Abstract

Fiscal policy in countries with a high degree of dependence on oil and other nonrenewable resources is complicated by the uncertainty and volatility of revenues, as well as by the fact that the resources are exhaustible. NRFs have been suggested as a way of dealing with the effects of price variability, making it easier to put revenues aside when prices are high so that they can be made available to maintain expenditures when prices are low. Funds may also serve as mechanisms to allow part of the nonrenewable resource wealth to be shared by future generations.

Fiscal policy in countries with a high degree of dependence on oil and other nonrenewable resources is complicated by the uncertainty and volatility of revenues, as well as by the fact that the resources are exhaustible. NRFs have been suggested as a way of dealing with the effects of price variability, making it easier to put revenues aside when prices are high so that they can be made available to maintain expenditures when prices are low. Funds may also serve as mechanisms to allow part of the nonrenewable resource wealth to be shared by future generations.

NRFs are, however, not an easy—nor necessarily an appropriate—solution to the fiscal policy problems faced by these countries. Statistical evidence suggests that the prices of nonrenewable resources such as oil may not have an average that is constant over time, or, if they have one, that the speed with which they return to it is too slow to be of practical relevance. This in turn means that there is no simple signal for when resources should be put aside and in what amount. It is also important to focus on the overall stance of fiscal policy: if a fund accumulates resources while the budget runs substantial deficits, there may be little effective contribution to stabilization or savings.

An NRF cannot substitute for effective fiscal management in the short run or for a measured intertemporal approach to fiscal policy in the longer term. The issue then becomes whether the establishment of an NRF might contribute to such policies. In some circumstances, this could be the case. Thus, an NRF might facilitate political acceptance of the idea of saving part of a windfall. Similarly, it might focus attention on the fact that the resources are limited. Large or rapidly growing NRFs, however, may themselves give rise to spending pressures.

There are additional risks and possible disadvantages to establishing an NRF. In the absence of liquidity constraints, an NRF may not constrain the overall stance of fiscal policy. Moreover, a fund does not reduce the volatility of prices, which might, in some cases, be too severe for it to handle. An NRF may itself spend excessive amounts of the resources it receives, or use them inappropriately. More generally, if the NRF is not well integrated with the budget, it can complicate fiscal management, lead to an inefficient allocation of the government’s total resources, and contribute to lack of transparency and to governance problems. Therefore, if a decision is made to establish an NRF. it is crucial that the fund be designed appropriately.

An NRF should be coherently integrated within the budget process. This can be achieved by identifying certain resources as belonging to the fund, but maintaining these revenues in identified accounts within the overall budget. A separate institutional structure might be argued, particularly where budget management of resources has been poor. Governance problems can, however, emerge just as easily in the NRF. Even with a separate institutional structure, it would be preferable for all spending and transfers to go through the budget. In any event, budget formulation and reporting should focus on a consolidated presentation, and expenditure should best be executed by the treasury.

An NRF may receive large amounts of resources, lending importance to its asset-management strategy. This should be effectively coordinated with other government financing operations. A strong case may exist for placing the NRF’s assets abroad, since investment in domestic nongovernment financial assets could transmit resource revenue volatility to the economy.

Similarly, the rules and operations of an NRF should be transparent, with stringent mechanisms to ensure accountability and prevent the misuse of resources. This requires regular and frequent disclosure and reporting on the principles governing the fund, its inflows and outflows, and the allocation and return on assets. The NRF’s activities should be audited by an independent agency, and investment performance should be periodically evaluated.

The limited number of cases, and problems with data, complicate the evaluation of the operations of existing NRFs. In some countries with NRFs, expenditure has tended to respond less to changes in resource prices than in those without funds, although this experience is not uniform. Moreover, the data suggest that these countries followed similarly prudent expenditure policies both before and after the establishment of a fund. It could, however, be argued that establishment of a fund helped these countries to maintain cautious policies in the face of ongoing revenue volatility.

More detailed evaluation of country experience suggests that NRFs have been associated with a variety of operating rules and fiscal policy experience. In several cases, rules have been bypassed or changed and do not themselves seem to have effectively constrained spending, and the integration of the fund’s operations with overall fiscal policy has often proven problematic. Although flexible transfer rules may not formally restrict government behavior, they could still make expenditure restraint more politically acceptable. There is evidence that NRFs have been more difficult to operate when reliance on resource revenues was greatest.

Whether the political economy arguments for an NRF outweigh the potential disadvantages will need to be considered on the basis of the situation in each country. This decision should reflect two strong results that emerge from this study. First, NRFs should not be seen as a simple solution to a complex problem; rather, the question should be whether they might help to facilitate implementation of a sound overall fiscal policy. Second, if an NRF is to be established, then it should be designed appropriately; otherwise, it may well do more harm than good. Key features of a well-designed fund would include coordination of the fund’s operations with those of the rest of the public sector, in the context of a sound fiscal policy; effective integration with the budget; an appropriate asset-management strategy; and mechanisms to ensure full transparency and acountability.

  • Alier, Max, and Martin Kaufman, 1999, “Nonrenewable Resources: A Case for Persistent Fiscal Surpluses,” Working Paper 99/44 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arrau, Patricio, and Stijn Claessens, 1992, “Commodity Stabilization Funds,” Worid Bank Policy Research Working Paper 835 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auerbach, Alan J., Jagadeesh Gokhale, Laurence J. Kotlikoff, and Erling Steigum, Jr., 1993, “Generational Accounting in Norway: Is Norway Overconsuming Its Petroleum Wealth?Ruth Pollak Working Papers Series on Economics, No. 24 (Boston: Boston University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basch, Miguel, and Eduardo Engel, 1993, “Temporary Shocks and Stabilization Mechanisms: The Chilean Case,” in External Shocks and Stabilization Mechanisms, Engel Eduardo Patricio and Meller (Washington: Inter-American Development Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cashin, Paul, and Hong, Liang, and C. John McDermott, 1999, “How Persistent Are Shocks to World Commodity Prices?” Working Paper 99/80 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cashin, Paul, C. John McDermott, and Alasdair Scott, 1999, “Booms and Slumps in World Commodity Prices,” Working Paper 99/155 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chalk, Nigel, 1998, “Fiscal Sustainability with Nonrenewable Resources,” Working Paper 98/26 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Claessens, Stijn, and Jonathan Coleman, 1991, “Hedging Commodity Price Risks in Papua New Guinea,World Bank Policy, Research, and External Affairs Working Paper 749 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Claessens, Stijn, and Sweder van Wijnbergen, 1993, “1990 Mexico and Venezuela Recapture Clauses: An Application of Average Price Options,Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 17 (June), pp. 73345.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Claessens, Stijn, and Panos Varangis, 1994.Oil Price Instability, Hedging, and an Oil Stabilization Fund: The Case of Venezuela,World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 1290 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corsetti, Giancarlo, and Nouriel Roubini, 1993, “The Design of Optimal Fiscal Rules for Europe After 1992,” in Adjustment and Growth in the European Monetary Union, Francisco Torres and Francisco Giavazzi (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Engel, Eduardo, and Patricio Meller, eds., 1993, External Shocks and Stabilization Mechanisms (Washington: Inter-American Development Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Engel, Eduardo, and Rodrigo Valdés, 2000, “Optimal Fiscal Strategy for Oil Exporting Countries,” Working Paper 00/118 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fasano, Ugo, 2000, “Review of the Experience with Oil Stabilization and Savings Funds in Selected Countries,” Working Paper 00/112 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gelb, Alan, and associates, 1988, Oil Windfalls: Blessing or Curse? (New York: Oxford University Press for the World Bank).

  • Hausmann, Ricardo, 1995, “Dealing with Negative Oil Shocks: The Venezuelan Experience in the Eighties,” Working Paper 307 (Washington: Inter-American Development Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hausmann, Ricardo, Andrew Powell, and Roberto Rigobón, 1993, “An Optimal Spending Rule Facing Oil Income Uncertainty (Venezuela),” in External Shocks and Stabilization Mechanisms,Eduardo Engel and Patricio Meller (Washington: Inter-American Development Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, various years, World Economic Outlook (Washington).

  • Kopits, George, and Steven Symansky, 1998, Fiscal Policy Rules, Occasional Paper 162 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Kumar, Manmohan S., 1992, “Forecasting Accuracy of Crude Oil Futures Prices,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 39 (June), pp. 432

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Liuksila, Claire, Alejandro Garcia, and Sheila Bassett, 1994, “Fiscal Policy Sustainabiiity in Oil-Producing Countries,” Working Paper 94/137 (Washington: International Monetary Fund),

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Morauta, Hon. Sir Mekere. 2000, “Economic and Development Policies,2000 Budget of Papua New Guinea. Vol. 1 (Department of Finance and Treasury). Available via the Internet: http://www.treasury.gov.pg/treasury/treasury.nsf/pages/budget2000.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Potter, Barry H., and Jack Diamond, 1999, Guidelines for Public Expenditure Management International Monetary Fund).

  • Servén, Luis, and Andrés Solimano, eds., 1993, Striving for Growth after Adjustment: The Role of Capital Formation (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Spilimbergo, Antonio, 1999, “Copper and the Chilean Economy, 1960–98.” Working Paper 99/57 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Steigum, Erling, Jr., and Øystein Thøgersen, 1995, “Petroleum Wealth, Debt Policy, and Intergenerational Welfare: The Case of Norway.Journal for Policy Modeling, Vol. 17 (August), pp. 42742.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tersman, Gunnar, 1991, “Oil, National Wealth, and Current and Future Consumption Possibilities,” Working Paper 91/60 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 1996, Price Risk Management in the Fuels Sector: A Manual (New York, Geneva: UNCTAD).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Varangis, Panos, Takamasa Akiyama, and Donald Mitchell, 1995, Managing Commodity Booms—and Busts (Washington: World Bank).

  • Varangis, Panos, and Don Larson, 1996, “Dealing with Commodity Price Uncertainty,World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 1667 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Warrack, Allan A., and Russell R. Keddie, 2000, “Alberta Heritage Fund vs. Alaska Permanent Fund: A Comparative Analysis,” paper presented at the 39th Annual Meeting of the Western Regional Science Association, Kauai, Hawaii, February.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Weiner, Robert J., 1996, “Petroleum Fiscal Dependence: Revenue Forecasting and Oil Price Volatility,George Washington University School of Business and Management Working Paper 96—44 (Washington: George Washington University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wickham, Peter, 1996, “Volatility of Oil Prices,Working Paper 96/82 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • World Bank, 1993, “Venezuela, Oil and Exchange Rates: Historical Experience and Policy Options,” World Bank Report No. 10481-VE (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 1994, “Nigeria—Macroeconomic Risk Management: Issues and Options,” World Bank Report No. 11983-UNI (Washington).

  • World Bank, 1999, “Dealing with Commodity Price Volatility in Developing Countries: A Proposal for a Market-Based Approach,” Discussion Paper for the Round-table on Commodity Risk Management in Developing Countries, Washington, September.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation