Abstract

This section provides an overview of the fiscal policy responses of oil-producing countries to the oil boom through 2005.1 Although the analysis focuses on broad trends, the significant diversity of the oil-producing countries in the sample should be borne in mind. In particular, country-specific factors that show great differentiation among oil-producing countries include level of development, institutional capacity, macroeconomic situation, fiscal dependence on oil revenue, public debt and liquidity positions, and the stock and expected duration of oil reserves in the ground. Box 1 compares developments under the recent oil boom with the oil shocks in the 1970s.

This section provides an overview of the fiscal policy responses of oil-producing countries to the oil boom through 2005.1 Although the analysis focuses on broad trends, the significant diversity of the oil-producing countries in the sample should be borne in mind. In particular, country-specific factors that show great differentiation among oil-producing countries include level of development, institutional capacity, macroeconomic situation, fiscal dependence on oil revenue, public debt and liquidity positions, and the stock and expected duration of oil reserves in the ground. Box 1 compares developments under the recent oil boom with the oil shocks in the 1970s.

Fiscal Policy Responses to the Recent Oil Boom Through 2005

The current oil boom is defined to have started in 2000. Following a sharp decline in 1998 and a recovery in 1999, oil prices increased by more than 50 percent in 2000 and broadly stabilized at that level in 2001– 03.2 Oil prices accelerated again in 2004–05, reaching US$53 per barrel on average in 2005, their highest level in real terms since 1984.

On average, through 2005 governments used close to half of the additional fiscal oil revenue in the form of higher non-oil primary spending and/or lower non-oil primary revenue.3 These rates are measured on the basis of the cumulative increase in non-oil primary deficits in 2000–05 relative to the cumulative change in fiscal oil revenue (or in the fiscal oil balance in those countries with public sector coverage in the fiscal accounts) in the same period (Figure 2.1). The average non-oil primary fiscal deficit increased from 26 percent of non-oil GDP in 1999 to 37½ percent of non-oil GDP in 2005.4 Additional oil revenues not spent were used in part to lower debt stocks and accumulate financial assets. However, the size of the oil boom and the fiscal response varied substantially across countries.

Figure 2.1.
Figure 2.1.

Cumulative Change in the Non-Oil Primary Deficit Relative to Additional Oil Revenue, 2000–051

Source: IMF staff estimates.1 Equatorial Guinea and Libya are not shown because of their very large changes in oil revenue as a ratio to non-oil GDP.

Oil-producing countries turned overall fiscal deficits in the late 1990s into growing fiscal surpluses. The average overall balance changed from a deficit of 3½ percent of GDP in 1999 to a surplus of 12 percent of GDP in 2005. The variance across countries, however, was significant.

The increase in total government spending in real terms averaged about 12 percent a year during 2000–05, with capital spending growing faster than current spending. The average rate of growth of primary current spending in real terms accelerated from about 3½ percent a year during 1992–99 to 12 percent a year during 2000–05. Capital spending increased on average by about 19½ percent a year in real terms during 2000–05. The average ratio of capital spending to non-oil GDP surged from 8 percent in 1999 to 14½ percent in 2005 (Figure 2.2, panel B, and Appendix I).5 Interest payments, on the other hand, declined in a number of countries as gross public debts were reduced.

Figure 2.2.
Figure 2.2.

Expenditure Growth and Sustainability Analysis

Source: IMF staff estimates.1Excludes Angola.2Excludes Angola and Equatorial Guinea.3Excludes Timor-Leste.4The sustainability ratios are computed as the ratio of sustainable primary expenditure relative to actual primary expenditure. In the chart, countries with a value lower than 1 would have to adjust to reach the sustainable benchmark. Countries that are above the 45-degree line improved their fiscal sustainability position between 2000 and 2005. The analysis excluded Chad and Timor-Leste.

The acceleration in spending was stronger in the last few years of the period under consideration, with more than 50 percent of the additional spending in 2000–05 occurring during 2004–05 (see Appendix I). This followed the large increase in oil revenue in the last two years of that period and might have been attributable in part to growing perceptions of a long-lasting increase in oil prices. It might also reflect the time required to design and begin the execution of new capital projects. In addition, although average primary government spending substantially increased between 1999 and 2005, there were large differences across countries. For instance, increases in spending as a share of non-oil GDP exceeded the increase in oil revenues in Indonesia, Sudan, and the Syrian Arab Republic. In contrast, expenditure as a share of non-oil GDP declined in Cameroon, the Republic of Congo, Gabon, Kuwait, and the United Arab Emirates. Spending patterns varied significantly between lower- and higher-income oil-producing countries. Whereas on average the increase in total spending accounted for 27 percent of the increase in oil revenue in higher-income countries, this increase was as high as 40 percent in lower-income countries.

The Recent Oil Boom and Previous Oil Shocks

The increase in oil prices in the oil boom up to 2005 was smaller and more gradual than in the 1970s. In real terms, prices expanded by more than 400 percent between 1973 and 1981 (an increase of US$59 per barrel at 2005 U.S. dollars) compared to 150 percent (an increase of US$32 per barrel) between 1999 and 2005. The increase in prices up to 2005 was more gradual than in the 1970s (figure). This can be partly explained by the presence of synchronized global growth and sustained increases in the demand for oil, in contrast to the supply-side shocks of the 1970s.

The fiscal revenue impact of the oil boom from 1999 to 2005, however, was comparable to the 1970s. The average change in fiscal revenue in real terms relative to expenditure and revenue levels just before the oil price increases was similar in both periods.1 Several factors explain this development:

  • The 1999–2005 oil boom was accompanied by increases in oil production.

  • As a result of sharp downward real exchange rate adjustments that started in the mid-1980s following the collapse of oil prices, real exchange rates in oil-producing countries were more depreciated in the late 1990s than at the outset of the 1970s shock. Thus, the domestic purchasing power of a given level of fiscal oil revenue in U.S. dollar terms was higher at the outset of the current boom than at the outset of the 1970s episode.

  • The currencies of oil-producing countries appreciated more in real terms in the 1970s than in the current boom, which more rapidly eroded the domestic purchasing power of higher oil prices.2

The evolution of overall fiscal positions differed in both periods. In contrast to the period 2000–05, in the 1970s the average overall fiscal position barely improved during the windfall from a better starting point (table).

The more gradual fiscal use of the additional oil revenue in the oil boom through 2005 may be partly related to the different evolution of spot oil prices and oil price expectations during the two booms (see Figure 3 in the text). First, oil prices increased more gradually during the current boom. Second, in the 1970s and early 1980s observers generally expected rising oil prices in the medium term. In the current boom, in contrast, futures markets generally remained in backwardation until early 2005. Since then, futures market expectations about tight crude oil markets going forward firmed up, and futures prices switched to contango or at least to medium-term prices similar to current price levels.

uch02bxfig01

Real Oil Prices

(US$ per barrel at 2005 prices)1

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook.1IMF World Economic Outlook oil prices deflated by the U.S. consumer price index.

Fiscal Impact of the Current and Previous Oil Booms

article image
Source: IMF staff estimates.

Angola is excluded from the calculation of average charges in inflation rates during this decade.

1 A ratio of 1.4 in 1974–81 compared to 1.8 in 2000–05.2 Larger appreciations were associated with high inflation and mostly stable nominal exchange rates in many oil-producing countries in the 1970s. In the current boom, average inflation has been lower, though with a large variance. On the other hand, if oil-producing countries’ oil exports are deflated by a trade-weighted Group of Seven countries (G-7) non-oil export price, the current oil boom would be larger in absolute terms than the one in the 1970s (IMF, 2006). This trend partly explains the sharp reversal in external current account balances in the 1970s.

Government Effectiveness, Sustainability, and Vulnerability Issues

Higher oil revenues, and the prospect that a significant portion of the rise in oil prices may be long-lasting, provided oil-producing countries an opportunity to increase public spending on priority economic and social goals and/or reduce taxes. For countries with relatively strong financial positions, a sustainable fiscal position (taking into account oil reserves in the ground and net public financial assets), and a reasonable capacity to identify and implement good spending programs, a gradual increase in the non-oil fiscal deficit may be an appropriate response to higher oil revenues, provided it does not lead to excessive demand pressures.

The quality of government institutions and public financial management is critical for the effectiveness of scaling up public spending. In this connection, although expenditures increased in almost all oil-producing countries in recent years, many countries that saw a rapid increase in spending are characterized by low indices of government effectiveness. This may raise questions about certain countries’ ability to use the additional resources effectively. The analysis suggests an inverse relationship between spending growth and government effectiveness (Figure 2.2, panel C).6 Institutional capacity—which includes the collection of laws, organizations, and behaviors that define the way fiscal policy is determined, managed, and governed—is positively correlated with the countries’ level of income (with a correlation coefficient of 0.8). Thus, countries that arguably have more urgent needs and spending pressures tend to be those where the quality of spending may be most affected by institutional weaknesses. This poses trade-offs between pressing developmental needs on the one hand, and the institutional ability to address them effectively and efficiently on the other. Indications of a significant acceleration of spending in some oil-producing countries in 2006–07 make this issue more pressing.

To analyze trends in the long-term sustainability of fiscal policy in oil-producing countries during the period through 2005, the actual fiscal position was compared to a “sustainable fiscal benchmark” calculated for each country in the sample. The sustainable fiscal benchmark is defined as the (permanent) annual non-oil primary deficit derived from government net wealth, which is the present value of projected future oil revenues plus the value of net government financial assets. This exercise, based on a permanent income hypothesis model, assesses whether the fiscal position at a specific point in time could be sustained indefinitely given that fiscal oil wealth is finite (Appendix II describes the methodology in greater detail and provides a discussion of some of the issues not addressed by this approach).

Sustainable fiscal benchmarks were calculated for 2000 and 2005.7 Some countries recorded substantial improvements, but the average increase in sustainability between those years was limited, and a number of countries were running unsustainable fiscal policies compared to the sustainability benchmark (Figure 2.2, panel D).8 Even some countries that saved a significant share of the additional oil revenue experienced a deteriorating sustainability position. The key explanation is that several countries had an expansion in the non-oil primary deficit that was larger than the change in the long-term sustainable non-oil primary deficit associated with the changes in government net wealth.9

These results are subject to some caveats. First, any estimate of the permanently sustainable non-oil primary deficit is subject to considerable uncertainty, including uncertainties about oil reserves and future oil prices. This implies that the benchmark results should be updated regularly with the availability of new information. Second, the quality of government spending, including public investment, can have effects on growth, fiscal revenues, and thus on fiscal sustainability, which are not captured in the exercise. In particular, public investment could stimulate growth, yield returns to the government, and improve sustainability, provided that the investment is of high quality and governments are able to reap sufficient fiscal dividends from the additional growth to cover the costs of the investment. The relationship between public investment and growth is difficult to model and generalize, and should be looked at on a country-by-country basis, partly because major determinants of growth are connected to the quality of policies, institutions, and decision making, and the management of exogenous shocks.10

Oil price fluctuations may expose some oil-producing countries to the need for significant adjustments. Fiscal policy decisions should take into account the vulnerability of oil-producing countries to cash flow shocks. There is ample evidence that oil prices exhibit significant volatility in the short run and large fluctuations over the medium term.11 Moreover, market forecasts have often been wrong in the past (Figure 2.3). In a number of oil-producing countries, the fiscal stance and sustainability position in 2005 were comfortable, and many of them accumulated substantial public financial assets and/or reduced their liabilities in recent years. Others, however, were exposed to the possible need for large fiscal adjustments. If the oil price in 2005 had been one standard deviation lower, the average overall fiscal balance of oil-producing countries in the sample would have been nearly 10 percentage points of GDP lower, and about half the countries in the sample would have recorded overall fiscal deficits.12

Figure 2.3.
Figure 2.3.

Oil Price Projections1

Sources: U.S. Department of Energy Annual Energy Outlook (1982, 1986, and 1989); and IMF, World Economic Outlook.1 The solid lines are spot oil prices. The dotted and dashed lines are price forecasts.2West Texas Intermediate (WTI) crude oil.
1

Throughout the paper, the term “oil” is used as substitute for the more encompassing terms “hydrocarbon” or “petroleum,” because gas is also an important resource in several countries.

2

Crude oil prices are computed as the simple average of three spot prices (Brent, West Texas Intermediate, and Dubai) and deflated by the U.S. consumer price index. The coefficient of variation fell from 0.6 in 1970–85 to 0.2 in 1986–99.

3

The quantitative analysis of fiscal developments focuses on the central or general government for most countries in the sample, and on the public sector for Ecuador, Mexico, and Venezuela.

4

Non-oil primary revenue increased on average by about 1 percentage point of non-oil GDP during the period.

5

Excluding Angola and Equatorial Guinea.

6

The government effectiveness indicator, developed by Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2005), was used as a proxy of spending quality. The indicator is measured in units ranging from −2.5 to 2.5, with higher values corresponding to better effectiveness outcomes.

7

Proven reserves and actual oil prices prevalent in those years were used in the exercise.

8

The sustainability ratios are computed as the ratio of the implied sustainable expenditure relative to actual expenditure; that is, countries with a value lower than 1 would have to adjust to reach the sustainable benchmark. In Figure 2, countries that are above the 45 degree line improved their fiscal sustainability position between 2000 and 2005.

9

In addition, the appreciation of the currencies in real terms of a number of oil-producing countries reduced the domestic purchasing power of higher international oil prices, and growth in the non-oil sector reduced the relative size of the increase in oil wealth relative to non-oil GDP.

10

See IMF (2004, 2005) and IMF and World Bank (2006).

11

According to Cashin, Liang, and McDermott (1999), there is a one-in-three chance of a monthly oil price change greater than 8 percent. The average annual oil price change in 1970–2005 was 27 percent.

12

These estimates refer to the first-round effects and do not allow for policy responses. They also assume local linearity between oil export revenues and fiscal oil revenues, as well as between oil prices and oil GDP.

Cited By

The Role of Fiscal Institutions
  • Aizenman, Joshua, and Jaewoo Lee, 2005, “International Reserves: Precautionary vs. Mercantilist Views, Theory, and Evidence,IMF Working Paper 05/198 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Richard, Allen, Dimitar Radev, 2006, “Managing and Controlling Extrabudgetary Funds,IMF Working Paper 06/286 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Manuel Arellano, Stephen Bond, 1991, “Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations,Review of Economic Studies, No. 58 (April), pp. 27797.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Askari, Hossein, Vahid Nowshirvani, and Mohamed Jaber, 1997, Economic Development in the GCC: The Blessing and the Curse of Oil, Contemporary Studies in Economic and Financial Analysis (Greenwich, Connecticut: Jai Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baltagi, Badi H., 2005, Econometric Analysis of Panel Data (Hoboken, New Jersey: John Wiley & Sons, 3rd ed.).

  • Barnett, Steven, and Rolando Ossowski, 2003, “Operational Aspects of Fiscal Policy in Oil-Producing Countries,” in Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries, ed. by J. M. Davis, R. Ossowski, and A. Fedelino (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barnett, Steven, and Alvaro Vivanco, 2003, “Statistical Properties of Oil Prices: Implications for Calculating Government Wealth,in Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries, ed. by J. M. Davis, R. Ossowski, and A. Fedelino (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bartsch, Ulrich 2006, “How Much Is Enough? Monte Carlo Simulations of an Oil Stabilization Fund for Nigeria,IMF Working Paper 06/142 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • British Petroleum, 2005, BP Statistical Review of World Energy (London).

  • Cashin, Paul, Hong Liang, and John McDermott, 1999, “How Persistent Are Shocks to World Commodity Prices?IMF Working Paper 99/80 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Celasun, Oya, Xavier Debrun, and Jonathan David Ostry, 2006, “Primary Surplus Behavior and Risks to Fiscal Sustainability in Emerging Market Countries: A ‘FanChart’ Approach,IMF Working Paper 06/67 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Davis, Jeffrey, Rolando Ossowski, James Daniel, Steven Barnett, 2001, Stabilization and Savings Funds for Non-renewable Resources, IMF Occasional Paper No. 205 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Davis, Jeffrey, Rolando Ossowski, and Annalisa Fedelino, 2003, Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, Jack, 2006, Budget System Reform in Emerging Economies: The Challenges and the Reform Agenda, IMF Occasional Paper No. 245 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eifert, Benn, Alan Gelb, and Nils Borje Tallroth, 2003, “The Political Economy of Fiscal Policy and Economic Management in Oil-Exporting Countries,in Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries, ed. by J. M. Davis, R. Ossowski, and A. Fedelino (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fabrizio, Stefania, and Ashoka Mody, 2006, “Can Budget Institutions Counteract Political Indiscipline?IMF Working Paper 06/123 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Iimi, Atsushi, 2006, “Did Botswana Escape from the Resource Curse?IMF Working Paper 06/138 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2004, “Public Investment and Fiscal Policy” (Washington). Available via the Internet: www.imf.org/external/np/fad/2004/pifp/eng/PIFP.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2005a, “Oil Market Developments and Issues” (Washington). Available via the Internet: www.imf.org/ external/np/pp/eng/2005/030105.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2005b, “Public Investment and Fiscal Policy—Lessons from the Pilot Country Studies” (Washington). Available via the Internet: www.imf.org/external/np/ pp/eng/2005/040105a.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2006, “Oil Prices and Global Imbalances,in World Economic Outlook, April 2006: Globalization and Inflation, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2007, “Fiscal Policy Response to Scaled-Up Aid” (Washington). Available via the Internet: www.imf.org/external/np/pp/2007/eng/060507.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, and World Bank, 2006, “Applying the Debt Sustainability Framework for Low-Income Countries Post Debt Relief” (Washington). Available via the Internet: www. imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2006/110606.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Katz, Menachem, Ulrich Bartsch, Harinder Malothra, and Milan Cuc, 2004, Lifting the Oil Curse, Improving Petroleum Revenue Management in Sub-Saharan Africa (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, Massimo Mastruzzi, 2005, “Governance Matters IV: Governance Indicators for 1996–2004,Policy Research Working Paper No. 3630 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kopits, George, and Steven Symansky, 1998, Fiscal Policy Rules, IMF Occasional Paper No. 162 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Kumar, Manmohan, and Teresa Ter-Minassian, 2007, Promoting Fiscal Discipline (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Paolo, Manasse, 2006, “Procyclical Fiscal Policy: Shocks, Rules, and Institutions—A View from MARS,IMF Working Paper 06/27 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mehlum, Halvor, Karl Ove Moene, and Ragnar Torvik, 2006, “Institutions and the Resource Curse,Economic Journal, Vol . 116 (January), pp . 120.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Oxford Policy Management (OPM), 2000, “Medium-Term Expenditure Frameworks—Panacea or Dangerous Distraction?OPM Review Paper No. 2 (Oxford, May).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Potter, Barry, and Jack Diamond, 1999, Guidelines for Public Expenditure Management (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Rodrik, Dani, 2006, “The Social Cost of Foreign Exchange Reserves,NBER Working Paper No. 11952 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feridoun Sarraf, 2005, Integration of Recurrent and Capital “Development” Budgets: Issues, Problems, Country Experiences, and the Way Forward (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schick, Allen 1998, A Contemporary Approach to Public Expenditure Management (Washington: World Bank).

  • Herman, Schwartz, 1997, “Reinvention and Retrenchment: Lessons from the Application of the New Zealand Model to Alberta, Canada,Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, Vol . 16 (Summer), pp. 40522.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Spackman, Michael, 2002, “Multi-Year Perspective in Budgeting and Public Investment Planning,” draft background paper for discussion at the OECD Global Forum on Sustainable Development, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris, April 2426.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Takizawa, Hajime, Gardner, Edward and Kenichi Ueda, 2004, “Are Developing Countries Better Off Spending Their Oil Wealth Upfront?IMF Working Paper 04/141 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tornell, Aaron, and Philip R. Lane, 1999, “The Voracity Effect,American Economic Review, Vol . 89 (March), pp. 2246.

  • United States Department of Energy, 1982, “1981 Annual Report to Congress, Vol. 3, Energy Projections” (Washington: Energy Information Administration).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States Department of Energy, 1986, “Annual Energy Outlook 1985, with Projections to 1995” (Washington: Energy Information Administration).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States Department of Energy, 1989, “Annual Energy Outlook 1989 with Projections to 2000” (Washington: Energy Information Administration).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 1998, Public Expenditure Management Handbook (Washington).

  • World Bank, 2005, “The Medium-Term Expenditure Framework: The Challenges of Budget Integration in SSA Countries,Africa Region Working Paper No. 82 (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2006, Experiences with Oil Funds: Institutional and Financial Aspects, Energy Sector Management Assistance Program Report No. 321/06 (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation