Abstract

Since the mid-1980s, there has been a marked shift in the orientation of the trade and industrial policies of most developing countries90 away from a heavy reliance on direct intervention and inward-looking industrial policies toward less controlled and more export-oriented trade regimes. In a selected group of 36 regionally important developing countries that have embarked on trade reform programs since around 1985, 17 have virtually eliminated quantitative restrictions from their restrictive trade systems. Another 8 countries have maintained or further liberalized their open or somewhat open trade systems (Tables 11–13).

Since the mid-1980s, there has been a marked shift in the orientation of the trade and industrial policies of most developing countries90 away from a heavy reliance on direct intervention and inward-looking industrial policies toward less controlled and more export-oriented trade regimes. In a selected group of 36 regionally important developing countries that have embarked on trade reform programs since around 1985, 17 have virtually eliminated quantitative restrictions from their restrictive trade systems. Another 8 countries have maintained or further liberalized their open or somewhat open trade systems (Tables 1113).

Table 11.

Developing Country Trade Regimes Before Liberalization

article image
Sources: International Monetary Fund, Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions; United Nations Conference on Trade and Development; General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade.Note: FX = foreign exchange. Countries are classified based on the following criteria. In regimes with tight and significant control, quantitative restrictions (QRs) cover more than 50 percent or between 15 percent and 50 percent of imports, respectively. Relatively open regimes have QRs covering 5–15 percent of imports or QRs covering less than 5 percent of imports and maximum tariffs and charges that exceed 50 percent. An open regime has tariffs and other import taxes not greater than 50 percent and QRs covering less than 5 percent of imports. No allowance has been made for differences in the administration of QRs or the structure of tariffs that may also affect the degree of restrictiveness of the trade system.

Year immediately before trade reform. Information in the other columns refers to this year.

When available, a range of tariffs was used. If not available, the unweighted average of statutory rates or an average effective rate was used. Very high rates applied to only one or two items were disregarded. Charges were disregarded if they were applied equally to domestic and imported goods.

Quantitative restrictions include value limitations on imports through foreign exchange allocation or by the requirement that importers provide their own foreign exchange.

Percent of total imports covered by all quantitative restrictions unless otherwise specified.

In percent of total tariff code items.

Table 12.

Trade Reform Programs in Developing Countries

article image
Sources: International Monetary Fund (IMF), Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions; United Nations Conference on Trade and Development; and General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade.Note: EFF = Extended Fund facility; ESAF = enhanced structural adjustment facility; FX = foreign exchange; OGL = open general license; QRs = quantitative restrictions; SAF = structural adjustment facility; SBA = stand-by arrangement.

Main IMF program associated with the trade reform.

Included are measures implemented before May 1991. All measures have been carried out unless otherwise stated.

Rights accumulation program of the IMF.

Table 13.

Current Structure of Developing Country Trade Regimes

article image
Sources: International Monetary Fund, Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions; United Nations Conference on Trade and Development; General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade.Note: FX = foreign exchange. Countries are classified based on the following criteria. In regimes with tight and significant control, quantitative restrictions (QRs) cover more than 50 percent or between 15 percent and 50 percent of imports, respectively. Relatively open regimes have QRs covering 5–15 percent of imports or QRs covering less than 5 percent of imports and maximum tariffs and charges that exceed 50 percent. An open regime has tariffs and other import taxes not greater than 50 percent and QRs covering less than 5 percent of imports. No allowance has been made for differences in the administration of QRs or the structure of tariffs that may also affect the degree of restrictiveness of the trade system.

When available a range of tariffs is used. If not available the unweighted average of statutory rates or an average effective rate was used. Very high rates applied to only one or two items have been excluded. Charges that were applied equally to domestic and imported goods have also been excluded.

Quantitative restrictions include value limitations on imports through foreign exchange allocation or through the requirement that importers provide their own foreign exchange.

Percent of total imports covered by all quantitative restrictions unless otherwise specified.

In percent of total tariff code items.

Includes rights-of-refusal items.

Includes foreign exchange licensing and prior approval lists.

The restricted list covers 283 tariff lines and the banned list covers 818 items out of a total of 5,355. Reductions were undertaken in both categories after April 1991.

Refers to 1989.

Target, end of 1991.

Uniform tariff.

While most developing countries have made substantial progress in liberalizing their trade and trade-related exchange systems, progress across regions has been uneven. The shift in the orientation of trade policies is most striking in Latin America where almost all of the largest countries have, or are now committed to, open or relatively open trade systems. This contrasts starkly with the strong inward orientation that prevailed as late as 1984. The liberalization policies in these countries have been marked by a rapid elimination of quantitative restrictions and a clear plan for subsequent reductions in tariffs to quite low and uniform levels.91 In contrast, reforms in East and Southeast Asia, where most countries have had relatively open systems since the early 1980s, have tended to be gradual. Their reforms have progressively increased the range of sectors subject to import competition. While some low-income countries have made substantial progress in liberalizing their trade systems, many countries in Africa and South Asia have not yet opened their economies to significant foreign competition; much of the reform has focused on inputs for production, and now they face the more difficult task of liberalizing quantitative restrictions on competing products and reducing very high tariffs. Reforms are continuing and more countries are likely to adopt open trade systems in the near future. A key feature of the latest round of reforms is that they are part of an integrated package of macroeconomic and structural reforms (often supported by multilateral institutions). Trade reforms that are accompanied by appropriate supporting policies are more likely to contribute to improved economic performance and to be sustained over time.

The increased participation of developing countries in the multilateral trade system is an important development linked to recent reforms. Many Latin American countries, for example, have bound 100 percent of their tariff schedules in GATT, in part to secure the trade reforms made so far. To consolidate these achievements, reciprocal liberalization within the framework of the Uruguay Round will be important. Secure access to foreign markets in the areas where developing countries have a comparative advantage is the most beneficial way of fostering genuine trade reforms and ensuring effective use of foreign aid and financing.

Trade Policies Prior to the Mid-1980s

Two important reasons explain the predominance of restrictive regimes prior to the mid-1980s. First, the desire to protect domestic industry to foster import substitution, which was seen as essential for development. Export pessimism, in terms of market access and unfavorable terms of trade, had played an important part in providing the justification for import substitution. Under the infant industry argument, import substitution required the protection of the industrial sector, to enable it to expand and to reduce its costs through economies of scale and learning by doing. Protected manufacturing industries were expected to provide externalities, such as urban employment, a “modern” industry, and diversification of the economy away from traditional exports of primary products. Corden (1987) reviews some of the arguments for protection and Bhagwati (1988) provides a historical perspective on the various reasons for this dirigiste approach.

Second, in the context of inappropriate macro-economic policies and real exchange rate appreciation, discretionary import licensing and foreign exchange restrictions were used to limit the demand for, and allocate the supply of, foreign exchange to cope with chronic balance of payments pressures.92 In some cases this was done on an ad hoc basis; in others it was done in the context of annual import plans (e.g., India, Pakistan, and Bangladesh).93 Whalley (1989) has argued that external sector controls in many developing countries were imposed cyclically to absorb some of the fluctuations in export receipts and capital flows. For example, the external regimes of many developing countries became more restrictive in response to the first oil crisis and the collapse of commodity prices in 1973, and the subsequent 1974–75 recession, after having been liberal in the 1960s and the early 1970s. Similarly, many developing countries responded to the debt crisis and recession starting in the early 1980s by initially tightening trade and exchange restrictions.

In this connection, some 80 percent of quantitative restrictions notified to the GATT by developing countries were justified for balance of payments reasons under Article XVIII:B. In addition, a number of countries employed foreign exchange restrictions on current account transactions, particularly those with tightly controlled regimes. In many of these countries, the restrictive measures used to shelter the import-competing sector had the important indirect effect of biasing the incentive structure against agriculture as well as exports.94

A number of developing countries nevertheless undertook trade reforms before the mid-1980s, with varying intensities and with mixed results. An extensive review of some of the main cases of trade liberalization prior to the mid-1980s is contained in Michaely, Papageorgiou, and Choksi (1991). An important conclusion of this study is that the strong reforms were likely to be sustained and the weak reforms were likely to be reversed. The single most important reason for the reversal of reforms was inadequate macroeconomic policies, which led to the reimposition of licensing or exchange controls to protect the balance of payments. In many cases where first attempts at reform were weak and failed, subsequent reforms were likely to succeed if they were strong. Some of the strong reforms that succeeded were those in Chile (1974–81), Indonesia (1966–72), Sri Lanka (1977–79), and Turkey (1980–84). Korea (with reforms in 1965–67 and 1978–79) is the only developing country with reforms classified as weak that succeeded. Two important and contrasting cases in the 1970s and 1980s are Chile and Korea. Their goals of high export growth were achieved through different strategies of trade liberalization. Chile adopted a strong and rapid liberalization program and became an open economy in the late 1970s. Korea adopted gradual, sustained reforms and became a partially open economy only in the mid-1980s. In both countries, generally prudent macroeconomic policies that stressed low inflation and a realistic exchange rate were, despite some slippages, the foundation of their success.

In the sample of 36 developing countries referred to earlier, most of the countries with nonrestrictive trade systems during the early to mid-1980s performed well in the 1980s in terms of real growth of exports and output. Five of the eight countries in this category had better export growth and six had better output growth than the average for developing countries in 1983–90. Two of the countries with weak performance, Costa Rica and Uruguay, had very high tariffs to foster import substitution, yet still performed close to the Western Hemisphere average. Senegal experienced export growth well below the average for sub-Saharan Africa. It is a member of the franc zone and is relatively free of quantitative restrictions, but it had a complex system of taxes on imports that resulted in very high tax rates, and used high reference prices for a large range of imports.

Trade Policies Since the Mid-1980s

Extent of Reforms

In recent years, many developing countries pursuing structural reforms have included some trade liberalization measures. In order to assess the extent and quality of trade reforms in these countries, a review was made of trade policies in 36 countries that have implemented trade reform programs since the mid-1980s (Box 2). In all but five of the programs reviewed, trade liberalization was supported by arrangements with the Fund and in many cases by World Bank adjustment loans. Of the 36 developing countries reviewed, 28 had either a tightly controlled (21) or a significantly controlled (7) trade regime, while only 8 had either a relatively open (7) or an open (1) regime (Table 11).

Methodology Used in Trade Review

Coverage

A review of the major countries in each geographic region based on the size of trade or gross domestic product (GDP) was undertaken to assess the extent and quality of trade reforms undertaken since the mid-1980s. All but five of the countries (Brazil, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Peru)—had Fund-supported trade reform programs after the mid-1980s, Brazil, India, and Peru have recently concluded agreements with the IMF. Indonesia’s trade reforms have been supported by World Bank loans and technical assistance from the Fund to introduce a value-added tax. The Eastern European countries are not included in this sample, but their trade reform programs are reviewed in Section IV. Comprehensive reform of their trade and payments systems is a key element of their reform programs.

Measurement of Trade and Trade-Related Measures

Tariffs and other import charges are measured in this study by the predominant maximum and minimum rates. The range of tariff rates provides information on the dispersion compared with average or effective tariff rates. Effective rates of protection would have been a preferable measurement, but are not available for most countries or for recent years. High tariff rates that applied only to a few items have been excluded and if exemptions are widespread, a zero minimum tariff rate has been used, even if there was no statutory zero rate.

Nontariff barriers are measured in terms of their coverage of import values. The import values generally relate to the pattern of imports in the measured year. It would be preferable to measure the coverage in terms of import patterns that would exist in the absence of restrictions, as otherwise the items subject to the most severe restrictions would receive the least weight. In the limit, items which are prohibited or for which no licenses are issued have a zero weight. Where this problem is quite extensive the proportion of tariff code items subjected to quantitative restrictions is provided as an alternative measure.

There are other shortcomings with the use of the coverage of quantitative restrictions in terms of import values or tariff code items as an indicator of the restrictiveness of quantitative trade measures. First, although this indicator is a measure of the existence of controls, it is not a good measure of the protective impact of quantitative restrictions, given the difference in size and diversification of the domestic industries of countries. In a small country, quantitative restrictions applied to a relatively small range of import values can protect a large proportion of domestic production. Tunisia, for example, had liberalized quantitative restrictions on 70 percent of import values by early 1991; however, 70 percent of domestic production remains sheltered by quantitative restrictions. In smaller, lower-income countries, the same proportion of domestic production is likely to be protected by an even smaller import coverage of quantitative restrictions. This problem can be overcome by weighing the coverage in terms of the shares of domestic production protected by them, but this measure is not available in most countries. Second, the coverage of quantitative restrictions indicates only the existence of one or more restrictions but not the scarcity value they imply.

Trade Liberalization

Trade liberalization covers decontrol—the elimination of nontariff measures—as well as policies that shift the trade regime toward neutrality—a reduction in the bias toward a particular activity, especially the production of import substitutes.

Neutrality is defined as a situation in which the effective exchange rate for a country’s exports—nominal exchange rate adjusted for export taxes and export subsidies and tax credits—is equal to the effective exchange rate for imports-nominal exchange rate adjusted for duties and premiums resulting from quantitative restrictions (Bhagwati (1988)). An incentive system that is approximately neutral is preferable in that it fosters an efficient use of resources. Export rebates or duty-drawbacks may improve neutrality because they offset the bias against exports created by the protective system. However, export subsidies could imply a shift away from neutrality and lead to an inefficient use of resources.

Decontrol does not necessarily imply a shift toward neutrality. An example of decontrol without a move toward neutrality is the replacement of quantitative restrictions with equivalent tariffs. However, the elimination of quantitative restrictions makes trade regimes more transparent, helps to reduce rent-seeking activities, increases the price sensitivity of the trade system, and serves as the basis for subsequent tariff reductions. Another example of decontrol without a more neutral incentive structure is the removal of quantitative restrictions on inputs to import-substituting sectors without the decontrol of the final goods. This encourages the expansion of protected production and may increase the effective rate of protection for final import-competing goods.

Criteria Used to Classify Trade Regimes

For the purposes of the review of trade reforms, the following criteria were used to classify countries’ trade regimes. In regimes with tight and significant control, quantitative restrictions (QRs) cover more than 50 percent or between 15 percent and 50 percent of imports, respectively. Relatively open regimes have QRs covering 5–15 percent of imports or QRs covering less than 5 percent of imports and maximum tariffs and charges that exceed 50 percent. An open regime has tariffs and other import taxes not greater than 50 percent and QRs covering less than 5 percent of imports. No allowance has been made for differences in the administration of QRs or the structure of tariffs that may also affect the degree of restrictiveness of the trade system.

Of the 28 countries with restrictive trade systems, 17 undertook comprehensive trade reforms that resulted in relatively open or open trade regimes, while 11 implemented only partial reforms that left their domestic sectors substantially protected by quantitative restrictions (Table 12).95 The 17 countries that introduced comprehensive reforms virtually eliminated trade and payments restrictions, usually within a two-year period, leaving tariffs and surcharges as the principal means of protection; 12 countries narrowed the range of tariffs, but 5 raised tariffs or surcharges when quantitative restrictions were lifted. In the partially open countries, tariffs remained high and widely dispersed, but the initial reforms greatly improved the transparency and price sensitivity of the trade regime. Thus by the end of the period under review, 60 percent of the countries with initially restrictive trade regimes had succeeded in removing the most distorting trade barriers (Table 13). In the 11 countries that implemented minor reforms, the quality of reforms varied, but in most cases the removal of quantitative restrictions was gradual and partial, with inputs for production or noncompeting imports decontrolled first, leaving quantitative restrictions on many final products and potentially raising their effective levels of protection. Such partial reforms may increase the level of effective protection on final import-competing products, rather than reduce it.

The main instruments used to promote export growth and diversification in the programs reviewed have been adjustments to exchange rates and producer prices and tariff reforms to reduce the anti-export bias in the structure of import protection. In countries with extensive foreign exchange controls, foreign exchange retention schemes for exporters were sometimes introduced; and in some cases, special licenses were provided to exporters to import inputs or duty drawback systems were used. In general, such schemes have not effectively addressed the anti-export bias facing export industries in restrictive systems and have proved difficult to administer. In more neutral regimes, however, duty exemption schemes can play an important role.

Overall, while most countries reviewed made considerable progress in substantially eliminating quantitative restrictions on trade and payments, tariff protection still remains high in most of them. Only nine have achieved an open trade regime with few quantitative restrictions and low tariff rates. Most others continue to maintain high and widely dispersed tariff structures that hinder the efficiency of resource use and growth prospects. A high tariff level results in inefficient import substitution and raises the cost structure of the economy; the resulting higher equilibrium value of the currency acts as a general tax on the export sector. A wide dispersion in the structure of tariff rates provides greater protection for those industries with the higher tariffs, attracting scarce resources from more efficient sectors.

Issues in the Design and Implementation of Trade Reforms

Compared with trade reform programs undertaken in earlier periods,96 the programs reviewed were more frequently designed and implemented in the context of comprehensive macroeconomic and structural adjustment programs that introduced complementary measures to deregulate domestic product and factor markets and improve the efficiency of the public sector. In addition to appropriate financial and exchange rate policies, structural measures that accompanied trade liberalization commonly included measures to improve public expenditure and tax programs, reform public enterprises and marketing boards, decontrol domestic prices and financial markets, attract foreign direct investment, and reduce labor market rigidities. These measures aimed to improve the responsiveness of economic agents to relative price changes and the climate for private sector investment and thereby reduce the costs of adjustment. In turn, the liberalization of trade and payments has supported macroeconomic adjustment by fostering greater competition in the domestic market and alleviating the foreign exchange constraint; it also eliminates distortions facing many developing countries and thereby stimulates production based on comparative advantage.

There is broad agreement, which is confirmed by experience under the programs reviewed, that credible and balanced macroeconomic policies are essential to reap the benefits from trade liberalization. Where macroeconomic policies lack credibility, the need for frequent changes in policies and nominal exchange rates have led to inflationary expectations, speculative imports, and the reimposition of import restrictions (the Philippines, Zambia). In some other cases, inadequate fiscal adjustment has placed too great a burden on monetary policy, putting upward pressure on real interest rates and exchange rates and penalizing the productive sector (Argentina and other Southern Cone countries in the 1970s; and Argentina, Brazil, Jamaica, and Peru in the 1980s and early 1990s).97

In the context of comprehensive programs, an important issue is the proper sequencing of trade reforms in relation to other policies. Views differ about whether macroeconomic stabilization needs to precede trade liberalization or whether the two go hand in hand. The review of experience indicates that trade liberalization has succeeded both after (Ghana, Korea) and during macroeconomic stabilization programs (Chile, Mexico, Venezuela).98 While the choice in sequencing depends on the initial conditions in the country concerned, the international economic environment, and the overall program design, there is a growing consensus that high priority should be given to trade reform at an early stage in the adjustment effort (Table 14). Financial, exchange rate, and wage policies are essential to the adjustment process, but when these policies are complemented by the liberalization of the trade and payments regime, a more efficient framework for restoring a viable external position can be achieved.

Table 14.

Trade Liberalization, Stabilization, or Both

article image
Source: Based on Table 4.1 in Operations Evaluation Departments, World Bank Support for Trade Policy Reform, Report No. 9527 (Washington: World Bank, 1991).

The interaction between the government budget and the various stages of trade reform needs to be considered when a trade liberalization program is designed. This includes both the direct fiscal impact of changes in trade-related taxes and the indirect effects of changes in budgetary receipts and payments owing to a possible initial contraction in economic activity and employment and the provision of safety net benefits.99 The initial stages of trade reform, when quantitative restrictions are replaced by tariffs and tariff exemptions are eliminated, can complement fiscal adjustment. However, in countries that depend heavily on import taxes, a reform of the domestic tax system is required before tariffs can be brought down to a sustainable basis. Of the countries reviewed, a number that have successfully liberalized have introduced value-added tax systems to broaden the domestic tax base (Indonesia, Mexico). Some others have delayed tariff reductions (Bolivia, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, Thailand) or introduced surcharges (Chile and Morocco) for revenue reasons.

Appropriate exchange rate policies are also essential to ensure that trade reforms are consistent with balance of payments objectives. Because the equilibrium exchange rate is partly determined by the degree of import restrictiveness, major reform programs often involve an exchange rate adjustment; ultimately, the choice of exchange rate policy will depend on initial conditions and the other elements of the macroeconomic program. In the sample reviewed, all but two of the programs that resulted in relatively neutral trade regimes with low tariffs were associated with a substantial devaluation of the nominal exchange rate at about the time trade reforms were initiated, which resulted in a real effective depreciation that was sustained by policies thereafter. Korea’s trade reform program, which was gradual and preannounced, was not associated with a major exchange rate adjustment.

As discussed above, the scope and pace of liberalization programs has varied significantly across geographic regions. Recent trade reform programs in Latin America and Eastern Europe have been comprehensive and relatively quick, while those in Southeast Asia have been gradual and most reforms in Africa and South Asia are not yet complete. It is difficult to assess at this stage whether the “big bang” or the gradual approach will be more enduring; however, an important measure of success has been achieved by countries that have substantially completed the liberalization process using either approach. Bolivia, Chile, and Venezuela in Latin America, and the dynamic Asian economies have all had considerable success in sustaining their earlier reforms.

There are strong indications that the completeness and the credibility of a reform program are the most important factors for success. Elements of trade reform programs that have contributed to sustained liberalization include the preannouncement of the timing and scope of reforms, the early removal of quantitative restrictions, the reduction of tariff levels and dispersion, and complementary domestic price, tax, and public enterprise reforms. Locking in reforms in various ways also enhances credibility. Many countries in Latin America have bound their entire tariff schedules in the GATT; Chile introduced an amendment to its constitution forbidding the use of quantitative import restrictions; and countries that adopt a relatively uniform tariff schedule may find it easier to resist pressures for protection from special interest groups.

The economic effects of trade liberalization are difficult to disentangle from the effects of other policies, but the evidence from a number of comprehensive studies indicates that the long-run effects of trade liberalization on output and employment growth, trade expansion, and the balance of payments were beneficial.100 A recent comparison by the IMF of the trade orientation and growth performance of 41 developing countries showed that during 1975–89, the outward-oriented countries achieved, on average, significantly higher growth rates of potential GDP and of total factor productivity than the inward-oriented countries.101 The review of countries’ trade reform programs also indicates that most of the countries that had open or relatively open trade regimes in the early 1980s have performed well in terms of the growth of output and exports and have avoided serious balance of payments problems.

Although trade liberalization has been shown to be beneficial in the longer run, shorter-run adjustment costs are likely to be incurred when formerly protected sectors are exposed to import competition. The elimination of price controls and rationing, which frequently accompanies trade reforms, can also put basic necessities out of reach of the poorest segments of the population. In these circumstances, public support for reforms can be enhanced and transition costs reduced by policies that improve external competitiveness, facilitate adjustment in labor markets, and target safety net benefits to the most needy.

Trade Liberalization Versus Export Promotion and Selective Intervention

Trade liberalization is now considered a more efficient instrument for promoting export diversification than some of the earlier schemes used for this purpose. These included export subsidies for nontraditional exports, including cash subsidies and income rebates, which were common in Latin America before the recent reforms, or duty relief schemes, which have assisted a large range of exports in Korea and relatively open countries, such as Indonesia and Malaysia. In the absence of a relatively open trade system, these schemes have not generally been successful in that by and large such countries did not reduce their reliance on traditional exports during the 1960s and 1970s. Export processing zones have been set up in a large range of countries to enable certain export production to avoid domestic taxes and restrictions altogether; however, their contribution to exports has been significant in only a few cases.

Competition provided by the liberalization of imports of final products can serve as part of an anti-inflation policy and can promote the adjustment of real wages needed to strengthen export competitiveness. In a protected industry, enterprises often give wage increases to workers to compensate for devaluation-induced price increases, rather than face industrial unrest. Competition from imports can induce greater restraint on the part of firms and workers. This objective has been an important part of the trade liberalization programs in Latin America as well as in Eastern Europe.

Despite the widespread shift to more market-oriented policies some development economists and governments advocate selective intervention in the economy through trade and industrial policies. The economic reform programs supported by the Fund and the World Bank envisage a strong and active role for governments in creating an environment for efficient economic activities, rather than the government intervening in the economy to “pick winners.”102 Proponents of selective intervention justify it on the basis of market failures or strategic needs. They envisage protection of a few sectors via planning, directed credit, or import allocation to create internationally competitive industries.103 Many of the arguments in favor of intervention are simply variations of the infant industry argument. Counterarguments stress that the choice of which industry to support requires a great deal of information as well as impartial and nonpolitical decision making. Since market prospects can change rapidly, such decisions have to be taken quickly while avoiding the temptation to prolong support to industries that are unprofitable. The possible gains from the few industries that may succeed have to be weighed against the large potential looses from incorrect decisions.

Issues & Development in intl. Trade
  • Anderson, Kym,The International Dimension of the Political Economy of Agricultural Policy,paper presented at a conference on International Dimensions to Structural Adjustment: Implications for Developing Country Agriculture (Paris, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anderson, Kym, and Rod Tyers,How Developing Countries Could Gain from Agricultural Trade Liberalization in the Uruguay Round,in Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries, ed. by Ian Goldin and Odin Knudsen (Paris: OECD Development Center, 1990), pp. 4775.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Australian Industry Commission, Strategic Trade Theory: The East Asian Experience (Canberra: Industry Commission, November 1990).

  • Balassa, Bela,Comparative Advantage in Manufactured Goods: A Reappraisal,Review of Economics and Statistics (May 1986), No. 68, pp. 31519.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balassa, Bela, and M. Noland, Japan in the World Economy (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1988).

  • Banks, Gary, Australia’s Antidumping Experience, PRE Working Paper No. 551 (Washington: World Bank, December 1990).

  • Barton, John H., “Toward an International Antitrust Code” (mimeograph, Stanford, California: Stanford International Center for Law and High Technology, July 1, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baumol, William J., and Kyu Sik Lee,Contestable Markets, Trade, and Development,in World Bank Research Observer (Washington), Vol. 6, (January 1991), pp. 117.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bell, A.,Antidumping Practice of the EEC: The Japanese Dimension,Legal Issues of European Integration (Deventer, Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers, 1987), pp. 131.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bergsten, C. Fred, and William R. Cline, The United States-Japan Economic Problem, Policy Analysis in International Economics 13 (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhagwati, Jagdish,Export-Promoting Strategy: Issues and Evidence,World Bank Research Observer (Washington), Vol. 3 (1988), pp. 2756.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhagwati, Jagdish, The World Trading System at Risk (Hamel Hempstead, England: Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1991).

  • Blejer, M., and A. Cheasty, “Fiscal Implications of Trade Liberalization,” in Fiscal Policy in Open Developing Economies, ed. by V. Tanzi (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boote, Anthony R., and Janos Somogyi, “Economic Reform in Hungary Since 1968,” IMF Occasional Paper, No. 83 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, July 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brander, James A., and Barbara J. Spencer,Export Subsidies and International Market Share Rivalry,Journal of International Economics (Amsterdam), Vol. 18 (February 1985), pp. 83100.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Broome, John,Recent Developments in Trans-Tasman Business Law,paper prepared for the 17th International Trade Law Conference (September 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burniaux, Jean Marc, Dominique van der Mensbrugghe, and Jean Waelbroeck, “Economy-Wide Effects of Agricultural Policies in OECD Countries: A GE Approach Using the WALRAS Model,” in Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries, ed. by Ian Goldin and Odin Knudsen (Paris: OECD Development Center, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Jacob A. Frenkel,From Centrally Planned to Market Economy,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 38 (June 1991), pp. 26899.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Canada, Bureau of Competition Policy, Europe 1992, Working Group Report on Competition Policy (Ottawa, January 1991).

  • Centre for Economic Policy Research, Monitoring European Integration: The Impact of Eastern Europe, CEPR Annual Report (London: CEPR, October 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Citrin, Daniel A., “Agricultural Policies in Japan and Their Economic Consequences,” in Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cline, William, The Future of World Trade in Textiles and Apparel (Washington: Institute for International Economics, rev. ed., 1990).

  • Cline, William, and S. Weintraub, eds., Economic Stabilization in Developing Countries (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1981).

  • Collins, Susan M., and Dan T. Rodrik, Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union in the World Economy, Policy Analysis in International Economics 32 (Washington: Institute for International Economics, May 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Collyns, Charles, and Steven Dunaway,The Cost of Trade Restraints: The Case of Japanese Automobile Exports to the United States,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 34 (March 1987), pp. 15075.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corbo, Vittorio, Morris Goldstein, and Mohsin Khan, eds., Growth-Oriented Adjustment Programs (Washington: International Monetary Fund and The World Bank, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corden, W.M., Protection and Liberalization: A Review of Analytical Issues, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 54 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corker, Robert,The Changing Structure of Japanese Trade Flows,IMF Working Paper, WP/90/107 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deardorff, Alan V.,Should Patent Protection Be Extended to All Developing Countries?in The World Economy, Vol. 13 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell Ltd., 1990), pp. 497507.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deardorff, Alan V., and Robert Stern, Computational Analysis of Global Trading Arrangements (Ann Arbor, Michigan: The University of Michigan Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de C. Grey, Rodney,The Conflict between Trade Policy and Competition Policy: A Comment,in Studies in Transnational Economic Law, The New GATT Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations, Legal and Economic Problems, ed. by Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann and Meinhard Hilf, Vol. 5 (Deventer, Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers, 1988), pp. 44753.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de la Torre, Augusto, and Margaret R. Kelly, Regional Trade Arrangements, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 93 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Melo, Jaime, and David Tarr, Welfare Costs of U.S. Quotas on Textiles, Steel and Autos, PPR Working Paper, No. 83 (Washington: The World Bank, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “Economic Declaration of the London Summit,” International Trade Reporter (Washington), Vol. 8 (July 24, 1991), p. 1128.

  • European Report, No. 1704 (1991).

  • Farhadian-Lorie, Z., and M. Katz, “Fiscal Dimensions of Trade Policy,” in Fiscal Policy, Stabilization and Growth in Developing Countries, ed. by M. Blejer and Ke-Young Chu (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feenstra, R.,Automobile Prices and Protection: The U.S.-Japan Trade Restraint,Journal of Policy Modelling, Vol. 7 (Spring 1985), pp. 4968.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feketekuty, Geza (1991a), “Changes in the World Economy and Implications for the World Trading System” (mimeograph, Washington: Office of U.S. Trade Representative, June 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feketekuty, Geza (1991b), “Beyond the Uruguay Round,IMF Survey (Washington), Vol. 20, (July 15, 1991), pp. 209.

  • Finger, J. Michael, “Antidumping and Antisubsidy Measures,” in The Uruguay Round: A Handbook on the Multilateral Trade Negotiations, ed. by J. Michael Finger and Andrzej Olechowski (Washington: The World Bank, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Finger, J. Michael, and Patrick A. Messerlin, The Effects of Industrial Countries’ Policies on Developing Countries, Policy and Research Series (Washington: The World Bank, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Finger, J. Michael, and Julio Nogues,International Control of Subsidies and Countervailing Duties,World Bank Economic Review (Washington), Vol. 1 (September 1987), pp. 70725.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley,Issues in Medium-Term Macroeconomic Adjustment,World Bank Research Observer (Washington), Vol. 1 (July 1986), pp. 16382.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley,Economic Growth and Economic Policy,in Growth-Oriented Adjustment Programs, ed. by Vittorio Corbo and others (Washington: International Monetary Fund and The World Bank, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley,Comments on Lipton and Sachs,Brookings Papers on Economic Activity I (1990), p. 147.

  • Ford, Robert, and Wim Suyker,Industrial Subsidies in the OECD Economies,OECD Economic Studies (Paris), No. 15 (Autumn 1990), pp. 3781.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frohberg, Klaus, G. Fischer, and K.S. Parikh, “World Developing Countries Benefit from Agricultural Trade Liberalization in OECD Countries,” in Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries, ed. by Ian Goldin and Odin Knudsen (Paris: OECD Development Center, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gelb, Alan H., and Cheryl W. Gray, “The Transformation of Economies in Central and Eastern Europe: Issues, Progress, and Prospects” (mimeograph, Washington: The World Bank, Country Economics Department, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Genberg, Hans,On Sequencing Reforms in Eastern Europe,IMF Working Paper, WP/91/13 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, February 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1989a), Council Overview of Developments in the International Trading Environment, Annual Report by the Director General, C/RM/OV/1 (Geneva: GATT, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1989b), Trade Policy Review, Australia 1989 (Geneva: GATT, March 1989).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1989c), Trade Policy Review, United States 1989 (Geneva: GATT, November 1989).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1990a), International Trade 89–90, Vols. I and II (Geneva: GATT, 1990).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1990b), Trade Policy Review, Sweden 1990 (Geneva: GATT, August 1990).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1990c), Trade Policy Review, Canada 1990 (Geneva: GATT, November 1990).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1990d), Trade Policy Review, Japan 1990 (Geneva: GATT, November 1990).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1990e), Trade Policy Review, New Zealand 1990 (Geneva: GATT, November 1990).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1991a), Council Overview of Developments in International Trade and the Trading System, Annual Report by the Director General, C/RM/OV/1 (Geneva: GATT, June 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1991b), Trade Policy Review, European Communities 1991 (Geneva: GATT, March 1991).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1991c), Council Overview of Developments in International Trade and the Trading System, Annual Report by the Director General, C/RM/OV/2 (Geneva: GATT, April 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1991d), Council Overview of Developments in International Trade and the Trading System, Annual Report by the Director General, C/RM/OV/1 (Geneva: GATT, June 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldberg, Linda, and Janusz Ordover, Nontariff Barriers and Trade and Competition: Theory and Evidence, Note for the Secretariat (Paris: OECD, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldin, Ian, and Odin Knudsen, eds., Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries (Paris: OECD Development Center, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Graham, Edward M., and J. David Richardson,Global Competition Policies” (Washington: Institute for International Economics, forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greer, Douglas F., Efficiency and Competition: Alternative, Complementary or Conflicting Objectives, Research Monograph 47 (Wellington, New Zealand: Institute of Economic Research Inc., March 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grossman, Gene M., Promoting New Industrial Activities: A Survey of Recent Arguments and Evidence, OECD Economic Studies (Paris), No. 14 (Spring 1990), pp. 87125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gruen, Fred Henry, Review of the Customs Tariff (Anti-Dumping) Act 1975 (Canberra, Australia: Canberra Publishing & Printing Co., March 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Harris, D., and others, Effects of the Liberalization of North Asian Beef Import Policies, ABARE, Discussion Paper No. 90.11 (Canberra, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Havrylyshyn, Oleh, and Lanit Pritchett,Direction of Trade After Transition in East Europe: Predictions from a Gravity Model,draft (May 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Havrylyshyn, Oleh, and David G. Tarr, Trade Liberalization and the Transition to Market Economy (Washington: The World Bank, 1991).

  • Hufbauer, Gary C., Diane Berliner, and Kimberly Ann Elliott, Trade Protection in the United States: 31 Case Studies (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hufbauer, Gary C., Jeffrey J. Schott, and Kimberly A. Elliott, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: Historical Current Policy (Washington: Institute of International Economics, 2d ed., 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Huff, H. Bruce, and Catherine Moreddu,The Ministerial Trade Mandate Model,OECD Economic Studies, No. 13 (Winter 1989–90), pp. 4567.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, “The Role of Structural Policies in Industrial Countries,” in Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, August 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, (1990a), World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1990).

  • International Monetary Fund, (1990b), World Economic Outlook, Staff Studies (Washington: International Monetary Fund, August 1990).

  • International Monetary Fund, (1990c), World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1990).

  • International Monetary Fund, (1991a), World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1991).

  • International Monetary Fund, (1991b), World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1991).

  • International Monetary Fund, The World Bank, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, and European Bank for Reconstruction Development, The Economy of USSR, a study undertaken in response to a request by the Houston Summit (1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Trade Reporter (Washington), Vol. 8 (October 2, 1991) and (July 17, 1991).

  • Jackson, John H., World Trade and the Law of GATT (Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill, 1969).

  • Jackson, John H., The World Trading System: Law and Policy of International Economic Relations (Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jacquemin, Alexis, and others, Merger and Competition Policy in the European Community, ed. by P.H. Admiral (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, Inc., 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Japan Economic Institute, “The Structure of Japan’s Imports: Causes and Consequences,JEI Report, No. 22A (Washington, June 14, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Japan, Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry, and Fishing, “Basic Direction of Japan’s Agricultural Policy Toward the 21st Century,Agricultural Review, Vol. 15 (1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Julius, DeAnne S., Foreign Direct Investment: The Neglected Twin of Trade, Occasional Papers 33 (Washington: Group of Thirty, 1991).

  • Junz, Helen B.,Integration of Eastern Europe into the World Trading System,The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 81 (May 1991), pp. 17680.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kelly, Margaret, and others, Issues and Developments in International Trade Policy, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 63 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kenen, Peter B.,Transitional Arrangements for Trade and Payments Among the CMEA Countries,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 38 (June 1991), pp. 23567.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Koulen, Mark,Potential Anti-Trust Liability of Exporters Participating in Various Forms of Export Restraint Arrangements,in Studies in Transnational Economic Law, The New GATT Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations, Legal and Economic Problems, ed. by Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann and Meinhard Hilf, Vol. 5 (Deventer, Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers, 1988), pp. 43746.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krissoff, Barry, John Sullivan, and John Wainio,Developing Countries in an Open Economy: The Case of Agriculture,in Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries, ed. by Ian Goldin and Odin Knudsen (Paris: OECD Development Center, 1990), pp. 15979.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, Anne, Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development: Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Ballinger Publishing Company, 1978).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation