Abstract

The reduction in inflation since the early 1990s right across the transition area is remarkable, particularly given the chaotic conditions at the outset. Inflationary pressures that had long been suppressed by price controls turned out to be one of the lesser challenges, as nascent policymaking institutions wrestled with collapsing output, employment, and fiscal revenues, as well as military conflicts and redrawn national boundaries. In such conditions, most currencies, new and old, collapsed, and inflation surged. But these difficulties notwithstanding, disinflation has been achieved throughout the region. Once undertaken, it was swift and there is no systematic evidence that it compounded output losses. Furthermore, major resurgences of inflation have been the exception. And in this lower inflation environment, growth has resumed, with formal evidence suggesting a direct link between reduced inflation and the resumption of growth.

The reduction in inflation since the early 1990s right across the transition area is remarkable, particularly given the chaotic conditions at the outset. Inflationary pressures that had long been suppressed by price controls turned out to be one of the lesser challenges, as nascent policymaking institutions wrestled with collapsing output, employment, and fiscal revenues, as well as military conflicts and redrawn national boundaries. In such conditions, most currencies, new and old, collapsed, and inflation surged. But these difficulties notwithstanding, disinflation has been achieved throughout the region. Once undertaken, it was swift and there is no systematic evidence that it compounded output losses. Furthermore, major resurgences of inflation have been the exception. And in this lower inflation environment, growth has resumed, with formal evidence suggesting a direct link between reduced inflation and the resumption of growth.

The robustness of output during disinflation reflects three factors.

  • The context for disinflation was better than it appeared: in the highest inflation cases, there was little inertia in prices and political support for disinflation was often strong; financial fragility rarely deepened during disinflation; and after the hurdle of initial relative price adjustment, price liberalization helped.

  • Inflation stabilization was implemented first, without waiting for the completion of allencompassing structural reforms, and it was intended to be rapid.

  • Comprehensive fiscal consolidation underwrote disinflation, and funding sources were diversified through the development of financial markets.

Just as collapsing tax revenues, rigid expenditures, and limited financing options had forced heavy reliance on seigniorage—notably in the Baltics, Russia, and other countries of the former Soviet Union in the early 1990s—so fundamental fiscal adjustments, usually focused on expenditure cuts, underlay disinflation. However, inflation stabilization did not require “fiscal solvency,” as defined by a primary surplus sufficiently high as to stabilize the public debt-to-GDP ratio. This is probably because dynamic solvency (the prospective evolution of the primary balance), rather than a snapshot of the primary balance, matters more in an environment characterized by deep structural changes. In addition, the relationship between fiscal adjustment and disinflation becomes more blurred at moderate inflation levels, when inflation is likely to be driven more by expectations than by fundamentals.

The role of monetary frameworks in strengthening disinflations is more controversial. Some, perhaps surprisingly few, countries adopted formal exchange rate pegs as their principal nominal anchors, especially in the disinflations after 1993. Most formally floated, though some of these pegged informally at times. Those that pegged throughout generally stabilized relatively rapidly but also experienced persistent moderate inflation, despite firm fiscal adjustment. The latter reflected Belassa-Samuelson effects and the correction of undervalued pegs through inflation above international levels, and was accommodated by capital inflows whenever domestic sources of monetary growth were restrictive. In some cases where fiscal adjustment accompanied an initial appreciation of the nominal exchange rate, such as Croatia and the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, disinflation was more rapid and low inflation was sustained. Both formal floaters and countries that pegged their exchange rates attempted to boost the credibility of their chosen monetary frame-works by deepening the independence of their central banks and by disinflating in the context of IMF-supported programs.

The progress made in reducing inflation should not obscure the fact that the achievements are—with few notable exceptions—not long-standing. Even aside from the major inflation reversals (including Russia during the summer of 1998), a number of countries have experienced some resurgence of inflation (Armenia, Belarus, and Uzbekistan), and in some cases (Belarus and Uzbekistan), price controls on basic consumer goods have recently been intensified. It would be premature to presume that labor markets and financial markets in transition economies now generally discount a low inflation environment. For this reason alone, policymakers that are perceived to believe that inflation has fallen far enough are at risk of losing control of inflation once again. This risk is even evident in countries that experienced persistent moderate inflation, where inflation has repeatedly exceeded official targets, albeit within manageable margins thus far.

But even where a moderate inflation environment is reasonably assured, there is much to commend more ambitious goals—to lower inflation to industrial country levels soon. The estimated threshold above which inflation involves significant output costs appears to be close to industrial country inflation rates for fully fledged market economies, and this provides the relevant benchmark for the most advanced transition economies, including the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, and Poland. With sizable relative price changes already achieved and substantial structural reform in place, those sequencing arguments that favor structural reform first may now be satisfied, setting the scene for further disinflation. And given that successful transition may entail currencies that appreciate in real terms and relatively large current account deficits—trends normally associated with weak policies—low and falling inflation may help to sustain investor confidence and the associated capital inflows.

Finally, there is no statistical evidence that the costs of disinflation are generally significant in transition economies, even at moderate inflation levels. This echoes findings for market economies (Ghosh and Phillips, 1998). And even if persistent moderate inflation has increased inflation inertia, rapid productivity growth should diminish the impact on profitability and employment of any inertia there may be in nominal wages during disinflation (Deppler, 1998).

Countries with persistent moderate inflation, as well as other advanced transition countries, now enjoy almost ideal circumstances for low-cost disinflation and would benefit from lowering inflation further. The commitment of many of them to achieving industrial country inflation rates in the near future in the context of entry to the European Union is appropriate, and others should be no less ambitious about their inflation goals.

Cited By

  • Amsden, Alice H., Jacek Kochanowicz, and Lance Taylor, 1994, The Market Meets Its Match: Restructuring the Economies of Eastern Europe (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anderson, Jonathan, and Daniel A. Citrin, 1995, “The Behavior of Inflation and Velocity,” in Policy Experiences and Issues in the Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union, edited by Daniel A. Citrin, and Ashok K. Lahiri, IMF Occasional Paper 133 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aslund, Anders, Peter Boone, Simon Johnson, 1996, “How to Stabilize: Lessons from Post-Communist Countries,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1 pp. 217313.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Lawrence, and N. Gregory Mankiw, 1994, “Asymmetric Price Adjustment and Economic Fluctuations,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 104 pp. 24761.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Begg, David, 1998, “Disinflation in Central and Eastern Europe: The Experience to Date,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry, (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Begg, David, L. Hesselman, and R. Smith, 1996, “Money in Transition: How Much Do We Know?” (mimeo; International Monetary Fund).

  • Berg, Andrew, Eduardo Borensztein, Ratna Sahay, and Jeromin Zettlemeyer, 1998, “The Evolution of Output in Transition Economies: Explaining the Differences” (mimeo; International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, 1998, “The Optimal Speed of Disinflation: The Case of Hungary,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruno, Michael, 1992, “Stabilization and Reform in Eastern Europe—A Preliminary Evaluation,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 39 (December), pp. 74177.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruno, Michael, 1996, Deep Crises and Reform: What Have We Learned? (Washington: World Bank).

  • Bruno, Michael, and William Easterly, 1995, “Inflation Crises and Long-Run Growth,” NBER Working Paper 5209 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Budina, Nina, and Sweder van Wijnbergen, 1997, “Fiscal Policies in Eastern Europe,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 13 no. 2 pp. 4764.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buiter, Willem H., 1997, “Aspects of Fiscal Performance in Some Transition Economies Under Fund-Supported Programs,” IMF Working Paper 97/31 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bulir, Ales, 1998, “Income Inequality: Does Inflation Matter?IMF Working Paper 98/7 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Burton, David, and Stanley Fischer, 1998, “Ending Moderate Inflations,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Fabrizio Coricelli, 1992, “Stabilizing a Previously Centrally Planned Economy: Poland 1990,” Economic Policy: A European Forum, no. 14 pp. 175208 and 21326.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cangiano, Marco, Carlo Cottarelli, and Luis Cubeddu, 1998, Pension Developments and Reform in Transition Economies, paper presented at the conference on Social Security Reforms: International Comparisons, held in Rome, March 1617, 1998.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Christoffersen, Peter, and Peter Doyle, 1998, “From Inflation to Growth: Eight Years of Transition,” IMF Working Paper 98/99 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coorey, Sharmini, Mauro Mecagni, and Erik Offerdal, 1998, “Disinflation in Transition Economies: The Role of Relative Price Adjustment,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cottarelli, Carlo, and Curzio Giannini, 1997, Credibility Without Rules? Monetary Frameworks in the Post-Bretton Woods Era, IMF Occasional Paper 154 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cottarelli, Carlo, Mark Griffiths, and Reza Moghadam, 1998, “The Nonmonetary Determinants of Inflation,” IMF Working Paper 98/23 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cottarelli, Carlo, and György Szapáry, eds., 1998, Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cukierman, Alex, 1992, Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and Independence: Theory and Evidence (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Cukierman, Alex, Geoffrey P. Miller, and Bilin Neyapti, 1998, Central Bank Reform, Liberalization and Inflation in Transition EconomiesAn International Perspectiv (mimeo; Tel Aviv University, Israel).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Broeck, Mark, Kornélia Krajnyák, and Henri Lorie, 1997, “Explaining and Forecasting the Velocity of Money in Transition Economies, with Special Reference to the Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union,” IMF Working Paper 97/108 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Melo, Martha, Cevdet Denizer, and Alan Gelb, 1997, “From Plan to Market: Patterns of Transition,” in Macro economic Stabilization in Transition Economies, edited by Mario J. Blejer and Marko Ŝkreb (Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deppler, Michael, 1998, “Is Reducing Moderate Inflation Costly?” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, 1976, “Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 84 pp. 116176.

  • European Bank for Reconstruction and Development 1997, Transition Report (London: EBRD).

  • Fedorov, Boris, 1995, “Macroeconomic Policy and Stabilization in Russia,” in Russian Economic Reform at Risk, edited by Anders Aslund (New York: Pinter).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos A. Végh, 1996, “Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 10 no. 2 pp. 4566.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos A. Végh, 1998, “From Transition to Market: Evidence and Growth Prospects,” IMF Working Paper 98/52 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ghosh, Atish, R., 1997, “Inflation in Transition Economies: How Much? And Why?” IMF Working Paper 97/80 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ghosh, Atish, R., and Steven Phillips, 1998, “Inflation, Disinflation, and Growth,” IMF Working Paper 98/68 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gomulka, Stanislaw, 1998, “A Comment on David Begg,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hansson, Ardo, H., 1997, “Macroeconomic Stabilization in the Baltic States,” in Macroeconomic Stabilization in Transition Economies, edited by Mario J. Blejer and Marko Ŝkreb (Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hendry, David, 1995, Dynamic Econometrics (New York: Oxford University Press).

  • Hernandez-Catá, Ernesto, forthcoming, “Price Liberalization, Money Growth, and Inflation During the Transition to a Market Economy” (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund 1997, World Economic Out-look, Chapter V (Washington), pp. 98118.

  • International Monetary Fund, 1998, Status of Market-Based Central Banking Reforms in the Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union, report prepared for the Eleventh Coordination Meeting of Cooperating Central Banks and International Institutions (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Knight, Malcolm, 1997, Central Bank Reforms in the Baltics, Russia, and the Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union, IMF Occasional Paper 157 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Koen, Vincent, and Paula R. De Masi, 1997, “Prices in the Transition: Ten Stylized Facts,” in Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kornai, János, 1998, “Comments on the Appropriate Speed of Disinflation,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krajnyák, Kornélia, and Christoph Klingen, 1998, Price Adjustment and Inflation in the Baltics, 1993–96 (mimeo; International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lougani, Prakash, and Nathan Sheets, 1997, “Central Bank Independence, Inflation, and Growth in Transition Economies,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 29, no. 3 (August), pp. 38199.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mackenzie, George A., and Peter Stella, 1996, Quasi-Fiscal Operations and Public Financial Institutions, IMF Occasional Paper 142 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul, Miguel A. Savastano, and Sunil Sharma, 1997, “The Scope for Inflation Targeting in Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper 97/130 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Medgyessy, Peter, 1998, “Introductory Remarks,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Morsink, James H.J., 1995, “Wage Controls during IMF Arrangements in Central Europe,” in IMF Conditionality: Experience Under Stand-By and Extended Arrangements, by Susan Schadler and others, IMF Occasional Paper 129 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nuxoll, Daniel, 1996, The Convergence of Price Structures and Economic Growth, paper presented at the NBER Conference on Research in Income and Wealth, Arlington, Virginia, March 1516.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Portes, Richard, editor, 1993, Economic Transformation in Central Europe: A Progress Report (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pujol, Thierry, and Mark Griffiths, 1998, “Moderate Inflation in Poland: A Real Story,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Radzyner, Olga, and Sandra Riesinger, 1997, “Central Bank Independence in Transition: Legislation and Reality in Central and Eastern Europe,” Focus on Transition, Vol. 2, no. 2, pp. 5790.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Richards, Anthony, and Gunnar Tersman, 1995, “Growth, Nontradeables, and Price Convergence in the Baltics,” IMF Working Paper 95/45 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rosenberg, Christoph, B., and Tapio O. Saavalainen, 1998, “How to Deal with Azerbaijan's Oil Boom? Policy Strategies in a Resource-Rich Transition Economy,” IMF Working Paper 98/6 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ross, Kevin, 1998, “Post Stabilization Inflation Dynamics in Slovenia,” IMF Working Paper 98/27 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sarel, Michael, 1996, “Nonlinear Effects of Inflation on Economic Growth,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 43 (March), pp. 199215.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sargent, Thomas J., and Neil Wallace, 1981, “Some Un-pleasant Monetary Arithmetic,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review (Fall), pp. 117.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Selgin, George, 1994, “On Ensuring the Acceptability of a New Fiat Money,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 26 (November), pp. 80826.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ŝkreb, Marko,A, Note on Inflation,” 1998, in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Suranyi, György, and János Vincze, 1998, “Inflation in Hungary (1990–97),” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Szapáry, György, 1998, “Disinflation Policies: Issues of Sequencing,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Van Elkan, Rachel, 1998, “How Stable Is Money Demand?” in Hungary: Economic Policies for Sustainable Growth, by Carlo Cottarelli and others, IMF Occasional Paper 159 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wozniak, Przemystaw, 1998, “Relative Price Adjustment in Poland, Hungary and the Czech Republic. Comparison of the Size and Impact on Inflation,” CASE-CEV, Working Paper Series, Budapest.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zavoico, Basil, 1995, A Brief Note on the Inflationary Process in Transition Economies (mimeo; International Monetary Fund).

  • Zettermeyer, Jeromin, and Daniel A. Citrin, 1995, “Stabilization: Fixed Versus Flexible Exchange Rates,” in Policy Experiences and Issues in the Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union, edited by Daniel A. Citrin and Ashok K. Lahiri, IMF Occasional Paper 133 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation