Abstract

Disinflation occurred while output was collapsing, and was often followed by large deteriorations in the external current account balance. This section discusses the links between these developments.

Disinflation occurred while output was collapsing, and was often followed by large deteriorations in the external current account balance. This section discusses the links between these developments.

Disinflation and Output Growth

The sharp output drop that accompanied some of the early disinflations led some commentators to voice concerns about the additional output costs that could be associated with fast disinflation (1992; Calvo and Coricelli, Portes, 1993; Amsden, Kochanowicz, and Taylor, 1994; and Fedorov, 1995). Other commentators, however, have subsequently noted that, as inflation stabilized, growth resumed, often within two years (Figure 1), thus suggesting that disinflation was a condition for sustainable growth (1996; Fischer, Sahay, and Vegh, and De Melo, Denizer, and Gelb, 1997).7 These two views are not, of course, inconsistent—the former focusing on the transitory costs of disinflation, the latter on the long-term relationship between inflation and growth—and they underscore the complications in assessing the relationship between inflation and growth from simple indicators. These complications are particularly apparent in a period of deep structural changes affecting potential output: the drop in output may have been due to the collapse of central planning, rather than to disinflation, while the recovery may have been due to the effect of structural change, rather than to the stabilized inflation environment. Only a few studies conduct formal tests of the relationship between inflation and growth for transition economies and they draw somewhat divergent conclusions. Lougani and Sheets (1997) find that, controlling for progress with transition reform (as well as other variables), output growth is negatively affected by inflation: a country with 500 percent inflation in one year loses about 2 percentage points of GDP the following year and 4 percentage points of GDP in the longer run. This finding is echoed by Berg and others (1998) who find different effects of inflation on the private and public sectors: whereas doubling inflation is associated with a decline of 5–15 percent in private sector output, it is associated with increased state sector output by about half that magnitude. They suggest that the latter arises because subsidies to state-owned firms boost their output, but also stoke inflation by raising the fiscal deficit. Thus, they conclude that the impact of inflation on output depends on the relative shares of the private and public sectors. Aslund, Boone, and Johnson (1996) find no significant role for inflation in determining output once both war-torn and ruble-zone dummies are included.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

The Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union and Central and Eastern Europe—GDP Growth, Inflation, and Transition Index

(In chronological and disinflation time) 1

Sources: National authorities; IMF, International Financial Statistics; various EBRD transition reports; and IMF staff estimates.1Stabilization dates are taken from Fischer and others (1996), and are reported in Table 2.

These studies, however, share two main shortcomings. First, they do not investigate whether the relation between inflation and growth may vary at different inflation levels—though there is increasing evidence of this pattern for nontransition economies. Second, they shed no light on the output costs of disinflation, namely whether the change in inflation, rather than the level of inflation, has implications for output. In background work for this paper, Christoffersen and Doyle (1998) address these issues, using panel data on 22 of the 25 transition countries reviewed here (see Appendix I). They find evidence of an inflation threshold for transition economies at about 13 percent: inflation above that level reduces output growth, while no significant effect on growth is apparent if inflation is below that level. They also find no evidence of generalized output loss owing to disinflation.

It is notable that the inflation threshold appears to be higher than that found in market economies (see Appendix I). This suggests that the threshold may be falling in transition time, implying that the threshold is lower for the advanced reformers than for the panel as a whole. More specifically, Christoffersen and Doyle (Chapter IV, p. 29) note that inflation may have played a role in facilitating the large growth-enhancing relative price changes at the outset of transition, offsetting other negative effects of inflation on growth. But with structural reforms and the largest of the initial relative price adjustments completed, these initial benefits from inflation would decline, and the relationship between inflation and output in transition economies would come to resemble that of long-established market economies more closely. Thus, the net benefits from low inflation may increase as transition deepens.

In summary, there is evidence that low inflation boosts growth, even after controlling for structural reform and for an inflation threshold that may fall over time as structural reform proceeds. Such a decline in the threshold would be consistent with findings in Fischer, Sahay, and Vegh (1996) and Cottarelli, Griffiths, and Moghadam (1998) that fast reformers have, ceteris paribus, lower inflation rates. No clear evidence of a high output cost of disinflation has been found.

Disinflation and the External Current Account

Cukierman (1992) notes that one of the motives for inflation is the perceived risk that disinflation may pose for the external current account. An exchange rate based disinflation may lead to a real appreciation and, thus, affect competitiveness; and competitiveness may also deteriorate in the context of a floating exchange regime if the nominal exchange rate overshoots (Dornbusch, 1976). Indeed, concerns about the possible impact of tighter monetary policies on the external current account have been mentioned by some country authorities (for example, in Hungary) as one of the reasons why accelerating disinflation through a tighter exchange rate policy or the shift to a float was regarded as excessively risky (Suranyi and Vincze, 1998).

External current account deficits relative to GDP have increased significantly during the 1990s in both the Central and Eastern European countries and the Baltics, Russia, and other countries of the former Soviet Union. In the early 1990s, the median balance in both was close to zero, while in 1997, it was a deficit in excess of 5 percent of GDP.

Recasting the current account data in inflation stabilization time highlights possible links between these trends and disinflation. The top panel of Figure 2 shows that inflation stabilization was accompanied by a weakening of the external accounts: the external balance declined sharply after disinflation in the Central and Eastern European countries, recovering somewhat in the third year. The Baltics, Russia, and other countries of the former Soviet Union exhibit a smoother decline, of similar magnitude.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

The Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union and Central and Eastern Europe—-Current Account Balance, in Percent of GDP, 1990–97

(In disinflation time)

Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations.

Evidence of a widening of the external accounts, however, should not necessarily be taken as a proof that stabilization was accompanied by a shift to an unsustainable external position. As noted above, stabilization is a precondition for growth and a recovery of investment. In transition economies, such an acceleration of investment should be expected to be financed partially from abroad, through FDI and other long-term capital inflows. In turn, these inflows are likely to increase in stabilized macroeconomic conditions. Thus, the observed weakening of the external account after the stabilization may, at least in part, reflect the recovery of growth and investment, rather than an unsustainable loss of competitiveness. In this respect, it is useful to note that the external current account net of FDI in stabilization time shows stronger trends (bottom panel of Figure 2): the debt-financed external balance weakens markedly in the Central and Eastern European countries in the first two years, while in the Baltics, Russia, and other countries of the former Soviet Union, the initial weakening is less marked. But by the third year, the balance has strengthened considerably due to the strong inflow of FDI.

Cited By

  • View in gallery

    The Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union and Central and Eastern Europe—GDP Growth, Inflation, and Transition Index

    (In chronological and disinflation time) 1

  • View in gallery

    The Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union and Central and Eastern Europe—-Current Account Balance, in Percent of GDP, 1990–97

    (In disinflation time)

  • Amsden, Alice H., Jacek Kochanowicz, and Lance Taylor, 1994, The Market Meets Its Match: Restructuring the Economies of Eastern Europe (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anderson, Jonathan, and Daniel A. Citrin, 1995, “The Behavior of Inflation and Velocity,” in Policy Experiences and Issues in the Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union, edited by Daniel A. Citrin, and Ashok K. Lahiri, IMF Occasional Paper 133 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aslund, Anders, Peter Boone, Simon Johnson, 1996, “How to Stabilize: Lessons from Post-Communist Countries,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1 pp. 217313.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Lawrence, and N. Gregory Mankiw, 1994, “Asymmetric Price Adjustment and Economic Fluctuations,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 104 pp. 24761.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Begg, David, 1998, “Disinflation in Central and Eastern Europe: The Experience to Date,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry, (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Begg, David, L. Hesselman, and R. Smith, 1996, “Money in Transition: How Much Do We Know?” (mimeo; International Monetary Fund).

  • Berg, Andrew, Eduardo Borensztein, Ratna Sahay, and Jeromin Zettlemeyer, 1998, “The Evolution of Output in Transition Economies: Explaining the Differences” (mimeo; International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, 1998, “The Optimal Speed of Disinflation: The Case of Hungary,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruno, Michael, 1992, “Stabilization and Reform in Eastern Europe—A Preliminary Evaluation,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 39 (December), pp. 74177.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruno, Michael, 1996, Deep Crises and Reform: What Have We Learned? (Washington: World Bank).

  • Bruno, Michael, and William Easterly, 1995, “Inflation Crises and Long-Run Growth,” NBER Working Paper 5209 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Budina, Nina, and Sweder van Wijnbergen, 1997, “Fiscal Policies in Eastern Europe,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 13 no. 2 pp. 4764.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buiter, Willem H., 1997, “Aspects of Fiscal Performance in Some Transition Economies Under Fund-Supported Programs,” IMF Working Paper 97/31 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bulir, Ales, 1998, “Income Inequality: Does Inflation Matter?IMF Working Paper 98/7 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Burton, David, and Stanley Fischer, 1998, “Ending Moderate Inflations,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Fabrizio Coricelli, 1992, “Stabilizing a Previously Centrally Planned Economy: Poland 1990,” Economic Policy: A European Forum, no. 14 pp. 175208 and 21326.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cangiano, Marco, Carlo Cottarelli, and Luis Cubeddu, 1998, Pension Developments and Reform in Transition Economies, paper presented at the conference on Social Security Reforms: International Comparisons, held in Rome, March 1617, 1998.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Christoffersen, Peter, and Peter Doyle, 1998, “From Inflation to Growth: Eight Years of Transition,” IMF Working Paper 98/99 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coorey, Sharmini, Mauro Mecagni, and Erik Offerdal, 1998, “Disinflation in Transition Economies: The Role of Relative Price Adjustment,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cottarelli, Carlo, and Curzio Giannini, 1997, Credibility Without Rules? Monetary Frameworks in the Post-Bretton Woods Era, IMF Occasional Paper 154 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cottarelli, Carlo, Mark Griffiths, and Reza Moghadam, 1998, “The Nonmonetary Determinants of Inflation,” IMF Working Paper 98/23 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cottarelli, Carlo, and György Szapáry, eds., 1998, Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cukierman, Alex, 1992, Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and Independence: Theory and Evidence (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Cukierman, Alex, Geoffrey P. Miller, and Bilin Neyapti, 1998, Central Bank Reform, Liberalization and Inflation in Transition EconomiesAn International Perspectiv (mimeo; Tel Aviv University, Israel).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Broeck, Mark, Kornélia Krajnyák, and Henri Lorie, 1997, “Explaining and Forecasting the Velocity of Money in Transition Economies, with Special Reference to the Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union,” IMF Working Paper 97/108 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Melo, Martha, Cevdet Denizer, and Alan Gelb, 1997, “From Plan to Market: Patterns of Transition,” in Macro economic Stabilization in Transition Economies, edited by Mario J. Blejer and Marko Ŝkreb (Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deppler, Michael, 1998, “Is Reducing Moderate Inflation Costly?” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, 1976, “Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 84 pp. 116176.

  • European Bank for Reconstruction and Development 1997, Transition Report (London: EBRD).

  • Fedorov, Boris, 1995, “Macroeconomic Policy and Stabilization in Russia,” in Russian Economic Reform at Risk, edited by Anders Aslund (New York: Pinter).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos A. Végh, 1996, “Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 10 no. 2 pp. 4566.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos A. Végh, 1998, “From Transition to Market: Evidence and Growth Prospects,” IMF Working Paper 98/52 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ghosh, Atish, R., 1997, “Inflation in Transition Economies: How Much? And Why?” IMF Working Paper 97/80 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ghosh, Atish, R., and Steven Phillips, 1998, “Inflation, Disinflation, and Growth,” IMF Working Paper 98/68 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gomulka, Stanislaw, 1998, “A Comment on David Begg,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hansson, Ardo, H., 1997, “Macroeconomic Stabilization in the Baltic States,” in Macroeconomic Stabilization in Transition Economies, edited by Mario J. Blejer and Marko Ŝkreb (Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hendry, David, 1995, Dynamic Econometrics (New York: Oxford University Press).

  • Hernandez-Catá, Ernesto, forthcoming, “Price Liberalization, Money Growth, and Inflation During the Transition to a Market Economy” (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund 1997, World Economic Out-look, Chapter V (Washington), pp. 98118.

  • International Monetary Fund, 1998, Status of Market-Based Central Banking Reforms in the Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union, report prepared for the Eleventh Coordination Meeting of Cooperating Central Banks and International Institutions (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Knight, Malcolm, 1997, Central Bank Reforms in the Baltics, Russia, and the Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union, IMF Occasional Paper 157 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Koen, Vincent, and Paula R. De Masi, 1997, “Prices in the Transition: Ten Stylized Facts,” in Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kornai, János, 1998, “Comments on the Appropriate Speed of Disinflation,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krajnyák, Kornélia, and Christoph Klingen, 1998, Price Adjustment and Inflation in the Baltics, 1993–96 (mimeo; International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lougani, Prakash, and Nathan Sheets, 1997, “Central Bank Independence, Inflation, and Growth in Transition Economies,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 29, no. 3 (August), pp. 38199.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mackenzie, George A., and Peter Stella, 1996, Quasi-Fiscal Operations and Public Financial Institutions, IMF Occasional Paper 142 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul, Miguel A. Savastano, and Sunil Sharma, 1997, “The Scope for Inflation Targeting in Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper 97/130 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Medgyessy, Peter, 1998, “Introductory Remarks,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Morsink, James H.J., 1995, “Wage Controls during IMF Arrangements in Central Europe,” in IMF Conditionality: Experience Under Stand-By and Extended Arrangements, by Susan Schadler and others, IMF Occasional Paper 129 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nuxoll, Daniel, 1996, The Convergence of Price Structures and Economic Growth, paper presented at the NBER Conference on Research in Income and Wealth, Arlington, Virginia, March 1516.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Portes, Richard, editor, 1993, Economic Transformation in Central Europe: A Progress Report (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pujol, Thierry, and Mark Griffiths, 1998, “Moderate Inflation in Poland: A Real Story,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Radzyner, Olga, and Sandra Riesinger, 1997, “Central Bank Independence in Transition: Legislation and Reality in Central and Eastern Europe,” Focus on Transition, Vol. 2, no. 2, pp. 5790.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Richards, Anthony, and Gunnar Tersman, 1995, “Growth, Nontradeables, and Price Convergence in the Baltics,” IMF Working Paper 95/45 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rosenberg, Christoph, B., and Tapio O. Saavalainen, 1998, “How to Deal with Azerbaijan's Oil Boom? Policy Strategies in a Resource-Rich Transition Economy,” IMF Working Paper 98/6 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ross, Kevin, 1998, “Post Stabilization Inflation Dynamics in Slovenia,” IMF Working Paper 98/27 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sarel, Michael, 1996, “Nonlinear Effects of Inflation on Economic Growth,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 43 (March), pp. 199215.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sargent, Thomas J., and Neil Wallace, 1981, “Some Un-pleasant Monetary Arithmetic,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review (Fall), pp. 117.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Selgin, George, 1994, “On Ensuring the Acceptability of a New Fiat Money,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 26 (November), pp. 80826.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ŝkreb, Marko,A, Note on Inflation,” 1998, in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Suranyi, György, and János Vincze, 1998, “Inflation in Hungary (1990–97),” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Szapáry, György, 1998, “Disinflation Policies: Issues of Sequencing,” in Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies, edited by Carlo Cottarelli and György Szapáry (Washington: International Monetary Fund and National Bank of Hungary).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Van Elkan, Rachel, 1998, “How Stable Is Money Demand?” in Hungary: Economic Policies for Sustainable Growth, by Carlo Cottarelli and others, IMF Occasional Paper 159 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wozniak, Przemystaw, 1998, “Relative Price Adjustment in Poland, Hungary and the Czech Republic. Comparison of the Size and Impact on Inflation,” CASE-CEV, Working Paper Series, Budapest.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zavoico, Basil, 1995, A Brief Note on the Inflationary Process in Transition Economies (mimeo; International Monetary Fund).

  • Zettermeyer, Jeromin, and Daniel A. Citrin, 1995, “Stabilization: Fixed Versus Flexible Exchange Rates,” in Policy Experiences and Issues in the Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union, edited by Daniel A. Citrin and Ashok K. Lahiri, IMF Occasional Paper 133 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation