Abstract

The explosive growth of international financial transactions and international capital flows is one of the single most profound and far-reaching economic developments of the late twentieth and early twenty-first centuries. This growth has several origins. Prominent among them are the removal of statutory restrictions on capital account transactions, itself a concomitant of economic liberalization and deregulation in both industrial and developing countries; macroeconomic stabilization and policy reform in the developing world, which have created a proliferation of attractive destinations for foreign capital; enterprise privatization, which has created a growing pool of commercial issuers of debt instruments; the multilateralization of trade, which has encouraged international financial transactions designed to hedge exposure to currency and commercial risk; and the growth of derivative financial instruments, which has permitted international investors to assume some risks while limiting their exposure to others.

The explosive growth of international financial transactions and international capital flows is one of the single most profound and far-reaching economic developments of the late twentieth and early twenty-first centuries. This growth has several origins. Prominent among them are the removal of statutory restrictions on capital account transactions, itself a concomitant of economic liberalization and deregulation in both industrial and developing countries; macroeconomic stabilization and policy reform in the developing world, which have created a proliferation of attractive destinations for foreign capital; enterprise privatization, which has created a growing pool of commercial issuers of debt instruments; the multilateralization of trade, which has encouraged international financial transactions designed to hedge exposure to currency and commercial risk; and the growth of derivative financial instruments, which has permitted international investors to assume some risks while limiting their exposure to others.

Along with these forces (indeed, underlying some of them) is the powerful role of technology. This takes the form of the revolution in information and communications technologies, which has transformed the financial services industry worldwide. Globalization has many dimensions, all of which have been stimulated by the decline in the costs of transportation, communication, data processing, and transactions.1 But nowhere does the revolution in information and communications technologies have such far-reaching ramifications as in the financial sphere.2

The financial innovation and liberalization that result are domestic as well as international phenomena. Not only have restrictions on international financial transactions been relaxed, resulting in the explosive growth of international capital movements, but also regulations constraining the operation of domestic financial markets have been relaxed or removed as countries have moved away from repressive financial policies. Domestic and international financial liberalization have generally gone hand in hand. They are responses to many of the same incentives and pressures.

However, in a significant number of cases, financial liberalization, both domestic and international, appears to have been associated with costly financial crises. This apparent association is somewhat deceptive, because financial crises are complex events that usually have multiple causes and that have occurred in less liberalized as well as more liberalized financial systems. Nevertheless, there have also been several cases in which financial liberalization, including capital account liberalization, is reasonably assessed to have played a meaningful role in crises. This raises a serious question about whether and under what conditions financial liberalization—and particularly capital account liberalization—will be beneficial rather than harmful. The answer advanced in this paper is the following. Capital account liberalization, and financial liberalization more generally, is essentially inevitable for all countries wishing to take advantage of the substantial benefits of broad participation in the open world economic system in this modern age of technology and communications. Financial liberalization also has its dangers, as liberalized systems generally afford opportunities for individuals, enterprises, and financial institutions to undertake greater and sometimes imprudent risks, thereby raising the potential for systemic disturbances. There is no way to completely suppress these dangers, other than through draconian financial repression, which creates worse problems. The dangers, however, can be limited quite considerably through a combination of sound macroeconomic policies to contain aggregate Financial imbalances and ameliorate the effects of financial disturbances and sound prudential policies to ensure proper private incentives for risk management. These must be backed up by adequate supervision and regulation, especially of the financial sector. With these important safeguards, capital account liberalization and broader financial liberalization are not only inevitable, but will clearly be beneficial.

At the theoretical level, the controversy over the benefits of financial liberalization reflects diverging views: are liberal financial markets predominantly efficient or, instead, are they so distorted by information asymmetries and other problems that financial transactions perceived to be beneficial to their direct participants too often yield outcomes detrimental to the general welfare? A large “efficient markets” literature argues the first hypothesis. At the same time, some observers insist that asymmetric information—a situation where one party to a transaction has less information than the other—is a key feature of capital markets and that it shapes the outcome of financial transactions so as to limit the efficiency of resource allocation. This is not to deny that information asymmetries exist also in other markets or that such problems, even when relatively mild or adequately controlled, can be a barrier to privately and socially beneficial transactions.3 However, they are not in general so serious as to preclude trade in goods and services altogether. Monitoring and verifying the quality of a tangible good or labor service are usually relatively straightforward and are often not a central issue, whereas for many financial transactions, acquiring accurate and reliable information to establish value is the essence of the issue.

Problems of asymmetric information are particularly prevalent in the international domain, where geographical and cultural distance complicates the task of acquiring and analyzing information.4 The revolution in information and communications technologies, by reducing data acquisition and processing costs, has had a particularly powerful effect in stimulating international financial transactions.5 And if the information and communications revolutions are irreversible, so is the growth of international capital flows.

The growth of international financial transactions concomitant with the information revolution thus poses a dilemma for policymakers. To the extent that information asymmetries are only attenuated but not eliminated, financial markets will continue to be affected to some degree by adverse selection, moral hazard, principal-agent problems, and herding behavior (see Box 1).6 In this setting, sharp investor reactions can give rise to unpredictable market movements and, in the extreme, financial crises. If these problems are serious enough, as they sometimes appear to be, then it may be necessary to temper the general presumption that market liberalization enhances the efficiency of resource allocation. A more accurate statement is that international financial liberalization, like domestic liberalization, unambiguously improves efficiency only when accompanied by the appropriate policies to limit moral hazard, adverse selection, excess volatility, and related problems and to contain their potentially damaging consequences.

Also, as has long been recognized, sound macroeconomic policies are essential (although not sufficient) for maintaining reasonable financial stability. Indeed, a liberalized financial system is probably more demanding in this respect than a repressed system, in which significant financial imbalances can sometimes be suppressed for extended periods, at great cost in terms of economic efficiency and often also of good governance. However, the ability to substitute financial controls for sound macroeconomic policies is being eroded by the economic and technological forces that are fundamentally driving financial liberalization. Even controls that may serve better purposes are generally subject to these forces, and policymakers will need to search for new ways, compatible with more liberal financial systems, of maintaining financial stability.

These observations provide the context for a discussion of the liberalization of capital account transactions and policy toward international capital flows. Capital account liberalization is defined as freedom from prohibitions on transactions in the capital and financial accounts of the balance of payments. Note the distinction between controls on the one hand and taxes on the other. While current account convertibility is defined under Article VIII of the IMF’s Articles of Agreement as freedom from restrictions on the making of payments and transfers for current international transactions (defined in Article XXX(d) to include certain transactions that are defined as capital transactions for purposes of balance of payments statistics), Article VIII does not proscribe the imposition of restrictions, such as import tariffs and taxes, on the underlying transactions. Correspondingly, capital account convertibility is taken here to mean the removal of exchange and other controls but not necessarily all taxlike instruments imposed on the underlying transaction, which agents retain the option of undertaking.

Asymmetric Information

Information is “asymmetric” when one party to an economic relationship or transaction has less information about it than the other party or parties. While asymmetric information is present in many markets, some economists believe that it is particularly pervasive in financial markets. Asymmetric information gives rise to adverse selection when the party does not know a relevant characteristic of the product that is being transacted or of the preferences or technology of the other party. For instance, the buyer of a used car may not know if the car is a “lemon,” or a lender may not know the riskiness of the borrower applying for a loan. Adverse selection typically results in inefficient pricing and, in extreme cases, may prevent efficient transactions from taking place. In credit markets, adverse selection may lead to credit rationing.

When one party cannot observe a relevant action to be undertaken by the other party, moral hazard may result. For instance, an insurer may not be able to observe whether the insured takes precautions to curb risk. Thus, a contract obliging the insured to take such precautions is not enforceable, and too much risk will result. In financial markets, a creditor may not be able to observe whether the borrower will invest in a risky project or a safe project, and, if the borrower is protected by limited liability or guarantees of some sort, too much investment in risky projects will result. An extreme case of moral hazard occurs when companies or banks with negative net worth borrow to gamble for redemption; namely they invest in ventures that can yield a high return (enough to stave off bankruptcy) but have a low probability. Gambling for redemption can result in large losses for the lenders. Moral hazard can also arise in the context of principal-agent situations, in which a principal asks an agent to perform certain tasks on her behalf (in exchange for compensation), but cannot perfectly monitor the execution of the tasks. To the extent that the agent’s preferences differ from those of the principal, the outcome will be suboptimal. For example, principal-agent situations arise when a small investor invests in a mutual fund and cannot perfectly monitor the investment strategy of the fund manager, or when equity holders entrust managers with running the business they own.

The importance of asymmetric information in financial markets is underscored by the fact that the very existence of financial institutions can be explained on asymmetric-information grounds. For instance, it has been argued that banks and other financial intermediaries specialize in assembling and analyzing information about borrowers and their investment projects, thereby attenuating informational asymmetries. From this perspective, banks and other financial intermediaries act as “delegated monitors” on behalf of their customers.

The next section describes recent trends in capital flows, focusing on the experience of developing countries, and elaborates on the role of technology in stimulating the growth of international financial transactions. It documents the far-reaching consequences of these developments, including the pressure they impart for the removal of capital controls and for changes in the exchange rate regime. It concludes with the observation that, despite experiences with serious financial crises in a number of cases, the decisions of many countries to proceed with financial liberalization are important evidence that such liberalization, including capital account liberalization, is generally beneficial when carried out under appropriate safeguards.

The paper then examines what economic theory has to say about the benefits and costs of capital mobility. It lays out the classical case for international capital mobility as intertemporal trade, as a mechanism for risk sharing, and as a means for enhancing the efficiency of financial services. It examines the counterarguments arising from problems of asymmetric information and other distortions that, if serious enough, could make financial liberalization harmful. It notes that, as some of these problems are the direct consequence of misguided government policies that should be reversed or can be removed by countervailing policies, they provide an argument for policy adjustment in connection with, rather than as a true barrier to, successful financial liberalization and the benefits that such liberalization can bring. Other problems, especially some of those associated with asymmetric information, are intrinsic to financial markets, both domestic and international, and cannot be entirely overcome. Noteworthy in this regard are problems of herding that may contribute to excessive volatility in financial markets and the nexus of problems relating to the banking system, which may be subject to runs and is influenced by moral hazard arising from expectations of government support to contain such runs. Here the answer is to structure appropriate prudential policies (especially for the banking system and to contain short-term debt), and supporting macroeconomic policies, to limit these problems to the point where the risks potentially arising from a liberalized financial system are at an acceptably low level—a level at which the benefits of liberalization clearly outweigh the costs. This is the approach taken by countries with respect to domestic financial liberalization, and the same approach is relevant for international financial liberalization.

The fourth and fifth sections assess countries’ practical experience with capital account liberalization by reviewing studies of the effects of capital account convertibility on economic growth, cyclical stability, and susceptibility to crises. This review highlights the difficulty of making unconditional statements like “capital account convertibility is beneficial” or “capital account convertibility is harmful.” Rather, what emerges is the need to marry capital account liberalization with domestic policy reform to ensure that the favorable effects dominate.

This leads to a discussion of the prudential regulation of financial institutions and markets, the role that can be played by limits on international capital flows, and the issue of sequencing. For purposes of this discussion, the range of prudential measures toward capital account transactions is conceived broadly, so as to encompass capital controls in the form of statutory prohibitions on certain transactions, open position limits, and taxes and tax equivalents that provide a pecuniary disincentive for such flows. The core question is what prudential measures are necessary to limit systemic risks that may arise more easily in liberalized financial markets and thereby ensure successful liberalization of the capital account.

1

The May 1997 edition of World Economic Outlook (International Monetary Fund, 1997) takes globalization as its theme and traces the implications not just for financial markets but also for the rest of the world economy.

2

For an overview of these developments see Werthamer and Raymond (1997).

3

For example, a firm producing and exporting a computer chip or a pharmaceutical product will know more than a potential importer about the quality-control methods under which it is produced and hence about the uniformity and reliability of the good, which will limit the volume of trade.

4

In addition, contracts are more difficult to enforce when they span national borders and legal jurisdictions. In principle, one way of neutralizing some of the adverse effects of information asymmetries is to write contracts whose payoffs are contingent on observed outcomes. But where enforcement is less effective (i.e., in the international domain), such relatively complex contingent contracts will be more difficult to write.

5

Historical experience is consistent with this view: even in the last era of financial globalization, prior to 1914, markets were significantly integrated only in securities issued by governments and railways, entities with tangible assets (the power to tax in the first instance, the road bed, railway, and rolling stock in the second) that were therefore largely exempt from the most severe information problems. The historical evidence on these questions is summarized in the next section and described in more detail in Appendix I.

6

Adverse selection arises in financial markets characterized by asymmetric information when the average quality of agents active in the pool of potential borrowers deteriorates with increases in the interest rate. Moral hazard arises in several areas, including when borrowers alter the characteristics of their investment projects after contracting a loan. Herding is defined as a situation where investors have an incentive to emulate the actions of other investors. For further discussion of some of these terms, see Box 1.

Cited By

Theoretical and Practical Aspects
  • Adams, Charles, and others, 1998, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Key Policy Issues, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Akerlof, George, and Paul M. Romer, 1993, “Looting: the Economic Underworld of Bankruptcy for Profit,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 2, Brookings Institution.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 1995, “Controlli sui Movimenti di Capitale e Politica Economica: Un’ Analisi Empirica,” in Studi per il Cinquantenario (Rome, Italy: Laterza).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto, Vittorio Grilli, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 1994, “The Political Economy of Capital Controls,” in Capital Mobility: The Impact on Consumption, Investment and Growth, ed. by L. Leiderman and A. Razin (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press for CEPR).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auernheimer, Leonardo, 1987, “On the Outcome of Inconsistent Programs under Exchange Rate and Monetary Rules,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 19, pp. 279305.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bacchetta, Philippe, 1992, “Capital Controls and the Political Premium: The Spanish Experience in the Late 80s” (unpublished; Barcelona, Spain: Institut d’ Analisi Econòmica).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bacchetta, Philippe, and Eric van Wincoop, 1998, “Capital Flows to Emerging Markets: Liberalization, Overshooting and Volatility,” NBER Working Paper No. 6530 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Backus, David K., Patrick J. Kehoe, and Finn E. Kydland, 1992, “International Real Business Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100 (August), pp. 74575.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Banerjee, Abhijit, 1992, “A Simple Model of Herd Behavior,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, pp. 797817.

  • Bank for International Settlements, 1997, “Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange Market Activity” (Basle, Switzerland: Bank for International Settlements, Monetary and Economic Department).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bartolini, Leonardo, and Allan Drazen, 1997a, “Capital Account Liberalization as a Signal,” American Economic Review, Vol. 87 (March), pp. 13854.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bartolini, Leonardo, and Allan Drazen, 1997b, “When Liberal Policies Reflect External Shocks, What Do We Learn?” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 42 (May), pp. 24973.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, 1990, “Saving-Investment Correlations: Immobile Capital, Government Policy, or Endogenous Behavior?” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 37 (June), pp. 36087.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, and Barry Eichengreen 1996, “The Stability of the Gold Standard and the Evolution of the International Monetary System,” in Modern Perspectives on the Gold Standard, ed. by Tamim Bayoumi, Barry Eichengreen, and Mark Taylor (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bernanke, Ben, 1983, “Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression,” American Economic Review, Vol. 73, No. 3 (June), pp. 25776.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhattacharya, Sudipto, and Anjan Thakor, 1994, “Contemporary Banking Theory,” Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 3 (October), pp. 250.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bikhchandani, Sushil, David Hirschleifer, and Ivo Welch, 1992, “A Theory of Fads, Fashion, and Cultural Change in Informational Cascades,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100 (October), pp. 9921026.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bisignano, Joseph, 1994, “The Internationalisation of Financial Markets: Measurements, Benefits and Unexpected Interdependence,” Cahiers Economiques et Monetaires, Banque de France, Vol. 43, pp. 971.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bloomfield, Arthur I., 1968, “Patterns of Fluctuation in International Finance Before 1914,” Princeton Studies in International Finance, Essays in International Finance, No. 21, International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, Michael D., and Hugh Rockoff, 1996, “The Gold Standard as a Good Housekeeping Seal of Approval,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 56 (June), pp. 389428.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, Michael, Barry Eichengreen, and Jong Woo Kim, 1998, “Was There Really an Earlier Period of International Financial Integration Comparable to Today?” paper prepared for the Bank of Korea Conference, “The Implications of Globalization of World Financial Markets,” Seoul, June.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boyd, John H., and Bruce D. Smith, 1992, “Intermediation and the Equilibrium Allocation of Investment Capital: Implications for Economic Development,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol 30, No. 3, pp. 40932.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brecher, Richard, and Carlos Diaz-Alejandro, 1977, “Tariffs, Foreign Capital, and Immiserizing Growth,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 7 (November), pp. 31722.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Browne, Francis, and Paul McNelis, 1990, “Exchange Rate Controls and Interest Rate Determination with Traded and Non-Traded Assets: The Irish-United Kingdom Experience,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 9 (March), pp. 4159.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buiter, Willem H., 1987, “Borrowing to Defend the Exchange Rate and the Timing and Magnitude of Speculative Attacks” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 23, pp. 22140.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calomiris, Charles, and R. Glenn Hubbard, 1996, “International Adjustment Under the Gold Standard: Evidence from the United States and Britain, 1879–1914,” in Modern Perspectives on the Gold Standard, ed. by Tamim Bayoumi, Barry Eichengreen, and Mark Taylor (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., 1991, “The Perils of Sterilization,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 38 (December), pp. 92126.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., Leonardo Leiderman, and Carmen M. Reinhart, 1993, “Capital Inflows and Real Exchange Rate Appreciation in Latin America: the Role of External Factors,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 40 (March), pp. 10851.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Enrique G. Mendoza, 1997, “Rational Herd Behavior and the Globalization of Securities Markets,” Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics Discussion Paper, No. 120–1 (August), Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Campbell, John Y., and N. Gregory Mankiw, 1989, “Consumption, Income and Real Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence,” Macroeconomics Annual (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caprio, Gerald, and Daniela Klingebiel, 1996, “Bank Insolvencies: Cross Country Experience,” Working Paper 1620, (Washington: Policy Research Department, World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cardoso, Eliana, and Ilan Goldfajn, 1998, “Capital Flows to Brazil: The Endogeneity of Capital Controls,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 45, (March), pp. 161202.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cardoso, Jaime, and Bernard Laurens, 1998, “The Effectiveness of Capital Controls on Inflows: Lesson from the Experience of Chile” (unpublished; Washington: Monetary and Exchange Affairs Department, International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chang, Roberto, and Andrés Velasco, 1998, “Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime,” NBER Working Paper No. 6469 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chari, V.V., and Ravi Jagannathan, 1988, “Banking Panics, Information, and Rational Expectations Equilibrium,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 43 (July), pp. 74963.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chari, V.V., and Patrick J. Kehoe, 1997, “Hot Money,” Staff Report 228 (Minneapolis, Minnesota: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chinn, Menzie, and Jeffrey Frankel, 1994, “Financial Links Around the Pacific Rim: 1982–1992,” in Exchange Rate Policy and Interdependence, Perspectives from the Pacific Basin, ed. by Reuven Glick, and Michael M. Hutchinson (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cole, Harold L., and Timothy J. Kehoe, 1996, “A Self-Fulfilling Model of Mexico’s 1994–95 Debt Crisis,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 41 (November), pp. 30930.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cooper, Richard N., 1998, “Should Capital-Account Convertibility Be a World Objective?” in Should the IMF Pursue Capital-Account Convertibility, ed. by Peter B. Kenen, Essays in International Finance, No. 207 (May), International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cuddington, J.T., 1987, “Capital Flight: Estimates, Issues and Explanations,” Essays in International Finance, No. 58 (December), International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • DeGrauwe, Paul, and Hans Dewachter, 1990, “A Chaotic Monetary Model of the Exchange Rate,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 466 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Demirgüç-Kunt, Ash, and Enrica Detragiache, 1997, “Banking Crises Around the World: Are There Any Common Threads?” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Demirgüç-Kunt, Ash, and Enrica Detragiache, 1998, “Financial Liberalization and Financial Fragility,” paper presented at the 1998 World Bank Conference on Development Economics, Washington, D.C., April 22.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Detragiache, Enrica, 1996, “Rational Liquidity Crises in the Sovereign Debt Market: In Search of Theory,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 43 (March), pp. 54570.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devenow, Andrea, and Ivo Welch, 1996, “Rational Herding in Financial Economics,” European Economic Review, Vol. 40, No. 3–5 (April), pp. 60315.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, Douglas, and Philip Dybvig, 1983, “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91 (June), pp. 40119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos, 1985, “Good-Bye Financial Repression, Hello Financial Crash,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 19 (September–October), pp. 124.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dobson, Wendy, and Pierre Jacquet, 1998, Financial Services Liberalization in the WTO (Washington: Institute for International Economics).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, 1988, “Capital Flight: A Response to Differences in Financial Risks,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 35 (September), pp. 42236.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, 1996a, “Capital Controls and Emerging Markets,” International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 1 (July), pp. 197205.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, 1996b, “A Survey of the Literature on Controls Over International Capital Transactions,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 43 (December), pp. 63987.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, 1996c, “The Tobin Tax: Good Theory, Weak Evidence, Questionable Policy,” in The Tobin Tax: Copying with Financial Volatility, ed. by Inge Kaul, Isabelle Grunberg, and Mahbub ul Haq (New York: Oxford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, and Peter Isard, 1980, “Capital Controls, Political Risks, and Deviations From Interest-Rate Parity,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88, No. 2 (April), pp. 37084.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, and Donald Mathieson, 1994, “Exchange Rate Policy, International Capital Mobility, and Monetary Policy Instruments,” in Exchange Rate Policy and Interdependence, Perspective from the Pacific Basin, ed. by R. Glick, and M. Hutchinson (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, and Donald Mathieson, and Liliana Rojas-Suarez, 1997, “Capital Mobility and Exchange Market Intervention in Developing Countries,” NBER Working Paper No. 6247 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1989, Real Exchange Rates, Devaluation, and Adjustment (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1998a, “Capital Flows, Real Exchange Rates, and Capital Controls: Some Latin American Experiences” (unpublished; University of California at Los Angeles).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1998b, “The Americas: Capital Controls Are Not the Reason for Chile’s Success,” Wall Street Journal, Section A, April 3, p. 19.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, and Mohsin Khan, 1985, “Interest Rate Determination in Developing Countries: A Conceptual Framework,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol 32 (September), pp. 377403.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Paul Masson, 1998, Exit Strategies: Policy Options for Countries Seeking Greater Exchange Rate Flexibility, IMF Occasional Paper No. 168 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Andrew K. Rose, 1998, “Staying Afloat When The Wind Shifts: External Factors and Emerging Market Banking Crises,” NBER Working Paper No. 6370, (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Andrew K. Rose, and Charles Wyplosz, 1996a, “Speculative Attacks on Pegged Exchange Rates: An Empirical Exploration with Special Reference to the European Monetary System,” in The New Transatlantic Economy, ed. by (Cambridge, M. B. Canzoneri, V. Grilli and P. Masson, U.K.: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Andrew K. Rose, and 1996b, “Is There a Safe Passage to EMU? Evidence from the Markets,” in The Micro-Structure of Foreign Exchange Markets, ed. by J. Frankel, G. P. Galli, and A. Giovannini (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Charles Wyplosz, 1993, “The Unstable EMS,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1, Brookings Institution.

  • Epstein, Gerald, and Juliet B. Schor, 1992, “Structural Determinants and Economic Effects of Capital Controls in OECD Countries,” in Financial Openness and National Autonomy: Opportunities and Constraints, ed. by Tariq Banuri and Juliet B. Schor (Oxford: Clarendon Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feldstein, Martin, and Charles Horioka, 1980, “Domestic Saving and International Capital Flows,” Economic Journal, Vol. 90 (June), pp. 31429.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Férnandez-Arias, Eduardo, and Peter Montiel, 1996, “The Surge of Capital Inflows to Developing Countries: An Analytical Overview,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 10 (January), pp. 5177.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fieleke, Norman, 1994, “International Capital Transactions: Should They Be Restricted?” New England Economic Review (March/April), pp. 2739.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, 1998, “Capital Account Liberalization and the Role of the IMF,” in Should the IMF Pursue Capital-Account Convertibility, ed. by Peter B. Kenen, Essays in International Finance, No. 207 (May), International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fisher, Matthew, and others, 1997, “Capital Account Convertibility and the Role of the Fund—Review of Experience and Consideration of a Possible Amendment of the Articles” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fishlow, Albert, 1985, “Lessons From the Past: Capital Markets During the 19th Century and the Interwar Period,” International Organization, Vol. 39 (Summer), pp. 383439.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flandreau, Marc, 1998, “Caveat Emptor: Dealing With Sovereign Risk in the Age of Globalization, 1871–1913” (unpublished; Paris, France: Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociale, Paris).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flandreau, Marc, Jacques Le Cacheux, and Frederic Zumer, 1998, “Stability Without a Pact? Lessons From the European Gold Standard, 1880–1914,” Economic Policy, No.7, (April), pp. 11562.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flood, Robert, and Peter Garber, 1984, “Collapsing Exchange Rate Regimes: Some Linear Examples,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 17 (August), pp. 113.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Folkerts-Landau, David, 1997, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Key Policy Issues (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Folkerts-Landau, David, and Takatoshi Ito, 1995, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Policy Issues (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Folkerts-Landau, David, and Carl-Johann Lindgren, 1998, Towards a Framework for Financial Stability (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., 1993, “Sterilization of Money Inflows: Difficult (Calvo) or Easy (Reisen)?” CIDER Working Paper No. 93–024 (Berkeley, California: University of California at Berkeley).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Sergio L. Schmukler, 1996, “Country Fund Discounts and the Mexican Crisis of December 1994: Did Local Residents Turn Pessimistic Before International Investors?” Open Economies Review, Vol. 7, Supp. 1, pp. 51134.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Sergio L. Schmukler, 1997, “Country Funds and Asymmetric Information” (unpublished; Berkeley, California: University of California at Berkeley, and Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fukao, Mitsushiro, 1990, “Liberalization of Japan’s Foreign Exchange Controls and Structural Changes in the Balance of Payments,” Bank of Japan Monetary and Economic Studies, Vol. 8 (September), pp. 10165.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garber, Peter, 1996, “Managing Risk to Financial Markets from Volatile Capital Flows: The Role of Prudential Regulation,” International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 1 (July), pp. 18395.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garber, Peter, 1998, “Buttressing Capital-Account Liberalization with Prudential Regulation and Foreign Entry,” in Should the IMF Pursue Capital Account Convertibility?, ed. by Peter B. Kenen, Essays in International Finance, No. 207 (May), International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia, Márcio, and Alexandre Barcinski, 1996, “Capital Flows to Brazil in the Nineties: Macroeconomic Aspects and the Effectiveness of Capital Controls,” Pontificia Universidade Catolica do Rio de Janeiro, Departamento de Economia, Texto Para Discussao No. 357, July.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gerlach, Stefan, and Frank Smets, 1995, “Contagious Speculative Attacks,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 11 (March), pp. 4563.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giavazzi, Francesco, and Alberto Giovannini, 1989, Limiting Exchange Rate Flexibility: The European Monetary System (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Glick, Reuven, and Andrew K. Rose, 1998, “Why Are Currency Crises Regional?” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 1947 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldfajn, Ilan, and Rodrigo Valdés, 1997, “Capital Flows and the Twin Crises: The Role of Liquidity,” IMF Working Paper 97/87 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldsmith, Raymond W., 1969, Financial Structure and Development (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press).

  • Goldstein, Morris, and David Folkerts-Landau, 1993, International Capital Markets: Part I, Exchange Rate Management and International Capital Flows, World Economic and Financial Surveys, (Washington: International Monetary Fund)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, and Philip Turner, 1996, “Banking Crises in Emerging Economies: Origins and Policy Options,” BIS Economic Papers No. 46, October.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, and John Hawkins, 1998, “The Origins of the Asian Financial Turmoil” (Australia: Reserve Bank of Australia).

  • Goodman, John B., and Louis W. Pauly, 1993, “The Obsolescence of Capital Controls,” World Politics, Vol. 46 (October), pp. 5082.

  • Greenwald, Bruce, Joseph Stiglitz, and Andrew Weiss, 1984, “Information Imperfections in the Capital Markets and Macroeconomic Fluctuations,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 74 (May), pp. 19499.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grilli, Vittorio, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 1995, “Economic Effects and Structural Determinants of Capital Controls,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 42, (September), pp. 51751.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gros, Daniel, 1987, “The Effectiveness of Capital Controls: Implications for Monetary Autonomy in the Presence of Incomplete Market Separation,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 34 (December), pp. 62142.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hanson, James A., 1995, “Opening the Capital Account: Costs, Benefits, and Sequencing,” in Capital Controls, Exchange Rates, and Monetary Policy in the World Economy, ed. by Sebastian Edwards (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hanson, Gordon H., and Antonio Spilembergo, 1996, “Illegal Immigration, Border Enforcement, and Relative Wages: Evidence from Apprehensions at the U.S. Mexico Border,” IMF Seminar Series, No. 1996–33, April.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haq, Mahbub, Inge Kaul, and Isabelle Grunberg, eds., 1996, The Tobin Tax (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

  • Haque, Nadeem, Manmohan Kumar, and Lamin Leigh, 1994, “International Capital Mobility: Estimates for Developing Countries Using Cointegration Methodology” (unpublished; Washington: Research Department, International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haque, Nadeem, and Peter Montiel, 1991, “Capital Mobility in Developing Countries: Some Empirical Tests,” World Development, Vol. 19 (October), pp. 139198.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions, (Washington), various issues.

  • International Monetary Fund, Balance of Payments Statistics Yearbook, (Washington: International Monetary Fund), various issues.

  • International Monetary Fund, 1997, World Economic Outlook, (May/October/December), World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).

  • Ito, Takatoshi, and David Folkerts-Landau, 1996, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Key Policy Issues (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jansen, Jos, and Günther Schulze, 1996, “A Note on the Effectiveness of Norwegian Capital Controls,” Aussenwirtschaft, Vol. 51, No. 3 (September), pp. 31325.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jeanne, O, and Paul R. Masson, 1996, “Was the French Franc Crisis a Sunspot Equilibrium?” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnston, Barry, and Chris Ryan, 1994, “The Impact of Controls on Capital Movements on the Private Capital Accounts of Countries’ Balance of Payments: Empirical Estimates and Policy Implications,” IMF Working Paper No. 94/78 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnston, Barry, and others, 1997, “Review of Experience with Capital Account Liberalization and Strengthened Procedures Adopted by the Fund” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnston, Barry, and others, 1998, “Developments and Issues in the International Exchange and Payments System” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnston, Barry, Salim Darbar, and Claudia Echeverria, 1997, “Sequencing Capital Account Liberalization: Lessons from the Experiences in Chile, Indonesia, Korea, and Thailand,” IMF Working Paper No. 97/157 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kamin, Steven, 1988, “Devaluation, Exchange Rate Controls, and Black Markets for Foreign Exchange in Developing Countries,” International Finance Discussion Papers No. 334 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kamin, Steven, 1991, “Argentina’s Experience with Parallel Exchange Markets: 1981–1991,” International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 407 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kaminsky, Graciela L., and Carmen M. Reinhart, 1996, “The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payments Problems,” International Finance Discussion Paper No. 544 (Washington: Federal Reserve Board).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kaminsky, Graciela L., Saul Lizondo, and Carmen M. Reinhart, 1998, “Leading Indicators of Currency Crises,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol.45, No. 1 (March), pp. 148.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kane, Edward, J., 1985, The Gathering Crisis in Deposit Insurance, (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, Robert, and Ross Levine, 1993a, “Finance, Entrepreneurship and Growth: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32 (December), pp. 51342.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, Robert, and Ross Levine, 1993b, “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108 (August), pp. 71737.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Klein, Michael W., and Nancy P. Marion, 1997, “Explaining the Duration of Exchange-Rate Pegs,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 54 (December), pp. 387404.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, 1979, “A Model of Balance of Payments Crises,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 11 (August), pp. 31125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, 1996, “Are Currency Crises Self-Fulfilling?” in Macroeconomics Annual (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, 1998, “What Happened to Asia” (unpublished; Cambridge, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology).

  • Labán, Raúl, and Felipe Larraín, 1997, “Can a Liberalization of Capital Outflows Increase Net Capital Inflows?” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 16 (June), pp. 41531.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Le Fort, Guillermo, and Carlos Budnevich, 1996, “Capital Account Regulation and Macroeconomic Policy: Two Latin American Experiences,” The Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Working Paper No. 162 (Washington: The Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard College).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lemmen, Jan J.G., and Sylvester C.W. Eijffinger, 1996, “The Fundamental Determinants of Financial Integration in the European Union,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 132, No.3, pp. 43256.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, Ross, 1997, “Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35 (June), pp. 688726.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, Ross, and Sara Zervos, 1998, “Stock Markets, Banks and Economic Growth,” American Economic Review, Vol. 88 (June) pp. 53758.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lewis, Karen K., 1996, “What Can Explain the Apparent Lack of International Consumption Risk-Sharing?” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 104 (April), pp. 26797.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lewis, Karen K., 1997, “Are Countries with Official International Restrictions ‘Liquidity Constrained’?” European Economic Review, Vol. 41, No. 6 (June), pp. 10791109.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lindgren, Carl-Johann, Gillian Garcia, and Matthew Saal, 1996, Bank Soundness and Macroeconomic Policy (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Maloney, William, 1997, “Testing Capital Account Liberalization Without Forward Rates: Another Look at Chile, 1979–1982,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 52 (February), pp. 13968.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul R., 1998, “Contagion: Monsoonal Effects, Spillovers, and Jumps Between Multiple Equilibria” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mathieson, Donald, and Liliana Rojas-Suárez, 1993, Liberalization of the Capital Account, IMF Occasional Paper No. 103 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald, 1973, Money and Capital in Economic Development (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press).

  • McKinnon, Ronald, 1993, The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to a Market Economy, Second Edition (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald, and Huw Pill, 1997, “Credible Economic Liberalizations and Over borrowing,” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 87, No. 2 (May), pp. 18993.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Memedovic, Olga, Arie Kuyvenhoven, and Willem Molle, eds., 1997, Globalization of Labour Markets: Challenges, Adjustment and Policy Response in the EU and LDCs (Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Micossi, Stefano, and Salvatore Rossi, 1986, “Controlli sui Movimenti di Capitale: II Caso Italiano,” Giornale degli Economisti, Vol. XLV, No. 1–2 (January/February), pp. 1753.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, and Assaf Razin, 1998a, “Sharp Reductions in Current Account Deficits: An Empirical Analysis,” European Economic Review, Vol. 42, No. 3–5, pp. 897908.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, and Assaf Razin, 1998b, “Current Account Reversals and Currency Crises: Empirical Regularities,” IMF Working Paper 98/89, June.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Miller, Merton, 1998, “Financial Markets & Economic Growth,” (unpublished, University of Chicago, Graduate School of Business).

  • Miller, Victoria, 1996, “Speculative Currency Attacks with Endogenously-Induced Commercial Bank Crises,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 15 (June), pp. 383403.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Miller, Victoria, 1998, “The Double Drain with a Cross Border Twist: More on the Relationship Between Banking and Currency Crises,” American Economic Review, Vol. 88, No. 2 (May), pp. 43943.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mishkin, Frederic S., 1996, “Understanding Financial Crises: A Developing Country Perspective,” NBER Working Paper No. 5600 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Montiel, Peter, 1993, “Capital Mobility in Developing Countries: Some Measurement Issues and Empirical Estimates,” Policy Research Department Working Paper No. 1103 (Washington:The World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mussa, Michael, 1998, “Changing Growth Patterns in the World Economy” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1986, “Rational and Self-Fulfilling Balance of Payments Crises,” American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 1 (March), pp. 7281.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1994a, “Risk-Taking, Global Diversification and Growth,” American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 5 (November), pp. 131029.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1994b, “The Logic of Currency Crises,” Cahiers Economiques et Monétaires (Banque de France) Vol. 43, pp. 189213.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1994c, “Are Industrial-Country Consumption Risks Globally Diversified?” in Capital Mobility: The Impact on Consumption, Investment and Growth, ed. by L. Leiderman and A. Razin (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1995, “International Capital Mobility in the 1990s,” in Understanding Interdependence: the Macroeconomics of the Open Economy, ed. by Peter B. Kenen (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1996, “Models of Currency Crises with Self-Fulfilling Features,” European Economic Review, Vol. 40, No. 3–5 (April), pp. 103747.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1998, “The Global Capital Market: Benefactor or Menace?” Journal of Economic Perspectives (forthcoming).