Global Economic Environment
The global economy expanded vigorously in 2006, growing 5.4 percent—¼ percentage point faster than anticipated at the time of the September 2006 World Economic Outlook (Table 1.1 and Figure 1.2). Activity in the United States faced strong headwinds from a sharp downturn in the housing market, while corporate investment in plant and equipment has also softened.
Current and Forward-Looking Indicators
(Percent change from a year ago unless otherwise noted)
Industrial production and trade indicators suggest that the pace of global expansion has eased somewhat since mid-2006, although generally positive readings on confidence continue to augur well for short-term prospects.
Sources: Business confidence for the United States, the Institute for Supply Management; for the euro area, the European Commission; and for Japan, Bank of Japan. Consumer confidence for the United States, the Conference Board; for the euro area, the European Commission; and for Japan, Cabinet Office; all others, Haver Analytics.1Australia, Canada, Denmark, euro area, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.2Argentina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Colombia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Latvia, Lithuania, Malaysia, Mexico, Pakistan, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Romania, Russia, Singapore, Slovak Republic, South Africa, Taiwan Province of China, Thailand, Turkey, Ukraine, and Venezuela.3Japan’s consumer confidence data are based on a diffusion index, where values greater than 50 indicate improving confidence.4Data for China, India, Pakistan, and Russia are interpolated.Current and Forward-Looking Indicators
(Percent change from a year ago unless otherwise noted)
Industrial production and trade indicators suggest that the pace of global expansion has eased somewhat since mid-2006, although generally positive readings on confidence continue to augur well for short-term prospects.
Sources: Business confidence for the United States, the Institute for Supply Management; for the euro area, the European Commission; and for Japan, Bank of Japan. Consumer confidence for the United States, the Conference Board; for the euro area, the European Commission; and for Japan, Cabinet Office; all others, Haver Analytics.1Australia, Canada, Denmark, euro area, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.2Argentina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Colombia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Latvia, Lithuania, Malaysia, Mexico, Pakistan, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Romania, Russia, Singapore, Slovak Republic, South Africa, Taiwan Province of China, Thailand, Turkey, Ukraine, and Venezuela.3Japan’s consumer confidence data are based on a diffusion index, where values greater than 50 indicate improving confidence.4Data for China, India, Pakistan, and Russia are interpolated.Current and Forward-Looking Indicators
(Percent change from a year ago unless otherwise noted)
Industrial production and trade indicators suggest that the pace of global expansion has eased somewhat since mid-2006, although generally positive readings on confidence continue to augur well for short-term prospects.
Sources: Business confidence for the United States, the Institute for Supply Management; for the euro area, the European Commission; and for Japan, Bank of Japan. Consumer confidence for the United States, the Conference Board; for the euro area, the European Commission; and for Japan, Cabinet Office; all others, Haver Analytics.1Australia, Canada, Denmark, euro area, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.2Argentina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Colombia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Latvia, Lithuania, Malaysia, Mexico, Pakistan, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Romania, Russia, Singapore, Slovak Republic, South Africa, Taiwan Province of China, Thailand, Turkey, Ukraine, and Venezuela.3Japan’s consumer confidence data are based on a diffusion index, where values greater than 50 indicate improving confidence.4Data for China, India, Pakistan, and Russia are interpolated.Overview of the World Economic Outlook Projections
(Annual percent change unless otherwise noted)
Simple average of spot prices of U.K. Brent, Dubai, and West Texas Intermediate crude oil. The average price of oil in U.S. dollars a barrel was $64.27 in 2006; the assumed price is $60.75 in 2007 and $64.75 in 2008.
Six-month rate for the United States and Japan. Three-month rate for the euro area.
Overview of the World Economic Outlook Projections
(Annual percent change unless otherwise noted)
Current Projections | Difference from September 2006 Projections | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
2005 | 2006 | 2007 | 2008 | 2007 | 2008 | |||
World output | 4.9 | 5.4 | 4.9 | 4.9 | — | — | ||
Advanced economies | 2.5 | 3.1 | 2.5 | 2.7 | -0.2 | — | ||
United States | 3.2 | 3.3 | 2.2 | 2.8 | -0.7 | -0.4 | ||
Euro area | 1.4 | 2.6 | 2.3 | 2.3 | 0.3 | 0.3 | ||
Germany | 0.9 | 2.7 | 1.8 | 1.9 | 0.6 | 0.4 | ||
France | 1.2 | 2.0 | 2.0 | 2.4 | -0.2 | — | ||
Italy | 0.1 | 1.9 | 1.8 | 1.7 | 0.5 | 0.3 | ||
Spain | 3.5 | 3.9 | 3.6 | 3.4 | 0.6 | 0.3 | ||
Japan | 1.9 | 2.2 | 2.3 | 1.9 | 0.2 | -0.1 | ||
United Kingdom | 1.9 | 2.7 | 2.9 | 2.7 | 0.1 | 0.2 | ||
Canada | 2.9 | 2.7 | 2.4 | 2.9 | -0.5 | 0.1 | ||
Other advanced economies | 3.9 | 4.3 | 3.8 | 3.8 | 0.1 | 0.1 | ||
Newly industrialized Asian economies | 4.7 | 5.3 | 4.6 | 4.6 | 0.2 | 0.2 | ||
Other emerging market and developing countries | 7.5 | 7.9 | 7.5 | 7.1 | 0.3 | 0.2 | ||
Africa | 5.6 | 5.5 | 6.2 | 5.8 | 0.3 | 0.5 | ||
Sub-Sahara | 6.0 | 5.7 | 6.8 | 6.1 | 0.5 | 0.7 | ||
Central and eastern Europe | 5.5 | 6.0 | 5.5 | 5.3 | 0.5 | 0.5 | ||
Commonwealth of Independent States | 6.6 | 7.7 | 7.0 | 6.4 | 0.5 | 0.2 | ||
Russia | 6.4 | 6.7 | 6.4 | 5.9 | -0.1 | -0.2 | ||
Excluding Russia | 6.9 | 9.7 | 8.3 | 7.5 | 1.9 | 1.1 | ||
Developing Asia | 9.2 | 9.4 | 8.8 | 8.4 | 0.2 | 0.1 | ||
China | 10.4 | 10.7 | 10.0 | 9.5 | — | — | ||
India | 9.2 | 9.2 | 8.4 | 7.8 | 1.1 | 0.7 | ||
ASEAN-4 | 5.2 | 5.4 | 5.5 | 5.8 | -0.1 | -0.2 | ||
Middle East | 5.4 | 5.7 | 5.5 | 5.5 | 0.2 | — | ||
Western Hemisphere | 4.6 | 5.5 | 4.9 | 4.2 | 0.6 | 0.4 | ||
Brazil | 2.9 | 3.7 | 4.4 | 4.2 | 0.5 | 0.3 | ||
Mexico | 2.8 | 4.8 | 3.4 | 3.5 | -0.1 | — | ||
Memorandum | ||||||||
European Union | 1.9 | 3.2 | 2.8 | 2.7 | 0.4 | 0.3 | ||
World growth based on market exchange rates | 3.3 | 3.9 | 3.4 | 3.5 | — | — | ||
World trade volume (goods and services) | 7.4 | 9.2 | 7.0 | 7.4 | -0.7 | 0.2 | ||
Imports | ||||||||
Advanced economies | 6.1 | 7.4 | 4.7 | 5.7 | -1.3 | 0.1 | ||
Other emerging market and developing countries | 12.1 | 15.0 | 12.5 | 12.2 | 0.4 | 1.1 | ||
Exports | ||||||||
Advanced economies | 5.6 | 8.4 | 5.5 | 5.8 | -0.5 | 0.1 | ||
Other emerging market and developing countries | 11.2 | 10.6 | 10.4 | 9.9 | -0.2 | — | ||
Commodity prices (U.S. dollars) | ||||||||
Oil1 | 41.3 | 20.5 | -5.5 | 6.6 | -14.6 | 8.2 | ||
Nonfuel (average based on world commodity export weights) | 10.3 | 28.4 | 4.2 | -8.8 | 9.0 | 0.3 | ||
Consumer prices | ||||||||
Advanced economies | 2.3 | 2.3 | 1.8 | 2.1 | -0.6 | -0.1 | ||
Other emerging market and developing countries | 5.4 | 5.3 | 5.4 | 4.9 | 0.3 | 0.3 | ||
London interbank offered rate (percent)2 | ||||||||
On U.S. dollar deposits | 3.8 | 5.3 | 5.3 | 5.1 | -0.2 | -0.4 | ||
On euro deposits | 2.2 | 3.1 | 3.8 | 3.7 | 0.1 | -0.1 | ||
On Japanese yen deposits | 0.1 | 0.4 | 0.9 | 1.2 | -0.2 | -0.3 |
Simple average of spot prices of U.K. Brent, Dubai, and West Texas Intermediate crude oil. The average price of oil in U.S. dollars a barrel was $64.27 in 2006; the assumed price is $60.75 in 2007 and $64.75 in 2008.
Six-month rate for the United States and Japan. Three-month rate for the euro area.
Overview of the World Economic Outlook Projections
(Annual percent change unless otherwise noted)
Current Projections | Difference from September 2006 Projections | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
2005 | 2006 | 2007 | 2008 | 2007 | 2008 | |||
World output | 4.9 | 5.4 | 4.9 | 4.9 | — | — | ||
Advanced economies | 2.5 | 3.1 | 2.5 | 2.7 | -0.2 | — | ||
United States | 3.2 | 3.3 | 2.2 | 2.8 | -0.7 | -0.4 | ||
Euro area | 1.4 | 2.6 | 2.3 | 2.3 | 0.3 | 0.3 | ||
Germany | 0.9 | 2.7 | 1.8 | 1.9 | 0.6 | 0.4 | ||
France | 1.2 | 2.0 | 2.0 | 2.4 | -0.2 | — | ||
Italy | 0.1 | 1.9 | 1.8 | 1.7 | 0.5 | 0.3 | ||
Spain | 3.5 | 3.9 | 3.6 | 3.4 | 0.6 | 0.3 | ||
Japan | 1.9 | 2.2 | 2.3 | 1.9 | 0.2 | -0.1 | ||
United Kingdom | 1.9 | 2.7 | 2.9 | 2.7 | 0.1 | 0.2 | ||
Canada | 2.9 | 2.7 | 2.4 | 2.9 | -0.5 | 0.1 | ||
Other advanced economies | 3.9 | 4.3 | 3.8 | 3.8 | 0.1 | 0.1 | ||
Newly industrialized Asian economies | 4.7 | 5.3 | 4.6 | 4.6 | 0.2 | 0.2 | ||
Other emerging market and developing countries | 7.5 | 7.9 | 7.5 | 7.1 | 0.3 | 0.2 | ||
Africa | 5.6 | 5.5 | 6.2 | 5.8 | 0.3 | 0.5 | ||
Sub-Sahara | 6.0 | 5.7 | 6.8 | 6.1 | 0.5 | 0.7 | ||
Central and eastern Europe | 5.5 | 6.0 | 5.5 | 5.3 | 0.5 | 0.5 | ||
Commonwealth of Independent States | 6.6 | 7.7 | 7.0 | 6.4 | 0.5 | 0.2 | ||
Russia | 6.4 | 6.7 | 6.4 | 5.9 | -0.1 | -0.2 | ||
Excluding Russia | 6.9 | 9.7 | 8.3 | 7.5 | 1.9 | 1.1 | ||
Developing Asia | 9.2 | 9.4 | 8.8 | 8.4 | 0.2 | 0.1 | ||
China | 10.4 | 10.7 | 10.0 | 9.5 | — | — | ||
India | 9.2 | 9.2 | 8.4 | 7.8 | 1.1 | 0.7 | ||
ASEAN-4 | 5.2 | 5.4 | 5.5 | 5.8 | -0.1 | -0.2 | ||
Middle East | 5.4 | 5.7 | 5.5 | 5.5 | 0.2 | — | ||
Western Hemisphere | 4.6 | 5.5 | 4.9 | 4.2 | 0.6 | 0.4 | ||
Brazil | 2.9 | 3.7 | 4.4 | 4.2 | 0.5 | 0.3 | ||
Mexico | 2.8 | 4.8 | 3.4 | 3.5 | -0.1 | — | ||
Memorandum | ||||||||
European Union | 1.9 | 3.2 | 2.8 | 2.7 | 0.4 | 0.3 | ||
World growth based on market exchange rates | 3.3 | 3.9 | 3.4 | 3.5 | — | — | ||
World trade volume (goods and services) | 7.4 | 9.2 | 7.0 | 7.4 | -0.7 | 0.2 | ||
Imports | ||||||||
Advanced economies | 6.1 | 7.4 | 4.7 | 5.7 | -1.3 | 0.1 | ||
Other emerging market and developing countries | 12.1 | 15.0 | 12.5 | 12.2 | 0.4 | 1.1 | ||
Exports | ||||||||
Advanced economies | 5.6 | 8.4 | 5.5 | 5.8 | -0.5 | 0.1 | ||
Other emerging market and developing countries | 11.2 | 10.6 | 10.4 | 9.9 | -0.2 | — | ||
Commodity prices (U.S. dollars) | ||||||||
Oil1 | 41.3 | 20.5 | -5.5 | 6.6 | -14.6 | 8.2 | ||
Nonfuel (average based on world commodity export weights) | 10.3 | 28.4 | 4.2 | -8.8 | 9.0 | 0.3 | ||
Consumer prices | ||||||||
Advanced economies | 2.3 | 2.3 | 1.8 | 2.1 | -0.6 | -0.1 | ||
Other emerging market and developing countries | 5.4 | 5.3 | 5.4 | 4.9 | 0.3 | 0.3 | ||
London interbank offered rate (percent)2 | ||||||||
On U.S. dollar deposits | 3.8 | 5.3 | 5.3 | 5.1 | -0.2 | -0.4 | ||
On euro deposits | 2.2 | 3.1 | 3.8 | 3.7 | 0.1 | -0.1 | ||
On Japanese yen deposits | 0.1 | 0.4 | 0.9 | 1.2 | -0.2 | -0.3 |
Simple average of spot prices of U.K. Brent, Dubai, and West Texas Intermediate crude oil. The average price of oil in U.S. dollars a barrel was $64.27 in 2006; the assumed price is $60.75 in 2007 and $64.75 in 2008.
Six-month rate for the United States and Japan. Three-month rate for the euro area.
However, consumption was sustained by continued employment growth (especially in the services sector) and oil prices declining from August highs. In the euro area, growth accelerated to its fastest pace in six years as domestic demand was boosted by increasing business confidence and improving labor markets, as well as special factors—including the Soccer World Cup and the boost to consumption in advance of a value-added tax (VAT) increase in Germany in January 2007. Activity in Japan slowed in the middle of the year, but regained traction toward year-end.
Rapid growth in emerging market and developing countries was led by China and India. China’s growth rate reached 10¾ percent in 2006, driven by investment and export growth, notwithstanding some easing in the second half as policy tightening helped to cool the pace of fixed asset investment. India’s expansion picked up momentum in the course of the year, with year-on-year growth rising to 9¼ percent. Elsewhere, growth was also generally sustained at robust rates, supported by high commodity prices and favorable financial conditions.
Strong growth and rising international oil prices in the first half of 2006 raised concerns about inflation, but pressures moderated in the second half, dampened by monetary policy tightening and the turnaround in oil markets (Figure 1.3). The oil price declines from August largely reflected some easing of security tensions in the Middle East, improved supply-demand balance in oil markets, and favorable weather conditions in the second half of 2006 (Appendix 1.1). In the advanced economies, headline CPI inflation dropped quite sharply after the summer as fuel costs fell. The core CPI inflation rate (excluding food and energy) also eased modestly in the United States, although remaining somewhat above the Federal Reserve’s implicit comfort zone. The Fed has kept the Federal funds rate on hold since June, seeking to balance risks from a cooling economy and continuing concerns about inflation. In Japan, downward revision of the CPI series has left inflation readings still uncomfortably close to zero, and the Bank of Japan has raised its policy interest rate only very gradually since exiting its zero interest rate policy in July 2006. The European Central Bank (ECB), the Bank of England, and other central banks in Europe have continued to remove monetary accommodation in the context of economic buoyancy. Some emerging market countries—including China, India, and Turkey—have tightened monetary conditions in the face of concerns about over-rapid growth, overheating, and (in the case of Turkey) external pressures, but, overall, inflation outcomes have continued to be favorable.
Global Inflation
(Annualized percent change of three-month moving average over previous three-month average, unless otherwise noted)
Measures of inflation and inflation expectations have generally moderated since mid-2006, helped by falling oil prices and some tightening of monetary conditions.
Sources: Haver Analytics; and IMF staff calculations.1Australia, Canada, Denmark, euro area, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the United States.2Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Estonia, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Poland, Singapore, South Africa, Taiwan Province of China, and Thailand.3In percent; nominal minus inflation-indexed yields on 10-year securities.Global Inflation
(Annualized percent change of three-month moving average over previous three-month average, unless otherwise noted)
Measures of inflation and inflation expectations have generally moderated since mid-2006, helped by falling oil prices and some tightening of monetary conditions.
Sources: Haver Analytics; and IMF staff calculations.1Australia, Canada, Denmark, euro area, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the United States.2Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Estonia, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Poland, Singapore, South Africa, Taiwan Province of China, and Thailand.3In percent; nominal minus inflation-indexed yields on 10-year securities.Global Inflation
(Annualized percent change of three-month moving average over previous three-month average, unless otherwise noted)
Measures of inflation and inflation expectations have generally moderated since mid-2006, helped by falling oil prices and some tightening of monetary conditions.
Sources: Haver Analytics; and IMF staff calculations.1Australia, Canada, Denmark, euro area, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the United States.2Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Estonia, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Poland, Singapore, South Africa, Taiwan Province of China, and Thailand.3In percent; nominal minus inflation-indexed yields on 10-year securities.Expectations of continued solid economic growth and fading inflation concerns contributed to buoyant global financial market conditions over most of the period since mid-2006. Markets have been more volatile since late February, but this recent episode seems to be more of a modest correction after a period of rising asset prices, rather than a fundamental change in market sentiment (see the April 2007 Global Financial Stability Report for further details). Notwithstanding recent declines, advanced economy equity markets remain close to all-time highs, supported by strong earnings growth (Figures 1.4 and 1.5). Long-term bond yields have generally receded since mid-2006, spreads on risky assets have narrowed in most market segments, and market volatility was extremely low until recently. Emerging bond and equity markets rebounded robustly from an earlier episode of turbulence in May–June 2006 as concerns about continued tightening of monetary policy in the United States eased, and remain at close to peak levels even after the recent correction (Figure 1.6). Capital flows to emerging markets were maintained at high levels in 2006 as a whole, with Asia and emerging Europe continuing to attract a large share of the flows and corporate borrowers replacing sovereigns as the main source of demand (Table 1.2).
Developments in Mature Financial Markets
Expectations of continued solid economic growth and moderating price concerns since mid-2006 have encouraged buoyant equity markets and declining long-term interest rates. Credit growth has eased somewhat but remains high.
Sources: Bloomberg Financial Markets, LP; CEIC Data Company Limited; Haver Analytics; OECD; IMF, International Financial Statistics; national authorities; and IMF staff calculations.1Ten-year government bond minus three-month treasury bill rate.Developments in Mature Financial Markets
Expectations of continued solid economic growth and moderating price concerns since mid-2006 have encouraged buoyant equity markets and declining long-term interest rates. Credit growth has eased somewhat but remains high.
Sources: Bloomberg Financial Markets, LP; CEIC Data Company Limited; Haver Analytics; OECD; IMF, International Financial Statistics; national authorities; and IMF staff calculations.1Ten-year government bond minus three-month treasury bill rate.Developments in Mature Financial Markets
Expectations of continued solid economic growth and moderating price concerns since mid-2006 have encouraged buoyant equity markets and declining long-term interest rates. Credit growth has eased somewhat but remains high.
Sources: Bloomberg Financial Markets, LP; CEIC Data Company Limited; Haver Analytics; OECD; IMF, International Financial Statistics; national authorities; and IMF staff calculations.1Ten-year government bond minus three-month treasury bill rate.Mature Financial Market Indicators
Real interest rates are generally below long-term averages, as are price-earnings ratios in equity markets and corporate spreads. Volatility has generally remained low.
Sources: Bloomberg Financial Markets, LP; Merrill Lynch; Thomson Financial; and IMF staff calculations.1Relative to headline inflation. Measured as deviations from 1990–2006 average.2Twelve-month forward-looking price-earnings ratios measured as three-month moving average of deviations from 1990–2007 (March) average.3Measured as three-month moving average of deviations from 2000–07 (March) average.4VIX is the Chicago Board Options Exchange volatility index. This index is calculated by taking a weighted average of implied volatility for the eight S&P 500 calls and puts.Mature Financial Market Indicators
Real interest rates are generally below long-term averages, as are price-earnings ratios in equity markets and corporate spreads. Volatility has generally remained low.
Sources: Bloomberg Financial Markets, LP; Merrill Lynch; Thomson Financial; and IMF staff calculations.1Relative to headline inflation. Measured as deviations from 1990–2006 average.2Twelve-month forward-looking price-earnings ratios measured as three-month moving average of deviations from 1990–2007 (March) average.3Measured as three-month moving average of deviations from 2000–07 (March) average.4VIX is the Chicago Board Options Exchange volatility index. This index is calculated by taking a weighted average of implied volatility for the eight S&P 500 calls and puts.Mature Financial Market Indicators
Real interest rates are generally below long-term averages, as are price-earnings ratios in equity markets and corporate spreads. Volatility has generally remained low.
Sources: Bloomberg Financial Markets, LP; Merrill Lynch; Thomson Financial; and IMF staff calculations.1Relative to headline inflation. Measured as deviations from 1990–2006 average.2Twelve-month forward-looking price-earnings ratios measured as three-month moving average of deviations from 1990–2007 (March) average.3Measured as three-month moving average of deviations from 2000–07 (March) average.4VIX is the Chicago Board Options Exchange volatility index. This index is calculated by taking a weighted average of implied volatility for the eight S&P 500 calls and puts.Emerging Market Financial Conditions
Emerging markets have generally remained buoyant, despite recurrent bouts of market volatility. Equity prices in many emerging markets have recorded new highs, while sovereign risk spreads are close to all-time lows. Credit growth remains rapid.
Sources: Bloomberg Financial Markets, LP; Capital Data; IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff calculations.1Average of 30-day rolling cross-correlation of emerging market debt spreads.Emerging Market Financial Conditions
Emerging markets have generally remained buoyant, despite recurrent bouts of market volatility. Equity prices in many emerging markets have recorded new highs, while sovereign risk spreads are close to all-time lows. Credit growth remains rapid.
Sources: Bloomberg Financial Markets, LP; Capital Data; IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff calculations.1Average of 30-day rolling cross-correlation of emerging market debt spreads.Emerging Market Financial Conditions
Emerging markets have generally remained buoyant, despite recurrent bouts of market volatility. Equity prices in many emerging markets have recorded new highs, while sovereign risk spreads are close to all-time lows. Credit growth remains rapid.
Sources: Bloomberg Financial Markets, LP; Capital Data; IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff calculations.1Average of 30-day rolling cross-correlation of emerging market debt spreads.Emerging Market and Developing Countries: Net Capital Flows1
(Billions of U.S. dollars)
Net capital flows comprise net direct investment, net portfolio investment, and other long- and short-term net investment flows, including official and private borrowing. In this table, Hong Kong SAR, Israel, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China are included.
Because of data limitations, flows listed under “private capital flows, net” may include some official flows.
Excludes grants and includes overseas investments of official investment agencies.
A minus sign indicates an increase.
The sum of the current account balance, net private capital flows, net official flows, and the change in reserves equals, with the opposite sign, the sum of the capital account and errors and omissions. For regional current account balances, see Table 25 of the Statistical Appendix.
Historical data have been revised, reflecting cumulative data revisions for Russia and the resolution of a number of data interpretation issues.
Consists of developing Asia and the newly industrialized Asian economies.
Includes Israel.
Emerging Market and Developing Countries: Net Capital Flows1
(Billions of U.S. dollars)
1996–98 | 1999 | 2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 | 2006 | 2007 | 2008 | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Total | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 159.3 | 74.6 | 56.7 | 70.2 | 88.3 | 173.3 | 238.6 | 257.2 | 255.8 | 252.7 | 259.3 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 142.3 | 177.4 | 168.6 | 182.8 | 152.2 | 165.3 | 190.0 | 266.3 | 266.9 | 283.7 | 288.9 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 60.0 | 60.1 | 11.4 | -80.5 | -90.9 | -12.1 | 25.0 | 29.4 | -76.3 | -62.0 | -52.2 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | -43.0 | -162.9 | -123.4 | -32.1 | 26.9 | 20.1 | 23.5 | -38.5 | 65.2 | 30.9 | 22.6 | ||
Official flows, net3 | 20.2 | 22.4 | -34.2 | 6.6 | 2.3 | -44.5 | -57.8 | -122.6 | -143.8 | -96.4 | -116.6 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -72.6 | -98.2 | -131.2 | -120.6 | -198.9 | -358.9 | -508.2 | -590.1 | -738.4 | -715.5 | -716.4 | ||
Memorandum | |||||||||||||
Current account5 | -72.1 | 34.4 | 123.5 | 86.8 | 132.3 | 229.4 | 299.7 | 511.6 | 638.5 | 548.6 | 567.1 | ||
Africa | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 6.5 | 9.0 | -4.2 | 2.2 | 0.9 | 2.7 | 12.3 | 18.3 | 20.2 | 28.6 | 39.9 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 5.8 | 8.6 | 7.6 | 23.1 | 13.5 | 15.4 | 16.8 | 27.0 | 19.1 | 21.9 | 29.4 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 5.0 | 9.1 | -1.8 | -7.9 | -1.6 | -0.5 | 5.4 | 4.1 | 18.5 | 12.3 | 13.6 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | -4.3 | -8.7 | -10.0 | -13.0 | -11.0 | -12.2 | -9.8 | -12.8 | -17.4 | -5.7 | -3.1 | ||
Official flows, net3 | 5.0 | 4.1 | 7.7 | 6.5 | 8.6 | 6.4 | 4.3 | -1.8 | -3.8 | 10.1 | 10.8 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -4.2 | -0.4 | -12.8 | -9.7 | -5.5 | -11.4 | -32.7 | -42.3 | -48.4 | -44.9 | -56.3 | ||
Central and eastern Europe | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 27.4 | 36.3 | 38.7 | 10.9 | 54.0 | 52.5 | 74.7 | 117.5 | 121.1 | 109.0 | 117.7 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 14.9 | 22.7 | 24.1 | 24.0 | 24.1 | 16.2 | 34.5 | 50.1 | 65.8 | 62.6 | 62.0 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 1.7 | 5.3 | 3.1 | 0.4 | 1.7 | 6.5 | 26.9 | 20.9 | 8.1 | 12.1 | 14.4 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | 10.8 | 8.3 | 11.6 | -13.4 | 28.3 | 29.9 | 13.3 | 46.4 | 47.1 | 34.3 | 41.2 | ||
Official flows, net3 | -0.5 | -2.4 | 1.6 | 6.0 | -7.5 | -5.0 | -6.6 | -8.3 | -4.9 | -3.1 | -3.3 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -8.8 | -12.1 | -6.0 | -3.0 | -18.5 | -11.5 | -13.6 | -48.2 | -21.2 | -14.9 | -22.1 | ||
Commonwealth of Independent States6 | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | -5.3 | -13.5 | -27.6 | 7.2 | 15.8 | 17.9 | 7.7 | 37.6 | 65.7 | 38.0 | 28.6 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 5.5 | 4.7 | 2.3 | 4.9 | 5.2 | 5.4 | 12.9 | 14.4 | 33.1 | 22.2 | 26.1 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 2.2 | -0.9 | -10.0 | -1.2 | 0.4 | -0.5 | 8.1 | -3.1 | 13.9 | 0.4 | 0.3 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | -13.0 | -17.3 | -19.9 | 3.5 | 10.2 | 13.0 | -13.4 | 26.3 | 18.8 | 15.4 | 2.1 | ||
Official flows, net3 | -1.0 | -1.8 | -5.8 | -4.9 | -10.4 | -8.9 | -7.3 | -22.1 | -32.6 | -3.6 | -4.3 | ||
Change in reserves4 | 5.1 | -6.4 | -20.3 | -14.5 | -15.1 | -31.8 | -53.8 | -75.6 | -126.9 | -108.4 | -98.7 | ||
Emerging Asia7 | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 36.9 | -1.9 | 4.5 | 23.5 | 25.4 | 69.2 | 142.5 | 69.7 | 53.9 | 30.7 | -5.8 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 56.0 | 70.9 | 59.8 | 52.0 | 52.6 | 73.1 | 68.0 | 105.8 | 102.4 | 96.1 | 94.1 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 16.0 | 54.1 | 19.6 | -50.2 | -60.1 | 7.8 | 11.2 | -8.1 | -99.4 | -78.9 | -88.8 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | -35.1 | -127.0 | -74.8 | 21.6 | 32.8 | -11.6 | 63.4 | -27.9 | 50.9 | 13.5 | -11.1 | ||
Official flows, net3 | 5.9 | 8.5 | -10.9 | -12.0 | 4.1 | -16.6 | -7.0 | -2.8 | -9.8 | -5.4 | -7.5 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -45.1 | -84.8 | -59.1 | -85.4 | -154.3 | -234.3 | -339.0 | -284.1 | -365.6 | -410.6 | -424.0 | ||
Middle East8 | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 11.8 | -3.8 | -10.0 | -5.5 | -19.4 | 4.7 | -12.0 | -19.9 | -15.5 | 14.4 | 34.8 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 7.0 | 4.4 | 4.9 | 12.3 | 9.7 | 17.8 | 8.8 | 17.6 | 12.0 | 19.6 | 18.2 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 0.5 | -8.6 | -1.2 | -13.5 | -17.4 | -14.9 | -14.0 | -14.9 | -5.0 | -3.3 | 4.4 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | 4.3 | 0.4 | -13.7 | -4.3 | -11.6 | 1.8 | -6.8 | -22.5 | -22.5 | -1.9 | 12.2 | ||
Official flows, net3 | 5.2 | 8.0 | -20.5 | -14.2 | -9.8 | -24.6 | -32.5 | -57.1 | -75.0 | -93.2 | -112.0 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -8.1 | -2.0 | -31.2 | -11.6 | -3.1 | -33.7 | -45.7 | -106.6 | -129.7 | -79.4 | -75.9 | ||
Western Hemisphere | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 82.0 | 48.5 | 55.2 | 31.9 | 11.5 | 26.2 | 13.3 | 33.9 | 10.4 | 32.0 | 44.2 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 53.1 | 66.1 | 70.0 | 66.5 | 47.2 | 37.5 | 49.1 | 51.4 | 34.5 | 61.3 | 59.1 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 34.6 | 1.0 | 1.7 | -8.1 | -13.9 | -10.5 | -12.5 | 30.5 | -12.4 | -4.6 | 3.9 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | -5.7 | -18.6 | -16.5 | -26.5 | -21.8 | -0.9 | -23.3 | -48.0 | -11.6 | -24.7 | -18.8 | ||
Official flows, net3 | 5.6 | 6.2 | -6.4 | 25.2 | 17.4 | 4.3 | -8.7 | -30.4 | -17.7 | -1.2 | -0.4 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -11.4 | 7.4 | -1.8 | 3.5 | -2.4 | -36.2 | -23.4 | -33.4 | -46.5 | -57.4 | -39.3 | ||
Memorandum | |||||||||||||
Fuel-exporting countries | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | -5.4 | -27.2 | -57.0 | -12.7 | -11.2 | 12.7 | -14.9 | -6.8 | -2.6 | 11.1 | 36.4 | ||
Other countries | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 164.8 | 101.8 | 113.6 | 82.9 | 99.5 | 160.6 | 253.4 | 264.0 | 258.4 | 241.6 | 223.0 |
Net capital flows comprise net direct investment, net portfolio investment, and other long- and short-term net investment flows, including official and private borrowing. In this table, Hong Kong SAR, Israel, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China are included.
Because of data limitations, flows listed under “private capital flows, net” may include some official flows.
Excludes grants and includes overseas investments of official investment agencies.
A minus sign indicates an increase.
The sum of the current account balance, net private capital flows, net official flows, and the change in reserves equals, with the opposite sign, the sum of the capital account and errors and omissions. For regional current account balances, see Table 25 of the Statistical Appendix.
Historical data have been revised, reflecting cumulative data revisions for Russia and the resolution of a number of data interpretation issues.
Consists of developing Asia and the newly industrialized Asian economies.
Includes Israel.
Emerging Market and Developing Countries: Net Capital Flows1
(Billions of U.S. dollars)
1996–98 | 1999 | 2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 | 2006 | 2007 | 2008 | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Total | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 159.3 | 74.6 | 56.7 | 70.2 | 88.3 | 173.3 | 238.6 | 257.2 | 255.8 | 252.7 | 259.3 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 142.3 | 177.4 | 168.6 | 182.8 | 152.2 | 165.3 | 190.0 | 266.3 | 266.9 | 283.7 | 288.9 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 60.0 | 60.1 | 11.4 | -80.5 | -90.9 | -12.1 | 25.0 | 29.4 | -76.3 | -62.0 | -52.2 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | -43.0 | -162.9 | -123.4 | -32.1 | 26.9 | 20.1 | 23.5 | -38.5 | 65.2 | 30.9 | 22.6 | ||
Official flows, net3 | 20.2 | 22.4 | -34.2 | 6.6 | 2.3 | -44.5 | -57.8 | -122.6 | -143.8 | -96.4 | -116.6 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -72.6 | -98.2 | -131.2 | -120.6 | -198.9 | -358.9 | -508.2 | -590.1 | -738.4 | -715.5 | -716.4 | ||
Memorandum | |||||||||||||
Current account5 | -72.1 | 34.4 | 123.5 | 86.8 | 132.3 | 229.4 | 299.7 | 511.6 | 638.5 | 548.6 | 567.1 | ||
Africa | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 6.5 | 9.0 | -4.2 | 2.2 | 0.9 | 2.7 | 12.3 | 18.3 | 20.2 | 28.6 | 39.9 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 5.8 | 8.6 | 7.6 | 23.1 | 13.5 | 15.4 | 16.8 | 27.0 | 19.1 | 21.9 | 29.4 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 5.0 | 9.1 | -1.8 | -7.9 | -1.6 | -0.5 | 5.4 | 4.1 | 18.5 | 12.3 | 13.6 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | -4.3 | -8.7 | -10.0 | -13.0 | -11.0 | -12.2 | -9.8 | -12.8 | -17.4 | -5.7 | -3.1 | ||
Official flows, net3 | 5.0 | 4.1 | 7.7 | 6.5 | 8.6 | 6.4 | 4.3 | -1.8 | -3.8 | 10.1 | 10.8 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -4.2 | -0.4 | -12.8 | -9.7 | -5.5 | -11.4 | -32.7 | -42.3 | -48.4 | -44.9 | -56.3 | ||
Central and eastern Europe | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 27.4 | 36.3 | 38.7 | 10.9 | 54.0 | 52.5 | 74.7 | 117.5 | 121.1 | 109.0 | 117.7 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 14.9 | 22.7 | 24.1 | 24.0 | 24.1 | 16.2 | 34.5 | 50.1 | 65.8 | 62.6 | 62.0 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 1.7 | 5.3 | 3.1 | 0.4 | 1.7 | 6.5 | 26.9 | 20.9 | 8.1 | 12.1 | 14.4 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | 10.8 | 8.3 | 11.6 | -13.4 | 28.3 | 29.9 | 13.3 | 46.4 | 47.1 | 34.3 | 41.2 | ||
Official flows, net3 | -0.5 | -2.4 | 1.6 | 6.0 | -7.5 | -5.0 | -6.6 | -8.3 | -4.9 | -3.1 | -3.3 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -8.8 | -12.1 | -6.0 | -3.0 | -18.5 | -11.5 | -13.6 | -48.2 | -21.2 | -14.9 | -22.1 | ||
Commonwealth of Independent States6 | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | -5.3 | -13.5 | -27.6 | 7.2 | 15.8 | 17.9 | 7.7 | 37.6 | 65.7 | 38.0 | 28.6 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 5.5 | 4.7 | 2.3 | 4.9 | 5.2 | 5.4 | 12.9 | 14.4 | 33.1 | 22.2 | 26.1 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 2.2 | -0.9 | -10.0 | -1.2 | 0.4 | -0.5 | 8.1 | -3.1 | 13.9 | 0.4 | 0.3 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | -13.0 | -17.3 | -19.9 | 3.5 | 10.2 | 13.0 | -13.4 | 26.3 | 18.8 | 15.4 | 2.1 | ||
Official flows, net3 | -1.0 | -1.8 | -5.8 | -4.9 | -10.4 | -8.9 | -7.3 | -22.1 | -32.6 | -3.6 | -4.3 | ||
Change in reserves4 | 5.1 | -6.4 | -20.3 | -14.5 | -15.1 | -31.8 | -53.8 | -75.6 | -126.9 | -108.4 | -98.7 | ||
Emerging Asia7 | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 36.9 | -1.9 | 4.5 | 23.5 | 25.4 | 69.2 | 142.5 | 69.7 | 53.9 | 30.7 | -5.8 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 56.0 | 70.9 | 59.8 | 52.0 | 52.6 | 73.1 | 68.0 | 105.8 | 102.4 | 96.1 | 94.1 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 16.0 | 54.1 | 19.6 | -50.2 | -60.1 | 7.8 | 11.2 | -8.1 | -99.4 | -78.9 | -88.8 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | -35.1 | -127.0 | -74.8 | 21.6 | 32.8 | -11.6 | 63.4 | -27.9 | 50.9 | 13.5 | -11.1 | ||
Official flows, net3 | 5.9 | 8.5 | -10.9 | -12.0 | 4.1 | -16.6 | -7.0 | -2.8 | -9.8 | -5.4 | -7.5 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -45.1 | -84.8 | -59.1 | -85.4 | -154.3 | -234.3 | -339.0 | -284.1 | -365.6 | -410.6 | -424.0 | ||
Middle East8 | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 11.8 | -3.8 | -10.0 | -5.5 | -19.4 | 4.7 | -12.0 | -19.9 | -15.5 | 14.4 | 34.8 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 7.0 | 4.4 | 4.9 | 12.3 | 9.7 | 17.8 | 8.8 | 17.6 | 12.0 | 19.6 | 18.2 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 0.5 | -8.6 | -1.2 | -13.5 | -17.4 | -14.9 | -14.0 | -14.9 | -5.0 | -3.3 | 4.4 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | 4.3 | 0.4 | -13.7 | -4.3 | -11.6 | 1.8 | -6.8 | -22.5 | -22.5 | -1.9 | 12.2 | ||
Official flows, net3 | 5.2 | 8.0 | -20.5 | -14.2 | -9.8 | -24.6 | -32.5 | -57.1 | -75.0 | -93.2 | -112.0 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -8.1 | -2.0 | -31.2 | -11.6 | -3.1 | -33.7 | -45.7 | -106.6 | -129.7 | -79.4 | -75.9 | ||
Western Hemisphere | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 82.0 | 48.5 | 55.2 | 31.9 | 11.5 | 26.2 | 13.3 | 33.9 | 10.4 | 32.0 | 44.2 | ||
Private direct investment, net | 53.1 | 66.1 | 70.0 | 66.5 | 47.2 | 37.5 | 49.1 | 51.4 | 34.5 | 61.3 | 59.1 | ||
Private portfolio flows, net | 34.6 | 1.0 | 1.7 | -8.1 | -13.9 | -10.5 | -12.5 | 30.5 | -12.4 | -4.6 | 3.9 | ||
Other private capital flows, net | -5.7 | -18.6 | -16.5 | -26.5 | -21.8 | -0.9 | -23.3 | -48.0 | -11.6 | -24.7 | -18.8 | ||
Official flows, net3 | 5.6 | 6.2 | -6.4 | 25.2 | 17.4 | 4.3 | -8.7 | -30.4 | -17.7 | -1.2 | -0.4 | ||
Change in reserves4 | -11.4 | 7.4 | -1.8 | 3.5 | -2.4 | -36.2 | -23.4 | -33.4 | -46.5 | -57.4 | -39.3 | ||
Memorandum | |||||||||||||
Fuel-exporting countries | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | -5.4 | -27.2 | -57.0 | -12.7 | -11.2 | 12.7 | -14.9 | -6.8 | -2.6 | 11.1 | 36.4 | ||
Other countries | |||||||||||||
Private capital flows, net2 | 164.8 | 101.8 | 113.6 | 82.9 | 99.5 | 160.6 | 253.4 | 264.0 | 258.4 | 241.6 | 223.0 |
Net capital flows comprise net direct investment, net portfolio investment, and other long- and short-term net investment flows, including official and private borrowing. In this table, Hong Kong SAR, Israel, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China are included.
Because of data limitations, flows listed under “private capital flows, net” may include some official flows.
Excludes grants and includes overseas investments of official investment agencies.
A minus sign indicates an increase.
The sum of the current account balance, net private capital flows, net official flows, and the change in reserves equals, with the opposite sign, the sum of the capital account and errors and omissions. For regional current account balances, see Table 25 of the Statistical Appendix.
Historical data have been revised, reflecting cumulative data revisions for Russia and the resolution of a number of data interpretation issues.
Consists of developing Asia and the newly industrialized Asian economies.
Includes Israel.
In foreign exchange markets, slower growth in the United States and the robust expansion in western Europe have fed expectations of narrowing interest rate differentials and contributed to a weakening of the U.S. dollar mainly against the euro and pound sterling. Over 2006 as a whole, the U.S. dollar depreciated by 4 percent in real effective terms, while the euro and pound sterling appreciated by around 7 percent (Figure 1.7). The yen also weakened further in 2006, notwithstanding Japan’s rising current account surplus, as declining “home bias” among domestic investors and low interest rates continued to encourage capital outflows. However, it recovered some ground in early 2007, as heightened market volatility contributed to some unwinding of carry trade outflows. The renminbi depreciated slightly in real effective terms despite a mild acceleration in its rate of appreciation against the dollar in recent months and a further rise in China’s current account surplus to 9 percent of GDP (Figure 1.8). The real effective value of Middle Eastern oil exporters’ currencies depreciated moderately, although strong growth in oil exports drove the current account surplus of these countries to 21 percent of GDP.
External Developments in Major Advanced Economies
The U.S. dollar has depreciated modestly in real effective terms since late 2005, but the U.S. current account deficit has remained wide. The euro area’s current account is close to balance, while the euro has appreciated. Japan retains a sizable current account surplus, while the real effective value of the yen has depreciated significantly below its long-term average.
Sources: Haver Analytics; and IMF staff calculations.External Developments in Major Advanced Economies
The U.S. dollar has depreciated modestly in real effective terms since late 2005, but the U.S. current account deficit has remained wide. The euro area’s current account is close to balance, while the euro has appreciated. Japan retains a sizable current account surplus, while the real effective value of the yen has depreciated significantly below its long-term average.
Sources: Haver Analytics; and IMF staff calculations.External Developments in Major Advanced Economies
The U.S. dollar has depreciated modestly in real effective terms since late 2005, but the U.S. current account deficit has remained wide. The euro area’s current account is close to balance, while the euro has appreciated. Japan retains a sizable current account surplus, while the real effective value of the yen has depreciated significantly below its long-term average.
Sources: Haver Analytics; and IMF staff calculations.External Developments in Emerging Market Countries
Movements in nominal exchange rates over the past year have generally moved real effective exchange rates in emerging market countries closer to historical averages. Current account surpluses in China and the Middle East have continued to rise.
Source: IMF staff calculations.1Newly industrialized economies (NIEs) include Hong Kong SAR, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China.2Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand.3Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland.4Botswana, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Chad, Republic of Congo, Côte d’Ivoire, Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Ethiopia, Gabon, Ghana, Guinea, Kenya, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, Senegal, South Africa, Sudan, Tanzania, Uganda, and Zambia.5Bahrain, Egypt, I.R. of Iran, Jordan, Kuwait, Lebanon, Libya, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Syrian Arab Republic, United Arab Emirates, and Republic of Yemen.6Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela.External Developments in Emerging Market Countries
Movements in nominal exchange rates over the past year have generally moved real effective exchange rates in emerging market countries closer to historical averages. Current account surpluses in China and the Middle East have continued to rise.
Source: IMF staff calculations.1Newly industrialized economies (NIEs) include Hong Kong SAR, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China.2Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand.3Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland.4Botswana, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Chad, Republic of Congo, Côte d’Ivoire, Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Ethiopia, Gabon, Ghana, Guinea, Kenya, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, Senegal, South Africa, Sudan, Tanzania, Uganda, and Zambia.5Bahrain, Egypt, I.R. of Iran, Jordan, Kuwait, Lebanon, Libya, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Syrian Arab Republic, United Arab Emirates, and Republic of Yemen.6Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela.External Developments in Emerging Market Countries
Movements in nominal exchange rates over the past year have generally moved real effective exchange rates in emerging market countries closer to historical averages. Current account surpluses in China and the Middle East have continued to rise.
Source: IMF staff calculations.1Newly industrialized economies (NIEs) include Hong Kong SAR, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China.2Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand.3Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland.4Botswana, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Chad, Republic of Congo, Côte d’Ivoire, Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Ethiopia, Gabon, Ghana, Guinea, Kenya, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, Senegal, South Africa, Sudan, Tanzania, Uganda, and Zambia.5Bahrain, Egypt, I.R. of Iran, Jordan, Kuwait, Lebanon, Libya, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Syrian Arab Republic, United Arab Emirates, and Republic of Yemen.6Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela.Outlook and Short-Term Risks
The world economy is expected to continue to grow robustly in 2007 and 2008—with a modest deceleration from the rapid pace of 2006 bringing growth more in line with potential and helping to contain inflationary pressures in the fifth and sixth years of the current expansion. Specifically, global growth would moderate to 4.9 percent in 2007, around ½ percentage point less than in 2006 and in line with the rate forecast at the time of the September 2006 World Economic Outlook, and maintain this pace in 2008 (Figure 1.9). As discussed in more detail in Chapter 2, among the major advanced economies, the slowdown in year-over-year growth in 2007 would be most pronounced in the United States, although the U.S. economy should gather momentum in the course of the year and into 2008 as the drag from the housing sector moderates. Growth is also projected to ease in the euro area, reflecting in part gradual withdrawal of monetary accommodation and further fiscal consolidation, as well as the unwinding of special factors, while the expansion would continue at about the same pace in Japan.
Global Outlook
(Real GDP; percent change from four quarters earlier)
Following a banner year in 2006, world growth is expected to ease in 2007 and 2008, but remain at high levels.
Sources: Haver Analytics; and IMF staff estimates.1Australia, Canada, Denmark, euro area, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.2Newly industrialized economies (NIEs) include Hong Kong SAR, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China.3Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, and Poland.4Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela.Global Outlook
(Real GDP; percent change from four quarters earlier)
Following a banner year in 2006, world growth is expected to ease in 2007 and 2008, but remain at high levels.
Sources: Haver Analytics; and IMF staff estimates.1Australia, Canada, Denmark, euro area, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.2Newly industrialized economies (NIEs) include Hong Kong SAR, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China.3Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, and Poland.4Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela.Global Outlook
(Real GDP; percent change from four quarters earlier)
Following a banner year in 2006, world growth is expected to ease in 2007 and 2008, but remain at high levels.
Sources: Haver Analytics; and IMF staff estimates.1Australia, Canada, Denmark, euro area, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.2Newly industrialized economies (NIEs) include Hong Kong SAR, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China.3Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, and Poland.4Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela.Emerging market and developing countries would continue to grow strongly, albeit at a somewhat less torrid pace than in 2006, drawing continued support from benign global financial conditions and commodity prices that would remain high notwithstanding some recent declines. China’s growth would moderate gradually in 2007 and 2008 from its very high rate in 2006, while the pace of expansion would also ease in India, reflecting in part policy tightening in response to overheating concerns. Commodity-rich countries in Africa, the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), the Middle East, and Latin America would continue to prosper, with growth in Africa accelerating in 2007 as new oil fields come on stream. Countries in emerging Europe and also Mexico would be somewhat more affected by spillovers from slower growth in Europe and the United States.
Risks around this “soft landing” scenario seem more evenly balanced than at the time of the September 2006 World Economic Outlook, but remain weighted on the downside. As shown in the fan chart (upper panel of Figure 1.10), the IMF staff see about a one in five chance of growth falling below 4 percent in 2008. The accompanying risk factor chart (lower panel of Figure 1.10) depicts the IMF staff’s current assessment of the principal sources of risk to projected output growth over the next 12 months, relative to the assessment at the time of the September 2006 World Economic Outlook. Downside risks related to the U.S. housing sector, supply-side inflation pressures, the oil market, and from a possible disorderly adjustment of global imbalances are all seen to have receded somewhat in recent months, but they still raise concerns. Risks related to overexten-sion of financial markets are viewed as moderately increased. There continues to be upside potential that domestic demand in emerging markets could be higher than projected, while domestic demand is also seen as a source of upside potential in western Europe.
Risks to the Global Outlook
Risks to global growth now seem more balanced than six months ago, as downside risks related to the U.S. housing sector, inflationary pressures, and oil supply seem less threatening.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1The fan chart shows the uncertainty around the World Economic Outlook (WEO) central forecast with 50, 70, and 90 percent probability intervals. As shown, the 70 percent confidence interval includes the 50 percent interval, and the 90 percent confidence interval includes the 50 and 70 percent intervals. See Box 1.3 in the April 2006 World Economic Outlook for details.2The chart shows the contributions of each risk factor to the overall balance of risks to global growth, as reflected by the extent of asymmetry in the probability density for global GDP growth shown in the fan chart. The balance of risks is tilted to the downside if the expected probability of outcomes below the central or modal forecast (the total “downside probability”) exceeds 50 percent (Box 1.3 in the April 2006 World Economic Outlook). The bars for each forecast vintage sum up to the difference between the expected value of world growth implied by the distribution of outcomes (the probability density) shown in the fan chart and the central forecast for global GDP growth. This difference and the extent of asymmetry in the probability density in the fan chart also depend on the standard deviation of past forecast errors—which, among other factors, varies with the length of the forecasting horizon. To make the risk factors comparable across forecast vintages, their contributions are rescaled to correct for differences in the standard deviations.Risks to the Global Outlook
Risks to global growth now seem more balanced than six months ago, as downside risks related to the U.S. housing sector, inflationary pressures, and oil supply seem less threatening.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1The fan chart shows the uncertainty around the World Economic Outlook (WEO) central forecast with 50, 70, and 90 percent probability intervals. As shown, the 70 percent confidence interval includes the 50 percent interval, and the 90 percent confidence interval includes the 50 and 70 percent intervals. See Box 1.3 in the April 2006 World Economic Outlook for details.2The chart shows the contributions of each risk factor to the overall balance of risks to global growth, as reflected by the extent of asymmetry in the probability density for global GDP growth shown in the fan chart. The balance of risks is tilted to the downside if the expected probability of outcomes below the central or modal forecast (the total “downside probability”) exceeds 50 percent (Box 1.3 in the April 2006 World Economic Outlook). The bars for each forecast vintage sum up to the difference between the expected value of world growth implied by the distribution of outcomes (the probability density) shown in the fan chart and the central forecast for global GDP growth. This difference and the extent of asymmetry in the probability density in the fan chart also depend on the standard deviation of past forecast errors—which, among other factors, varies with the length of the forecasting horizon. To make the risk factors comparable across forecast vintages, their contributions are rescaled to correct for differences in the standard deviations.Risks to the Global Outlook
Risks to global growth now seem more balanced than six months ago, as downside risks related to the U.S. housing sector, inflationary pressures, and oil supply seem less threatening.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1The fan chart shows the uncertainty around the World Economic Outlook (WEO) central forecast with 50, 70, and 90 percent probability intervals. As shown, the 70 percent confidence interval includes the 50 percent interval, and the 90 percent confidence interval includes the 50 and 70 percent intervals. See Box 1.3 in the April 2006 World Economic Outlook for details.2The chart shows the contributions of each risk factor to the overall balance of risks to global growth, as reflected by the extent of asymmetry in the probability density for global GDP growth shown in the fan chart. The balance of risks is tilted to the downside if the expected probability of outcomes below the central or modal forecast (the total “downside probability”) exceeds 50 percent (Box 1.3 in the April 2006 World Economic Outlook). The bars for each forecast vintage sum up to the difference between the expected value of world growth implied by the distribution of outcomes (the probability density) shown in the fan chart and the central forecast for global GDP growth. This difference and the extent of asymmetry in the probability density in the fan chart also depend on the standard deviation of past forecast errors—which, among other factors, varies with the length of the forecasting horizon. To make the risk factors comparable across forecast vintages, their contributions are rescaled to correct for differences in the standard deviations.U.S. housing market risk. The housing market downturn in the United States has, if anything, been deeper than projected at the time of the September 2006 World Economic Outlook, and residential investment was a substantial drag on U.S. GDP in the second half of 2006. Over the past few months, there have been some tentative signs of stabilization at least on the demand side, as sales of existing homes, mortgage applications, and potential homebuyer intentions have generally steadied or improved. However, the housing correction still has a way to run. Housing starts and permits are still heading downward, while inventories of unsold new homes are at their highest levels in 15 years. Moreover, there has been rising stress in the subprime sector of the market—which represents about 12 percent of the total mortgage market—in the form of sharp increases in delinquency and default rates. In this sector, there was clearly an excessive relaxation of lending and underwriting standards. There have also been some signs of deterioration in Alter-native-A mortgages, although delinquencies in prime mortgages remain well contained. The intensifying problems in the subprime mortgage market could start having a broader impact on the housing market as rising foreclosures could add further to inventories of unsold homes, and tightening of lending standards could depress housing demand. A turnaround in residential construction is still several quarters away.
The key question is whether the continuing difficulties in the housing sector will begin to have a broader impact on the U.S. economy. House prices have continued to decelerate nationally, with outright price declines in many metropolitan areas. Nonetheless, household finances still look solid. Equity gains over the past year have brought household net worth back up to previous peaks. Moreover, household cash flows continue to be sustained by employment and income growth. With interest rates still low, debt-service obligations generally look reasonable. Overall, the baseline view remains that difficulties in the housing sector will not have major spillovers, provided that employment and income growth remain resilient. But there remain risks that the fallout from the housing correction could be amplified, particularly if tightening lending standards in the subprime sector were to lead to a broader reappraisal of credit availability across the economy or if household cash flows were to weaken. Such a development could imply a deeper and more prolonged slowdown or even a recession in the United States, with potential spillovers to other countries.
Domestic demand in western Europe. Western European economies ended 2006 with a robust fourth quarter, showing potential for stronger growth than projected in the World Economic Outlook baseline projection. The upside potential seems particularly relevant in Germany, where consumption could gather strength more commensurate with improved fundamentals and the stronger growth of employment, especially if wages pick up and the negative impact of the VAT increase on demand in early 2007 turns out to be milder than anticipated. In the United Kingdom too, domestic demand may turn out stronger than forecast despite recent monetary tightening, given the acceleration in house prices over the past year.
Domestic demand in emerging markets. IMF staff projections have consistently underpredicted emerging market growth in recent years, as China and India have continued to outperform expectations. A similar pattern could recur in 2007. It is not clear that the Chinese economy will slow consistently as a result of limited tightening measures introduced in 2006, while in India the strong momentum could be sustained despite recent interest rate increases. Both economies, as well as other emerging market oil importers more generally, will benefit significantly from recent oil price reductions. Among commodity exporters, there would seem to be some downside risk to projections in light of recent softening of their export prices. This risk however, seems contained as prices of oil and metals are still high by historical standards and recent price declines still leave significant fiscal revenue cushions. Therefore, sharp cutbacks in government spending plans seem unlikely at this point.
Inflation risk in advanced economies. Inflation pressures in the advanced economies have generally eased, and the probability that central banks may need to raise interest rates by more than now anticipated by markets seems less than last summer. That said, concerns do remain. In the United States, 12-month core inflation is still somewhat above the Federal Reserve’s implicit comfort zone and some measures of wages have risen over the past year. Moreover, a gradual slowing of productivity growth is adding to cost pressures, and there is considerable uncertainty about the extent to which this is a cyclical phenomenon or reflects a moderation of potential growth (Figure 1.11). In the United Kingdom, inflation is now well above the Bank of England’s target, despite policy tightening. In the euro area, price and wage increases remain subdued, but unemployment rates have fallen to cyclical lows, capacity utilization rates are high, and inflation pressures could emerge in the year ahead if labor markets continue to tighten (Figure 1.12). More generally, after four years of strong global growth and output gaps closing in emerging markets too, there is at least a possibility that the dampening impact of global competition on price- and wage-setting behavior in the advanced economies may start to moderate, while risks remain of commodity price spikes (see discussion in Chapter 3 of the April 2006 World Economic Outlook).
Productivity and Labor Cost Developments in Selected Advanced Economies1
(Percent change from four quarters earlier)
Slowing productivity and rising compensation have put upward pressure on unit labor costs in the United States. However, unit labor cost increases have moderated in Europe—as productivity performance has strengthened—and continue to fall in Japan.
Sources: Haver Analytics; OECD, Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations.1Estimates are for the nonfarm business sector for the United States, and the whole economy for the euro area and Japan.Productivity and Labor Cost Developments in Selected Advanced Economies1
(Percent change from four quarters earlier)
Slowing productivity and rising compensation have put upward pressure on unit labor costs in the United States. However, unit labor cost increases have moderated in Europe—as productivity performance has strengthened—and continue to fall in Japan.
Sources: Haver Analytics; OECD, Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations.1Estimates are for the nonfarm business sector for the United States, and the whole economy for the euro area and Japan.Productivity and Labor Cost Developments in Selected Advanced Economies1
(Percent change from four quarters earlier)
Slowing productivity and rising compensation have put upward pressure on unit labor costs in the United States. However, unit labor cost increases have moderated in Europe—as productivity performance has strengthened—and continue to fall in Japan.
Sources: Haver Analytics; OECD, Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations.1Estimates are for the nonfarm business sector for the United States, and the whole economy for the euro area and Japan.Measures of the Output Gap and Capacity Pressures1
Sustained growth has reduced output gaps and lowered unemployment rates. Tighter capacity constraints in commodities sectors have contributed to sharp increases in oil and metals prices.
Sources: OECD, Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.1Estimates of the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) come from the OECD. Estimates of the output gap, expressed as a percent of potential GDP, are based on IMF staff calculations.2Simple average of spot prices of U.K. Brent, Dubai Fateh, and West Texas Intermediate crude oil.Measures of the Output Gap and Capacity Pressures1
Sustained growth has reduced output gaps and lowered unemployment rates. Tighter capacity constraints in commodities sectors have contributed to sharp increases in oil and metals prices.
Sources: OECD, Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.1Estimates of the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) come from the OECD. Estimates of the output gap, expressed as a percent of potential GDP, are based on IMF staff calculations.2Simple average of spot prices of U.K. Brent, Dubai Fateh, and West Texas Intermediate crude oil.Measures of the Output Gap and Capacity Pressures1
Sustained growth has reduced output gaps and lowered unemployment rates. Tighter capacity constraints in commodities sectors have contributed to sharp increases in oil and metals prices.
Sources: OECD, Economic Outlook; and IMF staff estimates.1Estimates of the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) come from the OECD. Estimates of the output gap, expressed as a percent of potential GDP, are based on IMF staff calculations.2Simple average of spot prices of U.K. Brent, Dubai Fateh, and West Texas Intermediate crude oil.Supply-side risk from oil markets. The overall decline in oil prices since August 2006 has provided welcome relief to the global economy, particularly by supporting household spending power and alleviating inflation concerns. However, a rebound in prices since early 2007, as geopolitical tensions have risen, has provided a reminder that the oil market remains an important source of potential volatility. Prospects for substantial price declines from recent levels should be contained as long as the present global expansion is sustained, given the commitment by the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) to implement production cuts in response to price weakness. At the same time, spare capacity remains quite tight (notwithstanding a modest increase in recent months), and a deterioration in security in the Middle East or supply-side disruptions could still lead to another oil price spike. This concern is reflected in oil options pricing, which suggests that markets see price risk as clearly skewed upward. On April 2, options markets indicated a 1 in 6 chance that oil prices could rise above $88 a barrel by the end of 2007. Box 1.1 looks in more detail at the consequences of such a spike for the global economy, underlining that the negative economic impact from an adverse supply-side event would be significantly larger than from a demand-led surge in oil prices.
Financial stability risk. Although the recent episode of financial market turbulence in February–March 2007 appears to be contained in magnitude, it does serve as a healthy reminder of underlying financial risks. Recent years have been an unusual period for markets, with relatively low real interest rates and very low volatility, despite monetary tightening by major central banks. The concern is that, as discussed in the April 2007 Global Financial Stability Report, the drive for yield has led to greater risk taking in less-well-understood markets and instruments. While this strategy has been successful when markets remain buoyant, price setbacks, rising volatility, and emerging loan losses could lead to a reappraisal of investment strategies and a pull-back from positions that have become overextended. Such an unwinding could have serious macroeconomic repercussions.
The recent difficulties in the U.S. subprime mortgage market illustrate this concern. While the direct impact appears contained (in part reflecting this segment’s limited size in the overall market), the indirect effect could be larger. For example, financial institutions with exposure to the U.S. subprime mortgage markets, notably as arrangers of structured credit instruments backed by subprime lending, are experiencing adverse effects. There is also concern that the emergence of loose lending practices and rising delinquencies in subprime loans foreshadow similar trends in other market segments—including prime mortgages, consumer credit, high-yield corporate paper, and other new collateralized products. A general tightening of lending standards and credit conditions in the United States would have more pervasive effects. So far, at least, there has been little contagion to either the prime mortgage market or high-yield corporate paper, but this is an area that bears close watching.
Another area of concern discussed in the April 2007 Global Financial Stability Report relates to the recent surge in leveraged buyouts and share buybacks, often led by private equity firms. While overall corporate leverage remains very low, leverage is rising in certain sectors, and there are concerns that a failure of one of these operations could raise doubts about these deals more generally. Also, there are concerns about the increasing role of hedge funds, whose activities are little regulated and not transparent. To some degree, risks may be contained by structural improvements in markets, including the improved risk management made possible by the increasingly sophisticated and liquid derivatives markets, but new structures have not been fully tested under stressful financial conditions. Thus, vigilance is required to ensure that rising leverage and risk taking do not lead to the buildup of serious vulnerabilities.
Emerging market risks deserve particular attention since history offers numerous examples of boom conditions followed by devastating busts. The good news is that emerging market countries have generally continued to take advantage of the benign global environment. They strengthened public balance sheets, including further reductions in ratios of public debt to GDP; improved currency and maturity composition of debt stocks; and increased levels of international reserves. Credibility of policy management has also been enhanced through timely actions to address emerging concerns—such as steps in China to cool the rapid growth of investment, a fiscal package to lower Hungary’s large fiscal deficit, and monetary tightening in Turkey in the face of rising inflationary pressures. Responsible policy management has been reflected in continued improvement of credit ratings and the decline of sovereign spreads to near all-time lows.
Nevertheless, the recent increases in asset prices and compression in risk spreads in emerging markets may not be fully justified by improving fundamentals. Potential vulnerabilities include still-high public debt ratios in some countries, especially in Latin America, and the rapid buildup of bank lending and private debt, particularly in emerging Europe and the CIS countries. Events in May–June 2006, when rising interest rates and increased volatility in the advanced economies sparked a period of turbulence in emerging markets, provided a healthy reminder of the pressures that can occur. Moreover, the possibility of a disorderly reversal of carry trade capital outflows from Japan has raised concern, although any reversal would be unlikely to be as abrupt as what occurred in 1998, given the greater currency diversification and the broadening of the investor base since that time. Countries that could come under particular pressure in a more testing external financial environment include those that remain heavily dependent on capital inflows, those where balance sheet vulnerabilities may have been allowed to build, or those where macro-economic management may not yet have full credibility.
Risks from global imbalances. Over the past six months, there has been some welcome movement toward containing large global imbalances and the associated risk that a disorderly unwinding would have a highly disruptive impact on the world economy. Relevant developments include a further reduction in the real effective value of the U.S. dollar, some increase in flexibility in the currencies of surplus countries in Asia, lower international oil prices, and a somewhat more balanced pattern of domestic demand growth in the global economy. The U.S. non-oil trade deficit was reduced as a percent of GDP in 2006 as exports accelerated, while the U.S. net external liabilities are estimated to have again declined modestly, reflecting the depreciation of the U.S. dollar and substantial capital gains on foreign equity holdings (see discussion in Chapter 3). Against this, as mentioned earlier, the downward movement of the dollar has been largely focused against the euro and pound sterling, while currencies of the main surplus countries—China, Japan, and the Middle Eastern oil exporters—have tended to depreciate in real effective terms.
Nevertheless, the sum of these developments has not substantially changed the outlook. Projections based on the current constellation of real exchange rates and policies suggest that global imbalances would still remain large over the foreseeable future (Figure 1.13). The U.S. current account deficit is projected to be about 1 percentage point of GDP lower than at the time of the September 2006 World Economic Outlook, but would still remain around 6 percent of GDP in 2012, as a deteriorating net income balance offsets continued improvement on the trade balance. As a result, the U.S. net external liability position would deteriorate substantially in the absence of further valuation gains. Rapidly increasing domestic absorption and a lower oil price trajectory have lowered the path of projected surpluses in the oil-exporting countries, but China’s projected surplus has risen to around 10 percent of GDP in 2012, reflecting recent rapid export growth that has continued to outpace rising imports.
Current Account Balances and Net Foreign Assets
Under the baseline forecast, which assumes unchanged real effective exchange rates, global current account imbalances remain sizable through the projection period, with the U.S. current account deficit staying above 1.5 percent of world GDP. As a result, the U.S. net foreign liability position would deteriorate further in the absence of the valuation gains that have reduced U.S. net foreign liabilities in recent years.
(Percent of world GDP)
Sources: Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2006); and IMF staff estimates.1Algeria, Angola, Azerbaijan, Bahrain, Republic of Congo, Ecuador, Equatorial Guinea, Gabon, I.R. of Iran, Kuwait, Libya, Nigeria, Norway, Oman, Qatar, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Syrian Arab Republic, Turkmenistan, United Arab Emirates, Venezuela, and the Republic of Yemen.2China, Hong Kong SAR, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan Province of China, and Thailand.Current Account Balances and Net Foreign Assets
Under the baseline forecast, which assumes unchanged real effective exchange rates, global current account imbalances remain sizable through the projection period, with the U.S. current account deficit staying above 1.5 percent of world GDP. As a result, the U.S. net foreign liability position would deteriorate further in the absence of the valuation gains that have reduced U.S. net foreign liabilities in recent years.
(Percent of world GDP)
Sources: Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2006); and IMF staff estimates.1Algeria, Angola, Azerbaijan, Bahrain, Republic of Congo, Ecuador, Equatorial Guinea, Gabon, I.R. of Iran, Kuwait, Libya, Nigeria, Norway, Oman, Qatar, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Syrian Arab Republic, Turkmenistan, United Arab Emirates, Venezuela, and the Republic of Yemen.2China, Hong Kong SAR, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan Province of China, and Thailand.Current Account Balances and Net Foreign Assets
Under the baseline forecast, which assumes unchanged real effective exchange rates, global current account imbalances remain sizable through the projection period, with the U.S. current account deficit staying above 1.5 percent of world GDP. As a result, the U.S. net foreign liability position would deteriorate further in the absence of the valuation gains that have reduced U.S. net foreign liabilities in recent years.
(Percent of world GDP)
Sources: Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2006); and IMF staff estimates.1Algeria, Angola, Azerbaijan, Bahrain, Republic of Congo, Ecuador, Equatorial Guinea, Gabon, I.R. of Iran, Kuwait, Libya, Nigeria, Norway, Oman, Qatar, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Syrian Arab Republic, Turkmenistan, United Arab Emirates, Venezuela, and the Republic of Yemen.2China, Hong Kong SAR, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan Province of China, and Thailand.Thus far, the capital inflows needed to finance the large U.S. current account deficit have been forthcoming, but over time the composition of the flows has shifted from equity to debt, and within debt away from treasuries to riskier forms. These shifts suggest an increasing vulnerability to changes in market sentiment, particularly if returns on U.S. assets continue to underperform returns elsewhere. Hence, the concern remains that at some point more substantial adjustments will be needed to ensure that the global pattern of current account positions remains consistent with the willingness of international wealth-holders to build up net claims on the United States. The challenge is to ensure that this process occurs relatively smoothly, rather than through a much more disruptive disorderly adjustment (see Box 1.3 of the September 2006 World Economic Outlook).
Shifting patterns of saving and investment would play an important part in an orderly adjustment process. Over time, U.S. consumption growth can be expected to moderate to allow savings out of current income to return to more normal levels after a period in which capital gains on housing and equity substituted for such saving. Elsewhere, consumption in China should rise from its present low share of GDP as consumer finance becomes more easily available and precautionary savings motives are reduced by stronger social safety nets and increasing prosperity, while absorption by oil exporters should continue to rise as investment plans are advanced.
Changes in real effective exchange rates potentially could play a substantial supportive role to facilitate a smooth unwinding in global imbalances without large cyclical swings or overshooting of aggregate output. Supporting this point, Chapter 3 presents evidence showing that exchange rate movements have been important contributors to past episodes of external adjustment, by facilitating a shift in resources across sectors. It also finds that concern about “elasticity pessimism” in the United States—that is, that trade flows are unresponsive to exchange rate changes—is exaggerated. While short-term exchange rate movements respond to conjunctural factors and are hard to predict, over a medium-term horizon market-led exchange rate movements that could support a smooth reduction of imbalances in combination with rebalancing of demand across countries would include a significant further real effective depreciation of the U.S. dollar, and real effective appreciations of the renminbi, yen, and currencies of Middle Eastern oil exporters.
Cross-Country Spillovers: Can the Global Economy Decouple from a U.S. Slowdown?
While analyzing individual sources of downside risk, it must be borne in mind that shocks can be quickly transmitted across countries through trade and financial channels, leading to a complex pattern of interactions and spillovers. The increasing integration of the global economy over the past 20 years would seem likely to increase the scope for such spillovers. Moreover, there is always particular concern about the potential for spillovers from the United States, still the dominant global economy, accounting for 20 percent of global imports and having the world’s deepest, most sophisticated financial markets. The potential for such spillovers was underlined by the experience in 2000–01 when the collapse of the “hi-tech” stock market bubble in the United States quickly spread across the globe as stock market valuations and business investment dropped sharply in the context of a broader reappraisal of prospects. Thus, a key question for the present conjuncture has been whether the global economy would be able to decouple from a sharper-than-projected slowdown in the United States.
So far the cooling of U.S. activity seems to have had a limited impact beyond its immediate neighbors, Canada and Mexico. As discussed in Chapter 4 of this report, which takes up the issue of cross-country spillovers in detail, the recent experience may reflect a variety of ingredients. First, the U.S. slowdown has been focused on the residential sector, which has a relatively low imported-goods content. Second, spillovers have typically been muted in the context of a midcycle slowdown, compared with the impact of a full-blown recession. Third, to date at least, the housing downturn has been a U.S.-specific event as housing markets elsewhere have remained buoyant, unlike the common disturbances across many countries (such as an oil price shock or the bursting of the IT bubble in 2000–01) that have typically been the source of previous synchronized global downturns. Fourth, the increasing strength of corporate balance sheets and improved labor market conditions in Europe have boosted domestic demand and reduced reliance on growth of net exports.
However, a further cooling of the U.S. economy that increasingly spreads to weakness in consumption and business investment in 2007 would be challenging, particularly since the euro area economy is likely to be slowing. There would also be important risks of spillovers in emerging Asia and elsewhere, particularly if growth in China were to slow more abruptly. A key message from the analysis in Chapter 4 is that in the face of such spillovers, it would be important that policymakers respond in a flexible, forward-looking, and timely fashion to help cushion the impact of weaker external demand.
A particular concern relates to possible interactions between slowing economies, exchange rate swings, and protectionist pressures. A further sharp decline in the value of the U.S. dollar in the face of weak economic data could be problematic, particularly if upward pressures were concentrated in a few currencies—as happened in late 2006. The situation would be further complicated if abrupt exchange rate movements occurring in an environment of slowing activity and rising unemployment triggered a resurgence of protectionist sentiment. Such a risk is more salient given rising popular concerns about the impact of increasingly global markets on those less well-placed to take advantage of new opportunities. This issue is returned to below.
Understanding the Link Between Oil Prices and the World Economy
While oil prices are below their August 2006 peaks, there are still concerns that unless measures are taken to curtail demand for oil and create additional capacity, oil price variability may continue to pose significant risks for the global economy. A common notion based on the experience of the 1970s is that oil price shocks trigger recessions. However, the recent past does not fit this view—oil prices are about 2½ times their 2002 levels—but this increase has apparently not had much impact on the global economy. This seeming paradox has brought attention to the need to identify the sources of the oil price increase, in particular, to distinguish the role of supply and demand factors.
This box investigates these issues using an extended version of the Global Economy Model (GEM) to analyze the causes and consequences of changes in oil prices.1 It also looks at the global macroeconomic impact of higher taxes on petroleum products. It should be said at the outset that the analysis does not attempt to assess the relative importance of demand and supply factors in the recent run-up in oil prices. Rather, it focuses on modeling the channels through which oil prices and growth interact.2
Global Macroeconomic Implications of a Supply-Induced Oil Price Hike
First, consider the case where oil-exporting economies restrict the supply of oil (as in the 1970s). Oil prices rise sharply (100 percent at the peak of the simulation) and this results in a global slowdown as income is redistributed to the oil-exporting economies, which have a lower propensity to spend than the oil-importing economies. In addition, higher oil prices raise the cost of production and put upward pressure on the aggregate price level. This would cause central banks to increase interest rates, which—together with the direct impact on production costs—would further decrease activity in the short run. As a result, world GDP falls 1.4 percent below the baseline at the trough and global inflation rises by about 1.5 percentage points (first figure).
Oil Prices and World GDP
(Supply-induced oil price increase unless otherwise noted)
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Percent deviation from baseline.2Percent of GDP, percentage point deviation from baseline.3Percentage points, deviation from baseline.Oil Prices and World GDP
(Supply-induced oil price increase unless otherwise noted)
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Percent deviation from baseline.2Percent of GDP, percentage point deviation from baseline.3Percentage points, deviation from baseline.Oil Prices and World GDP
(Supply-induced oil price increase unless otherwise noted)
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Percent deviation from baseline.2Percent of GDP, percentage point deviation from baseline.3Percentage points, deviation from baseline.The regional macroeconomic consequences of higher oil prices depend on whether a country is a net oil exporter or importer, and on its oil intensity. Oil exporters run a large trade surplus, peaking at around 6 percent of GDP above the baseline, and also enjoy a vigorous expansion. In contrast, the oil-importing economies suffer a deterioration in their external balances and a slowdown in activity. The impact is more significant in emerging Asian economies primarily because of their higher oil intensities relative to advanced economies.
On balance, the effects on inflation and GDP in this scenario are significantly smaller than observed in many industrial countries in the 1970s. First, this partly reflects the lower oil intensities of consumption and production, which reduce both the direct effects on inflation and the medium- and long-term effects on GDP. Second, these simulations assume that forward-looking inflation targeting central banks raise interest rates promptly to prevent a ratcheting up of inflation expectations and a spillover into wages and other prices, unlike what happened in the 1970s. Third, many countries have implemented reforms that have increased flexibility in both labor and product markets, facilitating more rapid adjustment in relative prices in response to oil price shocks. Combined with credible monetary policies that have anchored longer-term inflation expectations, these structural improvements have allowed the containment of inflationary pressures caused by the higher oil prices without overly dampening output. However, the simulations do not account for possible business and consumer confidence effects or capital market disruptions, including difficulties in financing individual countries’ current account deficits.3
Persistent Productivity Shocks with Low Oil Capacity
Macroeconomic responses are very different in a situation in which oil prices are being boosted by a demand shock. Consider a situation of low spare oil production capacity in which the responsiveness of supply to oil price changes is very limited over the short to medium term. In this case, a significant increase in productivity growth in oil-importing countries that permanently raises global growth by ½ of a percentage point generates a significant short-run surge in oil prices that is sustained over the medium term (see first figure). This response of oil prices reflects the low short-term elasticity of supply as new capacity has to be brought on stream to satisfy higher levels of current and future demand. However, the short-run path for world GDP is opposite to that resulting from a supply-induced increase in the price of oil because higher prices are being caused by stronger growth.4
Impact of Higher Worldwide Gasoline Taxes
(Percent deviation from baseline unless otherwise noted)
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Percent of GDP, percentage point deviation from baseline.2Negative numbers indicate an appreciation.Impact of Higher Worldwide Gasoline Taxes
(Percent deviation from baseline unless otherwise noted)
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Percent of GDP, percentage point deviation from baseline.2Negative numbers indicate an appreciation.Impact of Higher Worldwide Gasoline Taxes
(Percent deviation from baseline unless otherwise noted)
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Percent of GDP, percentage point deviation from baseline.2Negative numbers indicate an appreciation.What Difference Would Higher Gasoline Taxes Make?
Low spare capacity and higher oil prices have heightened the awareness of the consequences of growing oil usage both now and in the future. Moreover, the consumption of hydrocarbons, particularly petroleum products, is a key source of climate-changing carbon emissions—a cost that is not internalized by the market. Given these concerns, a number of observers have suggested raising taxes on oil consumption, and it is useful to look at the macroeco-nomic consequences of such a policy shift.
Consider the implications of a worldwide increase of gasoline taxes by 10 percentage points accompanied by a corresponding reduction in labor taxes that keeps the fiscal stance unchanged (second figure).5 The gasoline tax encourages a gradual substitution away from energy consumption that builds steadily over time owing to the low short-run oil demand elasticities. In contrast, oil prices decline by about 7 percent on impact, creating a wealth transfer away from oil-exporting countries. The macroeconomic implications are the mirror image of the supply-induced rise in oil prices, now benefiting the oil-importing economies instead of the oil-exporting economies. The United States and emerging Asia experience improvements in growth, external positions, and consumption, which are further enhanced by an appreciation in their real exchange rates and a reduction in distortionary labor taxes made possible by higher fuel taxes.6 In contrast, oil-exporting countries experience a deterioration in their external balances and slower growth. On balance, however, world GDP is modestly higher—as taxation has shifted from a factor of production (labor) to a less price-elastic good (gasoline)—suggesting that it may be possible to design a framework that could share the income gains from such a policy in an equitable way across regions.
Note: The authors of this box are Selim Elekdag and Douglas Laxton, with support from Susanna Mursula. This work builds on some previous joint work with Dirk Muir, Rene Lalonde, and Paolo Pesenti.1 For a description of the model, see Elekdag and others (2006). The regions in the model are oil exporters, United States, emerging Asia, and a residual block of oil-importing countries.2 For a discussion of the role of supply and demand factors during the recent increase in oil prices, see Chapter 4 of the April 2005 World Economic Outlook.3 Also, these projections do not take into full account the potential impact of higher oil prices on other energy substitutes, or the role of speculative factors that may exacerbate the associated risk premium.4 If the same increase in productivity is considered in a version of the model that does not include oil, world GDP expands by slightly more in the short and medium term than in the model with oil. This suggests that while high oil prices have resulted in a drag on world growth, these effects are relatively minor.5 The structure of GEM explicitly differentiates energy inputs (crude oil) and refined petroleum products (gasoline) directly consumed by households, allowing a thorough investigation of the impact of higher gasoline taxes.6 Similar medium-term effects on world GDP would be obtained if the additional tax revenue was used to finance productive government investment.Medium-Term Challenges: Can the Productivity Boom Be Sustained?
Recent years have been a remarkable period for the world economy, as global output growth has reached its highest sustained rate since the early 1970s, with strong increases in virtually all regions. Inflation has generally been contained at the low levels achieved by the end of the 1990s, while a series of shocks and periods of turbulence—including sharp increases in oil and other commodity prices, and corrections in some richly valued equity and housing markets—have been largely weathered without major spillovers across sectors or regions.
What have been the sources of this global prosperity, and can the momentum be sustained? Rajan (2006) argues that a central arch of support for recent exceptional performance has been strong productivity growth. Buoyant productivity has made possible healthy growth in profits in combination with rising real wages, has allowed sharp increases in commodity prices to be absorbed without derailing inflation performance, and has contributed to rising asset values that have supported consumption and investment.
It is well known that productivity growth accelerated in the United States in the mid-1990s, in substantial part in response to increasing use of new information and communications technology (ICT), but productivity growth has also been strong and increasing in emerging market and developing countries over the same period. Figure 1.14 illustrates this point on the basis of a crude but readily available broad measure of productivity—output relative to working-age population. Detailed studies with more precise measures of total factor productivity confirm this trend, particularly for countries and regions that have undergone major structural transfor-mations—notably China, India, and emerging Europe, which have made dramatic progress in opening their economies and advancing market reform.1
Global Productivity Performance1
(Annual percent increase; three-year moving average)
Global productivity has accelerated in recent years, led by emerging market and developing countries. While China’s sustained performance since the early 1990s is particularly impressive, productivity growth has also been strong in emerging Asia and emerging Europe for a number of years.
Sources: World Bank, World Development Indicators (2006); and IMF staff calculations.1Measured as real GDP divided by working-age population.Global Productivity Performance1
(Annual percent increase; three-year moving average)
Global productivity has accelerated in recent years, led by emerging market and developing countries. While China’s sustained performance since the early 1990s is particularly impressive, productivity growth has also been strong in emerging Asia and emerging Europe for a number of years.
Sources: World Bank, World Development Indicators (2006); and IMF staff calculations.1Measured as real GDP divided by working-age population.Global Productivity Performance1
(Annual percent increase; three-year moving average)
Global productivity has accelerated in recent years, led by emerging market and developing countries. While China’s sustained performance since the early 1990s is particularly impressive, productivity growth has also been strong in emerging Asia and emerging Europe for a number of years.
Sources: World Bank, World Development Indicators (2006); and IMF staff calculations.1Measured as real GDP divided by working-age population.In turn, strong productivity growth has been supported by a combination of technological developments, an increasingly open global trading system, rising cross-country capital flows, and more resilient macroeconomic policy frameworks and financial systems. Chapter 5 of this report discusses how the rapid growth of international trade and the introduction of new technologies have allowed the production process to be unbundled, with both manufacturing and services activities being offshored to lower-cost locations in an increasingly global market, thus providing productivity gains both in source and in host countries. This process has been supported by important trade liberalization initiatives, including the entry of former Eastern bloc countries in Europe into a free trade zone with the European Union in 1994, Mexico’s participation in the North American Free Trade Agreement from 1994, China’s entry into the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001, and India’s progressive unilateral reduction in trade barriers since the early 1990s. The shifting production structure has also been supported by the increasing international mobility of capital, especially rising rates of foreign direct investment into emerging market countries, that has not only provided a conduit for financing but also embodied diffusion of new technologies and management skills.
Another central feature of the recent past has been that strong productivity growth has been achieved even while investment has remained relatively subdued around the world. Chapter 2 of the September 2005 World Economic Outlook looked at global investment and saving patterns in more detail. Since that report, there has been a modest rise in global investment relative to GDP, but this ratio remains low by historical standards (Figure 1.15). It is interesting to note that the recent increase in investment is focused almost entirely in China, where economic transformation has created such large opportunities (Figure 1.16). Meanwhile, saving outside the advanced economies has continued to rise, mainly attributable to increasing savings (public and private) in China and higher public savings in oil-producing countries, although plans to boost government spending are now well under way.
Global Saving, Investment, and Current Accounts
(Percent of world GDP)
Global investment has risen during the present economic cycle but remains low by historical standards, particularly in the industrial countries. The corresponding rise in saving has been exclusively in emerging market and oil-producing countries, which are building up high current account surpluses.
Sources: OECD Analytical Database; World Bank, World Development Indicators (2006); and IMF staff calculations.1Includes Norway.Global Saving, Investment, and Current Accounts
(Percent of world GDP)
Global investment has risen during the present economic cycle but remains low by historical standards, particularly in the industrial countries. The corresponding rise in saving has been exclusively in emerging market and oil-producing countries, which are building up high current account surpluses.
Sources: OECD Analytical Database; World Bank, World Development Indicators (2006); and IMF staff calculations.1Includes Norway.Global Saving, Investment, and Current Accounts
(Percent of world GDP)
Global investment has risen during the present economic cycle but remains low by historical standards, particularly in the industrial countries. The corresponding rise in saving has been exclusively in emerging market and oil-producing countries, which are building up high current account surpluses.
Sources: OECD Analytical Database; World Bank, World Development Indicators (2006); and IMF staff calculations.1Includes Norway.Saving and Investment in Emerging Market and Oil-Producing Economies
(Percent of each subregion’s GDP)
Although investment-to-GDP ratio has risen substantially in China in recent years, the rise in the savings ratio has been even more dramatic. Elsewhere in East Asia, investment has remained generally quite low. Rising oil prices have propelled a sharp increase in savings in oil-producing countries.
Sources: OECD Analytical Database; World Bank, World Development Indicators (2006); and IMF staff calculations.1East Asia emerging markets excluding China.Saving and Investment in Emerging Market and Oil-Producing Economies
(Percent of each subregion’s GDP)
Although investment-to-GDP ratio has risen substantially in China in recent years, the rise in the savings ratio has been even more dramatic. Elsewhere in East Asia, investment has remained generally quite low. Rising oil prices have propelled a sharp increase in savings in oil-producing countries.
Sources: OECD Analytical Database; World Bank, World Development Indicators (2006); and IMF staff calculations.1East Asia emerging markets excluding China.Saving and Investment in Emerging Market and Oil-Producing Economies
(Percent of each subregion’s GDP)
Although investment-to-GDP ratio has risen substantially in China in recent years, the rise in the savings ratio has been even more dramatic. Elsewhere in East Asia, investment has remained generally quite low. Rising oil prices have propelled a sharp increase in savings in oil-producing countries.
Sources: OECD Analytical Database; World Bank, World Development Indicators (2006); and IMF staff calculations.1East Asia emerging markets excluding China.These investment and saving trends have contributed to the generally supportive global financial environment, with low long-term real interest rates and low volatilities, even as monetary conditions have been tightened. Thus, the U.S. expansion has continued to benefit from robust consumption growth despite the housing downturn, with the resultant widening current account deficit financed without upward pressure on long-term interest rates. Developments in the global financial system have played an important role, including the ability of the United States to generate assets with attractive liquidity and risk management features, as well as the continuing role of the U.S. dollar as an international reserve currency (see Chapter 4 of the September 2006 World Economic Outlook).
What factors could threaten the continuation of this benign combination of trends? There are a number of reasons to think that global productivity growth may decelerate in the period ahead. The recent slowdown in productivity growth in the United States may reflect to some degree a diminishing of the boost from advances in the ICT sector, as well as normal cyclical factors. Most other countries have lagged the United States in reaping the benefits from ICT advances, and therefore should be able to achieve continuing gains. However, doing so will depend in part on sustained reforms to reduce regulatory impediments and increase competition, particularly in service sectors such as wholesale distribution and finance, where the U.S. productivity performance has been very strong.2
A second source of concern is that global productivity growth may receive less support from trade liberalization in the years ahead. The recent revival in the Doha Round of multilateral liberalization is very welcome—a successful conclusion of the round could provide significant efficiency gains, particularly in agricultural sectors. The process of bilateral and regional trade liberalization may continue, but it is not a substitute: such agreements—which already cover around one-third of global trade—are inherently less beneficial than liberalization on a “most favored nation” basis, and can be counterproductive if not well designed.
Moreover, there is a serious danger that protectionist forces could rise in the years ahead, reversing some of the gains from an increasingly integrated global economy. Already there are concerns about recent resort to antidumping and “safeguards” actions around the world—and anti-trade measures could intensify in the context of a cyclical downturn and rising unemployment that would give added force to popular concerns about the impact of globalization on the distribution of income, particularly in advanced economies. Chapter 5 discusses how the rapid growth of international trade and the increasingly global labor market, combined with the introduction of new technologies, have produced important gains for income levels in both advanced and developing countries, as well as had an impact on income distribution. The chapter presents evidence suggesting that recent declines in the share of labor in advanced economies reflect more technological change than increasing competition from a burgeoning global labor force. Nonetheless, more could be done to help those whose jobs may be particularly affected by recent trends in technology and trade, including through better education systems, more flexible labor markets, and welfare systems that cushion the impact of, but do not obstruct, economic change.
Third, global environmental and resource constraints are likely to impose increasing costs. Efforts to date to address the long-term problem of global warming have been limited and partial—few countries are expected to meet the goals for control of carbon emissions over 2008–12 set out in the Kyoto Protocol. The potential long-term economic consequences of climate change are increasingly recognized, leading to rising interest across countries to take actions to control carbon emissions that would inevitably add to the costs of doing business even while averting much graver long-term consequences. For example, the recent Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change estimates that it would cost about 1 percent of GDP a year to stabilize carbon dioxide concentrations in the atmosphere, while the consequences of taking no action would be long-term damage of 5 percent or more of global consumption, concentrated in lower-income countries in the tropics.3 Beyond such environmental consequences, the marginal costs of energy production are already rising, as easier-to-exploit oil reserves outside a few very large producers are being depleted and a rising share of non-OPEC production will take place in much more expensive offshore facilities or from low-grade, hard-to-extract deposits such as tar sands.
Fourth, aging populations, especially in advanced economies, pose challenges for maintaining productivity growth. As the share of new entrants to the labor force declines, it will become harder to continually raise the knowledge base, particularly related to the technological frontier, and there are risks of mismatches between specific labor skills and needs. A rising ratio of dependents to working-age population will also impose fiscal strains as pension and health care costs to governments rise. As discussed in Box 1.2, achieving fiscal sustainabil-ity in the face of these rising costs will require substantial adjustments of the order of 4 percent of GDP in the G-7 countries. In turn, this will put pressure to raise tax rates that will have an efficiency cost. To some degree, more open immigration policies and steps to encourage higher birth rates may help to address such concerns, but they would only be able to partially compensate for aging trends.
Slowing productivity would have implications for investment and consumption trends and the unwinding of global imbalances. Maintaining GDP growth rates in the face of slower growth of total factor productivity would require higher rates of capital accumulation than over the present expansion. At the same time, consumption growth could be dampened by lower expectations of future income growth, although aggregate consumption is likely to be boosted as a rising share of population in advanced countries retire and as populations in fast-growing countries in East Asia—especially in China—adjust to new levels of affluence and precautionary savings dwindle. The balance of these complex forces affecting saving and investment is hard to predict with any precision, but it does seem likely that the recent period of “savings glut” or “investment dearth” (depending on perspective) may come to an end, implying rising pressure on financial resources and increasing real long-term interest rates.
Ensuring Fiscal Sustainability in G-7 Countries
In the coming decades, rising longevity, falling fertility rates, and the retirement of the baby boom generation will substantially raise age-related government spending in G-7 countries. By 2050, the populations in most G-7 countries are expected to be smaller and considerably older, with old-age dependency ratios projected to double. These trends will put national fiscal positions under substantial additional pressure. According to the projections submitted by national authorities, general government age-related spending in these countries is expected to rise by an average of 4 percentage points of GDP over the next 45 years with substantial cross-country variation (see the figure).1 Estimates vary substantially across countries—from Canada at the high end, where age-related spending is projected to rise by 9 percentage points by 2050, to Italy at the low end, where such spending is projected to rise by just 2 percentage points. The bulk of the spending increase is expected to come from additional health costs, with long-term care and pension spending accounting for the remainder.
Assessing the impact of these demographic changes on the sustainability of public finances is complicated by uncertainties about long-term technological, demographic, labor supply, and productivity growth projections. A key issue is the strength of the link between aging and the cost of health care. The more traditional “expansion of morbidity” hypothesis (aging implies longer periods of illness and thus higher costs) is often contrasted with the “compression of morbidity” hypothesis (aging delays, but does not extend, the periods of illness and the associated costs).
Projected Cumulative Growth in Old-Age Population and Increase in Age-Related Spending Relative to 2005
Sources: Economic Policy Committee of the European Union (2006); OECD (2001); UN (2006); and IMF staff estimates.Projected Cumulative Growth in Old-Age Population and Increase in Age-Related Spending Relative to 2005
Sources: Economic Policy Committee of the European Union (2006); OECD (2001); UN (2006); and IMF staff estimates.Projected Cumulative Growth in Old-Age Population and Increase in Age-Related Spending Relative to 2005
Sources: Economic Policy Committee of the European Union (2006); OECD (2001); UN (2006); and IMF staff estimates.A comparison of age-related spending pressures across countries is complicated further by differences in methodology across age-related spending projections. The absence of a fully standardized projection framework is rooted in the complexity of preparing population-cohort-based long-term projections for countries with different old-age and health insurance systems. Nonetheless, there is a fairly close relationship between the projected old-age population growth rates and projected age-related expenditure (see the figure). Obtaining a more consistent set of cross-country estimates for future age-related spending pressures is an important priority for future research.
This box uses a standard indicator, the intertemporal primary gap, to assess the evolution of fiscal sustainability for each of the G-7 countries, and to evaluate the contribution of policy initiatives.2 The intertemporal primary gap measures the change in the primary balance required to equate the present discounted value of future primary balances to the current level of debt. This measure thus indicates the adjustment required to stabilize debt at a level that is permanently sustainable (not just attained in a certain year).
The indicator consists of three components:
the primary deficit component—the initial cyclically adjusted general government primary deficit;
the debt component—the debt-servicing costs of the initial debt stock (evaluated using either gross debt or net debt data); and
the aging component—the net present value of the projected increase in age-related expenditures times the growth-adjusted interest rate (nominal interest rate minus nominal growth), assumed, for ease of comparability, to be 2 percent per year in the baseline scenario for all countries.3
The first table presents the data for the three components used to evaluate the indicator as of 2005.
The estimated fiscal adjustment required to ensure long-run fiscal sustainability is substantial for all G-7 countries. In particular, as the second table reports, closing the intertemporal primary gap would require an average adjustment estimated at 3.9 to 4.5 percentage points of GDP (depending on whether net debt or gross debt is used to evaluate the indicator).4 Almost two-thirds of this adjustment need reflects the expected increase in age-related spending (aging component), while the remaining one-third reflects the interest on public debt (debt component). The largest primary gaps are shown for Japan and the United States. In the case of Japan, this reflects the largest primary deficit, high debt level, and the assumed interest rate—growth differential.5 In the case of the United States, the large gap is due to a combination of high primary deficits and high projected increases in age-related spending. The smallest primary gap is shown for Canada, where a primary surplus of 5.5 percent of GDP helps to offset the impact of the very large projected increase in age-related spending. Without any fiscal adjustment, the expected increases in age-related spending imply explosive debt dynamics in all seven countries.
G-7: Fiscal Positions as of 2005
(In percent of GDP unless otherwise stated)
G-7: Fiscal Positions as of 2005
(In percent of GDP unless otherwise stated)
Gross Debt (end-2005) | Net Debt (end-2005) | Structural Primary Balance (2005) | Projected Increase in Age-Related Spending, 2005–50 (in percentage points of GDP) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Canada | 70.8 | 30.2 | 5.5 | 9.0 |
France | 76.1 | 43.7 | -0.2 | 3.3 |
Germany | 71.1 | 51.5 | 0.1 | 3.2 |
Italy | 120.4 | 95.1 | 1.4 | 1.9 |
Japan | 173.1 | 86.4 | -3.0 | 2.2 |
United Kingdom | 46.7 | 40.0 | -1.5 | 4.1 |
United States | 61.8 | 43.5 | -1.8 | 5.9 |
Average | 88.6 | 55.8 | 0.1 | 4.2 |
G-7: Fiscal Positions as of 2005
(In percent of GDP unless otherwise stated)
Gross Debt (end-2005) | Net Debt (end-2005) | Structural Primary Balance (2005) | Projected Increase in Age-Related Spending, 2005–50 (in percentage points of GDP) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Canada | 70.8 | 30.2 | 5.5 | 9.0 |
France | 76.1 | 43.7 | -0.2 | 3.3 |
Germany | 71.1 | 51.5 | 0.1 | 3.2 |
Italy | 120.4 | 95.1 | 1.4 | 1.9 |
Japan | 173.1 | 86.4 | -3.0 | 2.2 |
United Kingdom | 46.7 | 40.0 | -1.5 | 4.1 |
United States | 61.8 | 43.5 | -1.8 | 5.9 |
Average | 88.6 | 55.8 | 0.1 | 4.2 |
While the overall adjustment required to achieve long-run fiscal sustainability in G-7 countries is large, there are significant growth benefits to putting public finances on a sustainable footing in the near term versus delayed adjustment. The following two scenarios illustrate this important point:
Near-term adjustment scenario. This scenario involves closing the intertemporal primary gap over a period of five years.
Delayed adjustment scenario. This scenario involves no changes in fiscal policy for 10 years, during which age-related spending pressures are allowed to build up. The intertemporal primary gap is then reassessed on the basis of as-of-then public debt and primary balance levels, and closed over the following five years.
G-7: Estimation Results—Primary Gaps in 2005
(Percent of GDP)
2 percent interest rate—growth differential.
The contributions are presented for calculations using the baseline 2 percent interest rate—growth differential.
1 percent interest rate—growth differential.
G-7: Estimation Results—Primary Gaps in 2005
(Percent of GDP)
Intertemporal Primary Gap1 | Contributions to Intertemporal Primary Gap (Gross Debt) from:2 | Intertemporal Primary Gap3 | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(Net debt) | (Gross debt) | Primary balance | Debt service | Aging costs | (Net debt) | (Gross debt) | |||
Canada | -1.4 | -2.2 | 5.5 | -1.4 | -6.3 | -2.3 | -2.7 | ||
France | -3.4 | -4.0 | -0.2 | -1.5 | -2.3 | -3.4 | -3.7 | ||
Germany | -2.7 | -3.0 | 0.1 | -1.4 | -1.7 | -2.8 | -3.0 | ||
Italy | -1.7 | -2.2 | 1.4 | -2.4 | -1.2 | -1.0 | -1.3 | ||
Japan | -6.2 | -7.9 | -3.0 | -3.4 | -1.6 | -5.6 | -6.5 | ||
United Kingdom | -4.8 | -4.9 | -1.5 | -0.9 | -2.5 | -5.1 | -5.1 | ||
United States | -6.9 | -7.3 | -1.8 | -1.3 | -4.2 | -7.2 | -7.4 | ||
Average | -3.9 | -4.5 | 0.1 | -1.8 | -2.8 | -3.9 | -4.2 |
2 percent interest rate—growth differential.
The contributions are presented for calculations using the baseline 2 percent interest rate—growth differential.
1 percent interest rate—growth differential.
G-7: Estimation Results—Primary Gaps in 2005
(Percent of GDP)
Intertemporal Primary Gap1 | Contributions to Intertemporal Primary Gap (Gross Debt) from:2 | Intertemporal Primary Gap3 | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(Net debt) | (Gross debt) | Primary balance | Debt service | Aging costs | (Net debt) | (Gross debt) | |||
Canada | -1.4 | -2.2 | 5.5 | -1.4 | -6.3 | -2.3 | -2.7 | ||
France | -3.4 | -4.0 | -0.2 | -1.5 | -2.3 | -3.4 | -3.7 | ||
Germany | -2.7 | -3.0 | 0.1 | -1.4 | -1.7 | -2.8 | -3.0 | ||
Italy | -1.7 | -2.2 | 1.4 | -2.4 | -1.2 | -1.0 | -1.3 | ||
Japan | -6.2 | -7.9 | -3.0 | -3.4 | -1.6 | -5.6 | -6.5 | ||
United Kingdom | -4.8 | -4.9 | -1.5 | -0.9 | -2.5 | -5.1 | -5.1 | ||
United States | -6.9 | -7.3 | -1.8 | -1.3 | -4.2 | -7.2 | -7.4 | ||
Average | -3.9 | -4.5 | 0.1 | -1.8 | -2.8 | -3.9 | -4.2 |
2 percent interest rate—growth differential.
The contributions are presented for calculations using the baseline 2 percent interest rate—growth differential.
1 percent interest rate—growth differential.
The effects of these two policy scenarios on economic activity—both in the short term and in the medium to long term—are assessed using the IMF’s Global Fiscal Model (GFM), calibrated to replicate the key empirical features of each G-7 country.6 Two main conclusions emerge from the analysis. First, delaying fiscal consolidation and allowing debt to increase implies the need to run permanently higher primary surpluses to service the higher interest costs. On average, the primary balance adjustment required to stabilize debt on a sustainable basis is 1.1 percentage points of GDP higher in the delayed compared with the near-term adjustment scenario. Second, early adjustment also brings significant long-run output gains. Early adjustment is estimated to deliver a total output gain of 1.8 percent of GDP on average. Given the upside risks to spending pressures, early fiscal adjustment would also provide greater fiscal space to absorb any higher-than-expected age-related expenditure needs.
Note: The main author of this box is Daniel Leigh. The box draws on a study prepared by Hauner, Leigh, and Skaarup (2007).1 See Economic Policy Committee of the European Union (2006) for France, Germany, Italy, and the United Kingdom; and OECD (2001) for Canada, Japan, and the United States. More recent long-run age-related spending projections for Canada, Japan, and the United States produced by national authorities are broadly consistent with the OECD (2001) projections.2 This indicator belongs to the family of primary gap indicators (as discussed in Chalk and Hemming, 2000) that is based on the European Commission’s (2004) approach to assessing fiscal sustainability. A similar approach is used in HM Treasury (2006).3 While a 2 percent interest rate—growth differential is broadly in line with the historical experience of major industrial countries, it is higher than the figure used in the debt sustainability analyses of a number of IMF Staff Country Reports. Lowering the interest rate—growth differential can substantially reduce the adjustment need for countries with high debt levels.4 While using net debt to evaluate fiscal sustainability is preferable in principle, methodological inconsistencies, notably in the evaluation of pension system assets, imply that net debt figures are not readily comparable across countries.5 The estimated adjustment need is highly sensitive to the interest rate—growth differential assumed. In the case of Japan in particular, a 10-year historical average spanning the deflation period is probably higher than the interest rate—growth differential going forward. Lowering this differential to ¼ of 1 percent would yield a required adjustment in line with the analysis and recommendations made in the context of the IMF’s 2006 Article IV Consultation with Japan.6 GFM is a general equilibrium model developed at the IMF to examine macroeconomic and structural fiscal policy issues, including pension reform, in a multicountry setting.In this context, countries with large current account deficits, such as the United States, may face greater difficulties in attracting continuing large-scale foreign financing as needed—particularly as other countries’ financial systems start closing the gap with the United States by offering a similar array of financial vehicles for savings. In such circumstances, prospects for a smooth unwinding of imbalances would benefit from trade reforms and other initiatives to remove obstacles to the smooth reallocation of resources in response to exchange rate movements, a point supported by the findings in Chapter 3.
Anticipating and modeling these long-term forces is a complex task, and it is hard to be confident about the outcomes. Nevertheless, the potentially large costs involved in dealing with such problems as climatic change, population aging, and the unwinding of global imbalances argue for forward-looking and well-calibrated policy responses to mitigate the risks involved.
Policy Issues
The immediate challenge for policymakers is to continue to steer the global economy on a sustainable path that is consistent with low inflation as the global expansion enters its fifth year. The major central banks face distinct challenges in managing monetary policy, reflecting differing cyclical positions and degrees of inflation pressure in their economies.
In the United States, the Fed continues to face a tricky task of balancing concerns of slowing activity against inflation risks, and the policy of holding rates steady remains appropriate for now. Financial markets are now pricing in a rate cut by September, following a string of weaker data. But the Fed has appropriately kept its options open, stressing that the path of monetary policy will depend on how incoming data affect the balance of risks between growth and inflation.
Inflation in the euro area has been more closely aligned with objectives, and a strengthening economy has provided a context for the ECB to progressively raise short-term interest rates to more neutral levels to forestall pressures on wages and prices. With the area’s growth projected to remain close to or above potential, and the possibility of some further upward pressure on factor utilization and prices, a further interest rate increase to 4 percent by the summer would seem warranted. Beyond this, additional policy action could still be required if growth momentum remains above trend and risks to wages and prices intensify.
In Japan, a very easy monetary stance has been key to the country’s exit from a decade-long stagnation—although it is likely to also have been a factor contributing to carry trade outflows and the weakness of the yen, which has raised some concerns about the impact on competitiveness in other countries as well as a possible disorderly reversal as policy is tightened. While the growth outlook is favorable, inflation readings have remained uncomfortably close to zero. With this background, the primary focus should remain on ensuring robust growth and a decisive departure from deflation. Thus, monetary accommodation should be removed only at a gradual pace, and on the basis of evidence confirming the continuing strength of the expansion.
The thrust of fiscal policy in the advanced economies should be directed at necessary consolidation and reform to maintain viability in the face of aging populations, while leaving room for automatic stabilizers to work as needed. Strong revenue growth has helped to strengthen fiscal positions in a number of major economies over the past three years (Table 1.3). However, it remains uncertain how much of this improvement is cyclical—boosted by high profits, rapid growth of earnings at the upper end of the income spectrum, and rising asset prices—and how much will be permanent. Attention must be paid to containing expenditure growth, which experience has shown provides a more durable path to fiscal consolidation. Among the major advanced economies, further sustained progress toward fiscal consolidation would seem particularly important in the United States—especially in view of low private savings, concerns about the wide current account deficit, and the projected high fiscal cost of population aging; Japan, where deficit and debt levels remain particularly high and population aging is occurring rapidly; and Italy, where modest growth and weakening competitiveness reinforce concerns about fiscal sustainability.
Major Advanced Economies: General Government Fiscal Balances and Debt1
(Percent of GDP)
Debt data refer to end of year. Debt data are not always comparable across countries.
Percent of potential GDP.
Beginning in 1995, the debt and debt-service obligations of the Treuhandanstalt (and of various other agencies) were taken over by general government. This debt is equivalent to 8 percent of GDP, and the associated debt service to ½ to 1 percent of GDP.
Excludes one-off receipts from the sale of mobile telephone licenses (the equivalent of 2.5 percent of GDP in 2000 for Germany, 0.1 percent of GDP in 2001 and 2002 for France, and 1.2 percent of GDP in 2000 for Italy). Also excludes one-off receipts from sizable asset transactions, in particular 0.5 percent of GDP for France in 2005.
Major Advanced Economies: General Government Fiscal Balances and Debt1
(Percent of GDP)
1991–2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 | 2006 | 2007 | 2008 | 2012 | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Major advanced economies | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -3.0 | -1.7 | -4.0 | -4.8 | -4.2 | -3.5 | -2.7 | -2.4 | -2.4 | -1.6 | ||
Output gap2 | 0.9 | 1.3 | - | -0.8 | -0.2 | -0.4 | -0.1 | -0.4 | -0.5 | — | ||
Structural balance2 | -3.2 | -2.2 | -3.9 | -4.4 | -4.1 | -3.3 | -2.7 | -2.3 | -2.2 | -1.6 | ||
United States | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -2.2 | -0.4 | -3.8 | -4.8 | -4.6 | -3.7 | -2.6 | -2.5 | -2.5 | -1.6 | ||
Output gap2 | 2.4 | 2.1 | 0.3 | -0.5 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.3 | -0.6 | -0.9 | — | ||
Structural balance2 | -2.9 | -1.2 | -3.9 | -4.6 | -4.5 | -3.6 | -2.7 | -2.4 | -2.4 | -1.6 | ||
Net debt | 49.4 | 35.5 | 38.3 | 41.1 | 42.8 | 43.6 | 43.4 | 44.2 | 44.6 | 43.7 | ||
Gross debt | 65.4 | 53.7 | 56.1 | 59.3 | 60.1 | 60.3 | 59.6 | 60.3 | 60.6 | 59.1 | ||
Euro area | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -3.8 | -1.9 | -2.6 | -3.1 | -2.8 | -2.4 | -1.6 | -1.2 | -1.1 | -0.7 | ||
Output gap2 | -0.2 | 1.4 | 0.3 | -0.8 | -0.7 | -1.3 | -0.6 | -0.3 | — | — | ||
Structural balance2 | -3.4 | -2.3 | -2.6 | -2.7 | -2.4 | -1.9 | -1.3 | -1.0 | -1.0 | -0.7 | ||
Net debt | 56.0 | 57.3 | 57.3 | 58.8 | 60.0 | 60.9 | 59.8 | 58.6 | 57.6 | 53.3 | ||
Gross debt | 69.2 | 68.3 | 68.2 | 69.3 | 69.7 | 70.5 | 69.3 | 67.9 | 66.7 | 61.7 | ||
Germany3 | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -2.2 | -2.8 | -3.7 | -4.0 | -3.7 | -3.2 | -1.7 | -1.3 | -1.3 | -1.3 | ||
Output gap2 | 0.3 | 1.7 | 0.5 | -0.9 | -0.9 | -1.2 | 0.1 | 0.6 | 1.1 | — | ||
Structural balance2,4 | -2.0 | -2.8 | -3.2 | -3.4 | -3.4 | -2.8 | -1.8 | -1.4 | -1.4 | -1.3 | ||
Net debt | 43.6 | 52.1 | 54.3 | 57.8 | 60.1 | 62.4 | 62.4 | 62.1 | 61.6 | 61.0 | ||
Gross debt | 52.4 | 57.9 | 59.6 | 62.8 | 64.8 | 66.4 | 66.8 | 66.5 | 65.9 | 64.9 | ||
France | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -3.6 | -1.6 | -3.2 | -4.2 | -3.7 | -2.9 | -2.6 | -2.6 | -2.4 | -1.1 | ||
Output gap2 | -1.4 | 1.0 | — | -0.9 | -0.9 | -1.7 | -1.8 | -1.9 | -1.6 | — | ||
Structural balance2,4 | -2.7 | -2.2 | -3.2 | -3.5 | -3.0 | -2.2 | -1.4 | -1.4 | -1.5 | -1.1 | ||
Net debt | 42.0 | 48.2 | 48.5 | 52.6 | 54.8 | 57.0 | 55.0 | 54.2 | 53.7 | 49.5 | ||
Gross debt | 51.2 | 56.3 | 58.2 | 62.3 | 64.5 | 66.7 | 64.7 | 63.9 | 63.4 | 59.2 | ||
Italy | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -6.3 | -3.1 | -2.9 | -3.5 | -3.4 | -4.1 | -4.4 | -2.2 | -2.4 | -2.3 | ||
Output gap2 | -0.9 | 1.2 | 0.3 | -0.8 | -0.8 | -1.9 | -1.4 | -0.9 | -0.6 | — | ||
Structural balance2,4 | -6.0 | -3.8 | -3.9 | -3.3 | -3.4 | -3.4 | -3.8 | -1.8 | -2.0 | -2.3 | ||
Net debt | 107.7 | 107.0 | 103.9 | 103.3 | 102.6 | 105.1 | 105.2 | 104.5 | 103.8 | 101.6 | ||
Gross debt | 113.4 | 108.7 | 105.6 | 104.3 | 103.8 | 106.2 | 106.8 | 106.0 | 105.3 | 103.1 | ||
Japan | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -3.8 | -6.3 | -8.0 | -8.0 | -6.2 | -4.8 | -4.3 | -3.8 | -3.5 | -2.7 | ||
Excluding social security | -5.6 | -6.5 | -7.9 | -8.1 | -6.6 | -5.1 | -4.3 | -3.8 | -3.7 | -3.8 | ||
Output gap2 | — | -0.9 | -1.9 | -1.8 | -0.7 | -0.5 | — | 0.4 | 0.3 | — | ||
Structural balance2 | -3.8 | -5.8 | -7.2 | -7.2 | -5.8 | -4.6 | -4.3 | -3.9 | -3.7 | -2.7 | ||
Excluding social security | -5.6 | -6.3 | -7.4 | -7.7 | -6.4 | -5.0 | -4.3 | -3.9 | -3.8 | -3.9 | ||
Net debt | 31.7 | 66.0 | 72.5 | 77.3 | 81.8 | 93.3 | 96.4 | 98.2 | 99.4 | 99.5 | ||
Gross debt | 100.3 | 151.6 | 160.8 | 167.7 | 177.8 | 182.9 | 184.8 | 185.0 | 184.3 | 177.8 | ||
United Kingdom | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -3.3 | 1.1 | -1.6 | -3.2 | -3.1 | -3.0 | -2.5 | -2.4 | -2.2 | -1.6 | ||
Output gap2 | -0.6 | 0.6 | -0.1 | -0.2 | 0.5 | -0.2 | -0.2 | — | — | — | ||
Structural balance2 | -2.9 | 0.6 | -1.8 | -3.1 | -3.4 | -3.0 | -2.7 | -2.2 | -2.0 | -1.6 | ||
Net debt | 34.2 | 32.7 | 32.7 | 34.5 | 36.1 | 38.0 | 38.5 | 39.0 | 39.1 | 38.6 | ||
Gross debt | 39.8 | 38.4 | 37.9 | 39.3 | 40.8 | 42.7 | 43.2 | 43.6 | 43.7 | 43.2 | ||
Canada | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -3.6 | 0.7 | -0.1 | -0.4 | 0.5 | 1.4 | 0.9 | 0.6 | 0.7 | 0.9 | ||
Output gap2 | -0.5 | 0.5 | 0.4 | -0.5 | — | 0.2 | 0.2 | -0.2 | -0.1 | — | ||
Structural balance2 | -3.1 | 0.3 | -0.2 | -0.1 | 0.6 | 1.3 | 0.8 | 0.7 | 0.8 | 0.8 | ||
Net debt | 61.0 | 43.7 | 42.6 | 38.5 | 34.4 | 30.2 | 27.9 | 26.3 | 24.3 | 17.1 | ||
Gross debt | 105.2 | 91.5 | 89.4 | 85.2 | 80.2 | 78.6 | 74.1 | 70.7 | 66.5 | 51.9 |
Debt data refer to end of year. Debt data are not always comparable across countries.
Percent of potential GDP.
Beginning in 1995, the debt and debt-service obligations of the Treuhandanstalt (and of various other agencies) were taken over by general government. This debt is equivalent to 8 percent of GDP, and the associated debt service to ½ to 1 percent of GDP.
Excludes one-off receipts from the sale of mobile telephone licenses (the equivalent of 2.5 percent of GDP in 2000 for Germany, 0.1 percent of GDP in 2001 and 2002 for France, and 1.2 percent of GDP in 2000 for Italy). Also excludes one-off receipts from sizable asset transactions, in particular 0.5 percent of GDP for France in 2005.
Major Advanced Economies: General Government Fiscal Balances and Debt1
(Percent of GDP)
1991–2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 | 2006 | 2007 | 2008 | 2012 | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Major advanced economies | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -3.0 | -1.7 | -4.0 | -4.8 | -4.2 | -3.5 | -2.7 | -2.4 | -2.4 | -1.6 | ||
Output gap2 | 0.9 | 1.3 | - | -0.8 | -0.2 | -0.4 | -0.1 | -0.4 | -0.5 | — | ||
Structural balance2 | -3.2 | -2.2 | -3.9 | -4.4 | -4.1 | -3.3 | -2.7 | -2.3 | -2.2 | -1.6 | ||
United States | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -2.2 | -0.4 | -3.8 | -4.8 | -4.6 | -3.7 | -2.6 | -2.5 | -2.5 | -1.6 | ||
Output gap2 | 2.4 | 2.1 | 0.3 | -0.5 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.3 | -0.6 | -0.9 | — | ||
Structural balance2 | -2.9 | -1.2 | -3.9 | -4.6 | -4.5 | -3.6 | -2.7 | -2.4 | -2.4 | -1.6 | ||
Net debt | 49.4 | 35.5 | 38.3 | 41.1 | 42.8 | 43.6 | 43.4 | 44.2 | 44.6 | 43.7 | ||
Gross debt | 65.4 | 53.7 | 56.1 | 59.3 | 60.1 | 60.3 | 59.6 | 60.3 | 60.6 | 59.1 | ||
Euro area | ||||||||||||
Actual balance | -3.8 | -1.9 | -2.6 | -3.1 | -2.8 | -2.4 | -1.6 | -1.2 | -1.1 | -0.7 | ||
Output gap2 | -0.2 | 1.4 | 0.3 | -0.8 | -0.7 | -1.3 | -0.6 | -0.3 | — | — | ||
Structural balance2 | -3.4 | -2.3 | -2.6 | -2.7 |