Abstract

Dollarization, the holding by residents of a significant share of their assets in the form of foreign-currency-denominated assets, is a common feature of developing countries and transition economies and is thereby typical—to a greater or lesser extent—of many countries that have IMF-supported adjustment programs.1 Of those countries that have had arrangements with the IMF at one time or another during the past ten years, at least half are dollarized, and a significant number are highly dollarized (Table 1).2 This paper explores the general question of the costs and benefits of dollarization for a country’s economy. In addition, it examines the issues that dollarization poses for the formulation and conduct of monetary policy, as well as for IMF program design.3

Dollarization, the holding by residents of a significant share of their assets in the form of foreign-currency-denominated assets, is a common feature of developing countries and transition economies and is thereby typical—to a greater or lesser extent—of many countries that have IMF-supported adjustment programs.1 Of those countries that have had arrangements with the IMF at one time or another during the past ten years, at least half are dollarized, and a significant number are highly dollarized (Table 1).2 This paper explores the general question of the costs and benefits of dollarization for a country’s economy. In addition, it examines the issues that dollarization poses for the formulation and conduct of monetary policy, as well as for IMF program design.3

Table 1.

Reported Ratios of Foreign Currency Deposits (FCD) Broad Money in Countries with IMF Arrangements Since 1986

article image
article image
Sources: IMF, IMF Staff Country Reports and International Financial Statistics (IFS).

Classification based on observations for 1995; countries in bold are those selected for review.

Latest year's observation for March.

Latest year's observation for June.

Latest year's observation for September.

Fiscal year.

The paper focuses on dollarization of the monetary sector, and in particular on holdings by residents of foreign currency deposits (FCD) and, where data are available, of foreign currency cash. The paper recognizes, however, that dollarization of monetary assets often is part of a larger process of financial market integration. For example, dollarization in the loan portfolio of banks is an important phenomenon, and the paper touches on this too. Cross-border deposits (bank deposits of residents in foreign countries) also play an important role as close substitutes for domestic FCD. The paper explores the various monetary policy strategies that may be pursued in the presence of dollarization, considers the implications of dollarization for the practical application and instruments of monetary policy, and examines the manner in which dollarization has influenced the design of IMF programs. The paper's conclusions are as follows.

  • The benefits of dollarization include closer integration with international markets, exposure to competition from these markets, and the availability of a more complete range of assets for domestic investors. In countries in which inflationary experience has destroyed confidence in the local currency, dollarization can sometimes help to remonetize the economy, restore local inter-mediation, and reverse capital flight. The costs of dollarization include the loss of seignorage and a potential for greater fragility of the banking system. Such fragilities can limit the policy options available to the authorities, as well as put an additional burden on the central bank as lender of last resort.

  • Dollarization can complicate the choice of intermediate targets of monetary policy by introducing a foreign currency component into the money supply. The suitability of a target that includes, or excludes, foreign currency depends on the target’s relationship with output and prices, and this is essentially an empirical matter. It is possible, however, that no reliable aggregate can be found. This problem, which is by no means confined to dollarized economies, brings into question the policy of monetary targeting as opposed to, for example, relying on a wider set of indicators. Although this issue is beyond the scope of this paper, there are good reasons to believe that dollar-denominated assets should play some role among the set of relevant indicators for monetary policy under any alternative approach.

  • While the general considerations regarding the choice of exchange rate system also apply to dollarized economies, the prevalence of currency substitution (the use of foreign-currency-denominated assets for transactions) tends to strengthen the case for a fixed-rate system. Such an exchange rate arrangement would protect the economy from the effects of potentially excessive exchange rate and money market volatility. When attempting stabilization from hyperinflation, in particular, a fixed exchange rate can be an effective instrument in highly dollarized economies. The same conclusion does not apply when dollarization reflects only asset substitution (the holding of foreign-currency-denominated assets as stores of value).

  • Dollarization requires the adoption of special prudential measures. The banking system must be able to withstand significant exchange rate adjustments, as well as possibly larger-than-normal swings in capital flows. To deal with the latter, commercial banks or the central bank need to hold a larger-than-normal volume of international reserves, or to arrange external lines of credit. Limits to banks’ foreign exposure positions need to be monitored carefully, as do off-balance-sheet operations that could entail foreign exchange risk. Since devaluations cannot shrink the value of dollar claims, steps have to be taken to ensure that banks do not incur undue risks in lending to dollar borrowers that do not have the capacity to honor their obligations when devaluations occur.

  • Should dollarization be discouraged? The answer depends on the role of dollarization in the economy. Asset substitution may be a natural accompaniment of the opening of financial markets, and in this respect it should be welcome. Moreover, globalization of financial markets will likely lead to some dollarization.4 Nonetheless, as with other forms of capital market liberalization, the proper sequencing of policies is essential. Asset substitution—and more especially, currency substitution—may also reflect the absence of macroeconomic stability and the existence of distortions in financial markets. In these circumstances, dollarization may complicate stabilization and cause additional volatility. However, in circumstances where it becomes very difficult to reestablish quickly stability of the national currency, economic well-being would likely be reduced by any administrative measures to reduce dollarization, and a case might be made for acceptance of continued dollarization in the quest for stability.

  • Macroeconomic stability is the first priority in dealing with dollarization, but this may not, in and of itself, be sufficient to reverse it. Other measures, such as the liberalization of domestic interest rates, the establishment of a competitive domestic currency payments system, and the development of domestic financial instruments are also steps that can help “dedollarize” an economy. More direct measures to reverse dollarization, however, can be problematic. Regulatory limits on FCD or punitive reserve requirements on dollar deposits may simply drive dollars offshore, while forced conversions will undermine confidence and may also encourage capital flight.

  • In general, IMF programs have treated dollarization as a symptom to be lived with rather than directly attacked and have concentrated on macroeconomic stabilization, in common with programs for nondollarized economies. In fact, dollarized countries with IMF programs have done only slightly worse in terms of meeting inflation targets than nondollarized economies with programs, although there is evidence of higher volatility in the former group. In some cases, concerns have arisen regarding the soundness of the banking system in dollarized economies. In other cases, the conventional practice of treating required reserves on FCD as a domestic, rather than foreign, liability may have put program objectives at risk. More broadly, program design in the presence of dollarization requires a more thorough analysis than usual in the selection of intermediate monetary targets and of the relationship of dollarization with ultimate targets.

Cited By

  • Agénor, Pierre-Richard, and Mohsin S. Khan, 1996, “Foreign Currency Deposits and the Demand for Money in Developing Countries,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 50, pp. 10118.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baliño, Tomás J.T., Charles Enoch, Alain Ize, Veerathai Santiprabhob, Peter Stella, and 1997, Currency Board Arrangements: Issues, Experiences, and Implications for IMF-Supported Programs, Occasional Paper 151 (Washington, D.C.: IMF).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Andrew, Eduardo Borensztein, and Zhaohui Chen, 1997, “Dollarization, Exchange Rates, and Monetary Policy” (unpublished; Washington: IMF).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, M., and E. Choudri, 1982, “Currency Substitution and Demand for Money: Some Empirical Evidence for Canada,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 14, pp. 4857.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, and Carlos Végh, 1992, “Currency Substitution in Developing Countries: An Introduction,” Revista de Análisis Económico, Vol. 7, pp. 328.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, and Carlos Végh, 1996, “From Currency Substitution to Dollarization and Beyond: Analytical and Policy Issues,”in Guillermo Calvo, Money, Exchange Rates, and Output (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press), pp. 15375.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clements, Benedict, and Gerard Schwartz, 1993, “Currency Substitution: The Recent Experience of Bolivia,” World Development, Vol. 21, pp. 188393.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cuddington, J., 1983, “Currency Substitutability, Capital Mobility and Money Demand,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 2, pp. 11133.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Drazen, Allen, and Paul R. Masson, 1994, “Credibility of Policies Versus Credibility of Policymakers,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 109, pp. 73554.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • El-Erian, Mohamed, 1988, “Currency Substitution in Egypt and the Yemen Arab Republic: A Comparative Quantitative Analysis,” Staff Papers, IMF, Vol. 35, pp. 85103.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Estrella, Arturo, and Frederic Mishkin, 1996, “Is There a Role for Monetary Aggregates in the Conduct of Monetary Policy?NBER Working Paper 5845 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feldstein, Martin, and James H. Stock, 1994, “The Use of Monetary Aggregates to Target Nominal GDP,” in N. Gregory Mankiw, ed., Monetary Policy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, 1982, “Seignorage and the Case for a National Money,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90, pp. 295313.

  • Friedman, Benjamin M., and Kenneth N. Kuttner, 1996, “A Price Target for U.S. Monetary Policy? Lessons from the Experience with Money Growth Targets,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1, 1996, pp. 77125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garber, Peter, 1996, “Managing Risks to Financial Markets from Volatile Capital Flows: The Role of Prudential Regulation,” International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 1, pp. 18395.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • García, Márcio, 1996, “Avoiding Some Costs of Inflation and Crawling Toward Hyperinflation: The Case of the Brazilian Domestic Currency Substitute,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 51, pp. 13959.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • García-Herrero, Alicia, 1997, “Banking Crisis in Latin America in the 1990s: Lessons from Argentina, Paraguay, and Venezuela,” Working Paper 97/140 (Washington: IMF).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giovannini, Albertoand Bart Turtelboom, 1994, “Currency Substitution,” in F. van der Ploeg, ed., Handbook of International Macroeconomics (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Blackwell).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Girton, Lance, and Don Roper, 1981, “Theory and Implications of Currency Substitution,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 13, pp. 1230.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guidotti, Pablo, and Carlos Rodríguez, 1992, “Dollarization in Latin America: Gresham’s Law in Reverse?” Staff Papers, IMF, Vol. 39, pp. 51844.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gulde, Anne Marie, Jean Claude Nascimento, and Lorena Zamalloa, 1997, “Liquid Asset Ratios and Financial Sector Reform,” Working Paper 97/144 (Washington: IMF).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kamin, Steven, and Neil Ericsson, 1993, “Dollarization in Argentina,” International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 460 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kiguel, Miguel, and Nissan Liviatan, 1994, “Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilization in Argentina and Chile: A Fresh Look,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 1318 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kochhar, Kalpana, 1996, “The Definition of Reserve Money: Does It Matter for Financial Programs?” Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment 96/9 (Washington: IMF).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald I., 1996, “Direct and Indirect Concepts of International Currency Substitution” in Paul Mizenand Eric J. Pentecost, eds., The Macroeconomics of International Currencies: Theory, Policy, and Evidence (Gloucestershire, U.K.: Edward Elgar), pp. 4459.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Miles, M.A., 1978, “Currency Substitution, Flexible Exchange Rates, and Monetary Independence,” American Economic Review, Vol. 68, pp. 42836.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Monetary and Exchange Affairs Department, IMF 1995, “Reserve Requirements on Foreign Currency Deposits,” MAE Operational Paper 95/1 (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mueller, Johannes, 1994, “Dollarization in Lebanon,” Working Paper 94/129 (Washington: IMF).

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff, 1996, Foundations of International Macroeconomics (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Porter, Richard, and Ruth Judson, 1996, “The Location of U.S. Currency: How Much Is Abroad?” Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 82, pp. 883903.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sahay, Ratna, and Carlos A. Végh, 1996, “Dollarization in Transition Economies: Evidence and Policy Implications,” in Paul Mizenand Eric J. Pentecost, eds., The Macroeconomics of International Currencies: Theory, Policy, and Evidence (Gloucestershire, U.K.: Edward Elgar), pp. 195224.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Savastano, M. A., 1992, “The Pattern of Currency Substitution in Latin America: An Overview,” Revista de Análisis Económico, Vol. 7, pp. 2972.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Savastano, M. A., 1996, “Dollarization in Latin America: Recent Evidence and Policy Issues,” in Paul Mizenand Eric J. Pentecost, eds., The Macroeconomics of International Currencies: Theory, Policy, and Evidence (Gloucestershire, U.K.: Edward Elgar), pp. 22555.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation