Abstract

Since the mid-1970s, many developing countries have altered their exchange rate regimes. They have moved away from pegging to a single currency toward either pegging to a basket of currencies or adopting a more flexible arrangement under which the domestic currency is frequently adjusted.

Since the mid-1970s, many developing countries have altered their exchange rate regimes. They have moved away from pegging to a single currency toward either pegging to a basket of currencies or adopting a more flexible arrangement under which the domestic currency is frequently adjusted.

Table 1 presents the patterns of exchange arrangements of developing countries during 1976–89. The proportion of developing countries pegging to a single currency has declined steadily from 63 percent in 1976 to 38 percent in 1989.1 The proportion of countries pegging to the U.S. dollar declined from 43 percent to 24 percent during this period. The share of countries pegging to the pound sterling fell even more dramatically; in fact, by 1989, no country pegged to this currency. By contrast, the French franc held its ground, as the countries in the Communauté Financière Africaine (CFA) franc zone maintained their currency union arrangement.

Table 1.

Developing Countries: Exchange Rate Arrangements, 1976-891

(In percent of total number of countries)

article image
Sources: Internacional Monetary Fund Annual Report (1982); International Monetary Fund Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions (1983); and International Monetary Fund international Financial Statistics (April 1990).

Based on mid-year classifications, except for 1989, which is based on end-year classification, excludes Democratic Kampuchea, for which no information is available.

Includes the following categories: “flexibility limited vis-à-vis single currency,” “managed floating,” and “independently floating.”

A number of countries have chosen to peg their currencies to the SDR as a convenient method of approximating the relative importance of the major currencies in international transactions. The proportion of these countries, however, has declined from about 10 percent during 1976-83 to 5 percent by the end of the 1980s. By contrast, the share of countries opting to peg to a trade-weighted basket of currencies has risen sharply—from 13 percent in 1976 to 23 percent in 1989.

The decision by an increasing number of developing countries to switch their pegging arrangement from a single currency to a composite basket of currencies has been prompted partly by the desire to minimize the adverse effects on their economies of fluctuations in the exchange rates of major currencies that have taken place since the advent of generalized floating in 1973, and particularly in the 1980s. These fluctuations have engendered various problems for the developing countries, ranging from uncertainty about the profitability of investment in traded goods sectors, to the management of public finances, external debt, and foreign exchange reserves.

Developing countries have also increased their reliance on more flexible arrangements under which the exchange rate is adjusted frequently. These arrangements are often officially described as “adjusting to indicators,” “managed floating” or “independently floating,” but these terms do not accurately reflect the arrangements in place, as in an overwhelming majority of cases the exchange rate is effectively set by the authorities, albeit adjusted frequently. For the purpose of the present discussion, these arrangements are described as “flexible.”2 As is evident from Table 1, during 1976-89 the proportion of countries relying on flexible arrangements more than doubled, to one third of the total.

The increased use of more flexible exchange rate arrangements in developing countries can be attributed to a number of factors. First, domestic rates of inflation in many developing countries have sharply accelerated during the 1980s. This acceleration was particularly pronounced in the countries of the Western Hemisphere—their average rate of inflation rose from 25 percent in the late 1970s to nearly 300 percent in the late 1980s—but was also evident in some of the developing countries in Africa and Europe. These countries were forced to depreciate their currencies rapidly to avoid a deterioration in external competitiveness. In fact, in many of these countries, the nominal exchange rate and domestic inflation were systematically linked.

Second, the adoption of more flexible arrangements has been encouraged by the uncertainty associated with the fluctuations in the exchange rates of the major currencies. As indicated earlier, many countries have adopted a basket peg to neutralize the effects of such fluctuations on their economies. However, some countries have been reluctant to adopt such an arrangement, as it would entail frequent adjustments of the exchange rate vis-à-vis the intervention currency according to a preannounced formula. These countries have been particularly unwilling to follow those movements of major currencies which they considered to be transitory. Furthermore, given the political stigma attached to devaluation under a pegged regime, an increasing number of countries have found it expedient to adopt a more flexible arrangement for adjusting the exchange rate on the basis of an undisclosed basket of currencies. Such an arrangement enables the authorities to take advantage of the fluctuations in major currencies to camouflage an effective depreciation of their exchange rate, thus avoiding the political repercussions of an announced devaluation.

It is useful to review the exchange rate arrangements adopted by the developing countries in different regions and the movements of the exchange rate indices under different arrangements. For the purposes of this review, the countries that kept their exchange rate arrangement broadly unchanged throughout 1982-89 were put into two groups—pegged and flexible.3 With very few exceptions, countries in Africa and in the Middle East adopted a pegged regime. Asian countries generally fell in the flexible category, although a few pegged their currency to a basket. The developing countries in Europe and in the Western Hemisphere adopted both types of arrangements, with low-inflation countries generally adopting a pegged regime, and high-inflation countries a flexible regime.

Table 2 provides the movements of exchange rate indices for the two groups. For the pegged group, the nominal exchange rate initially appreciated, but sharply depreciated after 1985, reflecting both a weakened U.S. dollar (to which the currencies of many of the countries in this group were pegged) and more frequent devaluations. This pattern was mirrored in the movements of the real exchange rate, despite a rise in the average rate of inflation for this group. For the whole period, the real exchange rate for the pegged group depreciated by about 11 percent, but this depreciation masked large differences among the subgroups using different pegging arrangements (single currency, trade-weighted baskets, or the SDR).

Table 2.

Trend Movements of Relative Prices, Nominal Effective Exchange Rate, and Real Effective Exchange Rate for Groups According to their Exchange Rate Arrangement, 1982-89

(Cumulative percentage change)

article image

Using a log-linear formulation, the real effective exchange rate (re) is defined as the nominal effective rate (ne) adjusted for the difference between a weighted average of foreign prices (fp) and domestic prices (dp):

(1)re=ne(fpdp)=nerp(2)ne=Σi=1nw(i)e(i)(3)fp=Σi=1nw(i)fp(i)

The w(i) are bilateral trade weights, e(i) is the bilateral exchange rate (units of foreign currency per unit of domestic currency), and fp(i) is the price index in country i with which the home country trades.

For the flexible group, an active exchange rate policy led to a significant depreciation of the real exchange rate (37 percent). Although the average inflation rate was much higher for the flexible group than the pegged group, the average depreciation of the real effective exchange rate was much greater for the flexible group. Thus, at this level of generality (and without any presumption about the direction of causality), exchange rate flexibility, improvement in external competitiveness, and domestic inflation seem to be positively correlated. The depreciation of the real exchange rate, however, was particularly pronounced for the Asian countries, which, although adopting a flexible arrangement, maintained low inflation rates.

1

Some countries classified under the pegged regime have undertaken frequent devaluations.

2

This grouping includes countries with a floating arrangement under which the exchange rare is determined by the market. Such floating arrangements, however, are relatively rare in the developing countries owing to institutional and structural reasons, although a number of countries have experimented with auction markets (see Quirk and others (1987)).

3

This period was chosen because the pattern of exchange rate arrangements across countries was much more stable after 1982 than in the earlier period.

Cited By

  • Adams, Charles Daniel Gros, The Consequences of Real Exchange Rate Rules for Inflation: Some Illustrative Examples,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 33 (September 1986). pp. 43976.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aghevli, Bijan B.Experiences of Asian Countries wiih Various Exchange Rate Policies,” in Exchange Rate Rules: The Theory, Performance, and Prospects of the Crawling Peg. ed. by Williamson, John (London: MacMillan, 1981), pp. 298318.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aghevli, Bijan B. and Peter J. Montiel, Exchange Rate Policies in Developing Countries,” in Exchange Rate Policies of Less Developed and Socialist Economies, ed. by E. Claasen (San Francisco: International Center for Economic Growth, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aizenman, Joshua, and Jacob A. Frenkel, Optimal Wage Indexation, Foreign Exchange Intervention, and Monetary Policy.” American Economic Review. Vol. 75 (June 1985), pp. 40223.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Argy, Victor and Paul De Grauwe. eds., Choosing an Exchange Rate Regime: The Challenge for Smaller Industrial Countries (Washington, D.C., International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balassa, Bela, The Purchasing Power Parity Doctrine: A Reappraisal,” Journal of Political Economy (December 1964), pp. 58496.

  • Barro, Robert J., David B. Gordon, Rules, Discretion, and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy,” Journal of Monetary Economics (July 1983), pp. 10121.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boyer, R., Optimal Foreign Exchange Market Intervention,” Journal of Political Economy (December 1978). pp. 104555.

  • Buiter, Willem, Fiscal Prerequisites for a Viable Managed Exchange Rate Regime: A Non-Technical Eclectic Introduction,” NBER Working Paper No. 2041 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau for Economic Research, October 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., Pablo E. Guidotti, Level and Variability of the Optimal Inflation Tax,” unpublished; International Monetary Fund (1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Canzoneri, Matthew B., Monetary Policy Games and the Role of Private Information,” American Economic Review (December 1985), pp. 105669.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Crockett, Andrew D., Saleh M. Nsouli, Exchange Rate Policies for Developing Countries.” Journal of Developing Studies, Vol. 13 (January 1977), pp. 12543.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, Exchange Rate Rules and Macroeconomic Stability,” in Exchange Rate Rules: The Theory, Performance and Prospects of the Crawling Peg, ed. by Williamson, John (London: MacMillan, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, PPP Exchange-Rate Rules and Macroeconomic Stability,” Journal of Political Economy (February 1982), pp. 15865.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, Purchasing Power Parity,” in The New Pat-grave Dictionary of Economics, ed. by John Eatwell, Murray Milgare, Peter Newman, (New York: Stockton Press, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, Real Exchange Rates, Devaluation and Adjustment: Exchange Rate Policy in Developing Countries (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flood, RobertCapital Mobility and the Choice of Exchange Rate Systems,” International Economic Review (June 1979), pp. 40516.

  • Frenkel, Jacob A.The Collapse of Purchasing Power Parities During the 1970s,” European Economic Review (May 1981), pp. 14565.

  • Frenkel, Jacob A. Joshua Aizenman, Aspects of the Optimal Management of Exchange Rates,” Journal of International Economics (September 1982), pp. 23156.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frenkel, Jacob A. Morris Goldstein, A Guide to Target Zones,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 33, No. 4 (December 1986). pp. 63373.

  • Frenkel, Jacob A. and Assaf Razin, Fiscal Policies and the World Economy (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1987).

  • Friedman, MiltonThe Case for Flexible Exchange Rates,” in Essays in Positive Economies, ed. by Friedman, Milton (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Genberg, HansPurchasing Power Parity as a Rule for a Crawling Peg,” in Exchange Rate Rules: The Theory. Performance and Prospects of the Crawling Peg, ed. by Williamson, John (London: MacMillan, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Genberg, HansExchange Rate Management and Macroeconomic Policy: A National Perspective,” unpublished (July 1989).

  • Giavazzi, Francesco, and Marco Pagano, The Advantage of Tying One’s Hands: EMS Discipline and Central Bank Credibility.” Centre for Economic Policy Discussion Paper No. 135 (October 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Harberger, Arnold C.Economic Adjustment and the Real Exchange Rate,” in Economic Adjustment and Exchange Rates in Developing Countries, ed. by Edwards, Sebastian Ahmed, Liaquat (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1986), pp. 371423.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Helpman, Elhanan, and Leonardo Leiderman, Exchange Rate Systems: Are There New Answers to Old Questions?unpublished (December 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnson, Harry G., The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates. 1969,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review (1969), pp. 1224.

  • Khan, Mohsin S., Developing Country Exchange Rate Policy Responses to Exogenous Shocks,” American Economic Review (May 1986), pp. 847.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., and J. Saul Lizondo, Devaluation. Fiscal Deficits, and the Real Exchange Rate,” World Bank Economic Review (January 1987), pp. 35774.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., and Peter Montiel, Real Exchange Rate Dynamics in a Small Primary-Exporting Country,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 34 (December 1987), pp. 681710.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kharas, Homi Brian Pinto, Exchange Rate Rules, Black Market Premia, and Fiscal Deficits: The Bolivian Hyperinflation,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 56 (1989), pp. 43548.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, PaulA Model of Balance of Payments Crises,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking (August 1979), pp. 31125.

  • Kydland, Finn and Edward Prescott, Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optima! Plans,” Journal of Political Economy (June 1977), pp. 73091.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lizondo, J. SaulReal Exchange Rate Targets, Nominal Exchange Rate Policies, and Inflation,” University of Tucuman, unpublished (November 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Marston, RobertWages, Relative Prices and Choice Between Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates,” Canadian Journal of Economics (February 1982), pp. 87103.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mussa, MichaelExchange Rate Policy for Developing Countries: The Case for a Pegged Exchange Rate,” unpublished (January 1978).

  • Obstfeld, MauriceBalance of Payments Crises and Devaluation,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking (May 1984), pp. 20817.

  • Officer, Lawrence H.The Productivity Bias in Purchasing Power Parity: An Econometric Investigation,” IMF Staff Papers. Vol. 23 (November 1976), pp. 54579.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Polak, J.J.Summary,” in Choosing an Exchange Rate Regime for Smaller Industrial Countries (Washington, D.C., International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Poole, W.Optimal Choice of Monetary Policy Instruments in a Simple Stochastic Macro Model,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84 (1970), pp. 197216.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Quirk, Peter J., and other Floating Exchange Rates in Developing Countries: Experience with Auction and Interbank Markets, IMF Occasional Paper 53, (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rogoff, Kenneth The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target,” Quarterly Journal of Economics (November 1985), pp. 116989.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Samuelson, Paul A., Theoretical Notes on Trade Problems,” Review of Economics and Statistics (May 1964), pp. 14554.

  • Taylor, John B., Staggered Wage Setting in a Macro Model,” American Economic Review (May 1979). pp. 10813.

  • Turnovsky, Stephen, The Relative Stability of Alternative Exchange Rate Systems in the Presence of Random Disturbances,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking (February 1976), pp. 2950.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Turnovsky, Stephen, Wage Indexation and Exchange Market Intervention in a Small Open Economy,” Canadian Journal of Economics (November 1985), pp. 57492.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wickham, Peter The Choice of Exchange Rate Regime in Developing Countries.” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 32 (June 1985), pp. 24888.

  • Williamson, John, ed., Exchange Rate Rules: The Theory, Performances and Prospects of the Crawling Peg (London: MacMillan, 1981).

  • Williamson, John, ed., A Survey of the Literature on the Optimal PegJournal of Development Economics (August 1982), pp. 3961.