of shared responsibility among different authorities. Several countries already have taken steps on the institutional front to bring together different authorities through the creation of bodies responsible for macroprudential policy (e.g., Mexico’s Consejo de Estabilidad del Sistema Financiero), or establishing agreements to improve the exchange of information across regulatory institutions.23

To address similar concerns, countries in Asia and emerging Europe also have implemented measures with macroprudential objectives.24 To manage procyclicality, central banks in the region have used countercyclical provisioning, loan-to-value ratios, loan-to-deposit requirements, and direct controls on lending to specific sectors. The authorities have been addressing cross-sectional risks through capital surcharges for systemically important financial institutions, liquidity requirements/funding ratios, and limits on currency mismatches. More recently, measures relating to property lending markets (for example, mortgage lending limits, tightened loan-to-value ratios, or down payment requirements), have been used to temper the surge in asset prices and/or sales in several countries and ease risks of asset bubbles or sharp market corrections in the event of capital outflows. These instruments were calibrated from existing microprudential settings taking into account macroeconomic conditions.25 Moreover, in line with the Latin American experience, the authorities have also used macroprudential measures to reduce the inflows and associated volatility from speculation in very specific asset markets (for example, limits on banks’ currency derivatives positions and on short-term external loans denominated in foreign currencies).

Dynamic Provisioning in Latin America

Dynamic loan-loss provisions are a countercyclical tool that requires the buildup of cushions against expected losses in good times and releases them in bad times.1 The calibration uses a statistical method to allow for losses that are inherent within the portfolio but which have not yet materialized (Financial Services Authority, 2009). In the economic downswing, some losses are met from the accumulated buffer.

In the region, Bolivia (2008), Colombia (2007), Peru (2008), and Uruguay (2001) have in place systems of dynamic provisioning (Table).2 In Uruguay, the formula offsets loan delinquencies with provisions—as in Spain—whereas in Peru the system is a GDP-based dynamic loan-loss provisioning rule that is applied equally to all banks. In Bolivia, the system prescribes a general provision on prime quality loans, which can be drawn upon fully during a downswing.

Dynamic Provisioning: Cross-Country Comparison

article image
Source: Various regulators.

From 2000–04, the provisioning system was slightly different (there were three types of provisions instead of the current two and there were also some differences in the value of the parameters provided by the central bank’s model).

Starting in April 2010 dynamic provision is bank-specific.

ch04ufig01

Stock of Uruguayan Dynamic Provisions under Different Formulas

(Millions of U.S. dollars)

Source: Wezel, 2010.

Dynamic provisioning helps lean against the wind. A recent IMF study compared the Bolivian, Spanish, Peruvian, and Uruguayan provisioning systems using the actual Uruguayan cycle (Wezel, 2010). Each system induces a different path for provisioning (see the figure). For example, the Bolivian and Peruvian formulas yield a smoother path than the Spanish or Uruguayan systems. The comparison leaves open the question of whether the level of provisions is adequate or optimal.

1 By contrast, capital adequacy ratios (CARs) protect a financial institution against unexpected losses. Although CARs also can be employed to deal with both expected and unexpected losses, provisions lessen fluctuations in recorded bank profitability at business cycle frequencies independently of the solvency of the bank (Borio and others, 2001).2 The Bank of Spain first introduced a dynamic and forward-looking provisioning system in 2000 to cope with credit risk (Fernández de Lis and others, 2001). The system was intended to account for “latent” risks of homogeneous categories of assets that could lead to expected levels of losses over the business cycle. Provisions were tied to the growth of assets and accumulated in a fund, which could be used to cover loan losses.

Macroprudential Policy Challenges in the Current Latin American Context

Amid lax global financing conditions (ample liquidity driven by low international interest rates and high risk tolerance) that will likely prove protracted, Latin American countries are currently facing capital inflow pressures that may be conducive to financial excess, including credit booms, asset price bubbles, and domestic demand exuberance, all of which increase systemic risk. Emerging market economies can be especially prone to credit booms and/or asset price bubbles. Lack of exchange rate flexibility and credit constraints can make domestic demand particularly sensitive to external financial conditions.26 Macroprudential policy would add an additional set of instruments to the policy toolkit, particularly when traditional macroeconomic policies may not be adequate, and would allow addressing financial excess in specific sectors.27

Despite the emerging agreement on the need to adopt a macroprudential policy perspective, its implementation may prove challenging. These policies cannot be seen in isolation and considered a “silver bullet” to prevent the buildup of systemic risk and achieve financial and macroeconomic stability. Macroprudential policies need to be coordinated with macroeconomic policies. Moreover, many issues are still under discussion, which include how to track systemic risk, the level of granularity of the approach (that is, general versus sector-specific tools), the balance between rules and discretion, the perimeter of regulation, institutional arrangements and mandates, coordination and cooperation in supervision at the national and international levels, and data requirements.28

Reserve Requirements as a Macroprudential Tool in Latin America

The use of reserve requirements as a macroprudential tool has gained prominence, especially in emerging economies. The reason is threefold. First, increasing reserve requirements can help contain the pace of credit growth during an upswing, thus operating as a speed limit. Second, increasing reserve requirement in the upswing builds a buffer, that is, a cushion of reserves that can be deployed during the downswing to contain liquidity risks. Finally, they can complement monetary policy at times when the credit cycle is at odds with its goals. For instance, raising interest rates to contain demand pressures in the context of large capital inflows can be self-defeating if exchange rate flexibility is overly limited. Under such circumstances, increasing reserve requirements may substitute for an increase in interest rates. However, these benefits have to be weighed against its potential costs. Reserve requirements are difficult to calibrate and are costly taxes on intermediation. Therefore, their use seems more appropriate when standard and less costly policy instruments are insufficient to achieve financial or price stability (see Vargas and others, 2010).

In Latin America, the central banks of Colombia and Peru have used marginal reserve requirements as a macroprudential tool in the recent past.1,2 They acted as a speed limit on credit growth during the upswing, as a countercyclical tool to manage capital flows and the credit cycle, and as a liquidity buffer that was built in good times and released in bad times. The central bank of Brazil also used reserve requirements as a device to pump up liquidity to the financial system during the crisis.

In Colombia, rapid demand growth was threatening to overheat the economy by 2006. Credit in some segments (e.g., consumption) was expanding at an annual rate of 50 percent in a context of a highly indebted private sector. Thus in early 2007, to contain the expansion of credit amid increasing capital flow pressures, the central bank imposed marginal reserve requirements on savings, checking, and CD deposits (see the figure). These measures were complemented with the use of price-based capital controls (unremunerated reserve requirements on capital inflows), and limits to derivatives exposures of the banking sector. In September 2008, the central bank removed the marginal reserve requirements in an effort to counteract adverse external conditions and support liquidity needs in the domestic financial system. Colombia did not experience major liquidity problems, and the countercyclical use of reserve requirements gave the central bank additional degrees of freedom to manage the external shock.3

ch04ufig02

Colombia: Average and Marginal Reserve Requirements

(Percent of deposits)

Source: Central Bank of Colombia.

In Peru, the central bank has been active in using reserve requirements, in the upswing (prior to the global crisis), during the crisis, and more recently as the new cycle begins (see figures below on Peru). However, its goals may have differed at moments in time. In the upswing and prior to the crisis, the use of reserve requirements was motivated by large speculative capital inflows, which prompted the central bank to intervene in the market to limit exchange rate volatility.4 Such interventions were sterilized by issuing CDs, part of which were bought by foreign investors. This forced the central bank to switch instruments, specifically long-term deposits that could not be sold to foreign investors, and to impose reserve requirements on local and foreign currency deposits. The aim was to reduce liquidity in the market. At the time the central bank estimated that these measures were effective in reducing the amount of speculative inflows and equivalent to a 50 basis point increase in the reference rate.

ch04ufig03

Peru: Average and Marginal Reserve Requirements on Foreign Currency Deposits

(Percent of deposits)

Source: Central Reserve Bank of Peru.
ch04ufig04

Peru: Average and Marginal Reserve Requirements on Foreign Currency Deposits

(Percent of deposits)

Source: Central Reserve Bank of Peru.

The case of Brazil has featured high levels of reserve requirements, allowing the central bank to lower reserve requirements for macroprudential purposes following the Lehman Brothers episode. In particular, to confront liquidity problems in the interbank market, the central bank reduced reserve requirements to support lending from large liquid banks to small illiquid banks (see figure at right). By introducing this liquidity provision mechanism during the crisis, the central bank was able to avoid financial stability problems in the system.

ch04ufig05

Brazil: Average Reserve Requirements

(Percent of deposits)

Source: Central Bank of Brazil.
1 By marginal, it is meant that reserves are required on each additional deposit made at a bank from the date on which the regulation is made.2 Reserve requirements have also been used countercyclically in other emerging market economies (EMEs), including China and India. For a discussion of the use of reserve requirements in EMEs and some historical data, see Mohanty and Turner (2008).3 For a detailed account of the developments and reasons surrounding the policy measures adopted in Colombia prior to the collapse of Lehman Brothers, see Uribe (2009). An analysis of the effects of reserve requirements in Colombia on the interest rate and interest rate pass-through is discussed in Vargas and others (2010).4 For details on this specific episode of capital inflows to Peru, see Jara and Tovar (2008).

For now, a number of general considerations may help guide the use of prudential tools for macroprudential purposes and help eventually integrate those tools into policy decision making in Latin America.

Interaction with monetary and fiscal policies. Macroprudential policies should not be a substitute for fiscal and monetary policies playing a primary countercyclical role. However in a context of external financing distortions contributing to overexuberant conditions, over-reliance on monetary and fiscal policies may be suboptimal and/or inadequate to contain the macroeconomic impact. For instance, interest rate policy could exacerbate capital inflows under conditions limiting exchange rate flexibility, or the fiscal effort required to counter the private sector exuberance could introduce other significant distortions or not be feasible. In such contexts, the use of prudential instruments for macroprudential purposes could effectively add to the macroeconomic policy toolkit. Yet such policies should not substitute for an appropriate degree of exchange rate flexibility, the first and critical line of defense amid capital inflows.

Broad-range oversight. Conditions of excess leverage can occur in any segment of the financial system (regulated or shadow) with material externalities to the rest of the system and the overall economy. Macroprudential oversight therefore should encompass the entire financial spectrum and may also require monitoring the balance sheet of the corporate sector.

Targeted intervention. To avoid distorting markets or segments not affected by overexuberant conditions, prudential measures should aim to “lean against the wind” in the specific sectors concerned at a particular juncture. Given the new nature of using prudential instruments for macroprudential purposes, constrained experimentation may be needed to explore effectiveness while taking into account potential negative side effects on the financial sector.29

Embedding macroprudential policies in an institutional setup. Given that there is an overlap of responsibilities and instruments in the conduct of macroprudential policies, it would be important to adopt an institutional mechanism with clear mandates, transparency, and principles for coordination and accountability. Because a macroprudential framework cannot only be rule based—it would be impossible to calibrate the appropriate tools for all circumstances—the approach would require some degree of judgment, with checks and balances among the different institutions in charge of stability.

Note: This chapter was prepared by Camilo E. Tovar and Mercedes Vera Martin.

1

Microprudential frameworks can be thought of as those policies limiting the failure of an individual institution by limiting idiosyncratic risks (see discussion below and Crocket, 2000).

2

For a discussion of the role of macroeconomic policies after the global financial crisis, see Blanchard, Dell’Ariccia, and Mauro (2010).

3

Some of these measures affect financial transactions between residents and nonresidents. The distinction between capital controls and prudential measures could be sometimes blurred, because, in some instances, prudential measures are imposed only on nonresidents, and therefore considered capital controls. This chapter does not enter into such distinction and considers measures aiming at financial stability as prudential or macroprudential.

4

For a broader discussion on redesigning the contours of the future financial system, see Kodres and Narain (2010).

5

Greater exchange rate flexibility helped temper the incentives for capital inflows; less procyclical fiscal policies helped moderate the cyclical exuberance; the financial system was not exposed to toxic assets, thanks in part to improved profit opportunities across sectors; and, despite the depth of the global crisis, commodity export prices did not collapse as in the past.

6

See Financial Stability Forum, International Monetary Fund, and Bank for International Settlements (2009) report for the G-20.

7

This characterization is from the Bank for International Settlements (BIS). For details, see BIS (2009), Borio (2010, 2009), and Persaud (2009). Earlier references include Borio and others (2001) and Crocket (2000). Similarly, the Bank of England (2009) uses the terms network and aggregate risks, respectively, for the cross-sectional and time dimensions of systemic risks.

8

Although the collapse of Lehman would not have been identified ex ante as a potential macroeconomic shock, it had systemic financial implications because of the uncertainty regarding exposures (“who holds the losses?”) in a highly interconnected financial system.

9

For a detailed discussion on policies to deal with procyclicality, see Andritzky and others (2010).

10

For example, excessive leverage was at the core of financial imbalances in the wake of the global financial crisis, as risk illusion and excessive liquidity led to underpricing of risks.

11

See IMF (2010e) for a general discussion about global liquidity expansion and the policy response options for “receiving” economies.

12

For example, during the global financial crisis, capital indicators gave a sense of security, but could not capture the liquidity risk, which was not well captured due to accounting practices (mark-to-market) which fueled the self-reinforcing cycle during the crisis (Financial Services Authority, 2009).

13

New methodologies are being developed. For instance, to identify systemic institutions, new approaches are being put in place, such as network analysis, Co-risk analysis, multivariate distress dependence matrix, or “bottom-up” univariate contingent claims to deal with systemic risk (Financial Stability Forum, IMF, and BIS, 2009; and IMFb, 2009).

14

The Data Gaps Initiative (under an interagency group involving the Bank for International Settlements, European Central Bank, Eurostat, International Monetary Fund, Organization for Economic Development and Cooperation (OECD), World Bank, and United Nations) aims at improving official statistics for financial surveillance in light of the crisis, mainly in the areas of interlinkages within the financial sector, exposures of the nonbank financial sector to vulnerabilities; and cross-border exposures of nonfinancial firms.

15

The agreement was endorsed in September 2010. For details, see Basel Committee on Banking and Supervision (BCBS) (2009, 2010a), and BCBS press release and Annex (2010c).

16

Extracting the benefits of better regulation will also require better supervision. This may involve not only the ability to supervise, but also the will to act in a more intrusive, skeptical, proactive, comprehensive, adaptative, and conclusive manner (Viñals and Fletcher, 2010).

17

The IMF, the FSB, and the BIS produced a set of principles to identify systemically important institutions, markets, and instruments. See FSB, IMF, and BIS (2009).

18

Estimates suggest that banks’ lending volumes would decline between 1 percent and 1.4 percent for each percentage point increase in target capital ratios over a four-year horizon, while lending spreads would rise by about 16 basis points over the same horizon. Costs of higher liquidity standards are about 50 percent higher for lending volumes, but similar for spreads. The FSB-BCBS’s Macroeconomic Assessment Group (MAG) and Long-term Economic Impact (LEI) reports estimate substantial declines in the probability of crisis and that each percentage point increase in required capital would subtract about 0.05 percentage points from annual growth during the assumed implementation period of four years. However, these assessments contrast with studies published by the banks, with estimates sometimes as much as ten times higher. See BCBS (2010b), FSB and BCBS (2010), and Bank of Canada (2010).

19

It is important to keep in mind that reserve requirements are also a monetary policy tool. However, its use had been phased out in advanced economies as direct instruments of monetary policy were replaced by indirect (i.e., market-based) instruments, such as interest rates.

20

See BIS (2010) for a Latin American perspective on how monetary policy and financial stability interact.

21

In the past, countries also relied on reserve requirements on short-term borrowing of banks (e.g., Argentina in the 1990s, and Peru in more recent times).

22

For a discussion on the implications of the global financial regulatory reform for the LAC region, see Rennhack (2009).

23

These agreements aim at strengthening the safety net of the financial system and improving confidence of the public in the system (e.g., Colombia’s formal agreements for the exchange of information between the Central Bank and the Supervisory Authority).

24

See IMF (2010b, 2010c) for details.

25

See CGFS paper No. 38 for details on experience with measures relating to property lending markets. For instance, an 80 percent loan-to-value maximum is widely interpreted as a norm for residential real estate loans from a microprudential point of view, and tightening of this instrument has taken the form of 10–20 percentage point reductions, some of which were later reversed when conditions in the targeted markets were seen to have normalized.

26

Beyond Dutch disease concerns, exchange rate flexibility in some countries may be limited for other reasons, including dollarization and risks of balance sheet effects. In this instance, macroprudential measures could play a bigger role in macroeconomic stability.

27

With large and protracted capital inflows being the potential destabilizing source, capital controls may also play a useful role. See Ostry and others (2010) for details.

28

See Bank of England (2009), Borio (2009), Brunnermeier and others (2009), Caruana (2008, 2010a), IMF (2009b), and IMF (2010) for discussions of these issues.

29

To evaluate the suitability of different macroprudential tools, an important challenge is how to incorporate the financial sector in macroeconomic modeling. See Tovar (2009) for a general discussion and Beneš, Ötker-Robe, and Vávra (2009) and N’Diaye (2009) for more concrete applications to emerging market economies.

Heating Up in the South, Cooler in the North
  • View in gallery

    Stock of Uruguayan Dynamic Provisions under Different Formulas

    (Millions of U.S. dollars)

  • View in gallery

    Colombia: Average and Marginal Reserve Requirements

    (Percent of deposits)

  • View in gallery

    Peru: Average and Marginal Reserve Requirements on Foreign Currency Deposits

    (Percent of deposits)

  • View in gallery

    Peru: Average and Marginal Reserve Requirements on Foreign Currency Deposits

    (Percent of deposits)

  • View in gallery

    Brazil: Average Reserve Requirements

    (Percent of deposits)

  • Andritzky, Jochen, John Kiff, Laura Kodres, Pamela Madrid, Andrea Maechler, Aditya Narain, Noel Sacasa, and Jodi Scarlata, 2009, “Policies to Mitigate Procyclicality,” IMF Staff Position Note 09/09 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank of Canada, 2010, “Strengthening International Capital and Liquidity Standards: A Macroeconomic Impact Assessment for Canada,” Bank of Canada report (Ottawa, August).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements, 2008, “New Financing Trends in Latin America: A Bumpy Road Towards Stability,” BIS Papers 36 (Basel, February).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements, 2009, Annual Report 2008/2009 (Basel).

  • Bank for International Settlements, 2010, “Perspectives on Inflation Targeting, Financial Stability and the Global Crisis,” BIS Papers 51 (Basel, March).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank of England, 2009, “The Role of Macroprudential Policy: A Discussion Paper” (London, November).

  • Barbosa, Nelson, 2010, “Latin America: Counter- Cyclical Policy in Brazil: 2008–09,” Journal of Globalization and Development, Vol. 1, Issue 1, Article 13.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2009, “Strengthening the Resilience of the Banking Sector,” Consultative Document, December.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2010a, “Broad Agreement on Basel Committee Capital and Liquidity Reform Package,” Press Release, July.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2010b, “An Assessment of the Long-term Economic Impact of Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements,” August.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2010c, “Announcement of Higher Global Minimum Capital Standards,” Press Release, September.

  • Batini, N., M. Estevão, and G. Keim, 2010, “Production and Jobs: Can We Have One Without the Other?” IMF Country Report No. 10/248 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beneš, Jaromír, İnci Ötker-Robe, and David Vávra, 2009, “Modeling with Macro-Financial Linkages: Credit and Policy Shocks in Emerging Markets,” Working Paper 09/123 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, Giovanni Dell’Ariccia, and Paulo Mauro, 2010, “Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy,” IMF Staff Position Note 10/03 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borensztein, Eduardo, Kevin Cowan, Barry Eichengreen, and Ugo Panizza, 2008, Bond Markets in Latin America: On the Verge of a Big Bang? (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borio, Claudio, Craig Furfine, and Philip Lowe, 2001, “Procyclicality of the Financial System and Financial Stability: Issues and Policy Options,” BIS Papers 1 (Basel: Bank of International Settlements).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borio, Claudio, Craig Furfine, and Philip Lowe, 2009, “Implementing the Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation and Supervision,” Financial Stability Review: The Future of Financial Regulation, Banque de France, September.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borio, Claudio, Craig Furfine, and Philip Lowe, 2010, “Implementing a Macroprudential Framework: Blending Boldness and Realism,” paper presented at the BIS-HKMA Conference on Financial Stability: Towards a Macroprudential Approach, Hong Kong, SAR, July 56.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brunnermeir, Markus, Andrew Crockett, Charles Goodhart, Avi Persaud, and Hyum Shin, 2009, The Fundamental Principles of Regulation, Geneva Reports on the World Economy, Vol. 11 (Geneva: International Centre for Monetary and Banking Studies and Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caruana, Jaime, 2010, “Macroprudential Policy: What Have We Learned and Where Are We Going?” paper presented at the Second Financial Stability Conference of the International Journal of Central Banking, Madrid, Spain, June 17.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Celasun, O., 2009, “Spillovers from U.S. Federal Debt Issuance: The Case of Emerging Market Sovereign Borrowing,” IMF Country Report No. 09/229 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Celasun, O., and M. Sommer, 2010, “The Financing of U.S. Federal Budget Deficits,” IMF Country Report No.10/248 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Center for Research on the Epidemiology of Disasters (CRED), 2010, Emergency Disaster Database (EMDAT).

  • Committee on the Global Financial System, 2007, “Financial Stability and Local Currency Bond Markets,” CGFS Publications, No. 28, June.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Committee on the Global Financial System, 2010, “Macroprudential Instruments and Frameworks: A Stocktaking of Issues and Experiences,” CGFS Papers No. 38, May.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Crocket, Andrew, 2000, “Marrying the Micro and Macroprudential Dimensions of Financial Stability” (Basel: Bank for International Settlements).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Nicolò, Gianni, Giovanni Dell’Ariccia, Luc Laeven, and Fabian Valencia, “Monetary Policy and Bank Risk Taking,” IMF Staff Position Note 10/09 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1009.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Denison, Edward, 1962, “Sources of Growth in the United States and the Alternative Before Us,” Supplement Paper 13 (New York: Committee for Economic Development).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Denison, Edward, Zvi Griliches, and Dale Jorgenson, 1972, “The Measurement of Productivity,” Survey of Current Business, Vol. 52 (May, part 2), pp. 3111 (special issue).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Erasmus, L., J. Leichter, and J. Menkulasi, 2009, “De-dollarization in Liberia—Lessons from Cross-Country Experience,” Working Paper 09/37 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Estevão, M., and E. Tsounta, forthcoming, “Is U.S. Structural Unemployment on the Rise?” Working Paper (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fernández de Lis, Santiago, Jorge Martìnez, Jesús Saurina, 2001, “Credit Growth, Problem Loans and Credit Risk Provisioning in Spain,” BIS Papers 1 (Basel: Bank of International Settlements).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ferreira, F., J. Gyourko, and J. Tracy, 2010, “Housing Busts and Household Mobility,” Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 68, pp. 3445.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Services Authority, 2009, The Turner Review: A Regulatory Response to the Global Crisis (London).

  • Financial Stability Board, International Monetary Fund, and Bank for International Settlements, 2009, Guidance to Assess the Systemic Importance of Financial Institutions and Instruments: Initial Considerations, Report to the G-20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors, October.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Stability Board and Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2010, Assessing the Macroeconomic Impact of the Transition to Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements. Interim Report, August.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia-Escribano, M., 2010, “Peru: Drivers of De-dollarization,” Working Paper Series No. 2010–11 (Lima: Central Reserve Bank of Peru).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia-Escribano, M., 2010, “Peru: Drivers of De-dollarization,” Working Paper 10/169 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Garcia-Escribano, M., and S. Sosa, forthcoming, “De-dollarization in Latin America: Facts and Factors,” Working Paper (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hall, Robert, and Charles Jones, 1999, “Why Do Some Countries Produce so Much More Output per Worker than Others?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114, pp. 83116.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hausmann, Ricardo, and Barry Eichengreen, 2005, Other People’s Money; Debt Denomination and Financial Instability in Emerging Market Economies (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heston, Alan, Robert Summers, and Bettina Aten, 2009, “Penn World Table v. 6.3,” Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hoskin, Kevin, Ian Nield, and Jeremy Richardson, 2009, “The Reserve Bank’s New Liquidity Policy For Banks,” Reserve Bank Bulletin, Vol. 72, No. 4, December (Reserve Bank of New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Inter-American Development Bank, 2004, “Unlocking Credit: The Quest for Deep and Stable Bank Lending,” Economic and Social Progress in Latin America 2005 Report (Washington: October)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2008–2010, World Economic Outlook (Washington: various issues).

  • International Monetary Fund, 2009a, “Initial Lessons of the Crisis,” paper prepared by the Research, Monetary and Capital Markets, and Strategy, Policy, and Review Departments. February.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2009b, Global Financial Stability Report: Responding to the Global Crisis (Washington, April).

  • International Monetary Fund, 2010a, International Financial Statistics (Washington).

  • International Monetary Fund, 2010b, Fiscal Monitor (Washington, May).

  • International Monetary Fund, 2010c, “Prudential-Regulatory Reform: Current Global Initiatives and Fund Advice,” Staff Policy Review Note, June.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2010d, Regional Economic Outlook: Asia and Pacific—Leading the Global Recovery; Rebalancing for the Medium Term (Washington, April).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2010e, Regional Economic Outlook: Europe—Fostering Sustainability (Washington, May).

  • Jara, Alejandro, and Camilo E. Tovar, 2008, “Monetary and Financial Stability Implication of Capital Flows in Latin American and Caribbean Economies,” BIS Papers 43 (Basel, Bank for International Settlements).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jaromír Beneš, İnci Ötker-Robe, and David Vávra, 2009, “Modeling with Macro-Financial Linkages: Credit and Policy Shocks in Emerging Markets,” Working Paper 09/123 (Washington, International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jorgenson, Dale, and Zvi Griliches, 1967, “The Explanation of Productivity Change,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 34, pp. 24980.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kamil, Herman, and Rajeswari Sengupta, forthcoming, “Financial Structure and Corporate Performance during the Global Crisis: Microeconomic Evidence for Latin America,” Working Paper (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kodres, Laura, and Aditya Narain, 2010, “Redesigning the Contours of the Future Financial System,” IMF Staff Position Note 10/10 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1010.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kokenyne, A., J. Ley, and R. Veyrune, 2010, “Dedollarization,” Working Paper 10/188 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Kumar, Manmohan, and Jaejoon Woo, 2010, “Public Debt and Growth,” Working Paper 10/174 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Laubach, T., 2009, “New Evidence on the Interest Rate Effects of Budget Deficits and Debt,” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 7, pp. 858-85.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lee, Jong-Wha, 2005, “Human Capital and Productivity for Korea’s Sustained Economic Growth,” Journal of Asian Economics, Vol. 16, pp. 66387.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Loayza, Norman, Pablo Fajnzylber, and Cesar Calderon, 2004, Economic Growth in Latin America and the Caribbean: Stylized Facts, Explanations, and Forecasts (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lo, Andrew, 2009, “The Feasiblity of Systemic Risk Measurements: Written Testimony for the House Financial Services Committee on Systematic Risk Regulation,” October.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Matthieson, Donald, Jorge Roldos, Ramana Ramaswamy, and Anna Ilyina, 2004, “Emerging Local Securities and Derivatives Markets” (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, Enrique G., and Marco E. Terrones, 2008, “An Anatomy of Credit Booms: Evidence from Macro Aggregates and Micro Data,” NBER Working Papers No. 14049 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mohanty, M., and P. Turner, 2008, “Monetary Policy Transmission in Emerging Market Economies: What Is New?” BIS Papers, No. 35 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • N’Diaye, Papa, 2009, “Countercyclical Macro Prudential Policies in a Supporting Role to Monetary Policy,” Working Paper 09/257 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ocampo, Jose A., and Camilo E. Tovar, 2008, “External and Domestic Financing in Latin America: Developments, Sustainability and Financial Stability Implications,” paper presented at the United Nations Workshop on Debt, Finance and Emerging Issues in Financial Integration, April, New York.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., Atish R. Ghosh, Karl Habermeier, Marcos Chamon, Mahvash S. Qureshi, and Dennis B.S. Reinhardt, 2010, “Capital Inflows: The Role of Controls,” IMF Staff Position Note 10/04 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1004.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pattillo, Catherine, Helene Poirson, and Luca Ricci, 2002, “External Debt and Growth,” Working Paper 02/69 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Persaud, Avinash, 2009, “Macro-prudential Regulation: Fixing Fundamental Market (and Regulatory) Failures,” The World Bank, Financial and Private Sector Vice-Presidency, Note Number 6, July. http://rru.worldbank.org/publicpolicyjournal.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinhart, Carmen, and Kenneth Rogoff, 2010, “Growth in a Time of Debt,” American Economic Review, Vol. 100, pp. 53778.

  • Rennack, Robert, 2009, “Global Financial Regulatory Reform: Implications for Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC),” IMF Staff Position Note 09/19 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Romeu, Rafael, and Andrew Wolfe, forthcoming, “Recession and Policy Transmission to International Tourism: Does Expanded Travel to Cuba Offset Crisis Spillovers?” Working Paper (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Romeu, Rafael, 2008 “Vacation Over: Implications for the Caribbean of Opening U.S.-Cuba Tourism,” Working Paper 08/162 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Scatigna, Michela, and Camilo E. Tovar, 2007 “Securitization in Latin America,” BIS Quarterly Review, pp. 718.

  • Shinasi, Garry, 2004, “Defining Financial Stability,” Working Paper 04/187 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Solow, Robert, 1957, “Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 39, pp. 31220.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tovar, Camilo, 2009, “DSGE Models and Central Banks. Economics,” The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, Vol. 3, 2009–16 www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/ journalarticles/2009–16.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Uribe, J., 2009, “Política Monetaria y Estabilidad Financiera” (Bogotá: Banco de la República). www.banrep.gov.co/documentos/presentaciones-discursos/Uribe/2009/Simposio_capitales.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Vargas, Hernando, Yanneth Betancourt, Carlos Varela, and Norberto Rodríguez, 2010, “Effects of Reserve Requirements in an Inflation Targeting Regime: The Case of Colombia,” Borradores de Economía, No. 587 (Bogotá: Banco de la República).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Viñals, José, and Jonathan Fietchter, 2010, “The Making of Good Supervision: Learning to Say ‘No,’” IMF Staff Position Note 10/08 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wexel, Torsten, 2010, “Dynamic Loan Loss Provisions in Uruguay: Properties, Shock Absorption Capacity and Simulation Using Alternative Formulas,” Working Paper 10/125 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2010, World Development Indicators (Washington, April).

  • World Tourism Organization, 1980–2009 Yearbook of Tourism Statistics (Madrid).