Recent years have witnessed a dramatic decline in inflation in emerging market economies.1 By the end of 2000, average inflation in emerging markets had declined from triple-digit figures in the late 1980s to some 5 percent excluding a few outlier cases—Indonesia, Turkey, and Venezuela (Table 4.1). Such low levels of inflation have not been seen since before World War II, when, mostly under the discipline of the gold standard system of fixed exchange rates, prices were roughly stable and episodes of deflation were not uncommon. The recent decline of inflation in emerging markets looks all the more impressive against the background of the 1970s and 1980s. Inflation began to rise gradually in the 1950s, but it accelerated dramatically in the 1970s and early 1980s, culminating in several episodes of triple-digit annual inflation and four major hyperinflations in the late 1980s/early 1990s (Figure 4.1).2 From that point on, disinflation was steep.
Inflation in Industrial Countries and Emerging Markets1
(Annual percent)
Average of annual percent change of the consumer price index over the specified period.
Inflation in Industrial Countries and Emerging Markets1
(Annual percent)
1900-13 | 1930-39 | 1950-60 | 1961-70 | 1971-80 | 1981-90 | 1991-95 | 1996-2000 | 2000 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Advanced Economies | 1.5 | 0.2 | 4.3 | 4.0 | 10.8 | 8.1 | 3.9 | 2.0 | 2.5 |
Selected Emerging Markets | 1.2 | 1.6 | 15.2 | 18.3 | 29.8 | 139.7 | 94.4 | 23.4 | 7.8 |
Selected Emerging Markets, excluding Bulgaria, Indonesia, Venezuela, and Turkey | 1.2 | 2.8 | 15.0 | 9.2 | 31.4 | 161.1 | 100.0 | 9.1 | 5.2 |
Average of annual percent change of the consumer price index over the specified period.
Inflation in Industrial Countries and Emerging Markets1
(Annual percent)
1900-13 | 1930-39 | 1950-60 | 1961-70 | 1971-80 | 1981-90 | 1991-95 | 1996-2000 | 2000 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Advanced Economies | 1.5 | 0.2 | 4.3 | 4.0 | 10.8 | 8.1 | 3.9 | 2.0 | 2.5 |
Selected Emerging Markets | 1.2 | 1.6 | 15.2 | 18.3 | 29.8 | 139.7 | 94.4 | 23.4 | 7.8 |
Selected Emerging Markets, excluding Bulgaria, Indonesia, Venezuela, and Turkey | 1.2 | 2.8 | 15.0 | 9.2 | 31.4 | 161.1 | 100.0 | 9.1 | 5.2 |
Average of annual percent change of the consumer price index over the specified period.

Inflation Over Time
(Percent change)
Emerging markets in Latin America, Europe, Africa, and the Middle East have recently accomplished a marked reduction in inflation, while Asia continues to sustain moderate to low inflation.
Sources: Brian Mitchell, International Historical Statistics (New York: Stockton Press, 1998); and IMF staff estimates.
Inflation Over Time
(Percent change)
Emerging markets in Latin America, Europe, Africa, and the Middle East have recently accomplished a marked reduction in inflation, while Asia continues to sustain moderate to low inflation.
Sources: Brian Mitchell, International Historical Statistics (New York: Stockton Press, 1998); and IMF staff estimates.Inflation Over Time
(Percent change)
Emerging markets in Latin America, Europe, Africa, and the Middle East have recently accomplished a marked reduction in inflation, while Asia continues to sustain moderate to low inflation.
Sources: Brian Mitchell, International Historical Statistics (New York: Stockton Press, 1998); and IMF staff estimates.This rise and fall of inflation in emerging markets appears to reflect in part changes in the international monetary system and inflation trends in advanced countries. One notable feature of the post-World War II period was an increase in inflation persistence compared with earlier historical eras, when inflation was either generalized and gradual (e.g., following the gold discoveries of the fifteenth through the nineteenth century), or rapid and specific, reflecting exceptional fiscal strains (as during or immediately after wars).3 This gradual increase in the persistence of inflation, combined with the breakup of the Bretton Woods international system of commodity-based money and the associated removal of external constraints on accommodative monetary policies, made it possible for the supply shocks of the 1970s to push world inflation to unprecedented peacetime levels, producing the “Great Inflation” of the 1970s and early 1980s.4 To the extent that emerging markets imported this inflation, loosened fiscal policies, and also adopted increasingly accommodative monetary policies during the period, these external trends were reflected in those countries’ prices and magnified further. Conversely, as governments in advanced countries responded to public dissatisfaction with inflation, and institutional and operational changes were put in place to foster monetary and fiscal policy discipline, this helped bring inflation in advanced countries back under control. This combination of falling external inflation and the adoption of sounder macroeconomic policies, also in response to public dissatisfaction with high inflation, explains much of the recent fall in inflation in emerging markets.
Within this broad picture, inflation performance has varied widely across emerging market countries and regions (Table 4.2). Asia has had the lowest inflation during much of the post-World War II period—a development associated with fiscal prudence and sound macroeconomic policies. Latin America has had the highest inflation, featuring several cases of long-lasting tripledigit inflation and hyperinflations associated with deep-seated fiscal problems and monetary accommodation. In between the Asian and Latin American extremes lie the experiences of the emerging markets of Africa, the Middle East, and Eastern Europe. Inflation has been persistently high in some (as in Israel through the early 1990s and Turkey to date), while in others, such as the Czech Republic, Poland, and Hungary, the combination of dismantling of price controls, nominal rigidities, and fiscal problems produced brief episodes of high inflation followed by gradual disinflation from the mid-1990s.
Inflation in Emerging Markets
(Annual percent change in the consumer price index)
Before 1993, the data refers to Czechoslovakia.
Before 1991, the data refers to the Soviet Union.
Inflation in Emerging Markets
(Annual percent change in the consumer price index)
1961-70 | 1971-80 | 1981-90 | 1991-95 | 1996-2000 | 2000 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Africa/Middle East | ||||||
Egypt | 3.2 | 9.5 | 17.0 | 13.9 | 4.4 | 2.7 |
Israel | 5.6 | 45.0 | 118.3 | 12.9 | 6.4 | 1.1 |
South Africa | 2.8 | 10.7 | 14.7 | 11.3 | 6.5 | 4.5 |
Asia | ||||||
China | … | 4.1 | 7.2 | 13.1 | 1.8 | 0.3 |
India | 6.4 | 8.2 | 8.9 | 10.5 | 7.5 | 3.4 |
Indonesia | 210.6 | 17.5 | 8.6 | 8.9 | 19.1 | 2.5 |
Korea | 14.8 | 16.5 | 6.4 | 6.2 | 4.0 | 2.3 |
Malaysia | 0.9 | 6.0 | 3.2 | 4.3 | 3.1 | 1.3 |
Pakistan | 3.5 | 12.4 | 7.0 | 11.2 | 7.3 | 4.4 |
Philippines | 5.7 | 14.9 | 13.7 | 10.1 | 7.1 | 4.4 |
Thailand | 2.3 | 10.0 | 4.4 | 4.8 | 4.3 | 1.5 |
Emerging Europe | ||||||
Bulgaria | … | … | 7.6 | 132.1 | 242.3 | 10.4 |
Czech Republic1 | 1.0 | 1.1 | 3.4 | 19.2 | 6.8 | 3.9 |
Hungary | 10.3 | 9.7 | 10.9 | 25.4 | 15.1 | 9.7 |
Poland | … | 4.7 | 107.7 | 44.0 | 12.8 | 10.1 |
Russia2 | 1.2 | 3.3 | 2.0 | 583.7 | 39.3 | 20.8 |
Turkey | 4.0 | 33.6 | 46.3 | 79.3 | 74.1 | 54.9 |
Latin America | ||||||
Argentina | 21.5 | 141.7 | 787.0 | 42.9 | -0.1 | -0.8 |
Brazil | 33.6 | 41.7 | 613.8 | 1113.8 | 7.6 | 7.5 |
Chile | 27.2 | 174.8 | 20.4 | 13.9 | 5.2 | 3.8 |
Colombia | 11.5 | 21.3 | 23.7 | 25.0 | 16.0 | 9.5 |
Mexico | 2.7 | 16.8 | 69.1 | 18.0 | 19.4 | 9.5 |
Peru | 9.4 | 31.9 | 1223.6 | 113.3 | 6.9 | 3.8 |
Venezuela | 1.1 | 8.5 | 24.9 | 44.9 | 45.1 | 16.2 |
Before 1993, the data refers to Czechoslovakia.
Before 1991, the data refers to the Soviet Union.
Inflation in Emerging Markets
(Annual percent change in the consumer price index)
1961-70 | 1971-80 | 1981-90 | 1991-95 | 1996-2000 | 2000 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Africa/Middle East | ||||||
Egypt | 3.2 | 9.5 | 17.0 | 13.9 | 4.4 | 2.7 |
Israel | 5.6 | 45.0 | 118.3 | 12.9 | 6.4 | 1.1 |
South Africa | 2.8 | 10.7 | 14.7 | 11.3 | 6.5 | 4.5 |
Asia | ||||||
China | … | 4.1 | 7.2 | 13.1 | 1.8 | 0.3 |
India | 6.4 | 8.2 | 8.9 | 10.5 | 7.5 | 3.4 |
Indonesia | 210.6 | 17.5 | 8.6 | 8.9 | 19.1 | 2.5 |
Korea | 14.8 | 16.5 | 6.4 | 6.2 | 4.0 | 2.3 |
Malaysia | 0.9 | 6.0 | 3.2 | 4.3 | 3.1 | 1.3 |
Pakistan | 3.5 | 12.4 | 7.0 | 11.2 | 7.3 | 4.4 |
Philippines | 5.7 | 14.9 | 13.7 | 10.1 | 7.1 | 4.4 |
Thailand | 2.3 | 10.0 | 4.4 | 4.8 | 4.3 | 1.5 |
Emerging Europe | ||||||
Bulgaria | … | … | 7.6 | 132.1 | 242.3 | 10.4 |
Czech Republic1 | 1.0 | 1.1 | 3.4 | 19.2 | 6.8 | 3.9 |
Hungary | 10.3 | 9.7 | 10.9 | 25.4 | 15.1 | 9.7 |
Poland | … | 4.7 | 107.7 | 44.0 | 12.8 | 10.1 |
Russia2 | 1.2 | 3.3 | 2.0 | 583.7 | 39.3 | 20.8 |
Turkey | 4.0 | 33.6 | 46.3 | 79.3 | 74.1 | 54.9 |
Latin America | ||||||
Argentina | 21.5 | 141.7 | 787.0 | 42.9 | -0.1 | -0.8 |
Brazil | 33.6 | 41.7 | 613.8 | 1113.8 | 7.6 | 7.5 |
Chile | 27.2 | 174.8 | 20.4 | 13.9 | 5.2 | 3.8 |
Colombia | 11.5 | 21.3 | 23.7 | 25.0 | 16.0 | 9.5 |
Mexico | 2.7 | 16.8 | 69.1 | 18.0 | 19.4 | 9.5 |
Peru | 9.4 | 31.9 | 1223.6 | 113.3 | 6.9 | 3.8 |
Venezuela | 1.1 | 8.5 | 24.9 | 44.9 | 45.1 | 16.2 |
Before 1993, the data refers to Czechoslovakia.
Before 1991, the data refers to the Soviet Union.
Given the harm caused by high inflation (see in Box 4.1), the recent decline of inflation in emerging markets is clearly welcome. Whether this more stable price environment is likely to be permanent and what steps need to be taken to keep inflation under control are questions of considerable policy relevance that have yet to be settled. This chapter aims to shed light on these issues by reviewing the cross-country evidence and by highlighting the main threats to the current low inflation environment. Four broad questions are addressed:
Why has inflation been historically high in emerging markets and why has it declined sharply in recent years?
Has there been a systematic relationship between fiscal performance and inflation?
Which monetary regime has been better in controlling money growth and inflation?
What additional steps need to be taken to curb inflation in some countries and to keep inflation at current low levels in others?
Why Do Countries Inflate?
The literature provides two main motives as to why inflation strikes: the need of governments to finance persistent fiscal deficits through seigniorage and the time inconsistency of economic policies.5 Governments have financed persistent fiscal deficits by issuing money since time immemorial—witness coin clipping that occurred in Roman times. At the root of the seigniorage motive is the government’s unwillingness or incapacity to avoid persistent deficits or to resort to other sources of financing to make up for the shortfall.6 Governments generally resort to seigniorage because, compared to other revenue sources, it tends to be easier to collect and enforce and does not require the approval of the legislative body, which can be lengthy and politically difficult.
Seigniorage has varied widely across countries and over time. Reasons that might account for such wide variations in seigniorage include different spending needs (as a ratio to GDP) and the relative cost of funding those needs through a variety of taxes and borrowing instruments, with the cost of using a particular instrument rising in proportion to its use. Accordingly, incentives to use seigniorage will be lower in countries where collection of formal taxes is more efficient and borrowing is cheaper due to more developed capital markets. Seigniorage will also tend to be lower in countries where public tolerance for inflation is lower (itself a function of institutional and historical factors), and where governments’ capacity to enhance the use of high-powered money (the tax base for seigniorage) is more limited—-this being the case, for instance, in highly “dollarized” small open economies relative to large economies in which domestic transactions in foreign currency are rarer. In addition to these country specific factors, seigniorage has also varied over time with the advent of paper money and, even more important, with changes in the international monetary system. In particular, the breakup of the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate system in the early 1970s, by ending the long period in which the international monetary system was commodity-based, reduced the external constraint on seigniorage. This made it easier for many countries to explore this source of revenue in the 1970s and 1980s, until public antipathy to inflation became an increasingly binding domestic constraint.
Relative to advanced countries, seigniorage has been a significant source of government revenue in many developing countries.7 Asian countries have generally collected the lowest levels and Latin America the highest (Figure 4.2). In extreme cases, such as in Argentina, Chile, Egypt, and Israel at various times during the 1970s and 1980s, seigniorage as a share of GDP reached the double-digits. Interestingly, despite the higher inflation rates, seigniorage in Latin America has not been substantially higher than that of other regions except Asia. This suggests that some Latin American countries operated beyond the point where revenues from seigniorage are maximized (i.e., the peak of the inflation-tax collection curves depicted in Figure 4.2), due to the shrinking of the tax base caused by falling real money balances as inflation kept rising. This implies that high inflation cannot be entirely explained as a result of efficient taxation.


Seigniorage in Emerging Market Economies, 1950-20001
(Three-year moving averages; percent of GDP)
Seigniorage has displayed a Laffer-curve shape, the peak of which has varied widely across countries.
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.1Seigniorage is calculated as the annual change in reserve money divided by nominal GDP.2Excluding three outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 200 percent as well as inflation and seigniorage in Israel for the period 1977 to 1985.3Excluding four outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 300 percent.4Excluding three outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 70 percent.5Availability of data for emerging Europe is as follows Czech Republic (1994-99), Hungary (1983-99), Poland (1980-99), Russia (1994-99), and Turkey (1962-99).6Excluding inflation and seigniorage in Israel for the period 1977 to 1985.

Seigniorage in Emerging Market Economies, 1950-20001
(Three-year moving averages; percent of GDP)
Seigniorage has displayed a Laffer-curve shape, the peak of which has varied widely across countries.
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.1Seigniorage is calculated as the annual change in reserve money divided by nominal GDP.2Excluding three outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 200 percent as well as inflation and seigniorage in Israel for the period 1977 to 1985.3Excluding four outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 300 percent.4Excluding three outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 70 percent.5Availability of data for emerging Europe is as follows Czech Republic (1994-99), Hungary (1983-99), Poland (1980-99), Russia (1994-99), and Turkey (1962-99).6Excluding inflation and seigniorage in Israel for the period 1977 to 1985.

Seigniorage in Emerging Market Economies, 1950-20001
(Three-year moving averages; percent of GDP)
Seigniorage has displayed a Laffer-curve shape, the peak of which has varied widely across countries.
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.1Seigniorage is calculated as the annual change in reserve money divided by nominal GDP.2Excluding three outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 200 percent as well as inflation and seigniorage in Israel for the period 1977 to 1985.3Excluding four outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 300 percent.4Excluding three outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 70 percent.5Availability of data for emerging Europe is as follows Czech Republic (1994-99), Hungary (1983-99), Poland (1980-99), Russia (1994-99), and Turkey (1962-99).6Excluding inflation and seigniorage in Israel for the period 1977 to 1985.

Seigniorage in Emerging Market Economies, 1950-20001
(Three-year moving averages; percent of GDP)
Seigniorage has displayed a Laffer-curve shape, the peak of which has varied widely across countries.
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.1Seigniorage is calculated as the annual change in reserve money divided by nominal GDP.2Excluding three outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 200 percent as well as inflation and seigniorage in Israel for the period 1977 to 1985.3Excluding four outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 300 percent.4Excluding three outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 70 percent.5Availability of data for emerging Europe is as follows Czech Republic (1994-99), Hungary (1983-99), Poland (1980-99), Russia (1994-99), and Turkey (1962-99).6Excluding inflation and seigniorage in Israel for the period 1977 to 1985.Seigniorage in Emerging Market Economies, 1950-20001
(Three-year moving averages; percent of GDP)
Seigniorage has displayed a Laffer-curve shape, the peak of which has varied widely across countries.
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.1Seigniorage is calculated as the annual change in reserve money divided by nominal GDP.2Excluding three outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 200 percent as well as inflation and seigniorage in Israel for the period 1977 to 1985.3Excluding four outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 300 percent.4Excluding three outlying observations with inflation rates greater than 70 percent.5Availability of data for emerging Europe is as follows Czech Republic (1994-99), Hungary (1983-99), Poland (1980-99), Russia (1994-99), and Turkey (1962-99).6Excluding inflation and seigniorage in Israel for the period 1977 to 1985.While the seigniorage theory emphasizes the behavior of the fiscal authority, the time inconsistency theory focuses on the behavior of the monetary authority. The theory highlights the inflationary bias to monetary policy from not being able to credibly commit to low inflation. The perception that output can be raised in the short-run by expansionary monetary policies may induce the central bank to run a looser monetary policy than is consistent with low inflation. This is particularly likely if the central bank is not independent from the rest of the government and when political considerations, such as electoral cycles, may influence policy. By the same token, the theory also helps explain why central banks may adopt an accommodative policy stance once inflation is triggered by other factors, such as adverse supply shocks.
Once triggered, higher inflation can also lead to the development of various indexation mechanisms that tie subsequent price and wage increases to past inflation, which can help to maintain existing inflationary momentum. In addition, other factors may contribute.8 One is the so-called province effect, where local governments have an incentive to increase expenditure, overlooking the impact on the national government deficit because they only pay part of the cost. As the resulting fiscal deficit is higher, so tends to be the resort to seigniorage. In addition, a war of attrition between social groups can also make it difficult for the government to reach a consensus on appropriate macroeconomic policies, leading to increased use of seigniorage.9 Finally, persistent inflation can arise out of the dynamics of interest payments on government debt. Once the nominal interest rate on the debt is given by private sector expectations of future inflation, the government will have an incentive to validate those expectations or inflate further, as disinflation increases the real value of the debt service.
Why Emerging Market Countries Should Strive to Preserve Lower Inflation
Following the decline in inflation in emerging markets in recent years, a widespread consensus has emerged among policymakers and the public that one of the key policy challenges is now to preserve these gains. Why is there so much concern about inflation, especially for emerging markets, where fostering economic growth and reducing poverty and unemployment might be considered to be of greater intrinsic importance?
Most economists agree that inflation, especially high inflation, harms economic efficiency and growth, but the nature and magnitude of these costs are not yet entirely understood. Several costs of inflation have been identified, including:
High inflation may distort relative prices of different goods and services, thereby lowering economic efficiency.
People devote time and resources to economizing on money balances whose real value is eroding over time.
Unexpected inflation leads to arbitrary redistribution: for example, from fixed interest rate lenders to borrowers.
Higher inflation is typically associated with higher uncertainty about future inflation, forcing people to spend time and resources protecting themselves from future changes in inflation.
High inflation may interfere with the financial system’s ability to allocate resources effectively, for example because of distortions to accounting and tax rules.
That said, moderate levels of inflation may also have benefits, such as facilitating needed relative price adjustment if the flexibility of nominal wages to downward adjustments is limited.
While few doubt that extremely high inflation is bad for economic growth and efficiency, there is a debate on whether moderate inflation is harmful and on exactly where the threshold lies between moderate, tolerable inflation and high, harmful inflation.1 The empirical literature on this issue is not conclusive, with estimates ranging from 2 to 7 percent a year in many studies to, as high as 40 percent a year according to one study. Nevertheless, recent trends in emerging markets reveal a clear preference for single-digit inflation levels.2 The costs of inflation will also differ across countries depending on specific characteristics, such as the degree of indexation and the ways in which the financial system has developed to cope with the uncertainties associated with inflation. Countries with a recent history of high inflation typically still have in place indexation mechanisms that may reduce the annual costs of inflation but may also make inflation—and its associated costs—more persistent.
Inflation and Financial Sector Development
The effects of inflation on the development of the financial system are complex and especially relevant for emerging markets. High inflation may be expected to increase the resources a country devotes to financial services. High expected inflation will lead households to make smaller cash withdrawals with greater frequency; banks will therefore need to build more branches and make more investments in automation and technology in order to satisfy increased customer activity. Higher and more volatile inflation will raise the demand for financial sector services aimed at protecting economic agents from the associated uncertainty. One study confirms that countries with higher inflation devote a greater share of their GDP to financial services.3 However, it seems that these resources, while protecting agents from inflation uncertainty, do not result in genuine financial development. Indeed private credit, bank assets, financial sector liquid liabilities, and stock market capitalization (all as a share of GDP) tend to be lower in countries with high inflation, with a marked drop in financial sector development around a threshold of 15 percent inflation.4
Inflation and the Poor
A possible cost of inflation, which is particularly relevant in developing countries, relates to its effects on the poor. There are a number of reasons why inflation often hurts the poor more than it hurts the rich. The poor have less access to financial instruments used to hedge against inflation. Moreover, the poor are more likely to rely on sources of income—such as pensions, subsidies, and transfers—that may be only partially indexed to inflation. There are, of course, counterarguments. First, in those countries where rural poverty remains widespread, poor households are likely to be engaged in subsistence farming, which is less affected by developments in the monetized economy: while inflation is likely to hurt the urban poor, it may have a smaller impact on the poor living in rural areas. Second, those below the poverty line in developing countries may have small cash holdings, no pensions, and no transfers or subsidies from the state. Finally, policies aimed at boosting aggregate demand may raise inflation but may also temporarily assist the poor by reducing unemployment.
Current evidence suggests that inflation tends to hurt the poor to a greater extent than it hurts the rich. Drawing on a polling data survey of more than 30,000 households in 38 countries, and controlling for other factors, a recent paper finds that [relatively] poor people are more likely to mention inflation as one of their top concerns.5 Moreover, the authors report that direct measures of improvement in the well-being of the poor are negatively correlated with inflation in cross-country samples for the past few decades. Another study confirms that, in an international panel, higher inflation is associated with lower income of the poor over the longer term.6 Using U.S. data over time, it also finds that any benefits to the poor of expansionary policies leading to higher inflation and lower unemployment are minor and short-lived. Such studies relying on data from developing countries are subject to a number of caveats, in particular whether surveys capture a sufficiently large share of the rural population, where many of the poor are to be found.
Indeed, one of the most common arguments that is put forward in favor of maintaining inflation at a low level (say 2-4 percent a year) rather than letting it increase to a moderate level (say 10-20 percent) is simply that it is important to avoid taking a slippery slope where moderate inflation might degenerate into excessive, harmful inflation.
See Michael Bruno and William Easterly, “Inflation Crises and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 41 (February 1998), pp. 3-26; Atish Ghosh and Steven Phillips, “Warning: Inflation May Be Harmful to Your Growth,” IMF Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 45, (December 1998), pp. 672–713; Mohsin S. Khan and Abdelhak S. Senhadji, “Threshold Effects in the Relationship Between Inflation and Growth,” IMF Working Paper 00/110 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, June 2000); and Peter Christoffersen and Peter Doyle, “From Inflation to Growth: Eight Years of Transition,” The Economics of Transition, Vol. 8, No. 2 (2000), pp. 421-451.
William B. English, “Inflation and Financial Sector Size,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 44, (December 1999), pp. 379-400.
John H. Boyd, Ross Levine, and Bruce D. Smith, The Impact of Inflation on Financial Sector Performance,” Journal of Monetary Economic (forthcoming).
William Easterly and Stanley Fischer, “Inflation and the Poor,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 2335 (Washington: The World Bank, 2000), forthcoming in the Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking.
Christina Romer and David Romer, “Monetary Policy and the Well-Being of the Poor,” NBER Working Paper No. 6793 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau for Economic Research, 1998).
These considerations reveal the complexity of inflationary processes. Inflation can be triggered by a host of factors—ranging from higher fiscal deficits to oil price shocks—and since the government, including the central bank, has a variety of incentives to accommodate such impulses, a complex inflationary dynamic can result with little connection to its original cause. Thus, any analysis of the determinants of inflation must look at several variables and recognize that, even then, a satisfactory explanation of specific developments in certain countries during certain periods might prove elusive.
The complexity of persistent high inflation can make it harder for governments to create consensus to stabilize the economy, underscoring the importance of reacting quickly to early signs of inflationary pressures. Failure to do so may mean that the macroeconomic situation will have to become clearly unsustainable—as under high and hyperinflation—before such a consensus is reached. Indeed, the difficulty in forging a consensus to lower inflation helps explain why many emerging market countries have tolerated moderate to high inflation rates until recently.
Empirical Evidence on the Determinants of Inflation
The extensive literature on the determinants of inflation across countries has explored the roles of fiscal deficits, monetary policy, and the combination of external shocks and inflation inertia in producing inflation. Studies that focused on the relationship between deficits, seigniorage, and inflation have yielded mixed results, with little evidence of a strong connection across a wide range of countries and inflation rates.10 On time inconsistency, the empirical literature has focused on two implications of the theory—namely, that central bank independence and greater openness to trade are associated with lower inflation. Such studies have found a negative relationship between inflation and central bank independence, while the results on openness have been found to be sensitive to the sample, specification, and period of estimation.11 Other studies have examined the role of monetary expansion, price inertia, and changes in nominal exchange rates and the world price of oil and other commodities. Inflation inertia and changes in money supply have been found to be key determinants of inflation, with oil and other world prices playing a less important role.12
Given the widespread view that fiscal policy is closely connected with the inflationary experience of many emerging market countries, the IMF has reexamined the relationship between fiscal deficits and inflation, focusing only on emerging markets (Box 4.2). This study finds a significant and relatively consistent long-run relationship between the size of government deficits—scaled by narrow money—and inflation. These results indicate that long-term inflation is positively related to fiscal deficits (measured as a ratio to GDP) and inversely related to the size of the inflation tax base (proxied by the ratio of narrow money to GDP).
Is There a Relationship Between Fiscal Deficits and Inflation?
Economists generally agree that fiscal deficits are one of the main causes of inflation, particularly high and hyper inflation. By creating excessive aggregate demand pressures recurrent fiscal deficits can both spark and sustain inflationary processes.1 Typically, governments facing persistent fiscal imbalances are incapable (or unwilling) to create the political consensus needed to increase taxes and/or reduce expenditures and find borrowing increasingly difficult. As a result, these governments pressure the central bank to finance those deficits by printing money. Indeed, there is a large literature documenting the crucial role played by fiscal deficits during the hyperinflation episodes of the 1920s, 1970s, and 1980s and high and moderate inflation episodes of the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s.2
Despite these case studies, more formal empirical analysis has had only limited success in establishing the existence of a relationship between the size of fiscal deficits and inflation.3 In general, this relationship is complex, and an important distinction needs to be made between the short and long run. In the short run, higher deficits do not necessarily lead to higher inflation, as they can be financed by additional borrowing. In the long run, however, high deficits will generally lead to higher inflation, as governments use seigniorage to finance them, although there will also be reverse causation through the impact of inflation on nominal interest rates. Because of this, it is useful to focus on the long-run relationship between fiscal deficits and inflation.
Long-Run Relationship Between Inflation, Fiscal Deficits, and Changes in World Prices1
The sample covered Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Egypt, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, Uruguay, Venezuela, and Zimbabwe.
Long-Run Relationship Between Inflation, Fiscal Deficits, and Changes in World Prices1
Government deficit/narrow money Coefficient | 0.32 | |
t-ratio | (18.1) | |
Change in world oil prices Coefficient | 0.08 | |
t-ratio | (9.4) | |
World inflation Coefficient | 0.29 | |
t-ratio | (7.3) |
The sample covered Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Egypt, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, Uruguay, Venezuela, and Zimbabwe.
Long-Run Relationship Between Inflation, Fiscal Deficits, and Changes in World Prices1
Government deficit/narrow money Coefficient | 0.32 | |
t-ratio | (18.1) | |
Change in world oil prices Coefficient | 0.08 | |
t-ratio | (9.4) | |
World inflation Coefficient | 0.29 | |
t-ratio | (7.3) |
The sample covered Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Egypt, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, Uruguay, Venezuela, and Zimbabwe.
Some initial work by IMF staff indicates there is a positive long-run relationship between the size of fiscal deficits scaled by narrow money (as defined by the IMF’s International Finance Statistics) and inflation for a sample of 23 emerging market economies during the period of 1970-99 (see the Table).4 The econometric specification used in this study has been derived from a small open economy that predicts that in the long run the ratio of government deficits to narrow money should be directly related to inflation. In other words, inflation will be higher the larger are the fiscal imbalances (as measured by the ratio of government deficit over GDP) and/or the lower the size of the inflation tax base (proxied by the ratio of narrow money to GDP).5 The existence of a long-run deficit-inflation relationship was tested using a dynamic panel regression.6 Despite the wide variety of inflation experiences in emerging market economies, a statistically significant long-run relationship between the ratio of government deficits to narrow money and inflation was found and was superior to including only the deficit as a ratio for GDP or narrow money as a ratio to GDP. Moreover, the hypothesis of long-run coefficient homogeneity could not be rejected.
This relationship is quite stable to the inclusion of other variables, as well as to the exclusion of countries that experienced hyperinflation episodes in the late 1980s/early 1990s (Argentina, Brazil, and Peru). The stability of the long-run relationship between deficits and inflation was explored by introducing into the long-run econometric specification indicators of openness, political instability, exchange rate regime, changes in oil prices, changes in non-oil commodity prices, and world inflation—variables that have featured prominently in previous empirical studies.7 In addition to government deficits, changes in world oil prices and world inflation were found to be significant, suggesting that external factors matter, including overall global monetary stability. As in other studies, a negative long-run association between openness and inflation was found; however, once the fiscal deficit is introduced in the specification, openness changes sign and becomes statistically insignificant, suggesting that the effect of openness on inflation is indirect and in the long run works mainly through the fiscal channel. The analysis also found no evidence of a statistically significant relationship between pegged exchange rate regimes (as measured by a dummy variable created from the de jure exchange rate classification compiled by the IMF) and inflation, although other studies have found this link in the short run.
These results point to a significant long-run relationship between deficits and inflation. Based on the estimated parameters, the model predicts that a (permanent) reduction in the government deficit by 1 percentage point of GDP is associated with a drop in inflation by 2 to 6 percentage points depending on the level of private sector’s holdings of narrow money. Likewise, a 10 percent reduction in oil prices changes would lead to a four-fifths of a percentage point reduction in the inflation rate, while a 10 percent change in world inflation translates into a reduction in domestic inflation of almost 3 percent.8
Inflation, by affecting government revenues and expenditures, also changes the size of the fiscal deficits, albeit in an uncertain direction. There is some evidence, however, that fiscal deficits tend to increase with high inflation because of high nominal interest payments. To eliminate the effects of inflation on the deficit, alternative deficit definitions have been proposed, including that of the operational fiscal deficit; however, these definitions are not problem free. See Vito Tanzi, Mario Blejer, and Mario Teijeiro, “Effects of Inflation on Measurement of Fiscal Deficits: Conventional Versus Operational Measures” in How to Measure the Fiscal Deficit, ed. by Mario Blejer and Adrienne Cheasty (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993).
See, for instance, Thomas Sargent, “The Ends of Four Big Inflations,” in Inflation, Causes, and Effects, ed. by Robert Hall (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,1982), pp. 41-97; and Rudiger Dornbusch and Stanley Fischer, “Stopping Hyperinflation Past and Present,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 122, (1986) and “Moderate Inflation,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol.7 (January 1993).
See for instance Robert King and Charles Plosser, “Money, Deficits, and Inflation,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 22 (Spring 1985), pp. 147-96; and Stanley Fischer, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos Vegh, “Modern Hyper-and High Inflations” (unpublished;Washington: International Monetary Fund, 2000).
See Luis Catão and Marco Terrones, “Government Deficits and Inflation: A New Look at the Emerging Markets Evidence,” IMF Working Paper (Washington: International Monetary Fund, forthcoming).
A battery of tests confirmed that the specification derived from theory was statistically superior to other ones that included deficit over GDP and narrow money over GDP.
A pooled mean group (PMG) estimator technique was used, as this is particularly good at dealing with dynamic processes and outliers, such as hyper inflation episodes. In addition, the PMG estimator is flexible enough to constrain the long-run parameters to be equal across countries while allowing other parameters (intercepts, short-run coefficients, and error variances) to vary freely from country to country. See M. Hashem Pesaran, Yongcheol Shin, and Ron Smith, “Pooled Mean Group Estimation of Dynamic Heterogeneous Panels,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 94 (June 1999), pp. 621-34.
See, for instance, Martha Campillo and Jeffrey Miron, “Why Does Inflation Differ Across Countries,” in Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy, ed. by Christina Romer and David Romer (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); and Chapter VI of the October 1996 World Economic Outlook.
Short-run estimates are less informative, as they are country specific. The lag structure for each country was selected using the Schwarz Bayesian criterion, subject to a maximum lag of two (because of data considerations). In more than half of the countries at least one lag of inflation was included.
As also discussed in Box 4.2, the same empirical study on emerging markets explored the stability of the long-run relationship between the fiscal deficit and inflation to the inclusion of other variables that have featured prominently in the literature. Among those, change in world oil prices and world inflation were the other variables found to have a long-run bearing on inflation, suggesting that global monetary stability also matters for emerging market inflation performance. In some specifications of the model, a negative long-run relationship between openness and inflation was also found, but became insignificant once the fiscal deficit variable was introduced. Similarly, no statistically significant relationship between (de jure) pegged exchange rate regimes was found, in contrast with the results of an earlier study.13 These results suggest that the influence of openness and exchange rate regimes on inflation may, over the long term, occur largely through fiscal policy and financial developments that affect the size of the inflation tax base.14
What Explains the 1990s Inflation Performance in Emerging Markets?
As noted above, inflation was reduced in almost all emerging countries in the 1990s, but the extent and speed at which countries reined it in varied considerably. Looking across the different regions, a variety of experiences can be identified.
In Latin America, Argentina, Brazil, and Peru experienced periods of hyperinflation during 1989-90. In each case, this had been preceded by persistent high inflation from the mid-1970s through the late 1980s, partly as a result of high fiscal deficits (itself reflecting political factors) and indexation in labor and financial markets. Moreover, access to international markets was limited in most cases following the 1980s debt crisis, forcing these countries to rely more on domestic financing of fiscal deficits, including seigniorage. As inflation increased, many of these economies saw money aggregates shrink as a ratio of GDP while the maturity of government debt shortened rapidly, laying the preconditions for hyperinflation. In these cases, the macroeconomic chaos and sharp collapse of output and employment associated with hyperinflation helped create political consensus over a relatively short time span for the ensuing stabilization. By the end of the 1990s, inflation in all three countries had been reduced to single digits (despite a sharp devaluation in Brazil in early 1999).
Other countries in Latin America, as well as Israel and Turkey, also experienced sustained moderate to high inflation—typically in the range of 20 to 80 percent—during the 1970s and 1980s, but without degenerating into hyperinflation. Most of these inflations were also reduced in the 1990s, although inflation remains high in Turkey (notwithstanding considerable progress before the collapse of its recent stabilization program—see Chapter 1) and to a lesser extent Venezuela.
In Asia, following some pickup in the wake of the oil price shocks of the 1970s, inflation was generally held at low levels during the 1980s and the 1990s. China experienced a marked but short-lived pickup in inflation during the early 1990s, associated with a surge in domestic investment, and a few countries—including Pakistan, the Philippines, India, and Indonesia—experienced persistent inflation in the high single or low double digits. With the exception of Indonesia, low inflation was generally maintained during the Asian crisis, notwithstanding substantial currency devaluations.
Among transition countries, almost all experienced a sharp burst of inflation in the early 1990s, reflecting price liberalization, the unwinding of the monetary overhang inherited from the period of central planning, and fiscal pressures caused by the collapse of central planning.15 In many respects, these inflations are more reminiscent of historical bouts of inflation due to war and political collapse—as for example following the breakup of the Austro-Hungarian empire in the early twentieth century. In most cases, aided by strong macroeconomic policies, inflation had been reduced to moderate double-digit levels in the mid-1990s and to close to single digit levels by 2000.16
While the forces behind disinflation in all these groups varied, fiscal consolidation in each case played a crucial role. Indeed, as shown in Table 4.3, fiscal deficits in emerging markets as a whole were reduced by about one-half from the levels observed in the 1970s and 1980s. On average, calculations based on the IMF’s empirical estimates reported in Box 4.2 suggest that the 2½ percentage points of GDP deficit reduction observed for the group of emerging markets (excluding transition economies) has led to a 5 to 15 percentage point reduction in inflation rates. With fiscal deficits in Asia already low, this fiscal consolidation effort in the emerging markets took place primarily in the Africa/Middle Eastern and Latin American regions (Figure 4.3 and Table 4.3).17 While the extent of fiscal adjustment is much more difficult to measure in transition economies—given the extent of quasifiscal activities, especially during the centrally planned period—it is clear that fiscal consolidation also played a central role in the disinflation process.18 Particularly in the second half of the 1990s, this was accompanied by financial deepening in all regions, which further reduced the need for seigniorage.


Inflation and Its Determinants in Emerging Markets
(Simple annual averages)
In the late 1990s, improved fiscal balances and restrained monetary growth have lowered inflation in Latin America, Europe, and the Africa/Middle East regions. Other factors, such as world inflation and oil prices, have also played a role.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.

Inflation and Its Determinants in Emerging Markets
(Simple annual averages)
In the late 1990s, improved fiscal balances and restrained monetary growth have lowered inflation in Latin America, Europe, and the Africa/Middle East regions. Other factors, such as world inflation and oil prices, have also played a role.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.

Inflation and Its Determinants in Emerging Markets
(Simple annual averages)
In the late 1990s, improved fiscal balances and restrained monetary growth have lowered inflation in Latin America, Europe, and the Africa/Middle East regions. Other factors, such as world inflation and oil prices, have also played a role.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.

Inflation and Its Determinants in Emerging Markets
(Simple annual averages)
In the late 1990s, improved fiscal balances and restrained monetary growth have lowered inflation in Latin America, Europe, and the Africa/Middle East regions. Other factors, such as world inflation and oil prices, have also played a role.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.Inflation and Its Determinants in Emerging Markets
(Simple annual averages)
In the late 1990s, improved fiscal balances and restrained monetary growth have lowered inflation in Latin America, Europe, and the Africa/Middle East regions. Other factors, such as world inflation and oil prices, have also played a role.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.Emerging Market Countries: Selected Variables
Average annual percent change of the consumer price index.
Emerging Market Countries: Selected Variables
Periods | Inflation1 | Deficit/GDP | Expenditures/GDP | Oil Prices1 | Imports/GDP | Narrow Money/GDP | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
All Emerging Markets | |||||||
1971-80 | 22.8 | 5.1 | 23.5 | 43.9 | 24.0 | 14.8 | |
1981-85 | 52.7 | 5.7 | 32.8 | -5.7 | 26.1 | 15.6 | |
1986-90 | 188.3 | 3.9 | 29.7 | 2.2 | 24.9 | 13.9 | |
1991-95 | 93.4 | 2.6 | 28.1 | -5.3 | 29.5 | 13.3 | |
1996-2000 | 23.1 | 2.7 | 111 | 15.1 | 32.8 | 14.7 | |
Latin America | |||||||
1971-80 | 58.0 | 2.1 | 14.2 | 43.9 | 15.2 | 11.2 | |
1981-85 | 107.9 | 4.1 | 20.8 | -5.7 | 14.2 | 9.1 | |
1986-90 | 681.6 | 4.9 | 20.0 | 2.2 | 15.3 | 7.7 | |
1991-95 | 195.9 | 1.0 | 18.1 | -5.3 | 17.9 | 7.0 | |
1996-2000 | 14.2 | 2.0 | 18.2 | 15.1 | 20.0 | 8.1 | |
Asia | |||||||
1971-80 | 10.2 | 3.5 | 16.7 | 43.9 | 19.9 | 13.4 | |
1981-85 | 8.3 | 5.0 | 20.1 | -5.7 | 25.4 | 14.5 | |
1986-90 | 6.5 | 3.2 | 19.8 | 2.2 | 26.4 | 15.8 | |
1991-95 | 8.6 | 1.2 | 18.7 | -5.3 | 33.5 | 17.3 | |
1996-2000 | 6.8 | 2.8 | 18.9 | 15.1 | 38.5 | 19.7 | |
Europe | |||||||
1971-80 | 6.1 | 2.5 | 18.6 | 43.9 | 24.4 | 16.2 | |
1981-85 | 14.2 | 2.4 | 38.0 | -5.7 | 24.3 | 18.5 | |
1986-90 | 44.9 | 2.5 | 39.1 | 2.2 | 24.2 | 14.4 | |
1991-95 | 156.6 | 4.4 | 37.9 | -5.3 | 34.4 | 13.7 | |
1996-2000 | 65.3 | 3.4 | 36.1 | 15.1 | 41.1 | 12.9 | |
Africa and the Middle East | |||||||
1971-80 | 16.9 | 12.4 | 44.3 | 43.9 | 36.6 | 18.5 | |
1981-85 | 80.2 | 11.2 | 52.2 | -5.7 | 40.4 | 20.3 | |
1986-90 | 20.3 | 5.3 | 39.8 | 2.2 | 33.4 | 17.6 | |
1991-95 | 12.4 | 3.7 | 37.6 | -5.3 | 32.0 | 15.3 | |
1996-2000 | 6.0 | 2.4 | 37.8 | 15.1 | 31.4 | 17.9 |
Average annual percent change of the consumer price index.
Emerging Market Countries: Selected Variables
Periods | Inflation1 | Deficit/GDP | Expenditures/GDP | Oil Prices1 | Imports/GDP | Narrow Money/GDP | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
All Emerging Markets | |||||||
1971-80 | 22.8 | 5.1 | 23.5 | 43.9 | 24.0 | 14.8 | |
1981-85 | 52.7 | 5.7 | 32.8 | -5.7 | 26.1 | 15.6 | |
1986-90 | 188.3 | 3.9 | 29.7 | 2.2 | 24.9 | 13.9 | |
1991-95 | 93.4 | 2.6 | 28.1 | -5.3 | 29.5 | 13.3 | |
1996-2000 | 23.1 | 2.7 | 111 | 15.1 | 32.8 | 14.7 | |
Latin America | |||||||
1971-80 | 58.0 | 2.1 | 14.2 | 43.9 | 15.2 | 11.2 | |
1981-85 | 107.9 | 4.1 | 20.8 | -5.7 | 14.2 | 9.1 | |
1986-90 | 681.6 | 4.9 | 20.0 | 2.2 | 15.3 | 7.7 | |
1991-95 | 195.9 | 1.0 | 18.1 | -5.3 | 17.9 | 7.0 | |
1996-2000 | 14.2 | 2.0 | 18.2 | 15.1 | 20.0 | 8.1 | |
Asia | |||||||
1971-80 | 10.2 | 3.5 | 16.7 | 43.9 | 19.9 | 13.4 | |
1981-85 | 8.3 | 5.0 | 20.1 | -5.7 | 25.4 | 14.5 | |
1986-90 | 6.5 | 3.2 | 19.8 | 2.2 | 26.4 | 15.8 | |
1991-95 | 8.6 | 1.2 | 18.7 | -5.3 | 33.5 | 17.3 | |
1996-2000 | 6.8 | 2.8 | 18.9 | 15.1 | 38.5 | 19.7 | |
Europe | |||||||
1971-80 | 6.1 | 2.5 | 18.6 | 43.9 | 24.4 | 16.2 | |
1981-85 | 14.2 | 2.4 | 38.0 | -5.7 | 24.3 | 18.5 | |
1986-90 | 44.9 | 2.5 | 39.1 | 2.2 | 24.2 | 14.4 | |
1991-95 | 156.6 | 4.4 | 37.9 | -5.3 | 34.4 | 13.7 | |
1996-2000 | 65.3 | 3.4 | 36.1 | 15.1 | 41.1 | 12.9 | |
Africa and the Middle East | |||||||
1971-80 | 16.9 | 12.4 | 44.3 | 43.9 | 36.6 | 18.5 | |
1981-85 | 80.2 | 11.2 | 52.2 | -5.7 | 40.4 | 20.3 | |
1986-90 | 20.3 | 5.3 | 39.8 | 2.2 | 33.4 | 17.6 | |
1991-95 | 12.4 | 3.7 | 37.6 | -5.3 | 32.0 | 15.3 | |
1996-2000 | 6.0 | 2.4 | 37.8 | 15.1 | 31.4 | 17.9 |
Average annual percent change of the consumer price index.
External developments also contributed to falling inflation in the 1990s. First, as discussed in the previous section, the decline in global inflation, both through its direct impact on import prices as well as indirectly (through, among other things, pressure on emerging markets’ external competitiveness and demonstration effects of the virtues of low inflation), clearly helped. Second, the decline in oil prices in the first half of the 1990s also provided modest support to disinflation programs at that time (although, with prices rising thereafter, oil prices likely had an adverse effect for the decade as a whole).
A number of other forces—while not directly captured in the econometric model described earlier—also contributed, although their impact likely varied considerably across different countries. These included:
Institutional reforms. In most emerging markets, the independence of the central bank was enhanced, helping to address the time inconsistency problem discussed above. Many countries (most notably Argentina and Brazil) also greatly reduced or eliminated indexation of wage and financial sector contracts, helping to reduce inflation inertia. This was accompanied by some increase in political stability, primarily in emerging markets of Europe, Africa, and the Middle East.
Structural reforms. Most countries undertook wide-ranging structural reforms in trade, product, and labor markets, which tend to reduce inflationary pressures. One outcome of these reforms was the substantial rise in trade openness for emerging markets as a group (Table 4.3), particularly in Asia and emerging Europe (less so in Latin America and the Middle East). In addition, financial sector regulations and supervisory frameworks were improved, fostering discipline in credit markets that, together with widespread privatization of public banks, posed an additional constraint on fiscal profligacy.
Access to global capital markets. Capital flows to emerging markets substantially increased, particularly to Asia and Latin America in the first half of the 1990s, as well as to a number of emerging European countries, particularly Hungary and the Czech Republic. While this should in principle be beneficial for disinflation—for instance by reducing the need for seigniorage—it also contributed to overheating and inflationary pressures in countries with fixed exchange rate regimes or where the authorities were reluctant to let the exchange rate appreciate. The important role of capital inflows in slowing down the disinflation process has been observed in Eastern Europe.
A particular issue of importance in a number of Asian and Latin American countries in recent years has been the behavior of the exchange pass-through. While inflation picked up in all countries in the wake of dramatic currency devaluations, the effect was relatively short-lived and far from one-to-one in most countries (Figure 4.4). Recent studies, including work by IMF staff, have sought to explain this limited exchange rate pass-through in a broad sample of advanced and developing countries.19 They find that, in general, the extent of the pass-through is positively related to the size of the output gap and negatively related to the degree of real exchange rate appreciation immediately preceding the devaluation, with some evidence that it may also be a negative function of average inflation levels in the years preceding the devaluation. Since all emerging market countries that experienced sharp devaluations in the 1990s had already achieved low inflation levels and displayed some degree of real exchange rate appreciation on the eve of the devaluation, these two factors plus the severity of the subsequent output contractions explain the limited pass-through.

Exchange Rate Pass-Through in Emerging Markets in the 1990s1
(Inflation as a percent of change in nominal effective exchange rate)
Exchange rate pass-through has been well below unity in most emerging market countries in the aftermath of major devaluations.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Calculated as the ratio of cumulative percentage change in the consumer price index over 12- and 24-month periods by the one-month lagged percentage change in the nominal effective exchange rate over 12- and 24-month periods, respectively.
Exchange Rate Pass-Through in Emerging Markets in the 1990s1
(Inflation as a percent of change in nominal effective exchange rate)
Exchange rate pass-through has been well below unity in most emerging market countries in the aftermath of major devaluations.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Calculated as the ratio of cumulative percentage change in the consumer price index over 12- and 24-month periods by the one-month lagged percentage change in the nominal effective exchange rate over 12- and 24-month periods, respectively.Exchange Rate Pass-Through in Emerging Markets in the 1990s1
(Inflation as a percent of change in nominal effective exchange rate)
Exchange rate pass-through has been well below unity in most emerging market countries in the aftermath of major devaluations.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Calculated as the ratio of cumulative percentage change in the consumer price index over 12- and 24-month periods by the one-month lagged percentage change in the nominal effective exchange rate over 12- and 24-month periods, respectively.To summarize, lower rates of inflation in emerging markets during the 1990s appear to have been closely linked to domestic fiscal consolidation, aided by falling world inflation, and—in some cases—limited exchange rate pass-through. Other factors—such as institutional strengthening, financial sector development, trade, and product and labor market reforms—also played a role as well, although the precise extent is difficult to quantify. This is partly because of indirect effects through the fiscal channel, the lack of better proxy variables, and the fact that these contributions varied widely from country to country, making it harder to derive accurately their average impact from a wide range of countries.
Monetary Regimes and Inflation Performance
Although inflation is a monetary phenomenon, fiscal deficits are a key long-run determinant of inflation through the seigniorage channel. The conduct and institutions of monetary policy, however, clearly play a central role in price determination, particularly in the short to medium term. As has already been noted, in the short run the relationship between fiscal deficits and inflation may be relatively weak, since in most cases governments have access to noninflationary sources of financing. Moreover, the conduct and institutions of monetary policy may themselves influence fiscal policy. For example, a currency board tends to discourage persistently large fiscal deficits and the use of inflation tax, which are incompatible with sustainable pegs. This section reviews the record with the use of different monetary policy regimes, and the extent to which they have contributed to falling inflation rates during the 1990s.
What Does the Recent Record Tell Us?
The past 15 years or so witnessed a significant broadening of possible choices of monetary regimes and far-reaching institutional changes in the arrangements underpinning those regimes in emerging markets. Moving along the spectrum ranging from strict rules to full discretion, these regimes can be grouped as:
Hard exchange rate pegs, which comprise currency unions, the use of foreign currency as the only legal tender, and currency board arrangements;
Soft exchange rate pegs, including crawling pegs or bands, where the parity can be changed at the sole discretion of the monetary authority without violating any national law or international agreement;
Floating exchange rate regimes where the monetary authority has a statutory mandate to target inflation directly (inflation targeting); and
Other floating exchange rate regimes, including those where the monetary authority specifically targets the growth of monetary aggregates (monetary targeting), as well as hybrid arrangements whereby no single nominal anchor is systematically targeted.20
At one extreme—under hard pegs—the monetary authority has virtually no room for discretion, as domestic monetary conditions are strictly linked to those of the foreign country (or countries) through a rigid peg. Seigniorage and monetary accommodation are constrained through a visible and strict rule. At the other extreme—a floating exchange rate with no explicit nominal targeting—room for discretion is considerable, allowing monetary policy to be tailored to domestic business cycle conditions or respond to other considerations. In between, seigniorage and monetary accommodation are somewhat constrained either by a fixed peg (which can be adjusted within limits and often at a cost) or by a set of domestic laws and institutional arrangements, such as those that underpin an inflation targeting regime (Box 4.3).
Figure 4.5 summarizes trends in the use of four main competing regimes since the mid-1980s. Two main developments stand out. One is the continuing move toward more flexible exchange rate regimes and the erosion of soft pegs—an ongoing trend since the early 1970s that has been accelerated in recent years by greater international integration (notably through higher capital mobility and more open capital accounts) and by the exchange rate and financial crises of the mid and late 1990s.21 Second, there is a gradual emergence of a bipolar distribution among countries with more open capital accounts, which have been leaning toward either hard exchange pegs or floating exchange rates, with inflation targeting being increasingly popular among the latter.22

Monetary Regimes in Emerging Market Countries1
(Percent of all emerging market countries)
In recent years, countries have been moving away from “soft” pegs and instead gravitating toward either floating exchange rates in conjunction with inflation targeting or “hard” pegged exchange rates.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Based on “de facto” classification following the method used in Stanley Fischer’s “Exchange Rate Regimes: Is the Bipolar View Correct?” (speech to the American Economic Association, Jan. 6, 2001).2Including monetary targeting regimes.
Monetary Regimes in Emerging Market Countries1
(Percent of all emerging market countries)
In recent years, countries have been moving away from “soft” pegs and instead gravitating toward either floating exchange rates in conjunction with inflation targeting or “hard” pegged exchange rates.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Based on “de facto” classification following the method used in Stanley Fischer’s “Exchange Rate Regimes: Is the Bipolar View Correct?” (speech to the American Economic Association, Jan. 6, 2001).2Including monetary targeting regimes.Monetary Regimes in Emerging Market Countries1
(Percent of all emerging market countries)
In recent years, countries have been moving away from “soft” pegs and instead gravitating toward either floating exchange rates in conjunction with inflation targeting or “hard” pegged exchange rates.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Based on “de facto” classification following the method used in Stanley Fischer’s “Exchange Rate Regimes: Is the Bipolar View Correct?” (speech to the American Economic Association, Jan. 6, 2001).2Including monetary targeting regimes.Inflation Targeting in Emerging Market Economies: Implementation and Challenges
In recent years, several emerging market countries have joined a number of industrial countries in adopting monetary frameworks that formally target inflation. Brazil, Chile, the Czech Republic, Israel, Poland, and South Africa have adopted full-fledged inflation targeting, while others are moving toward this framework.1
The experience of the countries that have adopted inflation targeting suggests that the foundations for successful inflation targeting are built on the following:
a mandate to achieve price stability;
central bank instrument independence;
transparent policies to build accountability and credibility;
a good framework for forecasting inflation;
a reasonable understanding of transmission channels between policy instruments and inflation;
a well-developed financial system;
absence of fiscal dominance (i.e., and the conduct of domestic monetary policy should not be dictated by fiscal needs);
a reasonable degree of macroeconomic stability.
Although these elements need not be considered prerequisites for beginning the transition toward full-fledged inflation targeting, they can pose important challenges for many emerging market countries seeking to go down this path. In many cases, central banks have yet to be granted the operational independence (i.e., an ability to set policy instruments without government oversight) needed to set monetary policy in accordance with a price stability objective, and they are often reluctant to communicate their economic outlooks and policy intentions in a transparent manner. Ongoing structural change in their economies may impede their ability to forecast inflation, while weak links between monetary policy and inflation often associated with underdeveloped financial systems or partial dollarization complicate the assessment of the appropriate policy response. In addition, it might take some time to establish the credibility of an inflation targeting framework, particularly in cases where there are large fiscal debt burdens or an inadequate track record of entrenched macroeconomic stability. That said, it is also true that many of these issues pose similar challenges for other monetary regimes, particular those using floating exchange rates.
An examination of the differences between emerging market countries that target inflation and those that do not sheds some light on the preferred starting point and conditions that favor the choice of inflation targeting among other alternative monetary policy regimes. Usually, inflation targeting countries are relatively well developed and have more complex domestic financial systems, suggesting these attributes should be considered by other countries thinking of adopting this monetary framework. They are also countries that have opted for significant exchange rate flexibility, in part because their terms of trade may follow different cycles than those of their major trading partners.2
The legal frameworks of all inflation targeting countries give the central bank instrument independence, and make price stability a primary objective.3 A comparison suggests that emerging market countries tend to prefer a more formal institutional framework in support of inflation targeting than industrial countries. Emerging market countries usually modify the central bank legal framework before adopting inflation targeting, and all emerging market countries explicitly limit central bank financing of government deficits in the primary market. The more formal inflation targeting frameworks in emerging market countries compared to their industrial counterparts may reflect histories of greater government intervention in monetary policy, higher and more variable rates of inflation, less developed financial systems, greater vulnerability to inflationary monetization of government debt, greater susceptibility to exchange rate crises, and IMF involvement.
There are also differences in the operation and design of inflation targeting between emerging market and industrial countries. Central banks in emerging market countries tend to rely less on statistical models in the conduct of monetary policy, intervene more frequently in foreign exchange markets, use shorter horizons to achieve their objectives, and target wider bands than industrial countries. These differences presumably reflect underlying differences between the two groups of countries. Structural changes in underlying economic relationships are more prevalent in emerging market countries, and they are inclined to be more vulnerable to shocks, especially those emanating from volatile capital flows. By mixing and matching the elements of the framework (such as the choice of the price index to be targeted, a point target or a range, and escape clauses) an inflation targeting central bank can design a framework that gives it the appropriate trade-off between credibility and the discretion needed to respond to shocks, such as unexpected hikes in oil prices.4
Volatile capital flows are usually associated with rapid movements in the exchange rate and pronounced swings in the spreads between domestic and international interest rates, which can be particularly disruptive for countries that are relatively open to trade or are large borrowers. In an inflation targeting framework, clear explanations by the central bank of the rationale underlying its policy stance may help to ensure that such shocks are not compounded by uncertainty regarding the conduct of monetary policy. Over time, a proven track record of attaining the inflation targets should help financial markets develop greater confidence in the motivations underpinning monetary actions.5 Nonetheless, central banks that target inflation have occasionally found it prudent to take action to moderate exchange rate movements to ensure that excessive changes do not destabilize inflation expectations or the domestic financial system while retaining exchange rate flexibility. Taking steps to moderate a rapid depreciation of the exchange rate can thus help to avoid the more dramatic tightening that might otherwise occur in response to financial instability, rather than because a tighter monetary stance is desired. This can be particularly important for partially dollarized economies, where the financial condition of the private sector is often sensitive to exchange rate fluctuations. However, it is important to unwind such actions as soon as practical to avoid moving away from the inflation target.
The transition to full-fledged inflation targeting is also an issue in many emerging market economies. Several countries have confronted the challenge of introducing this framework before they exited from an exchange rate targeting regime. The experiences of Israel and Poland suggest that a gradual shift from a fixed exchange rate regime to a looser exchange rate regime to an inflation targeting framework is feasible, but needs sound and supportive fiscal and structural policies to manage the transition and minimize the risk of undermining the credibility and effectiveness of the new framework by saddling the central bank with conflicting objectives.
For further reading, see Andrea Schaechter, Mark R. Stone, and Mark Zelmer, Adopting Inflation Targeting: Practical Issues for Emerging Market Countries, IMF Occasional Paper No. 202 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 2000).
For example, as a major exporter of precious metals, South Africa’s terms of trade are significantly affected by swings in commodity prices. A floating exchange rate regime anchored by an inflation targeting framework helps it manage the effects of commodity price movements on its economy.
In most inflation targeting frameworks, the inflation target is announced by the government or jointly by the government and the central bank. Thus, while the government can play an active role in setting the objectives for monetary policy, the central bank has the discretion to take the monetary actions it judges necessary to achieve the target, and is publicly held accountable for its actions.
Issues surrounding the design of inflation targeting frameworks are discussed in Ben Bernanke, Thomas Laubach, Frederic Mishkin, and Adam Posen, Inflation Targeting: Lessons from the International Experience (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999) and associated references.
It is worth noting that many inflation targeting countries, such as Australia, Chile, and New Zealand, have found that the pass-through effects from exchange rate movements to domestic inflation declined as their inflation rates fell and inflation targeting frameworks gained credibility, implying that over time they can be more tolerant of exchange rate movements. However, it must be recognized that this fall in pass-through has also occurred in several countries that did not adopt inflation targeting frameworks but have been successful in lowering inflation.
Partly reflecting these significant changes in the use of monetary and exchange rate regimes and the failure of many countries to reduce inflation on a sustained basis in the 1970s and 1980s, important institutional changes have taken place in recent years in central bank charters as well as in the overall design and goals of monetary policy in emerging markets. One of them is greater central bank independence and transparency. Following the pioneering experience of New Zealand and its adoption by other advanced countries, a growing number of emerging markets have given their central banks complete control over the instruments used to achieve a low inflation goal.
Along with central bank instrument independence, several emerging markets—inflation targeters or not—have also greatly increased the transparency and accountability of goals and procedures of monetary policy, often in the form of statutory arrangements, giving the central bank a well-defined mandate to pursue price stability. In Latin America, for instance, the Argentine central bank law of 1991 explicitly prescribes that “the primary and fundamental mission of the Bank is to preserve the value of the currency,” while Chile’s central bank act of the same year restricted the objectives of the central bank to “oversee monetary stability and the proper functioning of the internal and external payments system.” In a similar vein, the new central bank charters for most transition economies—including the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, and Russia—which were passed into law in the early 1990s, clearly stated that the main goal for monetary policy was low inflation. In the particular case of countries adopting inflation targeting, such as Israel, Chile, and, more recently, Brazil, Colombia, Korea, Mexico, and South Africa, these statutory changes have been combined with the public announcement of multiyear targets for inflation. This has helped to reduce the room for monetary policy discretion in the medium to long run, thus helping anchor long-term inflation expectations. To the extent that these institutional changes limit the scope for seigniorage, they are clearly conducive to greater fiscal discipline.
The other change in monetary arrangements introduced by several emerging markets has been to allow domestic bank accounts and transactions to be conducted in either domestic or foreign currency.23Such a dual currency arrangement has often been coupled with hard exchange rate pegs (as in Hong Kong SAR since 1982, Argentina since 1991, and Bulgaria from 1997) or floating exchange rate regimes (as in Peru from the early 1990s). In most cases, foreign currency denominated assets and liabilities in the domestic financial system have expanded very rapidly, so that some of these economies have become highly “dollarized” or “euroized” (Figure 4.6). Once such freedom to choose between foreign and domestic currency denominated assets is combined with the elimination of capital account restrictions, allowing residents to switch freely between onshore and offshore asset holdings—as has been the case in most of these countries—a significant constraint on monetary policy discretion is imposed. Not only is the monetary authority given control of a smaller share of the money supply but also this share can rapidly shrink (via currency switching) if the credibility of domestic policies falters. Indeed, in several countries the dollarization of financial intermediation appears to be quite sensitive to interest rate differentials, exchange rate volatility, and changes in devaluation risk.24 At the same time, to the extent that partial dollarization reduces the scope for monetary policy discretion and the base for seigniorage, it also helps foster fiscal discipline.

Foreign Currency Deposits
(Percent of M3)
The share of foreign currency deposits in the domestic banking systems rose significantly in recent years.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.
Foreign Currency Deposits
(Percent of M3)
The share of foreign currency deposits in the domestic banking systems rose significantly in recent years.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.Foreign Currency Deposits
(Percent of M3)
The share of foreign currency deposits in the domestic banking systems rose significantly in recent years.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.How do these different monetary regimes (and the new institutional arrangements underpinning them) fare relative to each other in terms of: (1) the speed at which inflation is brought down after the regime is adopted; (2) the output cost of the policies designed to drive down inflation (the so-called “sacrifice” ratio); and (3) their ability to foster fiscal discipline and sustain low inflation in the longer-term?
Most countries that experienced high inflation have at some point used exchange-rate-based stabilization programs to reduce price increases (see Table 4.4). Examples of soft pegs used to lower inflation from very high rates include the three attempted stabilizations in Argentina (including the Tablita and Austral plans) as well as stabilization programs in Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, Israel, Mexico, Poland, Russia and, most recently, Turkey. In addition, some countries with moderate inflation also used soft pegs to help reduce it (e.g., Egypt, Pakistan, and Hungary), whereas others—notably in east Asia—pegged their exchange rates as much to achieve foreign trade stability as to keep inflation low. Examples of exchange-rate-based stabilizations using hard pegs include Argentina from 1991 and Bulgaria since 1997.
Major Emerging Markets Exchange-Rate and Money-Based Stabilization Programs Since the 1970s
Where more than one arrangement is listed, the sequence of arrangements is indicated.
Major Emerging Markets Exchange-Rate and Money-Based Stabilization Programs Since the 1970s
12-Month Inflation | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Country | Beginning Date | Exchange Rate/Monetary Arrangement1 | At start of program | Third year of program | In 2000 | Did the Program End in a Currency Crash? |
Chile | April 1975 | Managed/Monetary aggregates | 394.3 | — | — | No. Ended December 1977. |
Chile (Tablita) | February 1978 | Crawling peg, peg. | 52.1 | 28.7 | 4.5 | Yes (February 1983). |
Argentina (Tablita) | December 1978 | Crawling peg | 169.9 | 131.3 | — | Yes (April 1982). |
Argentina (Austral) | June 1985 | Peg, crawling peg | 1,128.9 | — | — | Yes (September 1987). |
Israel | July 1985 | Peg, horizontal band, crawling band. | 445.4 | 16.0 | No | |
Brazil (Cruzado) | February 1986 | Peg. | 286.0 | — | — | Yes (March 1987). |
Mexico | December 1987 | Peg, crawling peg, widening band. | 143.7 | 29.9 | 8.9 | Yes (December 1994). |
Argentina (Bonex) | December 1989 | Float/Monetary aggregates | 4,923.3 | — | — | No. Ended February 1991. |
Poland | January 1990 | Peg, crawling peg, widening band. | 639.6 | 39.8 | 8.6 | No |
Brazil (Collor) | March 1990 | Managed/Monetary aggregates | 5,747.3 | — | — | No. Ended January 1991. |
Peru | August 1990 | Float/Monetary aggregates | 12,377.8 | 48.5 | 3.7 | No. |
Argentina | ||||||
(Convertibility) | April 1991 | Currency board. | 287.4 | 4.3 | 0.1 | No. |
Brazil (Cardoso) | July 1994 | Managed float, crawling peg. | 4,922.6 | 6.1 | 6.0 | Yes (January 1999). |
Russia | July 1995 | Band, crawling band. | 225.0 | 5.5 | 20.2 | Yes (August 1998). |
Bulgaria | July 1997 | Currency board. | 1,502.8 | 8.6 | 11.4 | No. |
Turkey | January 1998 | Crawling peg. | 99.1 | — | 39.0 | Yes (February 2001). |
Where more than one arrangement is listed, the sequence of arrangements is indicated.
Major Emerging Markets Exchange-Rate and Money-Based Stabilization Programs Since the 1970s
12-Month Inflation | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Country | Beginning Date | Exchange Rate/Monetary Arrangement1 | At start of program | Third year of program | In 2000 | Did the Program End in a Currency Crash? |
Chile | April 1975 | Managed/Monetary aggregates | 394.3 | — | — | No. Ended December 1977. |
Chile (Tablita) | February 1978 | Crawling peg, peg. | 52.1 | 28.7 | 4.5 | Yes (February 1983). |
Argentina (Tablita) | December 1978 | Crawling peg | 169.9 | 131.3 | — | Yes (April 1982). |
Argentina (Austral) | June 1985 | Peg, crawling peg | 1,128.9 | — | — | Yes (September 1987). |
Israel | July 1985 | Peg, horizontal band, crawling band. | 445.4 | 16.0 | No | |
Brazil (Cruzado) | February 1986 | Peg. | 286.0 | — | — | Yes (March 1987). |
Mexico | December 1987 | Peg, crawling peg, widening band. | 143.7 | 29.9 | 8.9 | Yes (December 1994). |
Argentina (Bonex) | December 1989 | Float/Monetary aggregates | 4,923.3 | — | — | No. Ended February 1991. |
Poland | January 1990 | Peg, crawling peg, widening band. | 639.6 | 39.8 | 8.6 | No |
Brazil (Collor) | March 1990 | Managed/Monetary aggregates | 5,747.3 | — | — | No. Ended January 1991. |
Peru | August 1990 | Float/Monetary aggregates | 12,377.8 | 48.5 | 3.7 | No. |
Argentina | ||||||
(Convertibility) | April 1991 | Currency board. | 287.4 | 4.3 | 0.1 | No. |
Brazil (Cardoso) | July 1994 | Managed float, crawling peg. | 4,922.6 | 6.1 | 6.0 | Yes (January 1999). |
Russia | July 1995 | Band, crawling band. | 225.0 | 5.5 | 20.2 | Yes (August 1998). |
Bulgaria | July 1997 | Currency board. | 1,502.8 | 8.6 | 11.4 | No. |
Turkey | January 1998 | Crawling peg. | 99.1 | — | 39.0 | Yes (February 2001). |
Where more than one arrangement is listed, the sequence of arrangements is indicated.
Exchange-rate-based stabilization programs generally succeeded in bringing inflation down rapidly in the short term, often accompanied by dramatic initial expansions in activity and appreciation of the real exchange rate (Figure 4.7), as inflation in the tradable goods sector slowed at a much faster rate than in nontradable goods.25This appreciation of the real exchange rate often led to unsustainable increases in domestic demand, output, and imports (as consumers and firms took advantage of the lower prices of foreign goods by accelerating such purchases), posing a clear threat to the balance of payments. Less credible pegs have been particularly susceptible to this effect, leading to a sharply negative short-run sacrifice ratio (the ratio of lost output to inflation reduction) at first, but at the cost of a significant recession later, particularly if the peg is abandoned.

Selected Exchange Rate Stabilization Programs, 1985–981
(Simple averages, three years prior and four years after program initiation, t)
Exchange rate stabilization has been generally associated with output growth in the early stages and a marked appreciation of the real exchange rate.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Simple averages for the following nine exchange rate stabilization programs: Israel, July 1985; Brazil (Cruzado), February 1986; Mexico, December 1987; Poland, January 1990; Argentina (Convertibility), April 1991; Brazil (Cardoso), July 1994; Russia, July 1995; Bulgaria, July 1997; and Turkey, January 1998.
Selected Exchange Rate Stabilization Programs, 1985–981
(Simple averages, three years prior and four years after program initiation, t)
Exchange rate stabilization has been generally associated with output growth in the early stages and a marked appreciation of the real exchange rate.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Simple averages for the following nine exchange rate stabilization programs: Israel, July 1985; Brazil (Cruzado), February 1986; Mexico, December 1987; Poland, January 1990; Argentina (Convertibility), April 1991; Brazil (Cardoso), July 1994; Russia, July 1995; Bulgaria, July 1997; and Turkey, January 1998.Selected Exchange Rate Stabilization Programs, 1985–981
(Simple averages, three years prior and four years after program initiation, t)
Exchange rate stabilization has been generally associated with output growth in the early stages and a marked appreciation of the real exchange rate.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Simple averages for the following nine exchange rate stabilization programs: Israel, July 1985; Brazil (Cruzado), February 1986; Mexico, December 1987; Poland, January 1990; Argentina (Convertibility), April 1991; Brazil (Cardoso), July 1994; Russia, July 1995; Bulgaria, July 1997; and Turkey, January 1998.Regarding the long-term impact on inflation, the difference between soft and hard pegs is important. In the case of soft pegs, growing balance of payments pressures have often led to their demise. This was so, for instance, in Argentina following the stabilization programs of 1978–81 (the tablita) and the 1985–86 Austral plan; Brazil during the 1986 cruzado plan and (to a lesser extent) the 1994–98 Real plan; the Chilean tablita program of 1978–82; Mexico following the 1987–94 stabilization; Russia in 1995–98; and it was a contributing factor in Turkey more recently.26 In addition, because fixed exchange rate regimes tend to encourage unhedged foreign currency borrowing (often backed by implicit or explicit government guarantees), the collapse of the peg has tended to produce severe domestic banking crises—as, for instance, in Mexico during the 1994–95 “Tequila” crisis, in several Asian emerging markets during 1997–98, and in Turkey more recently.27
Part—but certainly not all—of the sustainability problem with soft pegs seems related to the ambiguous relationship between pegged exchange rate regimes and fiscal discipline.28 On the one hand, fixed exchange rates should be expected to foster fiscal discipline, given that policymakers know all too well that fiscal discipline is required to maintain the peg and that failure to do so is likely to result in politically and economically costly devaluations.29 On the other hand, one can argue that fixed exchange rates can (temporarily) mask excesses in fiscal policy that would manifest themselves much faster in a floating exchange rate regime.30 This masking effect can be particularly hazardous at the onset of stabilization programs where inflation drops sharply following the introduction of the peg, giving a false impression that the stabilization gains are permanent and leading to procrastination in undertaking the necessary but unpopular fiscal measures. Indeed, a common pattern of several stabilization programs is that of monetary discipline being enforced first and fiscal adjustment coming later—sometimes too little and too late.31 This is largely because, as discussed earlier, consensus on fiscal adjustment and supportive reforms generally takes longer, is harder to achieve, and can be politically very costly. Consistent with these arguments about the ambiguous relationship between fiscal deficits and exchange rate regimes, a recent empirical study has found that the magnitude of fiscal deficits (measured as a ratio to GDP) has varied widely across pegged exchange rate regimes, that differences in fiscal performance between pegged and floating regimes are not statistically significant, and that the net effect depends on the choice of group of countries.32
That said, some soft exchange rate pegs have succeeded in bringing inflation down on a more sustained basis, particularly in the 1990s. Common general features of these experiences include fiscal restraint, broader structural and institutional reforms, and actions to break inflation inertia, such as wage freezes and labor market reform.33 In addition, a variety of macroeconomic strategies have accompanied these stabilizations. In Egypt, inflation was reduced through an exchangerate-based stabilization program and adherence to a soft-peg regime, which was supported by strong fiscal consolidation and gradually made more flexible. In other cases, such as Israel and Poland, inflation was reined in through a gradual loosening of the exchange rate band and, over time, the adoption of an inflation targeting regime (in Israel, capital controls also played a part). In Hungary, however the appreciation of the real exchange rate following stabilization was successfully contained through tight fiscal and monetary policies. In several Asian countries (notably Malaysia, Korea, and Thailand until the 1997–98 crisis), exchange rate pegs were also associated with low inflation. This history of monetary stability helped limit the exchange rate pass-through in the Asian crisis, enabling these countries to preserve low inflation.
In the case of hard pegs, devaluations have been much less frequent in both the recent and the distant past.34 One reason is that a government’s reputation tends to suffer following an exit from a hard peg; therefore, governments have been reluctant to abandon their hard pegs. The other reason is that countries under hard pegs have become highly “dollarized” or “euroized” following their adoption of dual currency arrangements in domestic banking and extensive foreign currency borrowing by the public and private sectors. As a result, the benefits of a devaluation on external competitiveness are smaller, while the impact on balance sheets can be highly contractionary if the nonfinancial private sector has a net short position in foreign currency. Yet, short-run output costs of sticking to the peg have at times been significant, as witnessed for instance by the experiences of Hong Kong SAR in 1997-98 and Argentina during the 1994-1995 “Tequila” crisis, as well as following the large external shocks associated with the Asian crisis of 1997-98 and the Russian crisis of 1998.
Until recently, the use of floating exchange rate regimes in stabilization programs has been mostly associated with the use of a monetary anchor. In this case, rather than pegging the exchange rate to that of a low inflation country, the central bank targets a monetary aggregate such as the monetary base or broad money, seeking to slow down its growth rate. Three main stylized facts have been generally associated with the use of monetary targeting in stabilization programs in emerging markets (Figure 4.8): (1) the slow convergence of inflation to the growth rate of the money supply, implying that dramatic monetary tightening is typically needed to produce a significant drop in inflation; (2) a real appreciation of the currency but without leading to a clearcut deterioration of the current account; and (3) an initial contraction (often dramatic) in economic activity. The third item implies that, in contrast with exchange-rate-based stabilizations, recessions will come earlier rather than later, in line with the kind of Phillips curve trade-offs observed in industrial countries.35 The initial recession tends to be very sharp.36 Partly for this reason, and in marked contrast with exchange rate pegs, the external trade and current account balances do not typically move sharply into deficits that bring into question the sustainability of the regime.

Selected Monetary Stabilization Programs, 1975-901
(Simple averages, three years prior and four years after program initiation, t)
Money-based stabilization programs have been generally associated with sharp output losses at their initial stages and limited appreciation of the real exchange rate.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Simple averages for the following four monetary stabilization programs: Chile, April 1975; Argentina (Bonex), December 1989; Brazil (Collar), March 1990; Peru, August 1990. Data for Argentina in years t + 1, t + 2, t + 3, and t + 4 excluded because it adopted a new exchange rate stabilization program in t + 1 (1991).2Money growth measured as annual percent change in M1.3Excludes Peru for which real effective exchange rate data was not available prior to 1979.
Selected Monetary Stabilization Programs, 1975-901
(Simple averages, three years prior and four years after program initiation, t)
Money-based stabilization programs have been generally associated with sharp output losses at their initial stages and limited appreciation of the real exchange rate.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Simple averages for the following four monetary stabilization programs: Chile, April 1975; Argentina (Bonex), December 1989; Brazil (Collar), March 1990; Peru, August 1990. Data for Argentina in years t + 1, t + 2, t + 3, and t + 4 excluded because it adopted a new exchange rate stabilization program in t + 1 (1991).2Money growth measured as annual percent change in M1.3Excludes Peru for which real effective exchange rate data was not available prior to 1979.Selected Monetary Stabilization Programs, 1975-901
(Simple averages, three years prior and four years after program initiation, t)
Money-based stabilization programs have been generally associated with sharp output losses at their initial stages and limited appreciation of the real exchange rate.
Source: IMF staff estimates.1Simple averages for the following four monetary stabilization programs: Chile, April 1975; Argentina (Bonex), December 1989; Brazil (Collar), March 1990; Peru, August 1990. Data for Argentina in years t + 1, t + 2, t + 3, and t + 4 excluded because it adopted a new exchange rate stabilization program in t + 1 (1991).2Money growth measured as annual percent change in M1.3Excludes Peru for which real effective exchange rate data was not available prior to 1979.There is also consensus that the use of monetary targeting to maintain low inflation has become increasingly problematic in emerging markets. As amply demonstrated by the experience of industrial countries, a major issue is the instability of the relationship between monetary aggregates and inflation, often exacerbated by growing international capital mobility and financial innovation.37 The issue is likely to be even more acute among emerging markets with long histories of monetary instability (which, among other things, makes it difficult to characterize the money-inflation relationship using long time series data) and where continuing currency substitution, the dollarization of bank deposits (in countries where they are allowed), and large swings in capital inflows stemming from changes in external interest rates complicate the control of domestic money growth.38 In addition, growing dollarization in several of these countries and associated currency mismatches in private sector balance sheets can make it very difficult for central banks to focus solely on the pre-set monetary target at the expense of exchange rate stability when conflict between them arises.39 For these reasons, monetary targeting regimes seem a clearly inferior alternative to other existing regimes outside the realm of stabilization programs in emerging markets—a contention supported by the fact that they have been largely abandoned in both advanced and emerging market economies.
The international experience with inflation targeting, albeit very recent, has been so far significantly more favorable. Regarding its capacity to lower inflation, a recent study including both industrial countries and emerging markets that have adopted inflation targeting over the past decade finds that it has taken about 10 quarters (2½ years) on average for a country to achieve stationary inflation levels following the adoption of inflation targeting.40 Among emerging markets, however, the variance has been higher—with Chile and Israel having experienced the longest transition periods (nine and six years, respectively) since they began to publicly announce inflation targets in the early 1990s—partly reflecting the wider discrepancies in inflation levels at the starting point of the new regime. Countries that adopted inflation targeting have also been generally successful in meeting their announced targets, a feature that stands in sharp contrast with the international experience with monetary targets, which were frequently breached and revised.41
Sacrifice ratios have also been considerably lower under inflation targeting than under monetary targeting, though not as favorable as under exchange-rate-based stabilizations. In countries that have been under inflation targeting for several years (Chile and Israel, among emerging markets, and Australia, Canada, Chile, Finland, New Zealand, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom), the sacrifice ratio has been estimated at 0.6 percent of annual GDP. For emerging market countries that adopted the framework over the past two years (Brazil, Colombia, Korea, Mexico, and South Africa) the average sacrifice ratio has to date been slightly negative (-0.4 of GDP).42 Both figures are substantially lower than traditional benchmark estimates of sacrifice ratios in advanced countries.43
Inflation targeting’s effect on fiscal performance is harder to establish, though the evidence is consistent with the hypothesis that it helps foster fiscal discipline. Table 4.5 shows that all countries that adopted inflation targeting experienced some improvement in their fiscal balances, typically with a one-to two-year lag (although in some cases the improvement preceded the introduction of inflation targeting). As the absence of fiscal dominance appears to be a pre-condition to successful inflation targeting (Box 4.3), fiscal discipline and maintenance of a targeting regime should be linked without necessarily implying that one causes the other.44 In any event, it is significant that in none of the countries where inflation targeting has been introduced has there been any evidence of a subsequent loosening of the fiscal stance.45
Fiscal Balances of Countries That Adopted Inflation Targeting1
(Annual percent)
Years under inflation targeting in bold.
Date for starting with inflation targeting at the point inflation targets began to be publicly announced.
Inflation targeting starting in 2001. Previously, monetary targets were announced.
Fiscal Balances of Countries That Adopted Inflation Targeting1
(Annual percent)
Country | 1985-89 | 1990 | 1991 | 1992 | 1993 | 1994 | 1995 | 1996 | 1997 | 1998 | 1999 | 2000 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Early inflation targeters | |||||||||||||
Chile2 | 1.01 | 3.48 | 2.38 | 3.02 | 1.75 | 2.26 | 3.63 | 2.58 | 2.10 | -0.11 | -2.37 | -1.06 | |
Israel2 | -3.49 | -4.35 | -6.08 | -3.65 | -2.50 | -2.30 | -4.10 | -3.70 | -2.70 | -2.30 | -2.25 | -0.61 | |
Australia | -0.18 | 0.91 | -1.39 | -3.44 | -3.90 | -3.27 | -2.37 | -1.48 | -0.29 | 0.66 | 1.46 | 1.32 | |
Canada | -5.33 | -4.91 | -5.45 | -5.12 | -5.48 | -4.57 | -3.93 | -2.04 | 0.50 | 0.52 | 0.62 | 1.43 | |
Finland | 0.98 | 1.02 | -4.54 | -8.11 | -10.65 | -10.77 | -8.72 | -7.20 | -3.67 | -1.48 | -0.78 | 1.34 | |
New Zealand | -2.66 | -1.68 | -4.48 | -4.61 | -0.69 | 2.20 | 3.61 | 2.72 | 1.64 | 0.97 | 0.43 | 0.30 | |
Spain | -3.84 | -2.80 | -2.20 | -2.67 | -5.91 | -4.92 | -5.92 | -3.93 | -2.67 | -2.14 | -1.09 | -0.72 | |
Sweden | -0.48 | 1.33 | -3.93 | -9.76 | -14.66 | -11.27 | -8.72 | -3.77 | -1.79 | 0.64 | 3.66 | 3.92 | |
United Kingdom | -1.42 | -0.84 | -2.78 | -7.24 | -8.18 | -6.91 | -5.48 | -4.16 | -1.48 | 0.25 | 1.48 | 3.80 | |
Average | -1.71 | -0.87 | -3.16 | -4.62 | -5.58 | -4.39 | -3.55 | -2.33 | -0.93 | -0.33 | 0.13 | 1.09 | |
Newcomers | |||||||||||||
Brazil | -1.51 | 2.64 | 0.19 | -0.87 | -0.10 | 0.10 | -2.27 | -2.57 | -2.63 | -5.40 | -6.89 | -3.20 | |
Colombia3 | -1.56 | -0.68 | 0.01 | -1.81 | -1.02 | -1.47 | -3.37 | -4.63 | -3.41 | -5.37 | -7.43 | -6.05 | |
Czech Republic | 2.52 | -2.07 | 4.15 | -0.62 | 0.46 | 1.24 | -0.25 | -0.10 | -0.94 | -1.63 | -1.61 | -2.30 | |
Mexico3 | -9.79 | -2.60 | 0.20 | 1.46 | 0.77 | -0.58 | -1.74 | -1.00 | -1.86 | -2.27 | -2.22 | -0.94 | |
Poland | -2.03 | 0.71 | -7.24 | -7.27 | -3.92 | -3.39 | -3.67 | -3.53 | -2.61 | -2.97 | -4.98 | -5.28 | |
South Africa | -4.46 | -3.11 | -4.76 | -8.73 | -9.42 | -5.24 | -5.19 | -4.51 | -3.84 | -2.34 | -2.06 | -2.65 | |
Thailand | -2.43 | 4.73 | 4.81 | 2.83 | 2.19 | 1.92 | 2.97 | 2.47 | -0.86 | -2.55 | -2.94 | -2.24 | |
Average | -2.80 | -0.85 | -1.24 | -2.97 | -2.20 | -1.56 | -2.75. | -2.72 | -2.55 | -3.33 | -4.20 | -3.40 |
Years under inflation targeting in bold.
Date for starting with inflation targeting at the point inflation targets began to be publicly announced.
Inflation targeting starting in 2001. Previously, monetary targets were announced.
Fiscal Balances of Countries That Adopted Inflation Targeting1
(Annual percent)
Country | 1985-89 | 1990 | 1991 | 1992 | 1993 | 1994 | 1995 | 1996 | 1997 | 1998 | 1999 | 2000 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Early inflation targeters | |||||||||||||
Chile2 | 1.01 | 3.48 | 2.38 | 3.02 | 1.75 | 2.26 | 3.63 | 2.58 | 2.10 | -0.11 | -2.37 | -1.06 | |
Israel2 | -3.49 | -4.35 | -6.08 | -3.65 | -2.50 | -2.30 | -4.10 | -3.70 | -2.70 | -2.30 | -2.25 | -0.61 | |
Australia | -0.18 | 0.91 | -1.39 | -3.44 | -3.90 | -3.27 | -2.37 | -1.48 | -0.29 | 0.66 | 1.46 | 1.32 | |
Canada | -5.33 | -4.91 | -5.45 | -5.12 | -5.48 | -4.57 | -3.93 | -2.04 | 0.50 | 0.52 | 0.62 | 1.43 | |
Finland | 0.98 | 1.02 | -4.54 | -8.11 | -10.65 | -10.77 | -8.72 | -7.20 | -3.67 | -1.48 | -0.78 | 1.34 | |
New Zealand | -2.66 | -1.68 | -4.48 | -4.61 | -0.69 | 2.20 | 3.61 | 2.72 | 1.64 | 0.97 | 0.43 | 0.30 | |
Spain | -3.84 | -2.80 | -2.20 | -2.67 | -5.91 | -4.92 | -5.92 | -3.93 | -2.67 | -2.14 | -1.09 | -0.72 | |
Sweden | -0.48 | 1.33 | -3.93 | -9.76 | -14.66 | -11.27 | -8.72 | -3.77 | -1.79 | 0.64 | 3.66 | 3.92 | |
United Kingdom | -1.42 | -0.84 | -2.78 | -7.24 | -8.18 | -6.91 | -5.48 | -4.16 | -1.48 | 0.25 | 1.48 | 3.80 | |
Average | -1.71 | -0.87 | -3.16 | -4.62 | -5.58 | -4.39 | -3.55 | -2.33 | -0.93 | -0.33 | 0.13 | 1.09 | |
Newcomers | |||||||||||||
Brazil | -1.51 | 2.64 | 0.19 | -0.87 | -0.10 | 0.10 | -2.27 | -2.57 | -2.63 | -5.40 | -6.89 | -3.20 | |
Colombia3 | -1.56 | -0.68 | 0.01 | -1.81 | -1.02 | -1.47 | -3.37 | -4.63 | -3.41 | -5.37 | -7.43 | -6.05 | |
Czech Republic | 2.52 | -2.07 | 4.15 | -0.62 | 0.46 | 1.24 | -0.25 | -0.10 | -0.94 | -1.63 | -1.61 | -2.30 | |
Mexico3 | -9.79 | -2.60 | 0.20 | 1.46 | 0.77 | -0.58 | -1.74 | -1.00 | -1.86 | -2.27 | -2.22 | -0.94 | |
Poland | -2.03 | 0.71 | -7.24 | -7.27 | -3.92 | -3.39 | -3.67 | -3.53 | -2.61 | -2.97 | -4.98 | -5.28 | |
South Africa | -4.46 | -3.11 | -4.76 | -8.73 | -9.42 | -5.24 | -5.19 | -4.51 | -3.84 | -2.34 | -2.06 | -2.65 | |
Thailand | -2.43 | 4.73 | 4.81 | 2.83 | 2.19 | 1.92 | 2.97 | 2.47 | -0.86 | -2.55 | -2.94 | -2.24 | |
Average | -2.80 | -0.85 | -1.24 | -2.97 | -2.20 | -1.56 | -2.75. | -2.72 | -2.55 | -3.33 | -4.20 | -3.40 |
Years under inflation targeting in bold.
Date for starting with inflation targeting at the point inflation targets began to be publicly announced.
Inflation targeting starting in 2001. Previously, monetary targets were announced.
Some aspects of inflation targeting remain controversial. First, in virtually all countries that adopted inflation targeting, inflation had already been slowing and several of them embarked upon the new regime with single-digit inflation levels. In two emerging markets where inflation was in the double-digits prior to the adoption of inflation targeting (Chile and Israel), the transition period was rather protracted, even though inflation had been already trending down. This may suggest that the main strength of inflation targeting as a monetary policy regime lies in its capacity to keep inflation under control once it is already low.
Second, economic theory maintains that a key ingredient to reduce inflation is regime credibility. This raises the question of where monetary policy credibility will come from in the case of emerging markets that are considering adopting inflation targeting following a long history of monetary instability and/or large devaluations. In this regard, a comparison between inflation targeting and its main competitor—exchange rate pegs—is illustrative. Under exchange rate pegging, credibility is largely imported—that is, it comes from a tangible (and hence credible) restraint on the behavior of tradable prices. In particular, under currency unions or unilateral adoption of the currency of a low inflation country, credibility clearly stems from national constitutional arrangements and/or international agreements that tend to be hard to revoke. In the absence of those, inflation targeting countries have to rely on the various institutional arrangements discussed above, such as greater transparency and accountability of monetary policies, granting the central bank operational (instrument) independence, and giving the central bank a clear mandate to lower inflation above anything else. As noted before, there is evidence that such arrangements have played a significant role in helping to control inflation; yet, building such credibility may take a significant time and, hence, protract stabilization.46
Third, inflation targeting may be a problem in countries that must maintain exchange rate stability to protect the unhedged balance sheet positions of the private sector. Indeed, because of potential financial fragilities arising out of large exchange rate movements, it has been argued that most developing countries tend to display a “fear of floating.”47 In principle, inflation targeting does not rule out some attention being paid to exchange rate movements by the central bank to the extent that they have a bearing on future inflation. This generally produces a pattern of monetary tightening when the exchange rate depreciates, a similar response (but not necessarily of the same magnitude) to that if the exchange rate were being targeted directly. So, inflation targeting does take into account the “fear of floating” argument, but only indirectly. To the extent that conflicting objectives between exchange rate stability and inflation arise or the magnitude of tightening needed to stabilize the exchange rate differs substantially from that needed to achieve the inflation targets, balance sheet considerations (as in several partially dollarized emerging market economies) may become paramount, limiting the use of inflation targeting and undermining the transparency of monetary policy.
Finally, successful inflation targeting has generally been associated with significant preconditions that some other emerging markets currently may find difficult to meet (see Box 4.3). Particular examples are the existence of well-developed financial markets, absence of fiscal dominance, reasonably well-understood transmission mechanisms, and central bank instrument independence.
Safeguarding Low Inflation in Emerging Markets
As discussed above, the decline in world inflation and greater monetary stability in advanced countries, together with the strengthening of institutional arrangements in recent years, have helped to address one of the main causes of emerging market inflation in previous decades—namely, the lack of a credible nominal anchor for private sector inflation expectations. In addition, the substantial progress made over the past decades in the theory and practice of monetary policy has undoubtedly contributed to sounder central banking practices. This includes not only more sophisticated forecasting tools and a better understanding of policy instruments, but also—and perhaps more crucially—the emphasis on transparency and accountability of central bank decisions and awareness of the perils of saddling the monetary authority with multiple objectives other than that of preserving price stability. Finally, other structural policies have helped by making economies more efficient and reducing inflation inertia, such as labor market and trade reform.
However, lower external inflation, sounder central bank arrangements, and better understanding of monetary policy do not guarantee price stability. Because monetary and fiscal policies are intrinsically linked through the budget constraint of the consolidated government, monetary policy soundness, and hence a country’s inflation performance, are dependent on the stance of its fiscal policy. While recent institutional changes in monetary policy arrangements do appear to have helped curb fiscal excesses, they cannot of themselves prevent persistent fiscal deficits. Indeed, history points to episodes of significant loosening of fiscal policies under currency boards, central bank independence, and partial and even full dollarization; moreover, significant reductions in fiscal deficits in several countries that adopted inflation targeting in recent years are yet to be seen. This suggests that monetary arrangements per se have only limited power to fix “real” problems arising from a fiscal regime inconsistent with the goal of price stability.
There have, of course, been other general developments that have helped restrain fiscal excesses in emerging markets, some of which may be of a more permanent nature. One of them is the rapid growth of domestic financial systems. As mentioned above, inflation appears to be inversely related to the depth of domestic financial markets, insofar as the latter lowers the cost of noninflationary financing of fiscal deficits and reduces the need of seigniorage. Financial sector concerns about inflation, combined with the sector’s growing economic importance, are also a contributing factor.48 A second key development is greater financial integration of emerging market countries within the world economy. To the extent that national governments compete among themselves for a given pool of world savings, and international capital markets monitor country-specific fiscal developments and price the respective sovereign spreads accordingly, this provides a clear incentive for fiscal prudence. Third, public tolerance for inflation appears to be lower. This may be merely due to a demonstration effect stemming from low inflation in industrial countries, but it may also reflect greater political weight in newly democratic regimes of lower income groups that are bound to lose more from inflation (see Box 4.1).
Other factors, however, may pose a threat to recent gains in price stabilization. First, some of the underlying institutional arrangements now in place in several emerging markets—notably those underpinning inflation targeting—are fairly new and have not been extensively tested. It remains to be seen whether they will be sustainable and effective in controlling inflation under a variety of crisis situations, such as those that plagued many emerging markets over the past decade. Second, despite substantial improvement in recent years, fiscal deficits remain relatively high in several emerging market countries, and in some countries public debt/GDP ratios are approaching those of advanced economies that have much more extensive welfare systems and a significant elderly population. Perhaps even more worrisome, fiscal consolidation efforts have been halted in quite a few countries over the past five years (see Table 4.3). Reasons for concern seem especially justified in some countries with hard exchange rate pegs where the accompanying requirement of stringent fiscal discipline has been somewhat lacking. To the extent that failure in taking bold steps in this direction increase the temptation to tackle the fiscal problem by resorting to the inflation tax, long-term price stability could be threatened.
Finally, consensus on how to distribute the fiscal cost of price stabilization remains hard to forge. This has been particularly the case in emerging markets with wide income disparities, long histories of fiscal and monetary imbalances, and sharply divided governments—factors that no doubt increase the political cost of monetary and fiscal prudence. Although low inflation per se may help create a strong constituency in favor of price stability, this cannot be taken for granted, at least on the basis of historical experiences to date.49 These political economy complications indicate that the achievement and preservation of price stability in those countries will require a firm political resolve and strong institutional arrangements to limit the discretion of both the monetary and the fiscal authorities.
For the purposes of this chapter, the following 24 countries are defined as emerging markets: Argentina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Colombia, Czech Republic, Egypt, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Russia, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, and Venezuela. This group comprises countries that either have small economies with relatively high per capita income or large economies with lower per capita income. All of them have nominal GDP in excess of $50 billion (in 1999 PPP-adjusted terms) with the exception of Bulgaria, which has a nominal GDP of $12 billion but is usually classified as an emerging market.
The underlying definition of hyperinflation follows that of Phillip Cagan’s seminal work, which defines hyper-inflation as consumer price increases in excess of 50 percent per month. See Phillip Cagan, “The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation,” in Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, ed. by Milton Friedman (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956). Those four episodes were: Argentina (May 1989-March 1990), Brazil (December 1989-March 1990), Peru (July–August 1990), and Russia (April 1991–January 1992).
See Barry Eichengreen and Nathan Sussman, “The International System in the (Very) Long Run,” World Economic Outlook Supporting Studies (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 2000) for a historical overview and bibliographical references.
For an account of the rise and fall of inflation in advanced countries since the 1970s, see the October 1996 issue of the World Economic Outlook.
For a survey and references see Stanley Fischer, “Modern Central Banking,” in The Future of Central Banking, ed. by ForrestCapie, Charles Goodhart, Stanley Fischer, and Norbert Schnadt (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1994), pp. 262-308.
In any period of time, seigniorage—the revenues the government obtains from issuing money—comprises both the “inflation tax”—the purchasing power losses that inflation causes to the holders of real money balances—and the change in real money balances. As the inflation tax is usually the main component of seigniorage, both terms are often used equivalently in the literature. In steady state, inflation tax and seigniorage are equal, as real balances are constant.
See, for instance, Berthold Herrendorf, “Time Consistent Collection of Optimal Seigniorage: A Unifying Framework,” Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 11 (March, 1997), pp. 1–46; and Alex Cukierman, Sebastian Edwards, and Guido Tabellini, “Seigniorage and Political Instability,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 82 (June 1992), pp. 537–55.
For a more detailed discussion and references, see Guillermo Calvo and Carlos Végh, “Inflation Stabilization and BOP Crises in Developing Countries,” in Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. by Taylor and Michael Woodford (New York: North-Holland,1999), pp. 1531-1614.
See Alberto Alesina and Allan Drazen, “Why Are Stabilizations Delayed?” American Economic Review, Vol. 81 (December 1991), pp. 1170-88; and Alejandro M. Werner, “Building Consensus for Stabilizations,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 59 (August 1999), pp.319-336.
See Robert King and Charles Plosser, “Money, Deficits, and Inflation,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 22 (1985), pp. 147-96; and Stanley Fischer, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos Vàgh, “Modern Hyper—and High Inflations,” Journal of Economic Literature (forthcoming).
See the large literature referenced in Sylvester C. Eijffinger, Independent Central Banks and Economic Performance (United Kingdom: Edward Elgar, 1997); and Marta Campillo and Jeffrey Miron, “Why Does Inflation Differ Across Countries,” in Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy, ed. by Christina Romer and David Romer (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); and Christina Terra, “Openness an Inflation: A New Assessment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 113 (May 1998), pp. 641-80.
See Prakash Loungani and Phillip Swagel, “Sources of Inflation in Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper (Washington, International Monetary Fund, forthcoming); and “The Rise and Fall of Inflation,” Chapter VI in the October 1996 World Economic Outlook.
See Atish Ghosh, Anne-Marie Guide, Jonathan Ostry, and Holger Wolf, “Does the Nominal Exchange Rate Regime Matter?,” IMF Working Paper 95/121 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1995).
Indeed, a recent study has found a positive correlation between openness and government size. This correlation may reflect the use of government spending as an external risk-reducing device. See Dani Rodrik, “Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 106 (October 1998), pp. 997-1032.
See, for instance, Carlo Cottarelli and Peter Doyle, Disinflation in Transition 1993–97, Occasional Paper No. 179 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1999).
The two important relapses in the fight against inflation have been Bulgaria (1996) and Russia (1998-99). Since then, Bulgaria has managed to stabilize prices under a currency board arrangement, and Russia has made considerable progress in lowering inflation under a floating exchange rate regime.
Fiscal deficits in Asia were mostly low to begin with, and only rose substantially during the 1997–98 financial crisis.
See Stanley Fischer and Ratna Sahay, “The Transition Economies After Ten Years,” IMF Working Paper 00/30 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 2000). The slight deterioration of the fiscal position indicator (scaled by M1) for merging Europe depicted in Figure 4.3 is entirely due to Turkey.
Ilan Goldfajn and Sergio R. C. Werlang, “The Pass-Through From Depreciation to Inflation: A Panel Study,” (unpublished; Brasilia: Central Bank of Brazil, 2000); and Eduardo Borensztein and José de Gregorio, “Devaluation and Inflation,” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund, March 2000).
The main features of the operation of each of these regimes are extensively described elsewhere. Useful reviews can be found in Carlo Cottarelli and Curzio Giannini, Credibility Without Rules? Monetary Frameworks in the Post-Bretton Woods Era, IMF Occasional Paper No. 154 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1997); and Frederic Mishkin, “International Experiences with Different Monetary Policy Regimes,” NBER Working Paper No. 7044 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, September 2000).
See Cottarelli and Giannini, Credibility Without Rules; and Michael Mussa, Paul Masson, Alexander Swoboda, Esteban Jadresic, Paolo Mauro, and Andrew Berg, Exchange Rate Regimes in an Increasingly Integrated World Economy, IMF Occasional Paper No. 193 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 2000).
Reasons for this growing bipolar outlook are discussed in Stanley Fischer, “Exchange Rate Regimes: Is the Bipolar View Correct?” address to the American Economic Association Meeting (January 2001), available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/010601a.htm.
A few emerging market economies in the Western Hemisphere started allowing domestic banks to take foreign currency deposits and supply foreign currency denominated loans to residents already in the early 1970s, mainly to retain foreign exchange reserves within the country. However, in Argentina, Peru, and Mexico, for instance, the convertibility of foreign currency denominated deposits was temporarily suspended during macroeconomic crises in the 1980s, entailing a de facto partial confiscation of those deposits. Since the early 1990s, this arrangement been fully honored in those countries.
The response of dollarization to interest rate differential in a few European emerging markets is examined in Fischer, Sahay, and Végh, “Modern Hyper—and High Inflations.” Evidence on the impact of real exchange volatility on dollarization in large cross-section of countries is provided in Alain Ize and Eduardo Levy-Yeyati, “Dollarization of Financial Intermediation: Causes and Policy Implications,” IMF Working Paper 98/28 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1998). For a theoretical analysis see Luis Catão and Marco Terrones, “Determinants of Dollarization: The Banking Side,” IMF Working Paper 00/146 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 2000).
For a stylized graphical description of the main macroeconomic regularities of exchange-rate-based stabilizations, see Guillermo Calvo and Carlos Végh, “Inflation Stabilization and BOP crises in Developing Countries;” and Mussa and others, Exchange Rate Regimes in an Increasingly Integrated World Economy.
In recognition of such concerns, the Turkish program included an exit strategy to a floating exchange rate system (see Chapter I for more details). However, the pegged exchange rate collapsed before the exit strategy could be implemented.
The frequent juxtaposition of currency and banking crises (the so-called “twin crises”) has been documented in Graciela Kaminsky and Carmen Reinhart, “The Twin Crisis: The Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payments Problems,” American Economic Review, Vol. 89 (June 1999), pp. 473–500.
Other sustainability problems are discussed in Stanley Fisher and Ratna Sahay, “The Transition Economies After Ten Years.”
Paul Krugman first formalized the relationship between fiscal deficits and speculative attacks in what became subsequently known as a “first-generation” model of currency crises. See Paul Krugman, “A Model of Balance-of-Payments Crises,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 11 (November 1979), pp.311-25.
This argument has been made by Aaron Tornell and Andres Velasco, “Fixed versus Flexible Exchange Rates: Which Provides More Fiscal Discipline?,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 45 (April 2000), pp.399–436. In other words, under flexible exchange rates the excesses of fiscal policy tend to be paid immediately, providing greater incentives to fiscal rectitude.
This was the case, for instance, in Mexico in 1988–94, Brazil during 1994–98, and Turkey through much of the 1990s.
See Antonio Fatas, and Andrew K. Rose, “Do Monetary Handcuffs Restrain Leviathan? Fiscal Policy in Extreme Exchange Rate Regimes,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 2692 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, 2001). A study for Latin America found no evidence that fixed exchange rates brought about greater fiscal discipline. See Michael Gavin and Roberto Perotti, “Fiscal Policy in Latin America,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual, ed. by Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg (Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press, 1997). At the other extreme, Aaron Tornell and Andrés Velasco, “Fixed versus Flexible Exchange Rates: Which Provides More Fiscal Discipline?,” find that floating exchange rate regimes have been more conducive to fiscal discipline in their sample of sub-Saharan African countries.
See Stanley Fischer and David Orsmond, “Israeli Inflation from an International Perspective,” IMF Working Paper 00/178 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 2000).
In the case of currency boards, the historical record indicates that most exits from the regime have been voluntary, and primarily reflecting political factors rather than external macroeconomic shocks. See Atish Ghosh, Anne-Marie Guide, and Holger Wolf, “Currency Boards: More than a Quick Fix?,” Economic Policy: A European Forum (October 2000).
This difference in output performance between the two types of stabilization strategies has been dubbed in the literature as the “recession now vs. recession later” hypothesis.
See Guillermo Calvo and Carlos Végh, “Inflation Stabilization and BOP Crisis in Developing Countries.”
Between the early 1970s and early 1980s, about half of the industrial countries adopted monetary targeting, but most of them discontinued the practice since. See Cottarelli and Giannini, “Credibility Without Rules.”
See, for instance, Guillermo Calvo and Carlos Végh, “Currency Substitution in Developing Countries: An Introduction,” Revista de Análisis Económico, Vol. 7 (June 1992), pp. 3-28; Ratna Sahay and Carlos Végh, “Dollarization in Transition Economies: Evidence and Policy Implications,” and Miguel Savastano, “Dollarization in Latin America: Recent Evidence and Policy Issues,” both in The Macroeconomics of International Currencies: Theory, Policy, and Evidence, ed. by Paul Mizen and Eric Pentecost (Gloucertershire, UK: Edward Elgar), pp. 193–224.
As discussed later, a similar trade-off may arise under inflation targeting.
See Vittorio Corbo, Oscar Landerretche Moreno, and Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, “Does Inflation Targeting Make a Difference?,” (unpublished; Santiago: Central Bank of Chile, 2000).
Corbo, Moreno, and Schmidt-Hebbel, “Does Inflation Targeting Make a Difference?,” estimate an annual absolute average deviation between actual and target inflation of 66 basis points during the period 1989-2000 for a sample of countries consisting of Australia, Canada, Chile, Finland, Israel, New Zealand, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. Regarding the experience of emerging markets that have joined the sample more recently (Brazil, Colombia, Korea, Mexico, and South Africa) those deviations have averaged 2.74 percentage points. Another related indicator is the frequency of quarterly breaches in inflation targets. These have been relatively infrequent during both the disinflation period and the long-run target period. See Andrea Schaechter, Mark R. Stone, and Mark Zelmer, “Adopting Inflation Targeting: Practical Issues for Emerging Market Countries,” IMF Occasional Paper No. 202 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 2000).
See Corbo, Moreno, and Schmidt-Hebbel, “Does Inflation Targeting Make a Difference?”
Estimates of sacrifice ratios in developed countries are provided in Laurence Ball, “What Determines the Sacrifice Ratio?,” in Monetary Policy, ed. by Gregory Mankiw (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1994), pp. 155-188.
It may simply be that a country decides to adopt inflation targeting once the fiscal situation is reasonably under control or there is already a firm resolve to lower the deficit.
Ideally, the way to measure the performance would be based on cyclical adjusted measures of the fiscal stance, rather than based on actual fiscal deficits scaled by nominal GDP. However, as previously noted, such measures are hard to obtain for emerging markets, partly due to a lack of consensual estimates of the output gap.
One possible alternative is to borrow temporarily such credibility from an external institution, such as the IMF, until the “nuts and bolts” of inflation targeting are put in place. Countries that adopted inflation targeting or started moving toward it while under IMF-supported programs include Brazil, Colombia, and Thailand.
See Guillermo Calvo and Carmen M. Reinhart, “Fear of Floating,” NBER Working Paper No. 7993 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2000).
The argument about financial sector distaste for inflation and its impact on macroeconomic discipline has been made by Adam Posen, “Why Central Bank Independence Does Not Cause Low Inflation: There Is No Institutional Fix for Politics,” in Finance and the International Economy: The AMEX Bank Review Prize Essays, ed. by Richard O’Brien, Vol. 1 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993).
This point is vividly illustrated in the words of Brazilian finance minister Pedro Malan in the wake of the 1994 Brazilian stabilization program: “We made a bet that the initial success at bringing down inflation would create the political support for the reforms required to consolidate those gains. This is a bet that’s still on thetable,” Wall Street Journal, October 4, 1995, quoted in Alejandro M. Werner, “Building Consensus for Stabilization.”
ANNEX: SUMMING UP BY THE ACTING CHAIRMAN
Directors agreed that prospects for global growth have weakened significantly, led by a marked slowdown in the United States, the stalling recovery in Japan, and a slowing of growth in Europe and in a number of emerging market countries. They noted that some slowdown from the rapid rates of global growth of late 1999 and early 2000 is both desirable and expected, especially in those countries most advanced in the cycle, but that the deceleration is proving to be steeper than earlier thought. At the same time, while headline inflation in most advanced economies has begun to stabilize, with moderate wage increases and declining oil prices, underlying inflation remains generally subdued, except perhaps in a number of faster growing European and emerging market economies.
Given the rapid policy response by several central banks in both advanced and emerging economies, Directors thought the chances are reasonable that the slowdown in global activity will be relatively short lived, although the pace of recovery may be slowed by the continuing decline in global equity markets. Declining short- and long-term interest rates should provide support to activity in the second half of 2001, and, with inflationary risks receding, policymakers in most advanced countries—with the important exception of Japan—have substantial room for further easing. Moreover, given the remarkable strengthening in fiscal positions in recent years, most advanced countries also have room for fiscal easing as a second line of defense, which the United States in particular is expected to use. In addition, while a number of emerging market countries continue to face serious difficulties, external and financial vulnerabilities have generally been reduced since the 1997–98 crises as a result of wide-ranging structural reforms, and the shift away from soft exchange rate pegs to flexible exchange rate systems has improved countries’ ability to manage external shocks.
Most Directors agreed, however, that the outlook remains subject to considerable uncertainty, and that a deeper and more prolonged downturn is possible. They noted that the adjustment process in the United States could be complicated by the substantial imbalances that developed during the expansion, including the large current account deficit, the apparent overvaluation of the U.S. dollar, and the negative household savings rate, as well as by the risk of possible further declines in equity markets.
Directors emphasized that the extent of the downturn will be affected by policy decisions by all countries. In the advanced economies, a more proactive approach to macroeconomic policies, particularly on the monetary side, may well be required, and should be pursued consistently with their respective cyclical positions and without compromising medium-term stabilization objectives. Where needed, these policies should be complemented with the determined pursuit of structural reforms. In view of the present fragility of external financing conditions, prospects in emerging markets depend critically on maintaining investor confidence. For these countries, Directors underscored the need to maintain prudent macroeconomic policies and to press ahead with corporate, financial and—especially in the transition economies—institutional reforms.
Directors noted with concern that the slowdown in global growth will adversely affect the low-income countries, both directly and through lower commodity prices. The need for countries to sustain strong policies is even greater in such circumstances, both in countries receiving debt relief under the Enhanced HIPC Initiative and in others. Directors stressed that to assist the efforts of low-income countries, the advanced economies have a special responsibility to increase aid flows, to support initiatives promoting peace and domestic stability, and to provide further assistance to fight the spread of the HIV/AIDS epidemic. They especially emphasized the importance, at the present juncture, of further reducing barriers to the exports of the developing countries, and of the poorest countries in particular. In this connection, the recent initiative of the European Union to eliminate tariffs on almost all exports of the least developed countries was welcomed.
Directors considered that, given the change in the global economic outlook, it is particularly important that the Fund, in its dialogue with member countries, as well as through its multilateral surveillance, continue to support actively the implementation of policies that promote economic stability and prosperity. A number of Directors emphasized the need for the Fund to continue to strengthen its surveillance activities.
Major Currency Areas
For the United States, Directors noted that the outlook is subject to more than the usual amount of uncertainty. While growth is likely to remain weak in the first half of 2001, reflecting rapid inventory adjustment, most Directors believed that activity, supported by lower short- and long-term interest rates, will pick up in the second half, although the rate of pickup may be slowed by the lagged effect of the recent decline in equity prices. However, Directors also acknowledged that there is a significant risk that the imbalances built up during the long expansion could unwind in a less orderly fashion, accompanied by further declines in confidence and increases in risk aversion in financial markets. With the balance of risks shifting increasingly toward weaker aggregate demand, Directors strongly welcomed the timely and significant easing of monetary policy in the first quarter. If economic and financial conditions remain weak, some further easing would be appropriate. While monetary policy remains the preferred instrument for responding actively to cyclical developments, Directors believed that, given the sustained fiscal surpluses in prospect in coming years, moderate and front-loaded tax cuts would also be appropriate from a cyclical perspective. These tax cuts should preferably be enacted in phases, with each phase put in place only once it is clear that sufficient budgetary resources will be available to finance it. The surpluses of the Social Security and Medicare Health Insurance trust funds should be preserved in order to help meet future pension and health care costs.
Directors expressed considerable concern at the renewed setback to recovery in Japan, which could exacerbate the slowdown and have a particularly serious impact on a number of Asian countries. While this setback partly reflects the slowdown elsewhere, especially the weakening of global demand for electronics equipment, it is also due to continued weak consumer confidence and underlying structural weaknesses, especially in the Japanese corporate and financial sectors. Given the deteriorating outlook and continued deflation, Directors welcomed the recent introduction of a new monetary policy framework, which effectively returns to the zero interest rate policy and includes a commitment to maintain the new framework until consumer prices have stopped declining, and (if needed) will step up outright purchases of long-term government bonds. They urged that the framework be forcefully implemented. Given the high level of public debt, Directors believed that the very gradual fiscal consolidation currently underway remains appropriate, and that further fiscal easing should be considered only as a last resort. They stressed, however, that the prospects for a return to sustained growth in the medium term depend most critically on determined action to address weaknesses in banks and life insurance companies, including through the vigorous application of the regulatory and supervisory framework, along with measures to further encourage corporate restructuring. In this respect, Directors looked forward to the staff’s assessment of the new reform package announced by the Japanese government.
Directors observed that while growth in the euro area remains relatively well sustained, signs of slowing activity have intensified in recent months and confidence has weakened. While headline inflation remains above the ECB’s target, underlying price pressures are muted, with little evidence thus far of pass-through effects of higher energy prices and the weaker euro on wages. Against this background, many Directors believed that a moderate cut in interest rates is now appropriate, with a further cut being in order if the exchange rate were to appreciate sharply or if indications of slowing growth were to mount. Directors considered that, while recent tax cuts in some countries would provide helpful stimulus, there is no further need to use fiscal policy actively to support output at this stage, although fiscal execution should allow the full play of automatic stabilizers. While welcoming the important progress that has been made in some areas of structural reform, Directors underscored that further deepening and acceleration of market-oriented reforms, especially of pension systems, labor markets, and product markets, is necessary both to raise potential output growth over the medium term, and to address the challenges posed by aging populations. They also underscored the need, over the medium term, to further reduce tax burdens, which remain very high in a number of euro area countries. Such reductions would need to be accompanied by spending restraint in order to allow medium-term budget targets to be met.
Emerging Economies
Directors observed that following a rapid recovery from the recent regional crisis, growth in emerging Asia has weakened as a result of higher oil prices, slowing growth in the United States and Japan, the downturn in the global electronics cycle, and—in some countries—the lagging pace of corporate and financial restructuring. They noted that growth is expected to slow most in the Newly Industrialized Economies and ASEAN countries, particularly those more advanced in the recovery and where the process of corporate and financial restructuring has lagged. In these countries, it will be crucial to restore the momentum of structural reforms. For countries with low inflation and sustainable fiscal positions, Directors recommended moderate interest rate reductions, coupled in some cases with an easier pace of fiscal consolidation. Directors noted that growth is expected to be relatively well maintained in China and India. In China, a gradual shift to a more neutral fiscal policystance is appropriate given considerations of medium-term sustainability. In India, the recent monetary policy easing should be supported by continued improvements in the environment for private investment and a substantial reduction, over the medium term, in the overall public sector deficit.
Directors noted that growth in LatinAmerica rebounded in 2000 following the sharp slowdown in 1999, in part reflecting strong adjustment measures put in place in many countries. In 2001, the direct impact of weakening external demand on activity is likely to be largest in Mexico and in several countries in the Andean region and Central America, but more moderate in those countries—such as Brazil and Argentina—that are less open and where trade links with the United States are less important. However, given Latin America’s large external financing requirements, the impact of the U.S. slowdown on financial markets will be critical. While a number of countries had been able to cover a substantial part of their annual public sector financing needs in early 2001, Directors expressed concern that, despite the easing of U.S. monetary policy, financing conditions have deteriorated following the latest crises in Argentina and Turkey, reflecting a rise in investor risk aversion and possible concerns about a slowdown in inward foreign direct investment. With intensifying scrutiny from global financial markets, it will be important to maintain prudent fiscal policies, along with structural reforms—particularly in financial and corporate sectors and labor markets. Directors generally welcomed the recent initiatives to strengthen the policy framework in Argentina, while stressing the need for continued fiscal restraint and strict adherence to the economic program at all levels of government.
Directors observed that growth in Africa has been constrained by war and civil conflict in some countries, weak commodity prices, and, for oil-importing countries, by higher oil prices. While countries that implement sound macroeconomic and structural policies and maintain political stability have been able to achieve relatively strong rates of growth, Directors were concerned that the outlook for the region could be adversely affected by the current global slowdown, particularly through a further weakening of commodity prices. Directors welcomed the recent strengthening of economic policies in many countries, which has been supported by debt relief through the Enhanced HIPC Initiative and the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility. It will be important to sustain the momentum for reform in the years ahead, particularly by improving the environment for private investment, strengthening public service delivery, improving tax administration and infrastructure, and enhancing governance. Directorsgenerally endorsed the conclusions of the staff analysis of trade integration in Sub-Saharan Africa, noting in particular the scope for further reductions in trade barriers by African countries. They agreed that a lasting improvement in Africa’s trade performance will depend on a broader mix of macroeconomic policies and structural reforms that will be key to improved efficiency and external competitiveness. Directors also welcomed the staff’s suggestions for rationalizing the current regional trade arrangements to allow them to reach their intended objectives.
Directors noted that, in the Middle East, higher oil prices combined with increased oil production have generally boosted activity and improved fiscal and external balances in 2000. With the windfall gains from higher oil prices having been prudently used, the projected decline in oil prices in 2001 and 2002 appears generally manageable. Nonetheless, a prudent approach to fiscal policy remains desirable, especially in those countries where government debt needs to be reduced. More generally, Directors underscored the need for continued reforms to promote economic diversification and growth, including the removal of remaining impediments to trade and foreign direct investment. Growth in most of the non-oil producing countries in the region is expected to remain stable, although it could be affected by a steeper than-anticipated global slowdown. Directors considered that reform of trade and foreign direct investment regimes is also a priority in many of these countries, which have yet to share fully in the benefits of globalization.
Directors observed that the situation in Turkey remains very difficult. They welcomed the steps taken to reform the financial system, particularly with regard to state banks, but noted that further decisive policy measures are needed to resolve the problems in the banking sector, strengthen the fiscal accounts, and achieve broad-based structural reforms. In central and eastern Europe, growth is expected to remain reasonably well sustained in 2001, although activity will be vulnerable to a greater-than-expected slowdown in Western Europe. Against the background of weakening external demand and large current account deficits, Directors favored a rebalancing of the policy mix toward relatively tighter fiscal policy, which would help restrain domestic demand while limiting upward pressure on interest rates and exchange rates. They also noted that further structural and institutional reforms are needed, especially with respect to privatization, enterprise restructuring, and financial regulation and supervision, to promote sustainable growth in the medium term and facilitate accession to the European Union.
Directors welcomed the recent improvement in growth performance and external positions in the countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), which reflects mainly higher world energy prices and buoyant growth in Russia. In Russia, growth is expected to moderate from the very rapid pace in 2000, as a result in part of lower oil prices and some real appreciation of the ruble, as well as the global slowdown. The government’s long-term reform plan is an important step forward, but Directors agreed that it needs to be both firmly implemented and significantly developed in a number of key areas, including banking reform and payments arrears and restructuring of infrastructural monopolies. Accelerating structural and institutional reform also remains the central challenge in most other CIS countries.
Maintaining Improved Fiscal and Monetary Policies
Directors welcomed the comprehensive discussion in the World Economic Outlook of the recent improvements in fiscal performance and the decline in inflation in many countries. They noted that the durability of recent fiscal consolidation in advanced economies is likely to be improved by the associated reductions in public expenditure (as a share of GDP) and the strengthening of fiscal frameworks over the past decade. Directors emphasized that fiscal discipline will be vital in the years ahead, given the substantial increases expected in public spending on pensions and health care as populations age. In order to meet pension liabilities and enhance output growth as dependency ratios rise, the policy response should be broad-based, encompassing both pension reform and structural reforms, including labor market improvements. Consideration should be given to directing a part of recent and projected fiscal improvements to increased pre-funding of future pension liabilities. Directors took note of the global perspective of population aging: as dependency ratios decline in many developing countries, increased saving by countries with aging populations could support growth in emerging markets and future consumption in advanced economies.
Directors reviewed the analysis of the decline in inflation in emerging economies in recent years. Improved monetary stability in advanced economies and substantial progress in institutional reform in emerging economies, including more independent central banks and improved knowledge about monetary policy transmission, have played an important contributing role in achieving this outcome. Directors noted that prudent fiscal policies have also been a key factor in achieving lower inflation and allowing the conduct of a stable monetary policy in the long run. While observing that experience with the more frequent use of inflation targeting to accompany flexible exchange rates has been generally encouraging so far, Directors considered that a more definitive verdict on inflation targeting will need to await further experience, particularly with the maintenance of price stability during sustained periods that include episodes of financial stress and exchange rate instability.
Finally, Executive Directors wished to take this opportunity to express their deep appreciation to Michael Mussa for his outstanding contribution as Economic Counsellor and Director of the Research Department to the Fund’s multilateral surveillance over the past ten years, especially through his oversight and direction of the World Economic Outlook, and his regular informal briefings on World Economic and Market Developments, which have been a highlight of the Board agenda.
STATISTICAL APPENDIX
The statistical appendix presents historical data, as well as projections. It comprises four sections: Assumptions, Data and Conventions, Classification of Countries, and Statistical Tables.
The assumptions underlying the estimates and projections for 2001–2002 and the medium-term scenario for 2003–2006 are summarized in the first section. The second section provides a general description of the data and of the conventions used for calculating country group composites. The classification of countries in the various groups presented in the World Economic Outlook is summarized in the third section. Note that the group of advanced economies now includes Cyprus.
The last, and main, section comprises the statistical tables. Data in these tables have been compiled on the basis of information available through the end of March 2001. The figures for 2001 and beyond are shown with the same degree of precision as the historical figures solely for convenience; since they are projections, the same degree of accuracy is not to be inferred.
Assumptions
Real effective exchange rates for the advanced economies are assumed to remain constant at their average levels during the period February 19–March 16, 2001. For 2001 and 2002, these assumptions imply average U.S. dollar/SDR conversion rates of 1.292 and 1.294, respectively.
Established policies of national authorities are assumed to be maintained. The more specific policy assumptions underlying the projections for selected advanced economies are described in Box A1.
It is assumed that the price of oil will average $25.50 a barrel in 2001 and $22.50 a barrel in 2002.
With regard to interest rates, it is assumed that the London interbank offered rate (LIBOR) on six-month U.S. dollar deposits will average 4.5 percent in 2001 and 4.3 percent in 2002; that the three-month certificate of deposit rate in Japan will average 0.3 percent in 2001 and 0.5 in 2002; and that the three-month interbank deposit rate for the euro will average 4.4 percent in 2001 and 4.1 percent in 2002.
With respect to introduction of the euro, on December 31, 1998 the Council of the European Union decided that, effective January 1, 1999, the irrevocably fixed conversion rates between the euro and currencies of the member states adopting the euro are:1
1 euro = | 13.7603 | Austrian schillings |
= | 40.3399 | Belgian francs |
= | 1.95583 | Deutsche mark |
= | 5.94573 | Finnish markkaa |
= | 6.55957 | French francs |
= | 340.750 | Greek drachma |
= | 0.787564 | Irish pound |
= | 1,936.27 | Italian lire |
= | 40.3399 | Luxembourg francs |
= | 2.20371 | Netherlands guilders |
= | 200,482 | Portuguese escudos |
= | 166.386 | Spanish pesetas |
1 euro = | 13.7603 | Austrian schillings |
= | 40.3399 | Belgian francs |
= | 1.95583 | Deutsche mark |
= | 5.94573 | Finnish markkaa |
= | 6.55957 | French francs |
= | 340.750 | Greek drachma |
= | 0.787564 | Irish pound |
= | 1,936.27 | Italian lire |
= | 40.3399 | Luxembourg francs |
= | 2.20371 | Netherlands guilders |
= | 200,482 | Portuguese escudos |
= | 166.386 | Spanish pesetas |
See Box 5.4 in the October 1998 World Economic Outlook for details on how the conversion rates were established.
Data and Conventions
Data and projections for 182 countries form the statistical basis for the World Economic Outlook (the World Economic Outlook database). The data are maintained jointly by the IMF’s Research Department and area departments, with the latter regularly updating country projections based on consistent global assumptions.
Economic Policy Assumptions Underlying the Projections for Selected Advanced Countries
The short-term fiscal policy assumptions used in the World Economic Outlook are based on officially announced budgets, adjusted for differences between the national authorities and the IMF staff regarding macroeconomic assumptions and projected fiscal outturns. The medium-term fiscal projections incorporate policy measures that are judged likely to be implemented. In cases where the IMF staff has insufficient information to assess the authorities’ budget intentions and prospects for policy implementation, an unchanged structural primary balance is assumed, unless otherwise indicated. Specific assumptions used in some of the advanced economies follow (see also Tables 14–16 in the Statistical Appendix for data on fiscal and structural balances).1
United States. The fiscal projections are based on the budget proposals made in the Administration’s FY2002 Budget (February 28, 2001), adjusted for the IMF staff’s macroeconomic assumptions.
Japan. The projections take account of the FY2000 supplementary budget and the FY2001 draft budget. The ¥11 trillion stimulus package of November 2000 includes additional public investment of ¥5 trillion (headline figure), most of which is projected to take place in the first two quarters of FY2001. Local governments are projected to largely offset their share in the stimulus package with cuts in own-account expenditures elsewhere. A “typical” supplementary budget of ¥1 trillion is included in the calculations for FY2001. The improvement in the fiscal balance in FY2001 is mainly on account of a decline in the use of public funds for the resolution of banking sector problems.
Germany. The fiscal projections incorporate the government’s fiscal consolidation package for 2000 and beyond and the income tax reform package 2001–2005 that were approved by Parliament in December 1999 and July 2000, respectively. The fiscal projections for 2000 also include the proceeds from the August 2000 sale of mobile phone licenses (UMTS) of DM 99.4 billion (US$ 46.9 billion), which amounts to 2.5 percent of GDP.
France. The projections are based on the national authorities’ targets. For 2001, the projections are adjusted for the Constitutional Court’s rejection of the targeted reduction in the generalized social contribution, for the introduction of the prime pour l’emploi, and for the IMF staff’s weaker macroeconomic projections. For the medium term, the projections are broadly consistent with the government’s stability program, adjusted for the differences between the IMF staff’s and the authorities’ macroeconomic assumptions.
Italy. The fiscal projections are based on the 2001 budget approved in December 2000 by parliament, the updated medium-term fiscal plan (DPEF) covering the period 2001–2004, and the 2001 stability program. The fiscal measures included in the 2001 budget are assumed to be implemented fully and to have the impact as indicated in the government’s fiscal plan. For the years 2002–2004, the IMF staff’s projections build on the authorities’ projections at unchanged legislation (tendenziale) and factor in differences in the macroeconomic assumptions for the medium term, the effect of changes in legislation needed on the basis of current policies (in particular, expected wage increases and new capital spending), and the announced fiscal targets (quadro programmatico), for the years 2005–06, the projections assume an unchanged primary structural balance. Details on the measures for 2002 will be unveiled in the budget law to be submitted to parliament in September. The estimates for 2000 include receipts from the sale of Universal Mobile Telecommunications Service (UMTS) licenses of about lire 23 trillion, or 1 percent of GDP.
United Kingdom. The fiscal projections are based on the November 2000 pre-budget, the July 2000 spending review, and the March 2000 budget. Additionally, the projections incorporate more recent statistical releases from the Office for National Statistics, including provisional budgetary outturns through December 2000. The main differences between the national authorities’ and the IMF staff’s projections are as follows: the IMF staff projections are based on potential growth of 2 percent rather than the 2¼ percent underlying the official projections, and the IMF staff projections assume that the fuel tax cut (about 0.2 percent of GDP a year starting in 2001/02) proposed for consultation in November 2000 is implemented. The IMF staff’s projections also include an adjustment for the proceeds of the recent UMTS license auction (about 2.4 percent of GDP) received in fiscal year 2001/02 to conform to the Eurostat accounting guidelines (the proceeds are not included in the computation of the structural balance).
Canada. The fiscal outlook prepared by the IMF staff assumes tax and expenditure policies in line with those outlined in the budget plan 2000 and the October 2000 economic statement and budget update, adjusted for the IMF staff’s macroeconomic projections. In line with the announcement in the October 2000 update, the staff expects a federal government budget surplus of Can $10 billion for the fiscal year 2000/01, reflecting the government’s new policy of announcing a debt reduction target each October for the current fiscal year. Over the medium term, the IMF staff assumes that the federal government budget will be in surplus by Can$3 billion a year, an amount equivalent to the contingency reserve. The consolidated fiscal position for the provinces is assumed to evolve in line with their stated medium-term targets.
Australia. The fiscal projections through FY2004 are based on the 2000/01 budget, which was released in May 2000. For the remainder of the projection period, the IMF staff’s projections assume unchanged policies.
Belgium. Fiscal projections through 2005 are based on the government’s medium-term tax and expenditure plans announced in the 2001 budget and on the targets and rules for the fiscal balance presented in the 2001–05 stability program. The projections incorporate the IMF staff’s assumptions for economic growth and interest rates, and assume resulting budgetary windfalls are devoted to improving the fiscal balance.
Greece. The fiscal projections are based on the authorities’ policies presented in the 2001 budget, adjusted for different macroeconomic assumptions. For the 2002–06 period, primary current expenditures are assumed to maintain their share of GDP, while the current revenue share is projected to decline slightly (by ¼ percent of GDP), as social insurance contributions—which are tied to wages—are expected to grow less rapidly than output. Thus, the overall surplus is projected to grow largely in line with a reduction in interest expenditures, which is the result of euro area membership.
Netherlands. The 2000 budget estimate includes revenues from the sale of mobile phone licenses of NLG 5.9 billion (0.7 percent of GDP). The fiscal projections through 2002 reflect the government’s rules-based approach to fiscal policy, which comprises medium-term real expenditure ceilings, and a baseline path for revenues adjusted for the IMF staff’s growth projections. As permitted under the rules, spending is projected to be increased up to the ceiling, thereby offsetting any growth-related windfalls. The revenue baseline path includes the effects of planned tax cuts in conjunction with the tax reform package implemented in 2001. For the period after 2002, real expenditures are assumed to grow by an annual average of 1.8 percent. The revenue ratio is projected to fall by 0.35 percent of GDP annually, reflecting the notion that part of the current revenue windfalls are not permanent.
Spain. Fiscal projections through 2004 are based on the policies outlined in the national authorities’ updated stability program of January 2001. Projections for subsequent years assume no significant changes in those policies.
Sweden. The fiscal data for 2000 are based on the general government budget outturn for January-November 2000 and preliminary full year figures for the central government. Projections for 2001 are based on the national authorities’ policies as presented in the 2001 budget adopted by the parliament. IMF staff projections for 2002–2005 take into account the ministry of finance’s medium-term projections and nominal ceilings on central government expenditures, both available through 2003. The authorities’ medium-term fiscal objective calls for achieving a general government surplus of 2 percent of GDP over the economic cycle. The projected substantial surpluses also take into account the authorities’ announced medium-term program of tax reductions.
Switzerland. The projections for 2001–04 are based on official budget plans that include measures to balance the Confederation’s budget in 2001 and strengthen the finances of the social security system. Privatization receipts and windfall revenue from the withholding tax and the stamp duty are assumed to be applied to debt reduction. Beyond 2004, the general government’s structural balance is assumed to remain unchanged.
Monetary policy assumptions are based on the established framework for monetary policy in each country. In most cases, this implies a nonaccommodative stance over the business cycle, so that official interest rates will increase when economic indicators suggest that inflation will rise above its acceptable rate or range, and decrease when indicators suggest that prospective inflation will not exceed the acceptable rate or range, that prospective output growth is below its potential rate, and that the margin of slack in the economy is significant. On this basis, the London interbank offered rate (LIBOR) on six-month U.S. dollar deposits is assumed to average 4.5 percent in 2001 and 4.3 percent in 2002. The projected path for U.S. dollar short-term interest rates reflects the assumption that the U.S. Federal Reserve will lower the target Federal Funds rate by another 25 basis points in the first half of 2001, with no further decreases in the remainder of 2001 and 2002. The rate on six-month Japanese yen deposits is assumed to average 0.3 percent in 2001, with the current accommodative policy stance being maintained, and 0.5 percent in 2002. The rate on six-month euro deposits is assumed to average 4.4 percent in 2001, reflecting the assumption of moderate easing in the course of the year, and 4.1 percent in 2002. Changes in interest rate assumptions compared with the October 2000 World Economic Outlook are summarized in .
The output gap is actual less potential output, as a percent of potential output. Structural balances are expressed as a percent of potential output. The structural budget balance is the budgetary position that would be observed if the level of actual output coincided with potential output. Changes in the structural budget balance consequently include effects of temporary fiscal measures, the impact of fluctuations in interest rates and debt-service costs, and other noncyclical fluctuations in the budget balance. The computations of structural budget balance are based on IMF staff estimates of potential GDP and revenue and expenditures elasticities (see the October 1993 World Economic Outlook, Annex I). Net debt is defined as gross debt less financial assets of the general government, which include assets held by the social security insurance system. Estimates of the output gap and of the structural budget balance are subject to significant margins of uncertainty.
Although national statistical agencies are the ultimate providers of historical data and definitions, international organizations are also involved in statistical issues, with the objective of harmonizing methodologies for the national compilation of statistics, including the analytical frameworks, concepts, definitions, classifications, and valuation procedures used in the production of economic statistics. The World Economic Outlook database reflects information from both national source agencies and international organizations.
The completion in 1993 of the comprehensive revision of the standardized System of National Accounts 1993 (SNA) and the IMF’s Balance of Payments Manual (BPM) represented important improvements in the standards of economic statistics and analysis.2 The IMF was actively involved in both projects, particularly the new Balance of Payments Manual, which reflects the IMF’s special interest in countries’ external positions. Key changes introduced with the new Manual were summarized in Box 13 of the May 1994 World Economic Outlook. The process of adapting country balance of payments data to the definitions of the new BPM began with the May 1995 World Economic Outlook. However, full concordance with the BPM is ultimately dependent on the provision by national statistical compilers of revised country data, and hence the World Economic Outlook estimates are still only partially adapted to the BPM.
The members of the European Union have recently adopted a harmonized system for the compilation of the national accounts, referred to as ESA 1995. All national accounts data from 1995 onward are now presented on the basis of the new system. Revision by national authorities of data prior to 1995 to conform to the new system has progressed, but has in some cases not been completed. In such cases, historical World Economic Outlook data have been carefully adjusted to avoid breaks in the series. Users of EU national accounts data prior to 1995 should nevertheless exercise caution until such time as the revision of historical data by national statistical agencies has been fully completed. See , Revisions in National Accounts Methodologies, in the May 2000 World Economic Outlook.
Composite data for country groups in the World Economic Outlook are either sums or weighted averages of data for individual countries. Arithmetically weighted averages are used for all data except inflation and money growth for the developing and transition country groups, for which geometric averages are used. The following conventions apply.
Country group composites for exchange rates, interest rates, and the growth rates of monetary aggregates are weighted by GDP converted to U.S. dollars at market exchange rates (averaged over the preceding three years) as a share of world or group GDP.
Composites for other data relating to the domestic economy, whether growth rates or ratios, are weighted by GDP valued at purchasing power parities (PPPs) as a share of total world or group GDP.3
Composite unemployment rates and employment growth are weighted by labor force as a share of group labor force.
Composites relating to the external economy are sums of individual country data after conversion to U.S. dollars at the average market exchange rates in the years indicated for balance of payments data and at end-of-year market exchange rates for debt denominated in currencies other than U.S. dollars. Composites of changes in foreign trade volumes and prices, however, are arithmetic averages of percentage changes for individual countries weighted by the U.S. dollar value of exports or imports as a share of total world or group exports or imports (in the preceding year).
For central and eastern European countries, external transactions in nonconvertible currencies (through 1990) are converted to U.S. dollars at the implicit U.S. dollar/ruble conversion rates obtained from each country’s national currency exchange rate for the U.S. dollar and for the ruble.
Unless otherwise indicated, multiyear averages of growth rates are expressed as compound annual rates of change.
Classification of Countries
Summary of the Country Classification
The country classification in the World Economic Outlook divides the world into three major groups: advanced economies, developing countries, and countries in transition.4 Rather than being based on strict criteria, economic or otherwise, this classification has evolved over time with the objective of facilitating analysis by providing a reasonably meaningful organization of data. A few countries are presently not included in these groups, either because they are not IMF members, and their economies are not monitored by the IMF, or because databases have not yet been compiled. Cuba and the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea are examples of countries that are not IMF members, whereas San Marino, among the advanced economies, is an example of an economy for which a database has not been completed. It should also be noted that, owing to a lack of data, only three of the former republics of the dissolved Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia (Croatia, the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, and Slovenia) are included in the group composites for countries in transition.
Each of the three main country groups is further divided into a number of subgroups. Among the advanced economies, the seven largest in terms of GDP, collectively referred to as the major advanced countries, are distinguished as a subgroup, and so are the 15 current members of the European Union, the 12 members of the euro area,5 and the four newly industrialized Asian economies. The developing countries are classified by region, as well as into a number of analytical and other groups. A regional breakdown is also used for the classification of the countries in transition. Table A provides an overview of these standard groups in the World Economic Outlook, showing the number of countries in each group and the average 2000 shares of groups in aggregate PPP-valued GDP, total exports of goods and services, and population.
Classification by World Economic Outlook Groups and Their Shares in Aggregate GDP, Exports of Goods and Services, and Population, 20001
(Percent of total for group or world)
The GDP shares are based on the purchasing-power-parity (PPP) valuation of country GDPs.
Classification by World Economic Outlook Groups and Their Shares in Aggregate GDP, Exports of Goods and Services, and Population, 20001
(Percent of total for group or world)
Number of Countries | GDP | Exports of Goods and Services | Population | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
← Share of total for → | |||||||||
Advanced economies | World | Advanced economies | World | Advanced economies | World | ||||
Advanced economies | 29 | 100.0 | 57.1 | 100.0 | 75.7 | 100.0 | 15.4 | ||
Major advanced economies | 7 | 79.5 | 45.4 | 62.9 | 47.7 | 74.3 | 11.5 | ||
United States | 38.5 | 22.0 | 18.8 | 14.2 | 29.7 | 4.6 | |||
Japan | 12.8 | 7.3 | 9.2 | 7.0 | 13.6 | 2.1 | |||
Germany | 8.1 | 4.6 | 11.0 | 8.4 | 8.9 | 1.4 | |||
France | 5.6 | 3.2 | 6.6 | 5.0 | 6.3 | 1.0 | |||
Italy | 5.4 | 3.1 | 5.1 | 3.9 | 6.1 | 0.9 | |||
United Kingdom | 5.5 | 3.1 | 6.7 | 5.1 | 6.3 | 1.0 | |||
Canada | 3.5 | 2.0 | 5.5 | 4.2 | 3.3 | 0.5 | |||
Other advanced economies | 22 | 20.5 | 11.7 | 37.1 | 28.1 | 25.7 | 4.0 | ||
Memorandum | |||||||||
European Union | 15 | 35.0 | 20.0 | 47.6 | 36.0 | 40.2 | 6.2 | ||
Euro area | 12 | 28.0 | 16.0 | 37.9 | 28.7 | 32.3 | 5.0 | ||
Newly industrialized Asian economies | 4 | 6.0 | 3.4 | 13.1 | 9.9 | 8.6 | 1.3 | ||
Developing countries | World | Developing countries | World | Developing countries | World | ||||
Developing countries | 125 | 100.0 | 37.0 | 100.0 | 20.0 | 100.0 | 77.9 | ||
Regional groups | |||||||||
Africa | 51 | 8.6 | 3.2 | 10.3 | 2.1 | 15.7 | 12.2 | ||
Sub-Sahara | 48 | 6.6 | 2.4 | 7.6 | 1.5 | 14.2 | 11.1 | ||
Excluding Nigeria and South Africa | 46 | 3.8 | 1.4 | 3.8 | 0.8 | 10.5 | 8.2 | ||
Developing Asia | 25 | 58.3 | 21.6 | 46.19 | 9.2 | 66.8 | 52.0 | ||
China | 31.2 | 11.6 | 18.4 | 3.7 | 27.0 | 21.1 | |||
India | 12.6 | 4.6 | 3.9 | 0.8 | 21.4 | 16.6 | |||
Other developing Asia | 23 | 14.5 | 5.4 | 23.7 | 4.7 | 18.4 | 14.3 | ||
Middle East, Malta, and Turkey | 16 | 10.5 | 3.9 | 20.9 | 4.2 | 6.6 | 5.1 | ||
Western Hemisphere | 33 | 22.6 | 8.4 | 22.7 | 4.5 | 10.9 | 8.5 | ||
Analytical groups | |||||||||
By source of export earnings | |||||||||
Fuel | 18 | 9.0 | 3.3 | 21.5 | 4.3 | 7.0 | 5.4 | ||
Nonfuel | 109 | 91.0 | 33.7 | 78.5 | 15.7 | 93.0 | 72.4 | ||
of which, primary products | 42 | 6.5 | 2.4 | 5.9 | 1.2 | 10.9 | 8.5 | ||
By external financing source | |||||||||
Net debtor countries | 113 | 97.3 | 36.0 | 87.8 | 17.6 | 99.3 | 77.3 | ||
of which, official financing | 43 | 5.6 | 2.1 | 5.1 | 1.0 | 13.8 | 10.8 | ||
Net debtor countries by debt- | |||||||||
servicing experience | |||||||||
Courntries with arrears and/or rescheduling during 1994-98 | 55 | 24.6 | 9.1 | 24.0 | 4.8 | 29.0 | 22.6 | ||
Other groups | |||||||||
Heavily indebted poor countries | 40 | 5.1 | 1.9 | 4.3 | 0.9 | 13.6 | 10.6 | ||
Middle East and north Africa | 21 | 10.3 | 3.8 | 20.3 | 4.1 | 7.5 | 5.9 | ||
Countries in transition | World | Countries in transition | World | Countries in transition | World | ||||
Countries in transition | 28 | 100.0 | 5.9 | 100.0 | 4.3 | 100.0 | 6.7 | ||
Central and eastern Europe | 16 | 39.2 | 2.3 | 51.4 | 2.2 | 29.7 | 2.0 | ||
CIS and Mongolia | 12 | 61.1 | 3.6 | 48.8 | 2.1 | 71.4 | 4.8 | ||
Russia | 42.0 | 2.5 | 34.3 | 1.5 | 36.8 | 2.5 | |||
Excluding Russia | 11 | 19.1 | 1.1 | 14.5 | 0.6 | 34.6 | 2.3 |
The GDP shares are based on the purchasing-power-parity (PPP) valuation of country GDPs.
Classification by World Economic Outlook Groups and Their Shares in Aggregate GDP, Exports of Goods and Services, and Population, 20001
(Percent of total for group or world)
Number of Countries | GDP | Exports of Goods and Services | Population | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
← Share of total for → | |||||||||
Advanced economies | World | Advanced economies | World | Advanced economies | World | ||||
Advanced economies | 29 | 100.0 | 57.1 | 100.0 | 75.7 | 100.0 | 15.4 | ||
Major advanced economies | 7 | 79.5 | 45.4 | 62.9 | 47.7 | 74.3 | 11.5 | ||
United States | 38.5 | 22.0 | 18.8 | 14.2 | 29.7 | 4.6 | |||
Japan | 12.8 | 7.3 | 9.2 | 7.0 | 13.6 | 2.1 | |||
Germany | 8.1 | 4.6 | 11.0 | 8.4 | 8.9 | 1.4 | |||
France | 5.6 | 3.2 | 6.6 | 5.0 | 6.3 | 1.0 | |||
Italy | 5.4 | 3.1 | 5.1 | 3.9 | 6.1 | 0.9 | |||
United Kingdom | 5.5 | 3.1 | 6.7 | 5.1 | 6.3 | 1.0 | |||
Canada | 3.5 | 2.0 | 5.5 | 4.2 | 3.3 | 0.5 | |||
Other advanced economies | 22 | 20.5 | 11.7 | 37.1 | 28.1 | 25.7 | 4.0 | ||
Memorandum | |||||||||
European Union | 15 | 35.0 | 20.0 | 47.6 | 36.0 | 40.2 | 6.2 | ||
Euro area | 12 | 28.0 | 16.0 | 37.9 | 28.7 | 32.3 | 5.0 | ||
Newly industrialized Asian economies | 4 | 6.0 | 3.4 | 13.1 | 9.9 | 8.6 | 1.3 | ||
Developing countries | World | Developing countries | World | Developing countries | World | ||||
Developing countries | 125 | 100.0 | 37.0 | 100.0 | 20.0 | 100.0 | 77.9 | ||
Regional groups | |||||||||
Africa | 51 | 8.6 | 3.2 | 10.3 | 2.1 | 15.7 | 12.2 | ||
Sub-Sahara | 48 | 6.6 | 2.4 | 7.6 | 1.5 | 14.2 | 11.1 | ||
Excluding Nigeria and South Africa | 46 | 3.8 | 1.4 | 3.8 | 0.8 | 10.5 | 8.2 | ||
Developing Asia | 25 | 58.3 | 21.6 | 46.19 | 9.2 | 66.8 | 52.0 | ||
China | 31.2 | 11.6 | 18.4 | 3.7 | 27.0 | 21.1 | |||
India | 12.6 | 4.6 | 3.9 | 0.8 | 21.4 | 16.6 | |||
Other developing Asia | 23 | 14.5 | 5.4 | 23.7 | 4.7 | 18.4 | 14.3 | ||
Middle East, Malta, and Turkey | 16 | 10.5 | 3.9 | 20.9 | 4.2 | 6.6 | 5.1 | ||
Western Hemisphere | 33 | 22.6 | 8.4 | 22.7 | 4.5 | 10.9 | 8.5 | ||
Analytical groups | |||||||||
By source of export earnings | |||||||||
Fuel | 18 | 9.0 | 3.3 | 21.5 | 4.3 | 7.0 | 5.4 | ||
Nonfuel | 109 | 91.0 | 33.7 | 78.5 | 15.7 | 93.0 | 72.4 | ||
of which, primary products | 42 | 6.5 | 2.4 | 5.9 | 1.2 | 10.9 | 8.5 | ||
By external financing source | |||||||||
Net debtor countries | 113 | 97.3 | 36.0 | 87.8 | 17.6 | 99.3 | 77.3 | ||
of which, official financing | 43 | 5.6 | 2.1 | 5.1 | 1.0 | 13.8 | 10.8 | ||
Net debtor countries by debt- | |||||||||
servicing experience | |||||||||
Courntries with arrears and/or rescheduling during 1994-98 | 55 | 24.6 | 9.1 | 24.0 | 4.8 | 29.0 | 22.6 | ||
Other groups | |||||||||
Heavily indebted poor countries | 40 | 5.1 | 1.9 | 4.3 | 0.9 | 13.6 | 10.6 | ||
Middle East and north Africa | 21 | 10.3 | 3.8 | 20.3 | 4.1 | 7.5 | 5.9 | ||
Countries in transition | World | Countries in transition | World | Countries in transition | World | ||||
Countries in transition | 28 | 100.0 | 5.9 | 100.0 | 4.3 | 100.0 | 6.7 | ||
Central and eastern Europe | 16 | 39.2 | 2.3 | 51.4 | 2.2 | 29.7 | 2.0 | ||
CIS and Mongolia | 12 | 61.1 | 3.6 | 48.8 | 2.1 | 71.4 | 4.8 | ||
Russia | 42.0 | 2.5 | 34.3 | 1.5 | 36.8 | 2.5 | |||
Excluding Russia | 11 | 19.1 | 1.1 | 14.5 | 0.6 | 34.6 | 2.3 |
The GDP shares are based on the purchasing-power-parity (PPP) valuation of country GDPs.
General Features and Compositions of Groups in the World Economic Outlook Classification
Advanced Economies
The 29 advanced economies are listed in Table B. The seven largest in terms of GDP—the United States, Japan, Germany, France, Italy, the United Kingdom, and Canada—constitute the subgroup of major advanced economies, often referred to as the Group of Seven (G-7) countries. The current members of the European Union (15 countries), the euro area (12 countries), and the newly industrialized Asian economies are also distinguished as subgroups. Composite data shown in the tables for the European Union and the euro area cover the current members for all years, even though the membership has increased over time.
Advanced Economies by Subgroup
On July 1, 1997, Hong Kong was returned to the People’s Republic of China and became a Special Administrative Region of China.
Advanced Economies by Subgroup
Newly Industrialized | Other | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
European Union | Euro Area | Asian Economies | Countries | ||
Major advanced economies | |||||
France | France | Canada | |||
Germany | Germany | Japan | |||
Italy | Italy | United States | |||
United Kingdom | |||||
Other advanced economies | |||||
Austria | Luxembourg | Austria | Hong Kong SAR1 | Australia | |
Belgium | Netherlands | Belgium | Korea | Cyprus | |
Denmark | Portugal | Finland | Singapore | Iceland | |
Finland | Spain | Greece | Taiwan Province | Israel | |
Greece | Sweden | Ireland | of China | New Zealand | |
Ireland | Luxembourg | Norway | |||
Netherlands | Switzerland | ||||
Portugal | |||||
Spain |
On July 1, 1997, Hong Kong was returned to the People’s Republic of China and became a Special Administrative Region of China.
Advanced Economies by Subgroup
Newly Industrialized | Other | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
European Union | Euro Area | Asian Economies | Countries | ||
Major advanced economies | |||||
France | France | Canada | |||
Germany | Germany | Japan | |||
Italy | Italy | United States | |||
United Kingdom | |||||
Other advanced economies | |||||
Austria | Luxembourg | Austria | Hong Kong SAR1 | Australia | |
Belgium | Netherlands | Belgium | Korea | Cyprus | |
Denmark | Portugal | Finland | Singapore | Iceland | |
Finland | Spain | Greece | Taiwan Province | Israel | |
Greece | Sweden | Ireland | of China | New Zealand | |
Ireland | Luxembourg | Norway | |||
Netherlands | Switzerland | ||||
Portugal | |||||
Spain |
On July 1, 1997, Hong Kong was returned to the People’s Republic of China and became a Special Administrative Region of China.
In 1991 and subsequent years, data for Germany refer to west Germany and the eastern Lander (i.e., the former German Democratic Republic). Before 1991, economic data are not available on a unified basis or in a consistent manner. Hence, in tables featuring data expressed as annual percent change, these apply to west Germany in years up to and including 1991, but to unified Germany from 1992 onward. In general, data on national accounts and domestic economic and financial activity through 1990 cover west Germany only, whereas data for the central government and balance of payments apply to west Germany through June 1990 and to unified Germany thereafter.
Developing Countries
The group of developing countries (125 countries) includes all countries that are not classified as advanced economies or as countries in transition, together with a few dependent territories for which adequate statistics are available.
The regional breakdowns of developing countries in the World Economic Outlook conform to the IMF’s International Financial Statistics (IFS) classification—Africa, Asia, Europe, Middle East, and Western Hemisphere—with one important exception. Because all of the non-advanced countries in Europe except Malta and Turkey are included in the group of countries in transition, the World Economic Outlook classification places these two countries in a combined Middle East, Malta, and Turkey region. In both classifications, Egypt and the Libyan Arab Jamahiriya are included in this region, not in Africa. Three additional regional groupings—two of them constituting part of Africa and one a subgroup of Asia—are included in the World Economic Outlook because of their analytical significance. These are sub-Sahara, sub-Sahara excluding Nigeria and South Africa, and Asia excluding China and India.
The developing countries are also classified according to analytical criteria and into other groups. The analytical criteria reflect countries’ composition of export earnings and other income from abroad, a distinction between net creditor and net debtor countries, and, for the net debtor countries, financial criteria based on external financing source and experience with external debt servicing. Included as “other groups” are currently the heavily indebted poor countries (HIPCs), and Middle East and north Africa (MENA). The detailed composition of developing countries in the regional, analytical, and other groups is shown in Tables C, D and E.
Developing Countries by Region and Main Source of Export Earnings
Developing Countries by Region and Main Source of Export Earnings
Fuel | Nonfuel, Of Which Primary Products | |
---|---|---|
Africa | ||
Sub-Sahara | Angola | Benin |
Congo, Rep. of | Botswana | |
Equatorial Guinea | Burkina Faso | |
Gabon | Burundi | |
Nigeria | Central African Rep. | |
Chad | ||
Congo, Democratic | ||
Rep.of | ||
C ∡te d’lvoire | ||
Gambia, The | ||
Ghana | ||
Guinea | ||
Guinea-Bissau | ||
Liberia | ||
Madagascar | ||
Malawi | ||
Mali | ||
Mauritania | ||
Namibia | ||
Niger | ||
Somalia | ||
Sudan | ||
Swaziland | ||
Tanzania | ||
Togo | ||
Zambia | ||
Zimbabwe | ||
North Africa | Algeria | |
Developing | Brunei Darussalam | Bhutan |
Asia | Cambodia | |
Myanmar | ||
Papua New Guinea | ||
Solomon Islands | ||
Vanuatu | ||
Vietnam | ||
Middle East. | Bahrain | |
Malta, and | Iran, Islamic Rep. of | |
Turkey | Iraq | |
Kuwait | ||
Libya | ||
Oman | ||
Qatar | ||
Saudi Arabia | ||
United Arab Emirates | ||
Western | Trinidad and Tobago | Belize |
Hemisphere | Venezuela | Bolivia |
Chile | ||
Guyana | ||
Honduras | ||
Nicaragua | ||
Paraguay | ||
Peru | ||
Suriname |
Developing Countries by Region and Main Source of Export Earnings
Fuel | Nonfuel, Of Which Primary Products | |
---|---|---|
Africa | ||
Sub-Sahara | Angola | Benin |
Congo, Rep. of | Botswana | |
Equatorial Guinea | Burkina Faso | |
Gabon | Burundi | |
Nigeria | Central African Rep. | |
Chad | ||
Congo, Democratic | ||
Rep.of | ||
C ∡te d’lvoire | ||
Gambia, The | ||
Ghana | ||
Guinea | ||
Guinea-Bissau | ||
Liberia | ||
Madagascar | ||
Malawi | ||
Mali | ||
Mauritania | ||
Namibia | ||
Niger | ||
Somalia | ||
Sudan | ||
Swaziland | ||
Tanzania | ||
Togo | ||
Zambia | ||
Zimbabwe | ||
North Africa | Algeria | |
Developing | Brunei Darussalam | Bhutan |
Asia | Cambodia | |
Myanmar | ||
Papua New Guinea | ||
Solomon Islands | ||
Vanuatu | ||
Vietnam | ||
Middle East. | Bahrain | |
Malta, and | Iran, Islamic Rep. of | |
Turkey | Iraq | |
Kuwait | ||
Libya | ||
Oman | ||
Qatar | ||
Saudi Arabia | ||
United Arab Emirates | ||
Western | Trinidad and Tobago | Belize |
Hemisphere | Venezuela | Bolivia |
Chile | ||
Guyana | ||
Honduras | ||
Nicaragua | ||
Paraguay | ||
Peru | ||
Suriname |
Developing Countries by Region and Main External Financing Source
Developing Countries by Region and Main External Financing Source
Net Debtor Countries | ||
---|---|---|
By main external financing source | ||
Countries | Net debtor countries | Of which, official financing |
Africa | ||
Sub-Sahara | ||
Angola | • | |
Benin | • | • |
Burkina Faso | • | • |
Burundi | • | • |
Cameroon | • | • |
Central African Rep. | • | • |
Chad | • | • |
Comoros | • | • |
Congo, Democratic Rep. of | • |