I Introduction
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Abstract

In 1971–73 an average of only eight countries a year had Fund-supported adjustment programs. The world economy had just emerged from a decade (1963–72) in which the volume of world trade had grown at an average annual rate of 8½ percent and in which economic growth in industrial and developing countries was close to, or in excess of, 5 percent a year, respectively. Against such a background of very modest Fund program activity and generally favorable economic performance, the global effects of Fund programs were hardly discussed.

In 1971–73 an average of only eight countries a year had Fund-supported adjustment programs. The world economy had just emerged from a decade (1963–72) in which the volume of world trade had grown at an average annual rate of 8½ percent and in which economic growth in industrial and developing countries was close to, or in excess of, 5 percent a year, respectively. Against such a background of very modest Fund program activity and generally favorable economic performance, the global effects of Fund programs were hardly discussed.

Scarcely more than a dozen years later, the situation is different. To begin with, the number of member countries, especially non-oil developing countries, undertaking Fund-supported adjustment programs has increased sharply in response to severe external payments deficits. In 1980–83, for example, an average of 23 countries a year had stand-by or extended Fund facility arrangements with the Fund; add to these the countries making purchases under the Fund’s compensatory financing facility and the figure rises to 31 countries a year.1 The background of this increase, of course, is the 1980–82 global recession, when, inter alia, economic growth fell short of 2 percent per annum in developing countries and of 1 percent in industrial countries, and when the volume of world trade was virtually stagnant. Seen in this light, it is perhaps not surprising that the global effects of Fund-supported adjustment programs have taken on an increased interest.

At the risk of over simplification, concerns about the global effects of Fund programs and of Fund policy prescriptions can be categorized into three areas. First, it is argued that simultaneous demand restraint policies in many program countries could impart a procyclical deflationary bias to the world economy, with adverse consequences for real output and employment in non-program and program countries alike.2 Second, there is concern about the consistency of the Fund’s policy prescriptions across countries—that, for example, the Fund’s prescriptions for appropriate monetary and fiscal policies in industrial countries might imply a lower demand for imports than the export objectives of Fund programs with non-oil developing countries.3 A third related concern is that because one program country’s imports are another’s exports, trade links among program countries may frustrate the trade objectives of individual countries.4 A final concern is that simultaneous exchange rate devaluation by many program countries, some of which export mainly primary commodities, will result primarily in a lower world price for the exports of program countries, with little beneficial effect on their export earnings. The common thread of these positions is that what might be feasible and desirable for a single program country acting alone will be neither for many program countries acting simultaneously.

This paper makes four contributions to the analysis of and debate on the global effects of Fund programs. First, it examines the strengths and weaknesses of alternative ways of defining and measuring the effects of programs, be they domestic effects or global effects. Second, it identifies the channels by which policies in program countries might be expected to affect both non-program and other program countries. Third, the paper reviews the empirical evidence on the likely size of such “aggregation” or “interdependence” effects of Fund programs. Finally, it discusses the ways in which the Fund currently takes these aggregation and interdependence effects into account, both in the design of stabilization programs and, more broadly, in the advice it gives to member countries.

Two restrictions have been placed on the scope of the paper to keep it manageable. First, in keeping with the emphasis on the global effects of Fund programs, the paper does not attempt either to appraise the effects of individual Fund-supported adjustment programs or to assess (in great detail) the effects of all Fund programs on individual regions, countries, industries, or financial institutions. Thus, for example, the paper investigates how a 15 percent change in the volume of imports in all program countries might affect export volumes and real gross national product (GNP) in industrial countries.5 But it does not investigate how, say, Fund-supported adjustment programs in Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico taken either individually or together, have affected U.S. capital goods exports or the market value of financial claims by the largest commercial banks against these particular countries.

The second restriction confines the analysis to the global effects of the most characteristic policy actions of past Fund-supported adjustment programs. (These include, for example, policies affecting the rate of domestic credit creation, the size of the public sector deficit, the level of foreign borrowing, the level of the real exchange rate and of real interest rates, and the restrictiveness of the trade and payments system.) The paper does not consider the international consequences of all possible policy scenarios by program countries. Thus, for example, although 11 of the 25 major borrowers among developing countries had Fund programs in 1983, there is no attempt to estimate the global consequences of, say, alternative large-scale debt rescheduling exercises for groups of program countries.6

The plan of the rest of the paper is as follows. Section II considers the thorny but important question of how to define the “effects” of Fund programs. It is argued there that if program effects are defined as the difference between what did happen in program countries and what would have happened in these countries in the absence of Fund programs, then any net transmission effects of programs may be quite different from what is of ten supposed. A case is likewise made for considering the long-run as well as the short-term effects of programs. Section II also shows why in practice it is so difficult to actually measure the effects of programs. Section III then presents some basic characteristics of the program country population that a priori should affect the size of any transmission effects from program countries to the rest of the world. These characteristics include: (1) the weight or share of program countries in world imports and exports; (2) the extent of trade interdependence among program countries; (3) the share of program countries in international capital flows; and (4) the size of initiating changes in import volumes, export prices, and real exchange rates in program countries themselves during the program period.

Section IV then utilizes these basic characteristics of program countries, in conjunction with some structural and behavioral parameters in industrial and oil exporting developing countries, to draw some inferences about the transmission effects of expenditure changes in program countries. Simulation results are reported for three World Trade Models, namely, the OECD Interlink Model, the Fund’s World Trade Model, and the Project LINK Model. (OECD stands for the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.) The focus of Section V is on the global effects of simultaneous exchange rate changes by program countries. In this connection, a distinction is made between exports of differentiated products (such as manufactures) and exports of homogeneous primary commodities. In order to identify those commodities for which exchange-rate-induced increases in production could affect the world price, data are presented on the country-concentration of production for many of the primary commodities that are most important in world trade, as well as on supply-price elasticities for these commodities. Indices of export and import “market power” for most Fund member countries are also presented. Section VI considers how the Fund takes aggregation and interdependence effects of programs into account in its operations. Emphasis is given to the World Economic Outlook exercises, to the interchange of information on programs among the Fund’s staff, and to the waiver and modification provisions in Fund programs. Finally, Section VII summarizes the paper’s main conclusions.

  • Anjaria, S.J., Z. Iqbal, N. Kirmani, and L.L. Perez, Developments in International Trade Policy, Occasional Paper No. 16 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, November 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balassa, Bela, The Process of Industrial Development and Alternative Development Strategies, Essays in International Finance No. 141 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University, December 1980).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bélanger, Gérard, “An Indicator of Effective Exchange Rates for Primary Producing Countries,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 23 (March 1976), pp. 11336.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bergsten, C. Fred and William R. Cline, “Trade Policy in the 1980s: An Overview,” in Trade Policy in the 1980s, edited by William R. Cline (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bond, M., “Agricultural Responses to Prices in Sub-Saharan African Countries” (unpublished, Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Branson, W. and L.T. Katseli-Papaefstratiou, “Income In-stability, Terms of Trade, and the Choice of Exchange Rate Regime,” Journal of Development Economics (Amsterdam), Vol. 7 (March 1980), pp. 4969.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brau, E., R.C. Williams, P.M. Keller, and M. Nowak, Recent Multilateral Debt Restructurings with Official and Bank Creditors, Occasional Paper No. 25 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chu, K.Y. and T. Morrison, “The 1981–82 Recession and Non-Oil Primary Commodity Prices: An Econometric Analysis” (unpublished, Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clark, P.B., “The Effects of Recent Exchange Rate Changes on the U.S. Trade Balance,” in The Effects of Exchange Rate Adjustments, edited by P. Clark, D. Lagne, and R. Sweeney (Washington: U.S. Treasury, 1977), pp. 20136.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cline, William R., et al., Trade Negotiations in the Tokyo Round: A Quantitative Assessment (Washington: The Brookings Institution. 1978).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Larosiere, J., Does the Fund Impose Austerity? (Washington: International Monetary Fund, June 1984).

  • Dell, Sidney, On Being Grandmotherly: The Evolution of IMF Conditionality, Essays in International Finance No. 144 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University. 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deppler, Michael C. and Duncan M. Ripley, “The World Trade Model: Merchandise Trade,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 25 (March 1978), pp. 147206.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fair, R., “On Modelling the Economic Linkages Among Countries,” in International Economic Policy—Theory and Evidence, edited by R. Dornbusch and J. Frenkel (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feltenstein, Andrew, Morris Goldstein, and Susan M. Schadler, “A Multilateral Exchange Rate Model for Primary Producing Countries.” Staff Papers. International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 26 (September 1979), pp. 54382.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Glowacki, J. and K. Ruffing, “Developing Countries in Project LINK,” in Modelling the International Trans-mission Process, edited by J.A. Sawyer (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris and Mohsin S. Khan. “Income and Price Effects in Foreign Trade.” in Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 2, edited by Ronald W. Jones and Peter B. Kenen (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1984: New York: Elsevier, 1984), pp. 10411105.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris and Effects of Slowdown in Industrial Countries on Growth in Non-Oil Developing Countries. Occasional Paper No. 12 (Washington. International Monetary Fund, August 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris and Peter Montiel, “Evaluating the Effects of IMF Stabilization Programs: Some Methodological Pitfalls” (unpublished, Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goreux, Louis M., Compensatory Financing Facility. IMF Pamphlet Series No. 34 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1980).

  • Grossman, Gene M., “Import Competition from Developed and Developing Countries,” Review of Economics and Statistics (Cambridge, Massachusetts). Vol. 64 (May 1982), pp. 27181.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guitian, M., Fund Conditionality: Evolution of Principles and Practices, IMF Pamphlet Series No. 38 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Havrylyshyn, Oli and Martin Wolf. Trade Among Developing Countries: Theory, Policy Issues, and Principal Trends. World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 479 (Washington. August 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heckman, James J., “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error,” Econometrica, Vol. 47 (January 1979). pp. 15361.

  • Helleiner, Gerald K., The IMF and Africa in the 1980s. Essays in International Finance No. 152 (Princeton. New Jersey: Princeton University. July 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Helliwell, J. and T. Padmore. “Empirical Studies of Macroeconomic Interdependence.” in Handbook of Inter-national Economics, edited by Peter Kenen and R. Jones (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hemphill, William L., “The Effect of Foreign Exchange Receipts on Imports of Less Developed Countries,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 21 (November 1974), pp. 63777.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hickman, Bert G. and V. Filatov, “A Decomposition of International Income Multipliers,” in Global Econometrics: Essays in Honor of Lawrence R. Klein, edited by F. Gerard Adams and Bert G. Hickman (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1983), pp. 34067.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Inter-American Development Bank, Commodity Export Prospects of Latin America (Washington: Inter-American Development Bank, March 1984).

  • International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, Occasional Paper No. 27 (Washington, 1984).

  • Isard, Peter, “The Price Effects of Exchange Rate Change,” in The Effects of Exchange Rate Adjustments, edited by P. Clark, et al. (Washington: U.S. Treasury, 1977).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin, “Import and Export Demand in Developing Countries,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 21 (November 1974), pp. 67893.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin, and Malcolm D. Knight, “Stabilization in Developing Countries: A Formal Framework,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 28 (March 1981), pp. 153.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Killick, Tony, “IMF Stabilization Programs,” in The Quest for Economic Stabilization, edited by Tony Killick (London: Heinemann for Overseas Development Institute, 1984), pp. 183226.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kirmani, Naheed, Luigi Molajoni, and Thomas Mayer, “Effects of Increased Market Access on Exports of Developing Countries,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 31 (December 1984), pp. 66184.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Larsen, F., J. Llewellyn, and S. Potter, “International Economic Linkages,” OECD Economic Studies, No. 1 (Autumn 1983), pp. 4492.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lewis, Harold Gregg, Unionism and Relative Wages in the United States: An Empirical Inquiry (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1963).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Meltzer, Alan, “Notes on the Problem of International Debt” (unpublished, September 1983).

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, OECD Interlink System—Structure and Operation (Paris: OECD, Autumn 1983).

  • Please, Stanley, The Hobbled Giant, Essays on the World Bank (Boulder: Westview Press, 1984).

  • Ridler, Duncan and Christopher A. Yandle, “A Simplified Method for Analyzing the Effect of Exchange Rate Changes on Exports of a Primary Commodity,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 19 (November 1972), pp. 55978.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Saunders, A., “An Examination of the Contagion Effect in the International Loan Market” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Waelbroeck, Jean, “Regional Models of Developing Countries,” in Models of Project LINK, edited by Jean Waelbroeck (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1976), pp. 397409.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Weinberg, C., “Comparisons of Policies to Stimulate the World Economy,” in Modelling the International Trans-mission Process, edited by J.A. Sawyer (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1979), pp. 12941.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Whalley, John, “The North-South Debate and the Terms of Trade: An Applied General Equilibrium Approach,” Review of Economics and Statistics (Cambridge, Massachusetts), Vol. 66 (May 1984), pp. 22434.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Williams, Richard, Peter Keller, John Lipsky, and Donald Mathieson, International Capital Markets: Developments and Prospects, Occasional Paper No. 23 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, July 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Williamson, John, The Lending Policies of the International Monetary Fund (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1982).

  • Williamson, John, ed., IMF Conditionality (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1983).

  • Winters, L. Alan, “Developing Countries' Manufactured Exports—Some Simple Models” (unpublished, Washington: World Bank, December 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, Price Prospects for Major Primary Commodities (unpublished, Washington: World Bank, December 1982).

  • World Bank, World Development Report 1984 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1984).