Abstract

Jorge Iván Canales-Kriljenko

Jorge Iván Canales-Kriljenko

Acomprehensive survey conducted by the International Monetary Fund in 2001 systematically documented the structure and main characteristics of the foreign exchange market in developing countries. The 90 countries classified as …developing” or …in transition” that responded to the survey accounted in 2000 for 85 percent of exports, 91 percent of imports, and 85 percent of GDP of all the world’s developing economies.1 They also held about 90 percent of the developing economies’ international reserves.

Based on the survey results, this chapter discusses the prevalence of foreign exchange intervention in developing countries across different exchange rate regimes and degrees of market access; the degree of sterilization practices; the size of foreign exchange intervention relative to the foreign exchange market; and central banks’ information advantage.

Prevalence of Foreign Exchange Intervention

The central banks in developed countries that issue the major international currencies are not active participants in the foreign exchange market. Their monetary policies target short-term interest rates, while foreign exchange intervention is limited to calm disorderly market conditions. Foreign exchange intervention, in general, does not take place frequently. Although it can be large in absolute size, it is estimated to be small relative to total foreign exchange market turnover. In recent years, only the Bank of Japan was active in the foreign exchange market and intervened to any sizable degree. By contrast, neither the U.S. Federal Reserve (the Fed) nor the European Central Bank (ECB) conducted official foreign exchange intervention on its own behalf.2

Most central banks in developing economies intervened in the foreign exchange market across all exchange rate regimes and degrees of market access during 2001 (Table 3.1). Most of the foreign exchange intervention took place in spot foreign exchange markets through foreign exchange transactions arranged by telephone conversations with banks as main counterparties (Table 3.2).

Table 3.1.

Foreign Exchange Intervention by Exchange Rate Regime and Market Access, 2001

(Percentage of countries answering the corresponding survey question in each category)1

article image
Source: Survey on the organization of foreign exchange markets conducted in 2001 by the IMF.Note:—stands for not applicable, zero, or negligible amount.

Refers to the percentage of the 90 countries classified as …developing” and …in transition” that responded to the IMF 2001 survey on the foreign exchange market.

Follows the IMF’s de facto exchange rate regime classification as published in the IMF’s International Financial Statistics.

As so defined in the IMF’s quarterly publication Emerging Market Financing: A Quarterly Report on Developments and Prospects.

The Central African Economic and Monetary Community (CAEMC) is a conventional fixed peg arrangement.

Table 3.2.

Characteristics of Foreign Exchange Intervention in Developing and Transition Economies, 2001

(Percentage of countries answering the corresponding survey question in each category)1

article image
Source: Survey on the organization of foreign exchange markets conducted in 2001 by the IMF.

Refers to the percentage of the 90 countries classified as …developing” and …in transition” that responded to the IMF’s 2001 survey on the foreign exchange market.

Follows the IMF’s de facto exchange rate regime classification as published in the IMF’s International Financial Statistics. The pegged regimes are those without a country-specific currency, currency boards, and conventional fixed peg arrangements. Intermediate regimes have pegged exchange rates within horizontal bands, crawling pegs, and exchange rates within crawling bands. Flexible regimes have managed and independently floating exchange rate regimes.

As so defined in the IMF’s quarterly publication Emerging Market Financing: A Quarterly Report on Developments and Prospects.

Foreign exchange intervention is prevalent even under flexible exchange rate regimes.3 For example, in a managed floating exchange rate regime, the monetary authority influences the movements of the exchange rate through interest rate changes and active foreign exchange intervention, without specifying (or precommitting to) a preannounced path for the exchange rate. In an independently floating exchange rate regime, foreign exchange intervention may be conducted to moderate the rate of change and prevent undue fluctuations in the exchange rate, rather than establish a level for it.

Sterilized or Not Sterilized?

When the central banks that issue the major international currencies intervene, they tend to sterilize foreign exchange interventions to achieve their short-term operating targets of monetary policy, usually short-term interest rates. The Fed sterilizes its foreign exchange intervention to keep the amount of bank reserves at levels that are consistent with established monetary policy goals. In particular, liquidity is adjusted for consistency with the federal funds target. The ECB has sterilized its foreign exchange intervention on the few occasions that it has been in the market (Frenkel, Pierdzioch, and Stadtmann, 2001).4 The Bank of Japan conducts foreign exchange intervention as the agent of the ministry of finance, with funds from a special account of the Japanese government. Thus, foreign exchange intervention does not affect the money base. Foreign exchange purchases are funded by issuing short-term, yen-denominated bills, and yen purchases are funded by selling foreign exchange funds from the special account in the market (Bank of Japan, 2000; and Ito, 2002).

Unlike the Fed, the ECB, and the Bank of Japan, most central banks in developing economies do not fully sterilize their foreign exchange interventions on a regular basis (Table 3.3). About 10 percent of the survey respondents reported that foreign exchange intervention is never sterilized; about half indicated that it is sometimes sterilized; and about 20 percent said it is always sterilized. About 25 percent of survey respondents did not answer the corresponding section of the survey.

Table 3.3.

Developing and Transition Economies That Do Not Always Sterilize Foreign Exchange Intervention, by Exchange Rate Regime and Market Access, 2001

(Percentage of countries answering the corresponding survey question in each category)1

article image
Source: Survey on the organization of foreign exchange markets conducted in 2001 by the IMF.Note:—stands for not applicable, zero, or negligible amount.

Refers to the percentage of the 90 countries classified as …developing” and …in transition” that responded to the IMF 2001 survey on the foreign exchange market.

Follows the IMF’s de facto exchange rate regime classification as published in the IMF’s International Financial Statistics.

As so defined in the IMF’s quarterly publication Emerging Market Financing: A Quarterly Report on Developments and Prospects.

The Central African Economic and Monetary Community (CAEMC) is a conventional fixed peg arrangement.

The frequency of sterilization varied slightly by exchange rate regime and market access. Countries that sometimes sterilize their foreign exchange interventions can be found in almost all types of exchange rate regimes. The countries that never sterilize are concentrated in the less flexible exchange rate regimes, as would be expected, but account for only a small share of all countries following these regimes. The countries that always sterilize their foreign exchange interventions are more likely to be found in the more flexible exchange rate regimes with market access, but they can also be found in soft peg exchange rate regimes.

Relative Size of Foreign Exchange Intervention

Foreign exchange intervention by the central banks that issue the major international currencies accounts for a small fraction of annual foreign exchange market turnover. Even in the case of the Bank of Japan, foreign exchange intervention against U.S. dollars in 2000 accounted for less than 0.2 percent of estimated annual foreign exchange market turnover. However, the size of foreign exchange intervention on any given day may be substantial, reaching a peak of 16 percent of foreign exchange market turnover.5

Foreign exchange intervention by some central banks in developing economies accounts for a much larger portion of foreign exchange market turnover than that conducted by the central banks that issue the major international currencies, especially at the level of interbank trading (Table 3.4).6 In six of the countries that responded to the survey, the size of foreign exchange intervention exceeds the volume of interbank foreign exchange market turnover (excluding trades with the central bank). In contrast, the size of intervention is below 10 percent of the volume of interbank trading in four countries. The size of foreign exchange intervention is usually significantly smaller as a fraction of bank-customer trading, reflecting the fact that interbank trading in developing economies usually accounts for only a small amount of turnover in the bank-customer segment of the market.7

Table 3.4.

Magnitude of Foreign Exchange Intervention in Selected Developing and Transition Economies, 2000

(Percentage of foreign exchange market turnover at different levels of trading)

article image
Sources: Survey on the organization of foreign exchange markets conducted in 2001 by the IMF; Bank for International Settlements (2001), Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity; and Bank of Japan.

The names of the countries are omitted for purposes of confidentiality.

The different levels of foreign exchange market turnover exclude transactions with the central bank.

Foreign exchange intervention conducted in U.S. dollars in 2000 versus spot market turnover of the yen against the U.S. dollar on a yearly basis, as published in Table E-2 of the 2001 triennial survey statistical annex of the Bank for International Settlements. To compute the figure on a yearly basis, 22 trading days are assumed each month.

Several reasons may help explain the relatively large size of foreign exchange intervention by some central banks in developing economies. First, these central banks are usually large customers in the foreign exchange market. Second, they use a variety of foreign exchange, monetary, and banking regulations to increase their relative size in the foreign exchange market, among other objectives. Third, central bank foreign exchange operating practices may prevent the development of an interbank foreign exchange market containing the growth of the turnover in the foreign exchange market.

Central Banks as Large Customers in the Foreign Exchange Market

Many central banks in developing economies are important players in the foreign exchange markets on their own behalf or on behalf of their governments. These central banks may buy or sell foreign exchange as customers on their own behalf for several reasons. Foreign exchange can be used to meet their foreign expenditures, such as paying their own external debt, or to sell the foreign exchange received from loans to support the balance of payments, including those from multilateral lending institutions. These central banks can also enter the foreign exchange market to adjust the actual level of international reserves to the desired level, for example, to meet some reserve adequacy targets. In addition, they often buy and sell foreign exchange to defend the level of the exchange rate or to reduce exchange rate volatility.

Many central banks in developing economies also conduct foreign exchange operations on behalf of their governments, state enterprises, and nonbudgetary government agencies. More than half of the survey respondents reported that the central bank is the exclusive foreign exchange agent of the government, with the government trading foreign exchange only with the central bank.8 State-owned enterprises and nonbudgetary government agencies in many developing and transition economies are also required to trade foreign exchange exclusively with the central bank. The survey found that about 8 percent of respondents had this exclusive arrangement with state-owned enterprises and about 15 percent had it with government agencies.

The governments and their agencies in developing economies are often an important source of foreign exchange, especially where the size of the government in the economy is large. In particular, the government, state enterprises, and nonbudgetary government agencies account for a large portion of foreign exchange traded in many countries. Concentration arises where financial aid from foreign donors is the main source of foreign exchange. It also occurs in countries where state enterprises account for the bulk of the export receipts and in some open economies where foreign exchange traded domestically arises mainly from taxes and royalties paid in foreign exchange. Finally, the government often becomes a large supplier of foreign exchange in countries where the fiscal deficit is financed abroad.

Moreover, many central banks in developing economies conduct foreign exchange operations with government entities to achieve exchange rate policy objectives. On several occasions, governments and state-owned companies have borrowed abroad with the main purpose of affecting the evolution of the exchange rate rather than financing fiscal expenditures or the companies’ operations. As documented by Taylor (1982), this form of secret foreign exchange intervention was also practiced in some developed countries in the late 1970s.

Regulations

Many central banks in developing economies use foreign exchange controls and monetary regulations that increase the size of intervention relative to the foreign exchange market. In contrast, none of the measures described in this section are currently used by the central banks that issue the major international currencies.

Foreign Exchange Controls

Foreign exchange controls increase the size of foreign exchange intervention relative to the market by either reducing the size of the foreign exchange market or concentrating the foreign exchange supply in the hands of the central bank.

Capital controls can reduce cross-border movements of capital and the volume of foreign exchange market turnover, increasing the relative size of central bank foreign exchange intervention. Banning cross-border investments is a way of discouraging nonresidents from using the domestic currency and residents from using foreign currencies, thus reducing the potential volume of transactions in the foreign exchange market. Capital controls can prevent large capital movements and significant increases in foreign exchange market turnover that accompany deviations from interest rate parity not explained by differences in risk premiums.

Surrender requirements to the central bank are obligations to sell foreign exchange proceeds (usually from exports) within a specified time frame. When directed to the central bank, surrender requirements concentrate the foreign exchange supply in the hands of the central bank, turn the central bank into the main foreign exchange intermediary, and increase the relative size of foreign exchange intervention. In practice, surrender requirements exist in about 40 percent of the survey respondents, but they are seldom directed to the central bank.9

Prohibitions on interbank foreign exchange trading limit the size of the foreign exchange market, increasing the relative size of foreign exchange intervention. In a few developing economies, banks are allowed to conduct foreign exchange trading only on behalf of their customers. Banks can still conduct foreign exchange intermediation, buying from sources of foreign exchange and selling to end users of foreign exchange. But they cannot engage in market making activities.10

Many central banks in developing economies establish a combination of measures to discourage financial institutions from taking net open foreign exchange positions.11 The measures include limits on the level and daily variations of the financial institutions’ net open foreign exchange positions. The positions subject to limits usually include open forward foreign exchange positions, since unhedged forward foreign exchange positions can trigger large pressures on the spot exchange rates when banks need to hedge their exposure and cannot find an adequate counterparty to take the opposite forward foreign exchange position.

About half of the survey respondents have in place measures that restrict the operation of forward markets, reducing the ability of nonfinancial institutions to fund speculative positions and hedging exchange rate risk. In particular, about 15 percent of survey respondents explicitly prohibit banks from issuing forward contracts, and about 40 percent impose certain requirements on banks that offer forward contracts, most notably the requirement that banks offer these contracts only for hedging the exchange rate risk of legally permitted, underlying, international transactions. Foreign exchange regulations in some countries also control the maturity of the forward contracts offered to customers. About 45 percent of survey respondents allow banks to issue forward contracts without any controls. However, the scope for speculative net open position taking is limited by the level of development, liquidity, and depth of the market. In particular, only 9 percent of survey respondents consider their forward foreign exchange markets to be developed, liquid, and deep, while 30 percent consider them to be undeveloped, illiquid, and shallow (Table 3.5).12

Table 3.5.

Selected Regulations on Forward Foreign Exchange Transactions in Developing and Transition Economies, 2001

(Percentage of countries answering the corresponding survey question in each category)1

article image
Source: Survey on the organization of foreign exchange markets conducted in 2001 by the IMF.

Refers to the percentage of the 90 countries classified as …developing” and …in transition” that responded to the IMF 2001 survey on the foreign exchange market.

Follows the IMF’s de facto exchange rate regime classification as published in the IMF’s International Financial Statistics.

As so defined in the IMF’s quarterly publication Emerging Market Financing: A Quarterly Report on Developments and Prospects.

Monetary Regulations

Monetary regulations can increase the relative size of central bank foreign exchange intervention by reducing the residents’ use of foreign currencies and nonresidents’ use of the domestic currency.

To reduce the scope for currency substitution, most countries that issue their own currencies have granted a series of legal privileges to their domestic currency. Residents usually must use their domestic currency as means of payment. In particular, monetary regulations in many of the survey respondents give the domestic currency the exclusive role of means of payment (forced tender) or, at least, the advantage of legal tender so that it must be accepted in payment for financial obligations. Moreover, about half of the survey respondents explicitly prohibit their residents from making payments to other residents in foreign currencies.

Most countries allow residents to use foreign currencies as a store of value. Nearly all survey respondents allowed banks to accept foreign currency deposits, especially from exporters.13 Some developing countries explicitly prohibit other private sector residents from holding foreign currency deposits in domestic banks. Banks may also accept foreign currency deposits from the public sector, especially from state enterprises. The number of countries allowing their financial systems to offer foreign currency deposits to nonresidents is smaller. The degree of dollarization of private sector deposits is above 10 percent in about half of the survey respondents, reaching the 75 to 100 percent range in a few countries.14

In addition, about one-third of developing economies impose controls on the use of their domestic currencies by nonresidents abroad. To avoid fueling speculation in foreign exchange markets, many countries—about 30 percent of survey respondents—explicitly prohibit their banking systems from extending short-term loans in domestic currency to nonresidents.

Information Advantage

To infer exchange rate pressures embedded in foreign exchange market activity, the literature on the microstructure of such markets emphasizes the importance of foreign exchange order flow. A positive foreign exchange order flow reflects an excess demand for foreign exchange that would tend to depreciate the domestic currency. Lyons (2001) surveys the literature that has empirically documented the positive relationship between order flow and exchange rate changes, and Vitale (2001) puts forward a theoretical argument in the context of foreign exchange intervention.

Some central banks in developing economies make use of their ability to issue regulations to obtain an information advantage over other market participants, requesting, among other things, specifics about foreign exchange order flow. They require market participants to submit information about their foreign exchange activities, sometimes in great detail.15 The information advantage arises because only a subset of the information collected is made available to other foreign exchange market participants. The data requested vary significantly across countries, ranging from all information on each of the foreign exchange transactions made by each authorized dealer to summary statistics, sometimes weighted by the size of the transactions. The collected information available to central banks often includes data for every licensed dealer on exchange rates (whose dispersion reflects the uncertainty in the foreign exchange market) and foreign exchange transaction volumes.

From the information on foreign exchange transactions, central banks can infer the size of foreign exchange order flow aggregated at some levels of trading.16 For example, in transactions between banks and their customers, market turnover usually equals aggregate foreign exchange order flow because customers are usually those initiating the foreign exchange transaction at the exchange rate quoted by dealer banks, especially in competitive foreign exchange markets where market makers operate. However, in transactions among banks, foreign exchange market turnover usually differs from foreign exchange order flow. The lack of order flow data at the interbank level is less important in developing and transition economies with shallow interbank markets since interbank trading accounts for a smaller fraction of the total foreign exchange order flow in the market.

Information about the net open foreign exchange positions of authorized dealers can be used to anticipate changes in order flow, as dealers with currency exposure are likely to go to the market to cover their positions, affecting order flow, when changes in the expected path of the exchange rate take place. This information also helps identify foreign exchange dealers that may be taking large net open foreign exchange positions and contributing to pressures on the exchange rate. In most developing countries, banks must report to the central bank their net open foreign exchange positions more than once a month, but the information obtained is seldom published.17 Most reporting is done daily. Weekly reporting is more common than monthly in all regions except Eastern Europe. About 70 percent of the countries with net open foreign exchange position limits, however, never publish this information.

In addition to obtaining information from reporting requirements, some central banks in developing economies obtain privileged information about foreign exchange order flow in certain centralized trading environments, for instance, when conducting foreign exchange auctions. Central banks conduct most foreign exchange auctions in 15 developing and transition economies that responded to the survey. The central bank actively participated in the auctions in three countries, but it indirectly participated in many other auctions by deciding the amounts to be auctioned. A few central banks also have privileged access to the information generated in electronic broking systems.18 The central bank may be able to compute foreign exchange order flow directly in countries where it observes foreign exchange transactions that take place among banks through an electronic broking system. However, this would cover only a fraction of the total foreign exchange order flow, since banks can usually trade among themselves outside of those trading platforms.

Control of the payment and settlement systems in the country can also give an information edge to the central bank, as many central banks in developing economies are directly involved in the settlement of foreign exchange transactions. In particular, control of these systems allows the settlement of one or both legs of foreign exchange transactions at central bank accounts. In many of the survey respondents where financial institutions are often required to open accounts at the central bank to meet reserve requirements, the debiting and crediting take place at central bank accounts. The foreign currency leg settlement requires that foreign currency accounts be opened at the central bank, a situation that often arises in dollarized economies in which the reserve requirements on foreign currency deposits are denominated in foreign currency.19 However, the information advantage obtained from the control of the payment and settlement systems may be difficult to obtain in practice unless special arrangements for the settlement of foreign exchange transactions are in place to distinguish foreign exchange from other transactions.

Conclusions

The evidence from the IMF’s 2001 survey on the organization of foreign exchange markets indicates that foreign exchange intervention is a widely used policy instrument in developing and transition economies.

The survey results show that official foreign exchange intervention conducted by some central banks in developing economies differs in a number of ways from that of the central banks of developed countries that issue the major international currencies. First, unlike the U.S. Federal Reserve Board, the European Central Bank, and the Bank of Japan, not all central banks in developing economies fully sterilize their foreign exchange operations on a regular basis. Many developing-country central banks back up their foreign exchange interventions with adjustments to their monetary policy stance. Second, unlike the central banks that issue the major international currencies, some central banks in developing economies conduct foreign exchange intervention in amounts that are significant relative to the level of foreign exchange market turnover, the money base, and the stock of domestic bonds outstanding. Third, some central banks in developing economies have a greater information advantage over the central banks that issue the major international currencies because, among other reasons, they can infer the aggregate foreign exchange order flow from reporting requirements. Finally, many central banks in developing economies also use foreign exchange and monetary regulations, as well as their own foreign exchange operating practices, to increase their information advantage and the size of foreign exchange intervention relative to the market.

1

The survey was sent to all 160 IMF member countries classified as …developing” or …in transition.” For more detail on the survey results, see Canales-Kriljenko (2003). See also Cheung and Chinn (1999) and Neely (2001).

2

The ECB drew from a foreign exchange swap arrangement signed with the Federal Reserve Bank of New York in the aftermath of the September 11, 2001, terrorist attacks, which alleviated liquidity demands that could have otherwise generated large pressures on the exchange rate. However, it cannot be considered foreign exchange intervention because the purpose of the operation was not to affect exchange rates but to smooth potential disruptions in the payment systems. Moreover, although a foreign exchange swap theoretically involves simultaneous spot and forward foreign exchange operations, market makers hedge their exposure by operations in the money market rather than in the foreign exchange market.

3

See Ishii and others (2003) for a discussion of exchange rate regime classification based on de facto policies.

4

The intervention operations conducted during 2001 by the ECB, and not considered in Frenkel, Pierdzioch, and Stadtmann (2001), were also sterilized. In particular, the foreign exchange intervention conducted on behalf of the Bank of Japan did not affect the money base.

5

This calculation considers only total turnover in the spot market between yen and U.S. dollars, as documented by the Triennial Central Bank Survey of the Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity of the Bank for International Settlements (2001). About 95 percent of foreign exchange intervention by the Bank of Japan is conducted against U.S. dollars.

6

Only a few survey respondents provided information about the amounts of foreign exchange intervention and foreign exchange market turnover that allows for the comparison.

7

In contrast, interbank trading accounts for most of the foreign exchange market turnover among the major international currencies.

8

In some countries, the government is not allowed to hold foreign currency deposits and must surrender its foreign exchange to the central bank. In others, the government may keep foreign exchange deposits in or out of the central bank, but when it decides to exchange them, it has to conduct the exchange through the central bank.

9

Surrender requirements to the government may be motivated by a desire to allocate foreign exchange to particular uses, make more foreign exchange available to the central bank for foreign exchange intervention in periods of pressure on the exchange rate, or meet public foreign exchange expenditure commitments.

10

The central bank thus reduces competition from the market in setting exchange rates, which increases the impact of foreign exchange intervention on the exchange rate.

11

Net open foreign exchange positions also play an important prudential role by limiting banks’ exposure to exchange rate risk.

12

In contrast, about 40 percent of the survey respondents perceived their spot foreign exchange markets to be developed, liquid, and deep, while only 6 percent perceived them to be undeveloped, illiquid, and shallow.

13

When the country imposes the requirement to surrender export receipts to the foreign exchange market, the exporter can often keep foreign exchange earnings in a foreign currency account for a period before it must sell the foreign exchange.

14

The survey did not capture information on the number of countries prohibiting financial contracts from being indexed to the exchange rate, which would preserve the store-of-value role of foreign currencies and could give rise to exchange rate pressures.

15

The provision of such information is often a condition for conducting foreign exchange intermediation, to the extent that some-times the obligation to provide information to the central bank is embedded in the foreign exchange license.

16

Reporting requirements provide a good picture of foreign exchange market turnover in a country where institutions reporting to the central bank make up the bulk of foreign exchange market turnover. This is more likely to be the case in about half of the countries in the sample, which actually prohibit the offshore trading of their currencies.

17

The United States requests information on the net open foreign exchange positions of the internationally active international banks every quarter. That information is available at http://www.fms.treas.gov/bulletin/index.html.

18

According to the survey, electronic broking systems are in place in about 40 percent of emerging market economies.

19

The fact that most countries also report that the foreign currency leg is settled at the accounts of correspondent banks abroad suggests that the central bank accounts serve as an intermediate netting scheme but that the final payments must be done at the accounts of correspondent banks, transferring money to or from the central bank.

Cited By

  • Andersen, Torben, and Tim Bollerslev, 1998, “Answering the Skeptics: Yes, Standard Volatility Models Do Provide Accurate Forecasts,” International Economic Review, Vol. 39, No. 4, pp. 885 –905.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements, 1994, Macroeconomic and Monetary Policy Issues Raised by the Growth of Derivatives Markets (Basel).

  • Bank for International Settlements, 2001, Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity (Basel: Bank for International Settlements).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank of Japan, 2000, “Outline of the Bank of Japan’s Foreign Exchange Intervention Operations.” Available via the Internet: www.boj.or.jp/en/about/basic/etc/faqkainy.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baillie, Richard T., and William Osterberg, 1997, “Why Do Central Banks Intervene?” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 16, No. 6, pp. 909 –19.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bartolini, Leonardo, 2002, “Foreign Exchange Swaps,” New England Economic Review, Second Quarter, p. 11.

  • Beattie, Neil, and Jean-Francois Fillion, 1999, “An Intraday Analysis of the Effectiveness of Foreign Exchange Intervention,” Bank of Canada Working Paper 99–4 (Ottawa: Bank of Canada).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beine, Michel, Agnès Bénassy-Quéré, and Christelle Lecourt, 2002, “Central Bank Intervention and Foreign Exchange Rates: New Evidence from FIGARCH Estimations,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 21, No. 1, pp. 115 –144.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bjorksten, Nils, and Anne-Marie Brook, 2002, “Exchange Rate Strategies for Small Open Developed Economies Such as New Zealand,” Reserve Bank of New Zealand Bulletin, Vol. 65 (March).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bonser-Neal, Catherine, and Glen Tanner, 1996, “Central Bank Intervention and the Volatility of Foreign Exchange Rates: Evidence from the Options Market,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 15, No. 6, pp. 853 –78.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bredin, Don, Stilianos Fountas, and Eithne Murphy, 2002, “An Empirical Analysis of Short-Run and Long-Run Irish Exports: Does Exchange Rate Volatility Matter?” Central Bank of Ireland Research Technical Paper 01/RT/02 (Dublin: Central Bank and Financial Services Authority of Ireland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Breuer, Peter, 1999, “Central Bank Participation in Currency Options Markets,” IMF Working Paper 99/140 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bubula, Andrea, and Inci Otker-Robe, 2002, “The Evolution of Exchange Rate Regimes Since 1990: Evidence from De Facto Policies,” IMF Working Paper 02/155 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Carmen Reinhart, 2002, “Fear of Floating,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117 (May), pp. 379 –408.

  • Canales-Kriljenko, Jorge Iván, 2003, “Foreign Exchange Intervention in Developing and Transition Economies: Results of a Survey,” IMF Working Paper 03/95 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Canales-Kriljenko, Jorge Iván, 2004, “Foreign Exchange Market Organization in Selected Developing and Transition Economies: Evidence from a Survey,” IMF Working Paper 04/4 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Canales-Kriljenko, Jorge Iván, Roberto Guimarães, and Cem Karacadag, 2003, “Official Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market: Elements of Best Practice,” IMF Working Paper 03/152 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carstens, Agustín G., and Alejandro M. Werner, 1999, “Mexico’s Monetary Policy Framework Under a Floating Exchange,” Documento de Investigación No. 9905 (Mexico City: Bank of Mexico, May).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Central Bank of Turkey, 2001, Annual Report (Ankara).

  • Central Bank of Turkey, 2002, Annual Report (Ankara).

  • Central Bank of Turkey, 2003, “General Framework of the Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy in 2003,” Press Release 2003–2 (Ankara).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cheung, Yin-Wong, and Menzie Chinn, 1999, “Currency Traders and Exchange Rate Dynamics: A Survey of the U.S. Market,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 20, No. 4, pp. 439 –71.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cumby, Robert, and Obstfeld, Maurice, 1983, “Capital Mobility and the Scope for Sterilization: Mexico in the 1970s,” in Financial Policies and the World Capital Market: The Problem of Latin American Countries, ed. by Pedro Aspe, Rudiger Dornbusch, and Maurice Obstfeld (Chicago: Chicago University Press), pp. 245 –69.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Domaç, Iker, and Alfonso Mendoza, 2002, “Is There Room for Foreign Intervention Under Inflation Targeting Framework? Evidence from Mexico and Turkey,” CBT Discussion Paper (Ankara: Central Bank of Turkey, December).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dominguez, Kathryn M., 1998, “Central Bank Intervention and Exchange Rate Volatility,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 17, No. 1, pp. 161 –90.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dominguez, Kathryn M., 2003, “The Market Microstructure of Central Bank Intervention,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 59, No. 1, pp. 25 –45.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dominguez, Kathryn M., and Jeffrey Frankel, 1993a, “Does Foreign Exchange Intervention Matter? The Portfolio Effect” American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 5, pp. 1356 –69.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dominguez, Kathryn M., and Jeffrey Frankel, 1993b, Does Foreign Exchange Intervention Work? (Washington: Institute for International Economics).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edison, Hali J., 1993, “The Effectiveness of Central-Bank Intervention: A Survey of the Literature After 1982,” Special Papers in International Economics, No. 18 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edison, Hali J., Paul Cashin, and Hong Liang, 2003, “Foreign Exchange Intervention and the Australian Dollar: Has It Mattered?” IMF Working Paper 03/99 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Enoch, Charles, 1998, “Transparency in Central Bank Operations in the Foreign Exchange Market,” IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment 98/2 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Central Bank, 2000, “The Single Monetary Policy in Stage Three: General Documentation on Eurosystem Monetary Policy Instruments and Procedures” (Frankfurt).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Evans, Martin D., and Richard Lyons, 2002, “Order Flow and Exchange Rate Dynamics,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 110 (February), pp. 170 –80.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Evans, Martin D., and Richard Lyons, 2005, “Are Different-Currency Assets Imperfect Substitutes?” in Exchange Rate Economics: Where Do We Stand? ed. by Paul De Grauwe (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press), pp. 1 –38.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fatum, Rasmus, 2000, “On the Effectiveness of Sterilized Foreign Exchange Intervention,” ECB Working Paper No. 10 (Frankfurt: European Central Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fatum, Rasmus, and Michael M. Hutchison, 2003a, “Effectiveness of Official Daily Foreign Exchange Market Intervention Operations in Japan,” NBER Working Paper No. 9648 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fatum, Rasmus, and Michael M. Hutchison, 2003b, “Is Sterilised Foreign Exchange Intervention Effective After All? An Event Study Approach,” Economic Journal, Vol. 113 (April), pp. 390 –411.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Markets Association, 2002, “The Model Code: The International Code of Conduct and Practice for the Financial Markets” (October) (Paris). Available via the Internet: www.aciforex.com/.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frenkel, Michael, Christian Pierdzioch, and Georg Stadt-mann, 2001, “The Foreign Exchange Interventions of the European Central Bank,” Banca Nazionale Del Lavoro Quarterly Review, Vol. 54, No. 218, pp. 249 –87.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Galán Medina, M., J. Duclaud González de Castillo, and A. Garcia Tames, 1997, “A Strategy for Accumulating Reserves Through Options to Sell Dollars,” Bank of Mexico, Mexico City. Available via the Internet: www.banxico.org.mx/siteBanxicoINGLES/bPoliticaMonetaria/FSpoliticaMonetaria.html.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guimarães, Roberto, 2004, “Foreign Exchange Intervention and Monetary Policy in Japan: Evidence from Identified VARs,” Money, Macro, and Finance Research Conference, Cass Business School, London. Available via the Internet: www.cass.city.ac.uk/conferences/mmf2004/day1.html.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hausmann, Ricardo, Ugo Panizza, and Ernesto Stein, 2001, “Why Do Countries Float the Way They Float?” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 66, No. 2, pp. 387 –414.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ho, Corrinne, and Robert N. McCauley, 2003, “Living with Flexible Exchange Rates: Issues and Recent Experience in Inflation Targeting Emerging Market Economies,” BIS Working Paper No. 130 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hooyman, Catharina J., 1994, “The Use of Foreign Exchange Swaps by Central Banks,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 41, No. 1, pp. 149 –62.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hung, Juann H., 1997, “Intervention Strategies and Exchange Rate Volatility: A Noise Trading Perspective,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 16, No. 5, pp. 779 –93.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 1998, “Reserve Impact of Forward Foreign Exchange Market Intervention,” International Capital Markets Report (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2002a, Annual Report on Exchange Arrangement and Exchange Restrictions (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2002b, “Principles of Fund Surveillance Members’ Exchange Rate Policies,” in Selected Decisions and Selected Documents of the International Monetary Fund, Twenty-Sixth Issue. Available via the Internet: www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sd/index.asp? decision=5392-(77/63).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ishii, Shogo, Karl Habermeier, John Leimone, Inci Otker-Robe, and Jorge Iván Canales-Kriljenko, 2003, Exchange Arrangements and Foreign Exchange Markets: Developments and Issues, IMF World Economic and Financial Survey Series (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ito, Takatoshi, 2002, “Is Foreign Exchange Intervention Effective? The Japanese Experiences in the 1990s,” NBER Working Paper No. 8914 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jones, Michael, 1984, “Optimal Foreign Exchange Intervention: Evidence from the Bretton Woods Era,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 66, No. 2, pp. 242 –55.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jorion, Phillipe, 1996, “Risk and Turnover in the Foreign Exchange Market,” in The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets, ed. by Jeffrey Frankel, Giampaolo Galli, and Alberto Giovannini (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Killeen, William, Richard Lyons, Michael Moore, 2001, “Fixed Versus Flexible: Lessons from EMS Order Flow,” NBER Working Paper No. 8491 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kim, Soyoung, 2003, “Monetary Policy, Foreign Exchange Intervention, and the Exchange Rate in a Unifying Framework,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 60, No. 2, pp. 355 –86.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lyons, Richard, 2001, The Microstructure Approach to Exchange Rates (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Mandeng, Ousmene-Jacques, 2003, “Central Bank Foreign Exchange Market Intervention and Option Contract Specification: The Case of Colombia,” IMF Working Paper 03/135 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mark, Nelson, 2001, International Macroeconomics and Finance: Theory and Econometric Methods (New York: Blackwell Publishers).

  • Moreno, Ramon, 1997, “Lessons from Thailand,” FRBSF Economic Letter, No. 97–33 (San Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mulder, Christian, and Roberto Perrelli, 2001, “Foreign Currency Credit Ratings for Emerging Market Economies,” IMF Working Paper 01/191 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Murray, John, Mark Zelmer, and Des McManus, 1996, “The Effect of Intervention on Canadian Dollar Volatility,” in Exchange Rates and Monetary Policy, proceedings of a conference held by the Bank of Canada, October.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mussa, Michael, 1981, “The Role of Official Intervention,” Group of Thirty Occasional Paper No. 6 (Washington: Group of Thirty).

  • Mussa, Michael, and Miguel A. Savastano, 1999, “The IMF Approach to Economic Stabilization,” IMF Working Paper 99/104 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Neely, Christopher, 2001, “The Practice of Central Bank Intervention: Looking Under the Hood,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Vol. 83, No. 3, pp. 1 –10.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nelson, Daniel, 1991, “Conditional Heteroskedasticity in Asset Returns: A New Approach,” Econometrica, Vol. 59, No. 2, pp. 347 –70.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1990, “The Effectiveness of Foreign-Exchange Intervention: Recent Experience, 1985–1988,” in International Policy Coordination and Exchange Rate Fluctuations, ed. by William Branson, Jacob Frenkel, and Morris Goldstein (Chicago: University of Chicago Press),pp. 197 –237.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Popper, Helen, and John Montgomery, 2001, “Information Sharing and Central Bank Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 55, No. 2, pp. 295 –316.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ramaswamy, Ramana, and Hossein Samiei, 2000, “The Yen-Dollar Rate—Have Interventions Mattered?” IMF Working Paper 00/95 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinhart, Carmen, and Kenneth Rogoff, 2003, “Evolution and Performance of Exchange Rate Regimes” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reserve Bank of India, 2002, “Inclusion of Euro as an Additional Intervention Currency,” Press Release No. 986/2001–2002 dated 04.03.2002, based on Notification S.O.235(E) dated February 27, 2002. Available via the Internet: www.gujaratchamber.org/notificationsrbi1.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rogoff, Kenneth, 1999, “Perspectives on Exchange Rate Volatility,” in International Capital Flows, ed. by Martin Feldstein (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 441 –53.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roper, Don E., and Stephen J. Turnovsky, 1980, “Optimal Exchange Market Intervention in a Simple Stochastic Macro Model,” Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 13, No. 2, pp. 296 –309.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sarno, Lucio, and Mark P. Taylor, 2001, “Official Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market: Is It Effective, and If So, How Does It Work?” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 39 (September), pp. 839 –68.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sarno, Lucio, and Mark P. Taylor, 2002, The Economics of Exchange Rates (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

  • Sveriges, Riksbank, 1999, “Currency Market Primary Dealer Agreement” (unpublished; Stockholm).

  • Tanner, Evan, 1998, “Deviation from Uncovered Interest Rate Parity: A Global Guide to Where the Action Is,” IMF Working Paper 98/117 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tapia, Matías, and Andrea Tokman, 2004, “Effects of Foreign Exchange Intervention Under Public Information: The Chilean Case,” Central Bank of Chile Working Papers No. 255 (Santiago: Central Bank of Chile).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Taylor, Dean, 1982, “Official Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market, or Bet Against the Central Bank,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90 (April), pp. 256 –68.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Vitale, Paolo, 2001, “Foreign Exchange Intervention, Policy Objectives, and Macroeconomic Stability,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 2886 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Werner, Alejandro, 1997, “El Efecto Sobre el Tipo de Cambio y las Tasas de Interes de las Intervenciones en el Mercado Cambiario y del Proceso de Esterilización,” Documento de Investigación No. 9706 (Mexico City: Bank of Mexico).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Werner, Alejandro, and Alexis Milo, 1998, “Acumulación de Reservas Internacionales a Través de la Venta de Opciones: El Caso de México,” Documento de Investigación No. 9801 (Mexico City: Bank of Mexico).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zapatero, Fernando, and Luis F. Reverter, 2003, “Foreign Exchange Intervention with Options,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 22, No. 2, pp. 289 –306.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation