Abstract

In the past few years. Eastern European countries have initiated and in some cases accelerated comprehensive reform programs designed to transform their economic systems rapidly into market-based economies.47 Liberalization of the trade and exchange system is an important component of these reforms. All six countries have eliminated the state monopoly of foreign trade, substantially reduced quantitative restrictions, and moved toward a trade regime in which price-based measures (tariffs and exchange rates) are the main trade policy instruments. Export subsidies, except those on some agricultural products, have been removed, and export licensing has been reduced significantly. In parallel with the removal of trade restrictions, all six countries have established the essential elements of convertibility for current international transactions although some restrictions remain in place.

In the past few years. Eastern European countries have initiated and in some cases accelerated comprehensive reform programs designed to transform their economic systems rapidly into market-based economies.47 Liberalization of the trade and exchange system is an important component of these reforms. All six countries have eliminated the state monopoly of foreign trade, substantially reduced quantitative restrictions, and moved toward a trade regime in which price-based measures (tariffs and exchange rates) are the main trade policy instruments. Export subsidies, except those on some agricultural products, have been removed, and export licensing has been reduced significantly. In parallel with the removal of trade restrictions, all six countries have established the essential elements of convertibility for current international transactions although some restrictions remain in place.

Notwithstanding these reforms, the Eastern European countries are not yet fully integrated into the multilateral trade system. Further progress in this area will depend, inter alia, on (i) further progress in their own systemic reforms; and (ii) increased and more secure access to foreign markets, particularly those of industrial countries. The latter is of particular importance given the collapse of trade among former members of the CMEA, the adverse impact of the Middle East conflict on some of these countries, and the rapid deterioration in economic conditions in most of Eastern Europe.

At the London economic summit in July 1991 the heads of state and government of the Group of Seven and the representatives of the European Community recognized that opening their markets was the most effective way to assist Eastern European and other developing countries. They undertook to bring the Uruguay Round to an “ambitious” conclusion and to improve access to industrial country markets, including in sectors such as agriculture, steel, and textiles and clothing. As major industrial countries are reluctant to reduce barriers in these sectors unilaterally, the outcome of the Uruguay Round is critical to the success of reforms in Eastern Europe. Greater security of access to foreign markets for Eastern Europe is also linked to negotiations to revise the conditions of their membership within GATT to reflect the greater market orientation of their economies.

Historical Setting: Trade Policy in the Context of Central Planning

After World War II, the Eastern European countries were reorganized under the influence of the U.S.S.R. system of central planning. This process was largely completed by 1950 and involved large-scale nationalization of the means of production and distribution, and the introduction of a central planning system to set output targets, prices and wages, and to allocate resources among enterprises.

The coordination of imports and exports was an integral part of the central planning process. The composition and level of trade were influenced by a number of control mechanisms including central allocation of foreign exchange, and licensing. Foreign trade organizations were established and had a state monopoly on foreign trade. Firms did not trade directly with their foreign counterparts or face world prices; they exported and imported products through foreign trade organizations at ruling domestic prices, with the difference between international and domestic prices being absorbed (in the case of losses) or taxed (in the case of profits) by the government budget. Thus, although tariffs were generally low, central-plan tools and exchange controls provided a high level of protection for domestic production.

Trade with other centrally planned economies and market economies involved different arrangements. The former was largely undertaken in non-convertible currencies within the arrangements of the CMEA.48 This trade was based on five-year bilateral agreements with annual negotiations to agree on prices and other details.49 A bilateral surplus with one country could not be used to finance a bilateral deficit with another country. Trade with market economies was undertaken mainly in convertible currencies and was subject to state control.

The CMEA arrangements resulted in a considerable increase in trade among member countries but also created strong structural dependencies among member countries and added to distortions in resource allocation.50 Although some Eastern European countries were quite open, in terms of the ratio of trade to GDP, their trade was highly concentrated in transactions with other centrally planned economies, in particular the former U.S.S.R.51

The commodity composition of CMEA trade with socialist countries (mostly in the CMEA area) differed significantly from that with the market economies (Tables A20 and A21).52 Machinery and transport equipment were the most important exports to socialist countries; while food, crude materials, and manufactured articles generally were the most important exports to industrial countries. The Eastern European countries exported mainly machinery equipment and other manufactures to the former U.S.S.R. in exchange for fuels and raw materials. Although the arbitrariness of cross exchange rates used between transferable rubles and local currencies complicates the analysis, it is generally agreed that until recently the prices of Eastern European exports to the former U.S.S.R., relative to the world market prices, were set more favorably than were the prices of Eastern European imports from the former U.S.S.R., relative to world market prices. Given the importance of the former U.S.S.R. in their total trade (and provided trade patterns were unchanged), this implied that the overall terms of trade of Eastern European countries were quite favorable compared with what they would have been without the CMEA arrangements; it has been estimated that moving to world market prices would involve a terms of trade deterioration in the range of 20 to 30 percent for Eastern Europe.53

Some Eastern European countries had undertaken partial economic reforms prior to the political revolution that swept Eastern Europe in 1989. For the most part, these reforms were undertaken within the context of the socialist system, and they attempted economic decentralization and partial decontrol of prices while retaining social ownership of the means of production.54 But market freedom remained circumscribed by state orders and remaining price controls. Although planners no longer exerted total control over trade, central planning tools and administrative control measures continued to dictate trade flows and patterns. The absence of private property rights limited the role of profit incentives and discouraged entrepreneurship.

Recent Reforms and Design Issues

Recent Reforms

While the extent of reform and the initial conditions have varied considerably across Eastern Europe, the process of systemic change has accelerated during the past two years.55 After decades of partial reforms, Hungary, Poland, and Yugoslavia accelerated their reform efforts in 1989, and in 1990 Poland implemented more far-reaching reform measures. Although their systems remained more centralized up to 1990, in early 1991, Czechoslovakia, Bulgaria, and Romania began to implement comprehensive reforms. In all countries, reforms are being supported by financial resources and technical assistance provided by the Fund and the World Bank.

A move toward currency convertibility and more open trade regimes are important components of reform in all Eastern European countries.56 As of June 1991, most of these countries had substantially liberalized their trade and payments systems (Table 6). In parallel with the removal of trade restrictions, all countries have established a degree of convertibility, although some restrictions remain in place. In Hungary and Poland, convertibility is largely limited to the enterprise sector, and most countries have maintained limits on travel allowances.57 Most countries have a unified official exchange rate for commercial transactions; in the 1980s Hungary, Poland, and Yugoslavia unified official exchange rates for trade with the convertible currency area, and Poland and Yugoslavia gradually eliminated various exchange subsidies, the level of which was dependent (except in the case of Hungary) on the end-user of foreign exchange. Bulgaria and Czechoslovakia unified exchange rates for commercial transactions between December 1990 and February 1991. In Czechoslovakia, Hungary, Poland, and Romania residents are authorized to hold foreign currency accounts and use them freely. In Yugoslavia, convertibility was largely established in January 1990, but various restrictions, including limitations on withdrawals from foreign currency accounts, were reintroduced toward the end of the year when foreign exchange reserves dwindled. All countries permit inward foreign investment and repatriation of dividends and profits.

Table 6.

Trade and Payments Systems of Eastern European Countries as of June 19911

article image
article image
Source: Various IMF documents.

For Yugoslavia, as of December 1990, and for Czechoslovakia, as of October 1, 1991.

In July 1991, further price liberalization resulted in only 14 items that are subject to price control.

In the trade area, all six countries have eliminated the state monopoly on foreign trade and drastically reduced quantitative import restrictions.58 In Yugoslavia, the share of liberalized imports increased from 15 percent in 1986 to 88 percent by the end of 1990. In Hungary, 90 percent of imports are being liberalized over a three-year period starting 1989, with most having been liberalized by 1990. In Romania, all quantitative restrictions have been eliminated. In Poland, most nontariff restrictions were removed in January 1990, Czechoslovakia virtually eliminated import licensing in January 1991, and Bulgaria eliminated import licensing except for a small negative list of imports, in February 1991.59

The elimination of most implicit and explicit nontariff barriers and the liberalization of exchange controls means that tariffs and exchange rates have become the principal trade policy instruments in these countries. Traditionally, the level of tariffs in Eastern Europe was relatively low and domestic industry was effectively protected by central planning tools. While some modifications in tariff rates and structures have been made, average tariff rates in these countries remain relatively low.60

Modifications in tariffs include the following: Poland unified its three commercial and noncommercial customs tariffs schedules (January 1990) and suspended customs duties (June 1990) on 4,500 import items until July 31, 1991. Poland recently restructured its tariff schedule to provide an average rate of about 14 percent, including a virtual across-the-board temporary surcharge of 5 percent; this is significantly above the rate that prevailed prior to suspension of some tariffs in June 1990. Yugoslavia reduced tariff rates and the number of items exempted from tariffs, which left the average effective tariff rate largely unchanged (March 1990). Romania eliminated various discriminatory features in its tariff system, such as the application of different tariff rates depending on the end use of imports and reduced its highest rates (January 1991); a further reduction in the average tariff level and a more simplified tariff structure are expected to be introduced in the second half of 1991. Czechoslovakia introduced a temporary surcharge of 20 percent on consumer goods imports (end of 1990) to mitigate the impact of rapid import liberalization on the balance of payments;61 the rate was reduced to 15 percent in June 1991 and is to be eliminated by the end of 1991. Bulgaria introduced a temporary surtax of 15 percent on imports of consumer and some other goods (early 1991) to provide protection to industries as they restructure and to safeguard the balance of payments. Major reviews of the tariff and protective structure have been initiated by Bulgaria and Czechoslovakia in consultation with the World Bank. Further adjustments are contemplated in tariffs in some countries in the context of multilateral and bilateral negotiations.

Measures have also been taken to liberalize exports. Most export subsidies have been removed and export licensing has been significantly reduced in most countries. However, some restrictions remain in place in all Eastern European countries, in particular, to comply with VERs and quotas applied by trading partners in sectors such as textiles and clothing, agriculture, steel, and coal. In addition, temporary export bans were introduced (Bulgaria in 1990) and licensing retained (Czechoslovakia) to ensure adequate domestic supplies of products such as foodstuffs and raw materials during the adjustment process62 and to prevent the export (or re-export) of products that are subject to domestic price controls or imported at the official exchange rate (Romania).

At its 1990 meeting in Sofia, the CMEA announced that it intended to conduct all trade in convertible currencies and at world market prices beginning January 1, 1991. However, with the collapse of CMEA trade, countries have made or are making arrangements aimed at maintaining some minimum level of trade with former CMEA countries, especially the Commonwealth of Independent States (Table 7). Poland, Bulgaria, and Czechoslovakia negotiated agreements with the former U.S.S.R. that contain a selective “indicative list” of tradable goods and barter trade. Hungary and Romania are also seeking to boost trade with the former U.S.S.R. through the use of bilateral trade arrangements that may involve barter trade. In June 1991, the former U.S.S.R. lifted the ban on barter trade that applied during the first several months of 1991.

Table 7.

Bilateral Trade Arrangements Between Eastern European Countries and the Former U.S.S.R.1

article image
Source: Based on information provided by national authorities.

Following the dissolution of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (CMEA), and the breakdown of trade among former members, the former U.S.S.R. announced its intention to return to clearing arrangements in national currencies with former CMEA countries. The former U.S.S.R. has allowed its banks to establish correspondent accounts in national currencies with banks in Czechoslovakia and Poland, which would serve for settlement in national currencies of certain trade in goods and services, including tourism expenditure.

By and large, the Eastern European countries now have relatively open trade and payments systems. However, with the collapse of CMEA trade and the deterioration in their domestic economies and external accounts, some of these countries are facing pressure to provide protection for domestic producers.63 In addition, partly in response to access difficulties in industrial country markets and EC export subsidies, some of the Eastern European countries have introduced measures to protect their agricultural sectors. In Czechoslovakia (pending amendments to customs tariffs and other forms of protection), export subsidies and import quotas were introduced on agricultural products in June 1991 to deal with mounting surplus production. Poland has reintroduced tariffs on some agricultural products, under pressure from its farm lobby.

Issues in the Design of Trade Reform

A broad consensus has emerged both on the need for a rapid and comprehensive reform in Eastern Europe and on the main elements of such a reform package.64 The latter include macroeconomic stabilization and control; liberalization of trade and establishment of convertibility for current account transactions; price liberalization and the development of a competitive private enterprise sector; the creation of efficient financial institutions and the liberalization of financial markets; deregulation of labor markets, and the establishment of a social safety net. Reform programs must be credible and specify the long-term objectives and transition path at the outset of the reform.65

Within this context, there is a broad consensus that trade liberalization should be implemented early in the reform process66 An accelerated pace of trade liberalization in reforming socialist economies is considered essential because, compared with market economies, relative prices are highly distorted, factor markets function poorly, domestic production is more highly concentrated, the extent of state ownership is much greater, and trade has been distorted by arrangements among former CMEA members.67 In these circumstances, liberalization of the trade and payments system helps to establish a rational set of relative prices for traded goods and to prevent distortions due to monopolistic pricing and the loss of productive efficiency. In addition, access to imports and foreign investment facilitates the acquisition of foreign technology.

Notwithstanding the above considerations, it has been suggested that temporary tariff protection might be provided in the short run to avoid the move to world prices being disruptive. McKinnon (1991a), for example, notes that enterprises in Eastern Europe have long faced distorted relative prices and argues that the tariff structure should initially continue to provide some protection to those industries that were heavily protected under the old system; this would involve differential tariff increases—not across-the-board surcharges—for industries that would be viable if provided a temporary adjustment period.68 Tariffs would subsequently be unified and phased down according to a preannounced schedule. In this connection, it has been noted that devaluation is not an option because it increases the price of all goods, including inputs for production, which would still result in negative value added in certain industries under the new world price structure.69

Others point out that consideration of the above approach also needs to take into account its potential costs and risks, as well as any GATT implications.70 In particular, this approach has risks if the preannounced schedule of tariff reductions lacks credibility; a perception that the weakened links between domestic and world relative prices could be extended for longer periods would reduce pressure for adjustment in precisely those enterprises facing the largest adjustment tasks and delay their integration into the world economy; in this context, even if a schedule is preannounced, a phased approach would allow time for political opposition to further liberalization to be mobilized. Apart from these considerations, experience elsewhere suggests that governments are not well placed to determine which industries are likely to be viable over the medium term. In addition, high average tariff rates, whatever the degree of dispersion, act as a tax on exports. A final point of particular importance to reforming socialist economies is that this approach would partly negate the positive contribution trade liberalization can make toward eliminating distortions due to monopolistic market structures.

Tariffs have been increased in some cases to protect the balance of payments, to reduce budget deficits (Bulgaria and Poland), and to discourage imports of consumer goods. Those who argue against the use of tariffs for these purposes note that devaluation supported by appropriate fiscal and monetary policies is normally a better option to protect the balance of payments and contain inflation, in that it provides a neutral incentive structure,71 and that domestic taxes are a less distortionary instrument to increase fiscal revenue and discourage consumption.

To the extent that the domestic tax instruments and other indirect policy instruments necessary for macroeconomic control are not in place, however, and that the administrative capacity to put such systems in place quickly is lacking, some temporary increases in tariffs may be unavoidable.72 In this connection, as a mechanism to control the balance of payments, price-based measures, such as tariffs, are preferable to quotas and other quantitative restrictions, in that they are more transparent and, provided tariffs are not prohibitive, they maintain the link between domestic and international prices.

As indicated above, Eastern European countries have negotiated or are seeking new bilateral trade and barter agreements with the former U.S.S.R. or the Commonwealth of Independent States (and in some cases with other former CMEA countries) as a way of cushioning the impact of the collapse of CMEA trade. In the current circumstances, with the collapse of trade due to the shortage of foreign exchange and disorganization in the Commonwealth of Independent States, these arrangements are considered necessary to maintain a certain level of trade and avoid unnecessary enterprise closure. In most cases, barter trade appears to involve inter-enterprise arrangements. These agreements tend to sustain the distorted production structures and trade flows and to delay the process of adjustment. To limit the possible adverse effects of such arrangements, it has been suggested that where they involve government agreements, they should ensure that they do not limit the autonomy of individual enterprises to negotiate with the foreign enterprises and that trade is conducted at world market prices and imbalances settled in convertible currencies within a relatively short period.73

With the collapse of CMEA, interest has re-emerged in regional clearing and payment arrangements covering Eastern Europe alone or together with the Commonwealth of Independent States. Two basic alternatives have been suggested: (i) a simple clearing arrangement with a relatively short interval between settlement dates (one to three months); and (ii) payments arrangements, where clearing is supplemented by a facility that provides short (one year) or even medium-term credit to the participants—similar to the European Payment Union (EPU) after World War II.74 It is widely recognized, however, that there are large differences between the postwar situation in Western Europe and the present situation in Eastern Europe. In particular, the combined market size of Eastern Europe is relatively small; the combined trade of Eastern Europe (in both convertible and nonconvertible currencies) was estimated at less than 4 percent of total world trade in 1988, while members of the EPU accounted for about 35 percent of world exports in 1950.75 Even if the former U.S.S.R. is included, the combined market size covered is relatively small;76 moreover, to the extent that trade with the former U.S.S.R. has been interrupted by administrative problems, there is great uncertainty regarding new clearing schemes that rely on better administration and communications. Thus, while such schemes may be somewhat less distortionary than bilateral ones, they are unlikely to resolve the underlying problems and could slow the process of integration of former CMEA countries into the international trade system.

Integration into the Multilateral Trading System

The full integration of the Eastern European countries into the multilateral trade system will depend on (i) further progress in their own systemic reforms; and (ii) increased and more secure access to Western markets. While the trade reforms already implemented will take time to have their full impact, further domestic reforms to make markets more competitive are required to enable Eastern Europe to realize the full benefits of the exchange and trade reforms recently implemented. In this connection, privatization, the development of competitive factor markets, and the establishment of the legal framework necessary to secure a competitive market environment are of particular importance.

As the Eastern European countries reform their economies, their trade expansion and changing trade pattern will need to be accommodated mainly by western industrial markets. Several recent studies estimate that, with the disappearance of the CMEA arrangements and the transition to market economies, the pattern of trade of Eastern Europe would be substantially changed, shifting from centrally planned economies to industrial markets, especially to Western European countries.77

The recent collapse of CMEA trade, especially with the dissolution of the U.S.S.R. and East Germany, and the disruption of trade with Iraq (a significant trade partner for Czechoslovakia, Bulgaria, and Romania) makes access to western markets of even greater importance. The volume of exports to former CMEA trading partners in 1991 is expected to decline by 35–65 percent in Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Romania, and by about 75 percent in Poland.78 This was mainly due to dislocation and foreign exchange shortage in the former U.S.S.R. (as well as in other CMEA countries, notably Romania and Bulgaria); the unification of Germany, which partly diverted east Germany’s trade from Eastern Europe; the inexperience of traders in managing trade under the new trade rules; and the expected adjustment of trade flows to the removal of controls and distortions that previously characterized the CMEA regime. This situation has been aggravated by the extension of tied aid and export credits by industrial countries to the former U.S.S.R., which may have diverted trade from Eastern Europe to industrial countries.

Access to Industrial Country Markets

During the past three years industrial countries have taken a number of steps to improve the access of Eastern Europe to their markets (Table 3). Previously, the lack of MFN tariff status was the major obstacle to the United States market. In 1989, only Hungary, Poland, and Yugoslavia had MFN status; imports from Romania, Bulgaria, and Czechoslovakia were subject to substantially higher-than-MFN rates of duty.79 The United States extended MFN status to Czechoslovakia in November 1990 and to Bulgaria in April 1991 and is expected to extend it to Romania soon. (It extended permanent MFN status to Hungary and Czechoslovakia in October 1991.) It also extended GSP treatment to Hungary (November 1989), Poland (January 1990), and Czechoslovakia (May 1991).80 In addition, the United States has increased the quantities of steel products subject to VERs that may be imported from Hungary and Poland. It plans to further relax quotas on textiles and steel imports from Czechoslovakia, Poland, and Hungary, and to expand the list of imports under GSP from these countries.81

Major changes in EC relations with Eastern Europe have occurred in the past three years. Prior to the Luxembourg Declaration between the EC and CMEA in June 1988, trade with CMEA countries was subject to extensive quantitative restrictions of both a selective (discriminatory) and nonselective nature. Between 1988 and 1991, the EC entered into separate Cooperation Agreements with Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, Poland, and Romania (Table 8).82 These agreements contained an MFN clause and provided for the phasing-out over a ten-year period of all selective quantitative restrictions. The implementation of these agreements was overtaken by the dramatic developments since 1989. In 1990, the EC abolished the application of selective quantitative restrictions, except in sensitive sectors, such as agriculture, textiles and clothing, steel, and coal, and suspended the application of nonselective quantitative restrictions to Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland. It also granted GSP treatment to all Eastern European countries.

Table 8.

Market-Opening Measures Taken by Industrial Countries for Eastern European Exports

article image
Sources: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (1990b); and national authorities.Note: EC = European Community; EFTA = European Free Trade Association; GSP = Generalized System of Preferences; MFN = most favored nation; OECD = Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.

Cooperation agreements with the EC that contained an MFN clause and provided for the phasing out over a ten-year period of all selective quantitative restrictions.

The agreements provide for the mutual extension of MFN treatment and will generally improve the capacity of American businesses to operate in the corresponding countries.

Cooperation agreements that cover trade promotion and economic, industrial, technological, and scientific cooperation.

MFN status suspended by United States on July 3, 1988 by mutual agreement. It is expected that the United States will resume MFN status soon.

In addition, the EC has concluded Association Agreements with Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland.83 In the trade area, these agreements will provide for a move to free trade between the EC and each of the three countries in most industrial products, but separate protocols are likely for agriculture, textiles and clothing, steel, and coal; the extent to which these sectors will be covered in the agreements is still under discussion. They are also expected to contain provisions on safeguards, rules of origin, antidumping rules, subsidies, intellectual property, the legal protection of nationals from the three Eastern European countries in the EC, and competition policy. The agreements are expected to be implemented over a maximum period of ten years, but the EC will likely reduce tariff and non-tariff barriers faster than its partners.

The likely provision of separate protocols for agriculture, steel, coal, and textiles and clothing, reflects the “sensitivity” of these sectors in EC member states. For agriculture, the coverage of products, particularly those covered by the CAP, has been subject to intensive discussion. A limited coverage of agriculture may raise doubts about the conformity of these agreements with GATT, in that Article XXIV of GATT requires, inter alia, that free trade agreements cover substantially all trade. The extension of these agreements to cover all agricultural products would, however, in the absence of a fundamental reform of EC agricultural policies, add to the surplus EC production, increase the budgetary costs of the CAP, and further depress world market prices.84 A significant increase in access to the EC market for Eastern European agricultural products would thus seem to be linked to the reform of the CAP and the outcome of the Uruguay Round negotiations.85

The inclusion of a separate protocol on coal and steel partly reflects institutional factors.86 In addition, in the case of coal, the move to free trade creates difficulties for EC member states (Germany and Spain) that have heavily subsidized coal sectors and limit imports of coal from Poland through bilateral agreements. Although steel will likely be covered by a separate protocol, the EC council decided (April 15, 1991) that this product would be treated as any other industrial product, provided the three Eastern European countries abide by EC rules on prices and subsidies. A question yet to be decided is whether the three Eastern European countries will be required to commit themselves to capacity reductions in steel.87 In the case of textiles and clothing, the EC and other industrial country markets are currently protected by the MFA and VERs. The main issue to be decided in the negotiations between the EC and the Eastern European countries involves the length of the transitional period to free trade.

Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland also signed cooperation agreements with the EFTA in June 1990 and agreed to jointly examine the conditions for gradually establishing a free trade area. For a transition period of ten years, tariff reductions by the EFTA members are envisaged to proceed more rapidly than in the partner countries.

In spite of measures taken so far, Eastern Europe still faces substantial barriers to industrial country markets, particularly in agriculture, textiles and clothing, and steel products, which are important export items of Eastern Europe to industrial countries.88 These barriers take the form of quotas, VERs, and other restrictions, as well as tariff peaks and escalation and also affect other developing countries (Table 9). In this connection, the EC quota on beef from Eastern Europe was cut in April 1991 to avoid a futher growth in stockpiles in the EC.

Table 9.

Industrial Countries’ Nontariff Barriers to Exports by Eastern Europe1

article image
Sources: Bureau of National Affairs, International Trade Reporter, various issues; General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Review of Developments in the Trading System, various issues; European Community (EC), Bulletin of the European Communities, various issues; and European Report, various issues.

Excluding bilateral quota agreements under the Multifiber Arrangement (MFA).

Measures effective during 1988–91.

Measures taken during the period of 1988–90. Figures in parentheses indicate the number of cases under each category.

Without substantial improvement in the access of Eastern Europe to industrial country markets, the economic reforms of these countries could be jeopardized. The major remaining barriers to industrial country markets are concentrated in sensitive areas, such as agriculture, steel, and textiles and clothing. Given the reluctance of major industrial countries to remove restrictions in these sectors on a unilateral basis, increased access to these sectors is dependent, in part, on the outcome of the Uruguay Round.

As indicated above, bilateral credits and easy financing terms offered by industrial countries that are tied to imports from industrial countries may have diverted trade from Eastern Europe. In this connection, the United States recently provided farm aid credit to the former U.S.S.R. that is tied to purchases of U.S. farm goods. The German authorities have put in place special export insurance facilities to support east German exports to the former U.S.S.R.; these facilities, which were granted a waiver from normal rules followed by OECD members until the end of 1991, permit zero cash down payments, a grace period on long-term credits, and extended repayment periods. In addition, budget subsidies granted by the German federal government for exports to the former U.S.S.R. by east Germany increased east German exports to the former U.S.S.R. in 1990, possibly displacing Eastern European exports.

Full Integration into GATT

All Eastern European countries, except Bulgaria, are Contracting Parties to the GATT. Bulgaria has been an observer to GATT since 1967 and applied for membership in 1986; a Working Party on its accession was established in 1986. With the exception of Czechoslovakia and Yugoslavia, special provisions were applied to these countries when they acceded to GATT to ensure that reciprocal trade concessions would not be impaired by non-market mechanisms (state-trading, artificial prices, bilateral trade arrangements, allocation of exports and imports). The five Eastern European countries joined GATT at different times and the conditions of membership differed, as did the concessions made to them by the Contracting Parties (Table 10). Czechoslovakia was an original contracting party and the terms of its accession were not renegotiated even though it substantially modified its foreign trade system after 1948.89 Yugoslavia acceded to GATT, in effect, as a market economy.

Table 10.

Current Situation of Eastern European Countries in GATT

article image
Source: General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT).

In the case of Hungary and Yugoslavia, the customs tariff was considered by Contracting Parties as their main concession when they acceded.

A discriminatory safeguard provision allowing Contracting Parties to restrict exports from the corresponding country which cause or threaten serious injury to domestic producers.

The suspension of concessions or other obligations under the protocol in case of disputes not settled in consultation.

A concession from Contracting Parties applying prohibition or quantitative restrictions against the corresponding country’s exports, which are inconsistent with GATT Article XIII, that these restrictions would be progressively eliminated within a certain time period.

Poland is currently renegotiating its protocol of accession.

Under its present protocol, Poland is required to increase its imports from Contracting Parties at an annual average compound rate of 7 percent in every three year period from 1973–75. Annual increase of imports value should be not less than 7 percent.

Romania committed to increase its imports to an amount that is not smaller than the expected total imports provided for in the Five-Year Plans.

As the Eastern European countries transform their economies into western-style market-based economies these special provisions in GATT will become unnecessary. For example, in the case of Poland the requirement to guarantee that imports increase by a certain percentage in value terms conflicts with the principles of a free market economy. Poland and Hungary are in the process of renegotiating their Protocols of Accession to reflect changes toward the greater market orientation of their economies (Appendix I).

Membership in GATT on normal terms is essential to provide Eastern Europe with greater security of access to markets of other Contracting Parties. At the same time, acceptance of the full obligations of GATT membership may enable Eastern European governments to lock in trade reforms and to resist protectionist pressures that may arise to backtrack on reforms.

Issues & Development in intl. Trade
  • Anderson, Kym,The International Dimension of the Political Economy of Agricultural Policy,paper presented at a conference on International Dimensions to Structural Adjustment: Implications for Developing Country Agriculture (Paris, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anderson, Kym, and Rod Tyers,How Developing Countries Could Gain from Agricultural Trade Liberalization in the Uruguay Round,in Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries, ed. by Ian Goldin and Odin Knudsen (Paris: OECD Development Center, 1990), pp. 4775.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Australian Industry Commission, Strategic Trade Theory: The East Asian Experience (Canberra: Industry Commission, November 1990).

  • Balassa, Bela,Comparative Advantage in Manufactured Goods: A Reappraisal,Review of Economics and Statistics (May 1986), No. 68, pp. 31519.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balassa, Bela, and M. Noland, Japan in the World Economy (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1988).

  • Banks, Gary, Australia’s Antidumping Experience, PRE Working Paper No. 551 (Washington: World Bank, December 1990).

  • Barton, John H., “Toward an International Antitrust Code” (mimeograph, Stanford, California: Stanford International Center for Law and High Technology, July 1, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baumol, William J., and Kyu Sik Lee,Contestable Markets, Trade, and Development,in World Bank Research Observer (Washington), Vol. 6, (January 1991), pp. 117.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bell, A.,Antidumping Practice of the EEC: The Japanese Dimension,Legal Issues of European Integration (Deventer, Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers, 1987), pp. 131.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bergsten, C. Fred, and William R. Cline, The United States-Japan Economic Problem, Policy Analysis in International Economics 13 (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhagwati, Jagdish,Export-Promoting Strategy: Issues and Evidence,World Bank Research Observer (Washington), Vol. 3 (1988), pp. 2756.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhagwati, Jagdish, The World Trading System at Risk (Hamel Hempstead, England: Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1991).

  • Blejer, M., and A. Cheasty, “Fiscal Implications of Trade Liberalization,” in Fiscal Policy in Open Developing Economies, ed. by V. Tanzi (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boote, Anthony R., and Janos Somogyi, “Economic Reform in Hungary Since 1968,” IMF Occasional Paper, No. 83 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, July 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brander, James A., and Barbara J. Spencer,Export Subsidies and International Market Share Rivalry,Journal of International Economics (Amsterdam), Vol. 18 (February 1985), pp. 83100.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Broome, John,Recent Developments in Trans-Tasman Business Law,paper prepared for the 17th International Trade Law Conference (September 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burniaux, Jean Marc, Dominique van der Mensbrugghe, and Jean Waelbroeck, “Economy-Wide Effects of Agricultural Policies in OECD Countries: A GE Approach Using the WALRAS Model,” in Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries, ed. by Ian Goldin and Odin Knudsen (Paris: OECD Development Center, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Jacob A. Frenkel,From Centrally Planned to Market Economy,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 38 (June 1991), pp. 26899.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Canada, Bureau of Competition Policy, Europe 1992, Working Group Report on Competition Policy (Ottawa, January 1991).

  • Centre for Economic Policy Research, Monitoring European Integration: The Impact of Eastern Europe, CEPR Annual Report (London: CEPR, October 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Citrin, Daniel A., “Agricultural Policies in Japan and Their Economic Consequences,” in Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cline, William, The Future of World Trade in Textiles and Apparel (Washington: Institute for International Economics, rev. ed., 1990).

  • Cline, William, and S. Weintraub, eds., Economic Stabilization in Developing Countries (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1981).

  • Collins, Susan M., and Dan T. Rodrik, Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union in the World Economy, Policy Analysis in International Economics 32 (Washington: Institute for International Economics, May 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Collyns, Charles, and Steven Dunaway,The Cost of Trade Restraints: The Case of Japanese Automobile Exports to the United States,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 34 (March 1987), pp. 15075.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corbo, Vittorio, Morris Goldstein, and Mohsin Khan, eds., Growth-Oriented Adjustment Programs (Washington: International Monetary Fund and The World Bank, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corden, W.M., Protection and Liberalization: A Review of Analytical Issues, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 54 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corker, Robert,The Changing Structure of Japanese Trade Flows,IMF Working Paper, WP/90/107 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deardorff, Alan V.,Should Patent Protection Be Extended to All Developing Countries?in The World Economy, Vol. 13 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell Ltd., 1990), pp. 497507.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deardorff, Alan V., and Robert Stern, Computational Analysis of Global Trading Arrangements (Ann Arbor, Michigan: The University of Michigan Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de C. Grey, Rodney,The Conflict between Trade Policy and Competition Policy: A Comment,in Studies in Transnational Economic Law, The New GATT Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations, Legal and Economic Problems, ed. by Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann and Meinhard Hilf, Vol. 5 (Deventer, Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers, 1988), pp. 44753.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de la Torre, Augusto, and Margaret R. Kelly, Regional Trade Arrangements, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 93 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Melo, Jaime, and David Tarr, Welfare Costs of U.S. Quotas on Textiles, Steel and Autos, PPR Working Paper, No. 83 (Washington: The World Bank, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “Economic Declaration of the London Summit,” International Trade Reporter (Washington), Vol. 8 (July 24, 1991), p. 1128.

  • European Report, No. 1704 (1991).

  • Farhadian-Lorie, Z., and M. Katz, “Fiscal Dimensions of Trade Policy,” in Fiscal Policy, Stabilization and Growth in Developing Countries, ed. by M. Blejer and Ke-Young Chu (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feenstra, R.,Automobile Prices and Protection: The U.S.-Japan Trade Restraint,Journal of Policy Modelling, Vol. 7 (Spring 1985), pp. 4968.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feketekuty, Geza (1991a), “Changes in the World Economy and Implications for the World Trading System” (mimeograph, Washington: Office of U.S. Trade Representative, June 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feketekuty, Geza (1991b), “Beyond the Uruguay Round,IMF Survey (Washington), Vol. 20, (July 15, 1991), pp. 209.

  • Finger, J. Michael, “Antidumping and Antisubsidy Measures,” in The Uruguay Round: A Handbook on the Multilateral Trade Negotiations, ed. by J. Michael Finger and Andrzej Olechowski (Washington: The World Bank, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Finger, J. Michael, and Patrick A. Messerlin, The Effects of Industrial Countries’ Policies on Developing Countries, Policy and Research Series (Washington: The World Bank, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Finger, J. Michael, and Julio Nogues,International Control of Subsidies and Countervailing Duties,World Bank Economic Review (Washington), Vol. 1 (September 1987), pp. 70725.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley,Issues in Medium-Term Macroeconomic Adjustment,World Bank Research Observer (Washington), Vol. 1 (July 1986), pp. 16382.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley,Economic Growth and Economic Policy,in Growth-Oriented Adjustment Programs, ed. by Vittorio Corbo and others (Washington: International Monetary Fund and The World Bank, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley,Comments on Lipton and Sachs,Brookings Papers on Economic Activity I (1990), p. 147.

  • Ford, Robert, and Wim Suyker,Industrial Subsidies in the OECD Economies,OECD Economic Studies (Paris), No. 15 (Autumn 1990), pp. 3781.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frohberg, Klaus, G. Fischer, and K.S. Parikh, “World Developing Countries Benefit from Agricultural Trade Liberalization in OECD Countries,” in Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries, ed. by Ian Goldin and Odin Knudsen (Paris: OECD Development Center, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gelb, Alan H., and Cheryl W. Gray, “The Transformation of Economies in Central and Eastern Europe: Issues, Progress, and Prospects” (mimeograph, Washington: The World Bank, Country Economics Department, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Genberg, Hans,On Sequencing Reforms in Eastern Europe,IMF Working Paper, WP/91/13 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, February 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1989a), Council Overview of Developments in the International Trading Environment, Annual Report by the Director General, C/RM/OV/1 (Geneva: GATT, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1989b), Trade Policy Review, Australia 1989 (Geneva: GATT, March 1989).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1989c), Trade Policy Review, United States 1989 (Geneva: GATT, November 1989).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1990a), International Trade 89–90, Vols. I and II (Geneva: GATT, 1990).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1990b), Trade Policy Review, Sweden 1990 (Geneva: GATT, August 1990).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1990c), Trade Policy Review, Canada 1990 (Geneva: GATT, November 1990).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1990d), Trade Policy Review, Japan 1990 (Geneva: GATT, November 1990).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1990e), Trade Policy Review, New Zealand 1990 (Geneva: GATT, November 1990).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1991a), Council Overview of Developments in International Trade and the Trading System, Annual Report by the Director General, C/RM/OV/1 (Geneva: GATT, June 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1991b), Trade Policy Review, European Communities 1991 (Geneva: GATT, March 1991).

  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1991c), Council Overview of Developments in International Trade and the Trading System, Annual Report by the Director General, C/RM/OV/2 (Geneva: GATT, April 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (1991d), Council Overview of Developments in International Trade and the Trading System, Annual Report by the Director General, C/RM/OV/1 (Geneva: GATT, June 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldberg, Linda, and Janusz Ordover, Nontariff Barriers and Trade and Competition: Theory and Evidence, Note for the Secretariat (Paris: OECD, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldin, Ian, and Odin Knudsen, eds., Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries (Paris: OECD Development Center, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Graham, Edward M., and J. David Richardson,Global Competition Policies” (Washington: Institute for International Economics, forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greer, Douglas F., Efficiency and Competition: Alternative, Complementary or Conflicting Objectives, Research Monograph 47 (Wellington, New Zealand: Institute of Economic Research Inc., March 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grossman, Gene M., Promoting New Industrial Activities: A Survey of Recent Arguments and Evidence, OECD Economic Studies (Paris), No. 14 (Spring 1990), pp. 87125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gruen, Fred Henry, Review of the Customs Tariff (Anti-Dumping) Act 1975 (Canberra, Australia: Canberra Publishing & Printing Co., March 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Harris, D., and others, Effects of the Liberalization of North Asian Beef Import Policies, ABARE, Discussion Paper No. 90.11 (Canberra, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Havrylyshyn, Oleh, and Lanit Pritchett,Direction of Trade After Transition in East Europe: Predictions from a Gravity Model,draft (May 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Havrylyshyn, Oleh, and David G. Tarr, Trade Liberalization and the Transition to Market Economy (Washington: The World Bank, 1991).

  • Hufbauer, Gary C., Diane Berliner, and Kimberly Ann Elliott, Trade Protection in the United States: 31 Case Studies (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hufbauer, Gary C., Jeffrey J. Schott, and Kimberly A. Elliott, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: Historical Current Policy (Washington: Institute of International Economics, 2d ed., 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Huff, H. Bruce, and Catherine Moreddu,The Ministerial Trade Mandate Model,OECD Economic Studies, No. 13 (Winter 1989–90), pp. 4567.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, “The Role of Structural Policies in Industrial Countries,” in Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, August 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, (1990a), World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1990).

  • International Monetary Fund, (1990b), World Economic Outlook, Staff Studies (Washington: International Monetary Fund, August 1990).

  • International Monetary Fund, (1990c), World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1990).

  • International Monetary Fund, (1991a), World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1991).

  • International Monetary Fund, (1991b), World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1991).

  • International Monetary Fund, The World Bank, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, and European Bank for Reconstruction Development, The Economy of USSR, a study undertaken in response to a request by the Houston Summit (1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Trade Reporter (Washington), Vol. 8 (October 2, 1991) and (July 17, 1991).

  • Jackson, John H., World Trade and the Law of GATT (Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill, 1969).

  • Jackson, John H., The World Trading System: Law and Policy of International Economic Relations (Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jacquemin, Alexis, and others, Merger and Competition Policy in the European Community, ed. by P.H. Admiral (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, Inc., 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Japan Economic Institute, “The Structure of Japan’s Imports: Causes and Consequences,JEI Report, No. 22A (Washington, June 14, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Japan, Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry, and Fishing, “Basic Direction of Japan’s Agricultural Policy Toward the 21st Century,Agricultural Review, Vol. 15 (1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Julius, DeAnne S., Foreign Direct Investment: The Neglected Twin of Trade, Occasional Papers 33 (Washington: Group of Thirty, 1991).

  • Junz, Helen B.,Integration of Eastern Europe into the World Trading System,The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 81 (May 1991), pp. 17680.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kelly, Margaret, and others, Issues and Developments in International Trade Policy, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 63 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kenen, Peter B.,Transitional Arrangements for Trade and Payments Among the CMEA Countries,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 38 (June 1991), pp. 23567.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Koulen, Mark,Potential Anti-Trust Liability of Exporters Participating in Various Forms of Export Restraint Arrangements,in Studies in Transnational Economic Law, The New GATT Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations, Legal and Economic Problems, ed. by Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann and Meinhard Hilf, Vol. 5 (Deventer, Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers, 1988), pp. 43746.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krissoff, Barry, John Sullivan, and John Wainio,Developing Countries in an Open Economy: The Case of Agriculture,in Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries, ed. by Ian Goldin and Odin Knudsen (Paris: OECD Development Center, 1990), pp. 15979.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, Anne, Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development: Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Ballinger Publishing Company, 1978).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, Anne, “Interactions Between Inflation and Trade-Regime Objectives in Stabilization Programs,” in Economic Stabilization in Developing Countries, ed. by W.R. Cline and S. Weintraub (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, Anne, “Problems of Liberalization,” in World Economic Growth, ed. by A. Harberger (San Francisco, California: ICS Press, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, Anne, Maurice Schiff, and Antonio Valdés,Agricultural Incentives in Developing Countries: Measuring the Effect of Sectoral and Economy Wide Policies,in World Bank Review (Washington), Vol. 2 (September 1988) pp. 25571.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul R.,Is Free Trade Passé?Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 1 (Fall 1987), pp. 13144.

  • Laird, S., and R. Vossenaar,Why We Should Be Worried About Non-Tariff Measures,Special Issue on Non-Tariff Measures (Madrid: Información Comercial Española, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laird, S., and Alexander J. Yeats, Quantitative Methods for Trade Barrier Analysis (New York: New York University Press, 1990).

  • Lane, Timothy D., and Elias Dinopoulos, Fiscal Constraints on Market-Oriented Reform in a Socialist Economy, IMF Working Paper, WP/91/75 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, August 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lawrence, Robert Z.,Imports in Japan: Closed Markets or Minds?Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (U.S.), No. 2 (1987), pp. 51754.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lawrence, Robert Z.,Efficient or Exclusionist? The Import Behavior of Japanese Corporate Groups: Comments and Discussion,Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (U.S.), No. 1 (1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lawrence, Robert Z., and Charles L. Schultze, eds., An American Trade Strategy: Options for the 1990s (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lexeconomics, Inc., The Relationship Between Competition Policy and Anti-Dumping Laws, The Canadian Experience (Ottawa, January 1990).

  • Lincoln, Edward J., Japan’s Unequal Trade (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1990).

  • Lipton, D., and Jeffrey Sachs,Creating Market Economy in Eastern Europe: The Case of Poland,Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (U.S.), No. 1 (1990), pp. 75147.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Low, Patrick, and Raed Safadi,Trade Policy and Pollution,World Bank Discussion Paper, No. 159 (Washington: The World Bank, May 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Marin, D.,Tying in International Trade: Evidence on Countertrade,in World Economy, Vol. 13 (September 1990), pp. 44562.

  • Matsushita, Mitsuo,Coordinating International Trade with Competition Policies,in Studies in Transnational Economic Law, The New GATT Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations, Legal and Economic Problems, ed. by Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann and Meinhard Hilf, Vol. 5 (Deventer, Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers, 1988), pp. 395432.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McCulloch, Rachel,Investment Policies in the GATT,NBER Working Paper Series, No. 3672 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald I.,Liberalizing Foreign Trade in a Socialist Economy: The Problem of Negative Value Added,Rivista di Politica Economía (Italy), Vol. 81 (June 1991), pp. 85120.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald I., and D. J. Mathieson, How to Manage a Repressed Economy, Princeton Essays in International Finance, No. 145 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, December 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Messerlin, Patrick A.,Antidumping Regulations or Pro-Cartel Law? The EC Chemical Cases,in The World Economy, ed. by David Greenaway and John Whalley, Vol. 13, No. 4 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell Ltd., 1990), pp. 46592.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Messerlin, Patrick A.,The Uruguay Negotiations on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures: Past and Future Constraints” (Washington: The World Bank, International Economics Department, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Messerlin, Patrick A.,The EC Antidumping Enforcement: The Procedures,paper prepared for seminars organized by the University of Wisconsin and Free University of BrusselsAre the Fair Trade and Safeguard Laws Operating as Intended?” (Paris, May 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Michaely, M.,Trade Liberalization Policies: Lessons of Experience,paper presented at the conferenceFor a New Policy Towards Foreign Trade” (Brazil, April 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Michaely, M., D. Papageorgiou, and A. Choksi, Liberalizing Foreign Trade: Lessons and Experience in the Developing World, Vol. 7 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell Ltd., 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Michalopoulos, Constantine, and David Tarr,Trade and Payments Arrangements in Post-CMEA Eastern and Central Europe,Working Paper WPS 644 (Washington: The World Bank, April 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • National Consumer Council, Trade and Competition Policy: The Consumer Interest, International Trade and the Consumer, National Consumer Council, Working Paper No. 5 (London: National Consumer Council, March 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nicolaides, Phedon,EC Antidumping Policy,in Tokyo Club Papers, No. 4 (London: The Royal Institute of International Affairs, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Office of the United States Trade Representative, 1991 Trade Policy Agenda and 1990 Annual Report of the President of the United States on the Trade Agreements Program (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Competition and Trade Policies: Their Interaction (Paris: OECD, 1984).

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, The Costs of Restricting Imports: The Automobile Industry (Paris: OECD, 1987).

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, (1990a), Industrial Policy in OECD Countries, Annual Review 1990 (Paris: OECD, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, (1990b), Reforming Agricultural Policies: Quantitative Restrictions on Production and Direct Income Support (Paris: OECD, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Agricultural Policies, Markets and Trade: Monitoring and Outlook 1991 (Paris: OECD, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostrom, Douglas,The Structure of Japan’s Imports: Causes and Consequences,JEI Report, No. 22A (Washington, June 14, 1991).

  • Ostry, Jonathan D.,Trade Liberalization in Developing Countries: Initial Trade Distortions and Imported Intermediate Inputs,in Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 38 (September 1991), pp. 44779.