Introduction
Chile, a small economy strongly integrated into world markets, is an important producer and exporter of commodities. Copper dominates its market: Chile has a one-third share in world copper production, and this represents more than half of Chile’s total exports (see Table 7.1). As Chile is a very open market economy, its specialization in production of copper (and other commodities) is driven more by its rich resource endowments and private investments than by government decisions, abstracting from the fact that the largest copper-producing corporation is government-owned CODELCO.
Chile’s export prices and volumes generally, and copper prices and volumes in particular, have major direct effects on government tax and non-tax revenue and, by affecting key macroeconomic variables such as GDP and the real exchange rate, exert additional indirect effects on government finances. As a small, open, and specialized economy, Chile also faces other external and domestic shocks that contribute to significant GDP (and consumption) volatility.
Over the last three decades, subsequent governments have gradually strengthened macroeconomic and financial institutions, regimes, and policies, motivated by two key objectives—to ensure government solvency and strengthen macro-financial stability. An independent central bank, inflation targeting, and a flexible exchange rate are the pillars for a prudent conduct of monetary policy that has yielded low and relatively stable inflation during the last decade. Strong banking regulation and prudential financial oversight have contributed to the development of deep and sound banks and capital markets.
Prudent fiscal management was re-established after the resolution of the banking and debt crisis of the early 1980s and strengthened in the 1990s and 2000s, reflected in budget surpluses. Fiscal sustainability and government solvency were attained with declining government debt levels and rising government assets. Gross government assets (including sovereign wealth funds) stand at 17.6 percent of GDP, whereas domestic and foreign government debt stands at 9.3 percent of GDP; hence, the government is a net creditor.
Central Government Accounts, Growth, and Copper Prices, 1990–2010
Copper-related and non-copper-related revenue for 2005–10.
Central Government Accounts, Growth, and Copper Prices, 1990–2010
1990–2001 | 2001–2010 | 2010 | |
Central government (% of GDP) | |||
Overall revenue | 21.7 | 23.1 | 23.0 |
Copper revenue1 | 6.0 | 4.7 | |
Noncopper revenue1 | 18.2 | 18.3 | |
Overall expenditure | 20.7 | 21.1 | 23.5 |
Government balance | 1.0 | 2.0 | −0.5 |
Cyclically adjusted balance | 0.5 | 0.0 | −2.3 |
Government assets | 13.7 | 12.6 | 17.6 |
Sovereign wealth funds | 10.0 | 8.0 | |
Government debt | 22.0 | 9.4 | 9.3 |
Net government assets | –8.3 | 3.2 | 8.3 |
GDP growth (%) | |||
Average | 6.2 | 3.7 | 5.2 |
Standard deviation | 3.5 | 2.2 | |
Committee’s average estimated future trend growth | 4.7 | 5.0 | |
Copper price (US$/lb) | |||
Average | 1.00 | 2.04 | 3.40 |
Standard deviation | 0.19 | 1.12 | |
Committee’s average estimated future trend level | 1.22 | 2.13 | |
Copper production (% of world production) | 25.8 | 34.9 | 33.7 |
Copper exports (% of Chile’s exports) | 38.6 | 46.6 | 56.1 |
Copper-related and non-copper-related revenue for 2005–10.
Central Government Accounts, Growth, and Copper Prices, 1990–2010
1990–2001 | 2001–2010 | 2010 | |
Central government (% of GDP) | |||
Overall revenue | 21.7 | 23.1 | 23.0 |
Copper revenue1 | 6.0 | 4.7 | |
Noncopper revenue1 | 18.2 | 18.3 | |
Overall expenditure | 20.7 | 21.1 | 23.5 |
Government balance | 1.0 | 2.0 | −0.5 |
Cyclically adjusted balance | 0.5 | 0.0 | −2.3 |
Government assets | 13.7 | 12.6 | 17.6 |
Sovereign wealth funds | 10.0 | 8.0 | |
Government debt | 22.0 | 9.4 | 9.3 |
Net government assets | –8.3 | 3.2 | 8.3 |
GDP growth (%) | |||
Average | 6.2 | 3.7 | 5.2 |
Standard deviation | 3.5 | 2.2 | |
Committee’s average estimated future trend growth | 4.7 | 5.0 | |
Copper price (US$/lb) | |||
Average | 1.00 | 2.04 | 3.40 |
Standard deviation | 0.19 | 1.12 | |
Committee’s average estimated future trend level | 1.22 | 2.13 | |
Copper production (% of world production) | 25.8 | 34.9 | 33.7 |
Copper exports (% of Chile’s exports) | 38.6 | 46.6 | 56.1 |
Copper-related and non-copper-related revenue for 2005–10.
Chile faces high and increasing government revenue volatility due to moderate GDP volatility and very large copper price volatility. The standard deviation of output growth declined from 3.5 percent in the 1990s to 2.2 percent in the 2000s, while copper price volatility exploded from US$0.2 per pound in the 1990s to US$1.1 per pound in the 2000s.
To deal with large output and even larger copper price shocks, fiscal policy has focused increasingly on shielding government spending from large revenue shocks. Even in the absence of an explicit fiscal rule during the 1990s, short-term shocks in government revenue were reflected more by government saving than by government spending. In 2000, a new incoming administration decided to adopt an explicit fiscal rule that at the time was unique in the world. Partly consistent with a permanent-income approach, the rule restricts overall central government spending to an estimate of trend central government revenue consistent with trend estimates for GDP and the price of copper. The difference between government spending and the estimate for trend government revenue, termed “cyclically adjusted balance” (CAB), is bound to a numerical target set initially at 1 percent of GDP. The ex ante total government balance reflects ex ante estimates for GDP and the price of copper; it differs from the CAB by the estimated impact of the cyclical components of GDP and the copper price on government revenue.
Although the fiscal rule has been modified over the years to accommodate some changes in budget structure and policy objectives, it has largely remained in place and represents a major component of Chile’s strong fiscal regime. Additional elements of the institutional framework for fiscal policy have been added over the years, starting with the establishment of independent committees to provide projections for future and trend GDP and copper prices; the 2006 enactment of a fiscal responsibility law that establishes institutional requirements for the fiscal framework (related to government commitment to a fiscal framework; the start of SWFs); and the 2010 establishment of an independent commission that has evaluated the fiscal policy framework (including the fiscal rule) and proposed further reforms.
This chapter evaluates Chile’s fiscal rule and fiscal policy framework with a focus on the lessons that can be drawn from Chile’s experience for framework design and conduct of fiscal policy in commodity-exporting countries. It then assesses Chile’s institutional framework for fiscal policy in the light of international experience, explains Chile’s fiscal rule that started in 2001, and goes over its implementation, changes, and implications for government accounts during its first decade. Its fiscal and macroeconomic impact are then assessed, and the shortcomings of the rule and recommendations for improvement are discussed. The closing section draws fiscal policy lessons for commodity-exporting countries from Chile’s experience.
Chile’s Institutional Framework for Fiscal Policy in International Comparison
Many countries are designing and implementing major reforms of their institutional framework for fiscal policy and financial management. These reforms are motivated by different reasons. First, they reflect a growing global consensus among academics and policymakers about the economic benefits of procedures and rules that shape and limit planning and execution of fiscal policy. Second, they also respond to the political benefits of requirements in regard to transparency and accountability in the exercise of fiscal policy in a democracy. Third, they respond to the failure of previous fiscal institutions and rules in many advanced economies, as in the case of the systematic violations of the fiscal rules of the Stability and Growth Pact by many member countries of the euro area.
A modern institutional framework for the conduct of fiscal policy and financial management should aim at addressing the principal-agent problems that arise between voters and political authorities due to governments’ impatience, lack of representation of future generations, electoral competition, sensitivity to special-interest lobbies, corruption, and use of asymmetric and biased information (von Hagen, 2005; Wren-Lewis, 2010). To overcome these distortions and negative externalities, the academic literature and international experience suggest adoption of an institutional framework for fiscal policy based on the following components (Debrun, Hauner, and Kumar, 2009; Ter-Minassian, 2010; IMF, 2009, 2010): a fiscal responsibility law, modern financial management, a planning horizon that exceeds one year, a fiscal rule for the budget, rules for government asset and liability management, requirements in regard to accountability and public information on the government’s financial management, effective external control and auditing, and establishment of a fiscal council (FC), fiscal committees, or both.
The following is a brief review of the international evidence and a description of Chile’s development of the eight latter components of a modern institutional framework of fiscal institutions.
Fiscal Responsibility Laws
Several countries have adopted fiscal responsibility laws specifying budgetary procedures and rules to strengthen fiscal policy transparency, accountability, and stability. Fiscal responsibility laws establish requirements that the executive transparently state its short- and medium-term policy objectives, set short- and medium-term targets for fiscal flow and stocks, provide transparent information on budget planning and execution to the legislature, implement a fiscal policy conducive to fiscal stability and solvency, and account ex post for its fiscal policy execution and attainment of policy objectives (Lienert, 2010).
However, fiscal responsibility laws do not necessarily spell out an explicit fiscal rule. Conversely, fiscal rules are often adopted in the absence (or outside) of a fiscal responsibility law. For example, in 2008, Germany adopted a fiscal rule by constitutional amendment, not as part of a fiscal responsibility law.
Fiscal responsibility laws are often enacted as a legal tool in support of the consolidation of fiscal adjustment, which sometimes occurs under a stabilization program agreed with the IMF so that its emphasis is on budgetary control rather than effective fiscal policy. However, in other conditions, such laws are adopted with the aim of strengthening the institutional framework for fiscal policy, focusing on the above-mentioned components of a modern institutional framework, such as in Chile’s case.
A selective review of fiscal responsibility laws adopted by 13 developed and developing countries since 1998 shows that these laws specify an explicit fiscal rule in 9 countries, define escape clauses in 7 countries, and set penalties for overspending in 6 countries (IMF, 2009). The evidence on the success of fiscal responsibility laws is mixed. When the targets are realistic and there is political will for taking necessary corrective measures to achieve them, these laws have been successful (e.g., in Australia and New Zealand). However, in many emerging economies, they have been unsuccessful in meeting their quantitative targets (e.g., in Argentina, Colombia, Peru). Cáceres, Corbacho, and Medina (2010) find limited empirical evidence in support of the view that fiscal responsibility laws have had a significant effect on fiscal performance.
Chile enacted Law No. 20128 on Fiscal Responsibility in 2006 to strengthen the institutional framework for a fiscal rule adopted five years earlier by a previous administration. This law was not adopted to enforce fiscal adjustment but to develop the institutional framework required to strengthen the links between the fiscal rule, the use of government savings, and the establishment of two SWFs. Its major provisions are the following (Rodríguez, Tokman, and Vega, 2006):
Note that that this law does not impose a particular fiscal rule on the government. It rather imposes a requirement to adopt and implement a fiscal policy aiming at fiscal sustainability and a distinction between actual and cyclically adjusted balances. This provides sufficient flexibility to new governments to define the explicit formula for the fiscal rule they commit to at the start of their administration. In addition, the law defines new institutions—adopted in 2006 and 2007—that strengthen operation of the fiscal rule.
Financial Management of the Budget
International best practice in regard to budgetary management is based on the adoption by the MoF of the following core elements for an efficient financial management (Ter-Minassian, 2010):
International evidence shows that countries that meet these requirements achieve better performance in budget execution, stability, and sustainability of fiscal policy (Alesina and Perotti, 1996; Stein, Talvi, and Grisanti, 1998; Alesina and others, 1999; Ter-Minassian, 2010).
Chile’s strong presidential system empowers the government with budgetary initiative (not shared with congress) and strong control over budget design and negotiation of the budget with congress. The executive holds the sole power of tax initiative. Congress lacks line-item veto and is entitled only to vote for or against the government’s proposed budget bill. Congress also lacks in-house capabilities to assess and evaluate in depth current fiscal policy, projections in the budget bill, and underlying macroeconomic assumptions.
However, significant budget negotiations take place between the government, represented by the MoF, and congress before the budget comes to vote. The latter negotiations tend to focus on budget composition (i.e., spending) rather than on taxation or the overall resource constraint, not the least because of the constraints imposed by the fiscal rule on the budget’s overall resource envelope.
Budget-Planning Horizon
Many countries are reforming their budget planning, shifting from a one-year horizon to a multiyear horizon. This change is aimed at different objectives: (1) achieving greater transparency, consistency, and intertemporal sustainability of fiscal policy; (2) reducing government short-term bias in public spending decisions; and (3) committing to a path of gradual correction of initially unsustainable fiscal positions.
On the one hand, there are governments that lack fiscal rules but adopt multi-annual budgeting to enhance sustainability and credibility of fiscal policy. On the other hand, there are governments that have one-year budgeting but that have adopted fiscal rules based on cyclical adjustments. The latter governments have an implicit multiannual budget horizon by distinguishing between actual and cyclically adjusted government accounts and balances. However, in the latter cases, the dissemination of explicit multiyear budgetary and fiscal targets contributes to additional potential gains in fiscal policy sustainability and credibility as well as macroeconomic stability.
Chile has a one-year budgeting framework in place. However, the aforementioned 2006 Fiscal Responsibility Law includes two items that require governments to adopt a fiscal policy that is at least in principle consistent with a horizon that exceeds one year: (1) the requirement imposed on new administrations to present their four-year fiscal policy framework and its implications for the cyclically adjusted government balance and (2) the requirement that the MoF submit annually, together with the draft budget law, a medium-term budget projection.
Moreover, by adhering to a CAB rule, governments are required to base the next year’s budget proposal on medium-term projections for GDP and the price of copper.
Chile’s government is not required to produce or commission long-term projections for government accounts and budgets based on the systematic assessment of fiscal sustainability and regular evaluation of long-term consequences of fiscal decisions with budgetary implications, like those conducted by the U.S. Congressional Budget Office and other governments in the world. However, there has been one exception to this rule, which was the commission of a technical study, required by the 2006 law, to assess the funding needs of the PRF to meet the government liabilities derived from the government pension subsidy (Pilar Pensional Solidario).
Fiscal Rules
The number of countries with fiscal rules at the national level has grown steadily over the past two decades, from 10 countries in 1990 to 30 in 2001 (which is also the year that Chile adopted the fiscal rule) and 51 in 2009 (IMF, 2009). Countries with fiscal rules adopted on average 2.5 active fiscal rules in 2009.
Fiscal rules are adopted to attain one or more of three objectives—sustainability of public debt, control of government size, and contribution to cyclical stability. Rules differ widely across countries in how they are defined. One category of rules comprises those that define numerical targets (targets, ceilings, or floors) for government balances, overall revenues, or expenditures that are fixed and hence independent of the business cycle. A paramount example of the latter rules is the Stability and Growth Pact ceilings on government deficit (3 percent of GDP) and debt (60 percent of GDP) for European Union (EU) member countries that were systematically violated before 2008 and have been almost universally thereafter. A second category is the fiscal rules that focus on stabilizing CABs, allowing for cyclical changes in actual government balances, with the aim of implementing a countercyclical fiscal policy or at least avoiding a procyclical policy bias. According to the IMF (2009), 10 countries (including Chile) had such a rule in place in 2009. Among them, only Germany, Sweden, and the United Kingdom had a fiscal rule in place that defines a numerical target for the actual budget balance throughout the economic cycle.
The IMF (2009) reviews the relative advantages of different fiscal rules, their design and complementarity with other institutional changes, the institutional prerequisites and economic determinants, and the strength in design, execution, and correction of deviations. It also positively assesses the fiscal and macroeconomic effects of fiscal rules in the world.
As noted previously, Chile is among the 10 countries with a fiscal rule that aims at stabilizing government CABs. However, in contrast to the other 9 cases, Chile corrects not only for the cyclical influence of the business cycle, as reflected by GDP deviations from trend, but also for the cyclical deviations of the price of copper from trend. Therefore, Chile’s experience is unique in the world and is exemplary for commodity-exporting countries, as highlighted by the IMF (2009).
However, unlike other countries with fiscal rules in place, Chile has established neither ex ante escape clauses from the rule that would apply under prespecified conditions nor ex post sanctions for violating the rule and ex post regulations to correct deviations from the rule.
Rules for Management of Government Assets and Liabilities
As commodity-exporting countries benefited from significant fiscal surpluses during the extended boom in commodity prices over the last decade, many of them have started to save their surpluses in SWFs invested in internationally diversified portfolios. This has been observed in countries with and without fiscal rules. Up to late 2009, 37 countries had SWFs in place, with outstanding aggregate assets of US$3.8 trillion. In the case of Chile, the outstanding investments of its two SWFs added up to US$14.7 billion at the end of 2009.
Countries with SWFs have committed to rules for saving in and dissaving from their funds. In the case of countries with a fiscal rule in place, accumulation into and withdrawal from their funds is determined by the rule. In addition, many countries have adopted legislation and institutions that define investment policies and management principles of their funds.
As mentioned above, in the case of Chile, its two SWFs were established by the 2006 Fiscal Responsibility Law. The latter also established the Financial Advisory Committee on Sovereign Funds of the Ministry of Finance, which advises the MoF on investment policies of these funds.
However, Chile (like most countries in the world) lacks both a policy and an institution focused on consistent management of government financial assets and liabilities with explicit objectives including risk, return, liquidity, and benchmarking.
Moreover, there is no comprehensive management of the government’s total balance sheet, including financial and nonfinancial assets, as well as explicit and contingent financial liabilities.
Requirements in Regard to Budget Accountability and Provision of Information on Financial Management
Worldwide efforts are underway by governments to improve accountability of their fiscal policy and transparency in the provision of financial information. This trend responds to the growing political and academic consensus about the democratic and economic efficiency gains of fuller accountability and transparency in fiscal policy. Although there is little empirical evidence on the benefits of high levels of accountability and transparency in fiscal policy, it seems legitimate to qualitatively infer from the evidence of accountability and transparency benefits associated with monetary policy (e.g., Geraats, Eijffinnger, and van der Cruijsen, 2006; Geraats, 2008).
The International Budget Partnership (2010) has compiled an Open Budget Survey, which is an international comparative database on partial and aggregate measures of global transparency and accountability of the budgets of central governments in the world. In the 2010 version of the survey, Chile ranked eighth among 94 countries (Figure 7.1 depicts ranking results for a selected subsample).
Government Budget Transparency and Accountability, 2010
Source: International Budget Partnership (2010).Transparency in regard to the two key budget assumptions—future GDP growth and copper prices—was ensured almost from the start of Chile’s fiscal rule, as projections for the two variables made by two ad hoc committees were made public (this is discussed in more detail later in the chapter). However, mapping of the latter projections into the actual budget calculations could not easily be replicated, particularly after several changes to the rule were introduced in 2008 and 2009. However, the 2010 Report on Public Finances for the Budget Law 2011 made significant improvements in the provision of information on the calculation of the CAB, which was coherent with the recommendations provided by the Advisory Committee on Fiscal Policy (2010, 2011).
Regarding SWFs, international heterogeneity in their management and investment accountability and transparency is very great. In the most recent international ranking of transparency in the management of SWFs, published by the Sovereign Wealth Fund Institute (2011), Chile ranked first, together with SWFs of seven other countries, including Norway’s Pension Fund (Figure 7.2). In general terms, the current state of transparency and accountability of Chile’s government accounts is varied, ranging from moderate to high.
Transparency of Sovereign Wealth Funds, 2011
Source: Sovereign Wealth Fund Institute (2011).Note: 1MDB: 1 Malaysia Development Berhad; ADIA: Abu Dhabi Investment Authority; CAD: China-Africa Development; CIC: China Investment Corporation; EIA: Emirates Investment Authority; GIC: Government of Singapore Investment Corporation; IPIC: International Petroleum Investment Company; NSSF: National Social Security Fund; PIF: Public Investment Fund; SAFE: State Administration of Foreign Exchange; SAMA: Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency; UAE: United Arab Emirates; US: United States.External Control and Auditing
There are three levels of external control and auditing of government budgets and accounts—the legislature, the government’s general comptroller or auditor, and fiscal councils and committees. In most countries, congress and especially the general comptroller exercise traditional accounting, financial, and managerial control of budget execution and government accounts. More recently, countries have been adopting fiscal committees and councils, which are empowered to provide an economic assessment of fiscal policy design and execution.
In Chile, government accountability in regard to budgetary compliance is largely limited to oversight and control by the General Comptroller’s Office (Contraloría General de la República). This institution focuses on accounting, procedural, and legal compliance by the government in its implementation of fiscal policy and execution of the budget. This oversight and control function by the General Comptroller is exercised at all levels of government. In this way, the General Comptroller’s Office has contributed decisively, both in the past and today, to limiting the extent of illegal government actions and government corruption.
However, there is almost no substantive ex ante, real-time, or ex post evaluation of fiscal policy implementation and its compliance with the fiscal rule, of government spending (either mandatory or discretionary), and of the efficiency and effectiveness of government programs and tax collection efforts. There are simply very few resources spent by congress, political parties, think tanks, or academia in conducting systematic evaluation of fiscal policy and its implementation due to the absence of an independent FC and/or a think tank or institute that focuses on fiscal policy. The only exceptions in regard to this dearth of fiscal policy evaluation are some academic papers and some initiatives at the MoF to assess sporadically some partial aspects of fiscal policy.
Fiscal Committees and Fiscal Councils
Fiscal committees are temporary or permanent advisory bodies to the MoF that are entrusted with specific narrow tasks such as providing advice on institutional changes or investments of SWFs. Their recommendations may or may not be binding on the government.
Independent FCs (and budget offices) are permanent government or congressional agencies entrusted with much broader tasks. Their recommendations can be binding on governments, more often than those of fiscal committees.
Although fiscal committees and FCs have different tasks, the latter may include the following (Debrun and Kumar, 2007; Debrun, Hauner, and Kumar, 2009; Ter-Minassian, 2010; Calmfors and Wren-Lewis, 2011):
Evaluation and validation of financial and macroeconomic assumptions for the budget;
Provision of independent projections for the budget and government financial conditions, both for the base scenario and risk scenarios, for the short term and the long term;
Provision of policy assessments and recommendations on fiscal policy and budgetary management, based on ex ante evaluation of whether fiscal policy is likely to meet its targets;
Assessment and advice to the government and/or the legislature on the stance of fiscal policy, its long-term sustainability and optimality, and its macroeconomic effects;
Assessment of and recommendations regarding policies for government asset and liability management;
Monitoring of budget implementation and provision of recommendations for budgetary corrections in cases of deviations in budget execution; and
Analysis of fiscal transparency.
Some governments (like Chile’s) have adopted advisory committees of the MoF that provide recommendations, both binding and not binding, on some aspects of the menu of possible tasks identified above.
Other governments have adopted advisory offices of the legislature to provide an independent analysis of the basis and consequences of fiscal policy and budgets of the respective governments. That is the case of the U.S. Congressional Budget Office, which was founded in 1974 (Rivlin, 2010), and the Parliamentary Budget Office in Canada, which was founded in 2008 (Levy, 2008), as well as similar offices in other countries, like Japan, the Republic of Korea, and Mexico.
Among the countries with some kind of FC are many members of the European Union (several with more than one FC), including Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Estonia, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, and the United Kingdom (Debrun, Hauner, and Kumar, 2009). Outside the EU, Japan and Sweden have fiscal agencies in place that provide tax advice. Debrun and Kumar (2007) provide some statistical evidence in support of the notion that FCs in the EU’s 25 member countries have contributed to fiscal discipline, especially when advice in regard to this is provided by an agency mandated by an ad hoc law. Yet the more recent fiscal crisis in several euro area member countries raises doubts regarding these findings.
More recently, and partly in response to fiscal crises, a rising number of countries (including France and the United Kingdom) have adopted or are adopting stronger FCs, based on an ad hoc law that grants them substantial degrees of government independence, strengthening their capabilities to provide independent assessment and advice. This new brand of FC—as well as some of the existing councils—tends to exhibit the following features:
Chile lacks an independent FC, but it has in place independent fiscal committees or expert groups: the Advisory Committee for Trend GDP of the MoF (ACTG), the Advisory Committee for the Reference Copper Price of the MoF (ACRCP), and the Financial Advisory Committee on Sovereign Funds of the MoF. Their role is limited to a consulting or advisory function, as stipulated by the 2006 Fiscal Responsibility Law.
The ACTG provides the MoF with projections for the rate of growth of capital, the labor force, and total factor productivity (TFP), which are used by the MoF to generate projections of potential GDP growth and the output gap, based on an MoF methodology. The ACRCP provides the MoF with projections of the international long-term or trend copper price. Current-year projections for the next year’s output gap and trend copper price are key inputs for the structural fiscal balance rule, which, as mandated by the Fiscal Responsibility Law, is key for determining the overall government budget envelope, that is, to set the levels of government spending, structural and actual government revenue, and hence the actual and structural government balance.
The three individual projections made by each of the 16 members of the ACTG and the single projection made by each of the 12 members of the ACRCP are binding for the budget. Each member provides projections that are averaged, after elimination of the two most extreme observations, to generate the MoF’s official estimates for the four variables. However, the MoF maintains significant discretionary power in determining the methodology (i.e., the equations and parameters) for setting how the structural fiscal balance rule and the four projected variables translate into budgetary projections. Although the MoF has been increasingly transparent about the details of its method, as reflected in technical papers, the summary notes of the ACTG and ACRCP annual meetings, and the 2010 Budget Law for 2011, this information also reflects remaining discretion maintained by the MoF in defining the government’s overall resource envelope.
Independent members of both of these advisory committees are invited by the MoF to serve for one budgetary exercise. Members are selected and designated by the MoF among the local communities of macroeconomists (for the ACTG) and copper market experts (for the ACRCP). They attend one technical meeting held at the MoF in July or August of each year and are then invited to submit their individual projections in the following weeks. Between August and October of each year, the MoF publishes two official notes, one for each advisory committee, that report individual and averaged projections and, in the case of the ACTG, potential growth and output gap estimates. There is no formal or direct communication by any of the two committees with congress or the press.
In contrast to the two previous committees, the Financial Advisory Committee on Sovereign Funds is based on a more formal institutional setup. The committee’s six independent members are selected by the MoF from among the local community of macroeconomists and financial experts, and their overlapping tenure is two years. The committee is composed of its chair (a president), a vice-president, and four additional members. The committee meets on average every six weeks at the MoF. Members are remunerated for their attendance at committee meetings. The secretariat of the committee is the international financial directorate of the MoF. Its head acts as secretary of the committee, and his staff (also present at committee meetings) prepares technical reports on international financial conditions and financial performance of SWF investments for each meeting. Committee members discuss financial developments and their implications for the performance of the funds, evaluate fund management by the CBC and meet occasionally with bank managers of the funds, and issue recommendations about fund investment policy and regulation to the MoF. It is very important to note that committee recommendations, in contrast to the projections submitted by the two aforementioned committees, are not binding on the MoF.
The committee issues a press communiqué after each meeting and publishes an annual report on the funds’ financial results and the committee’s investment policy recommendations to the MoF.
Chile’s Fiscal Rule
The Rule
Chile’s fiscal rule for the central government budget was developed in 2000 and implemented in 2001 by Finance Minister Nicolás Eyzaguirre and his main advisors. Although the rule has been subjected to several changes, its main features have remained unaltered. Therefore, it is now in its twelfth year of operation through three different administrations—the governments of presidents Lagos (2000 to 2006), Bachelet (2006 to 2010), and Piñera (since 2010), who is committed to its continuation through the 2010–14 term.
Chile’s fiscal rule aims at contributing to two policy objectives—fiscal sus-tainability and fiscal/macroeconomic stability. Fiscal stability is ensured by committing to a target level for the government’s CAB that is consistent with government saving needs (net of government investment). Fiscal (and possibly macroeconomic) stability is attained by committing to a government spending path that is consistent with cyclically adjusted government revenue.1 Therefore, Chile’s CAB rule combines a partial application of the permanent-income theory to government spending with a target level for long-term government saving. Hence, the rule’s aim is to save during high-revenue periods in order to withdraw from the latter savings in bad times, over and above saving or dissaving a fraction of government revenue over the cycle, that is, the CAB.
Chile’s largest sources of government cyclical volatility (i.e., the budget’s largest sensitivity to cyclical variables) are nonmining tax revenue and mining tax and transfer revenue. The business cycle reflected in the cyclical component of GDP largely determines the cyclical behavior of nonmining tax revenue, whereas mining tax and transfer revenue is largely determined by the cyclical component of the prices of copper and molybdenum.2
Chile’s government spending, compared to that of other OECD countries, is relatively insensitive to the business cycle because of the small size of automatic stabilizers on the expenditure side, such as government-financed unemployment benefits or institutionalized public employment programs during cyclical downturns. Hence, the fiscal rule distinguishes between actual and cyclically adjusted government revenue, but not between actual and cyclically adjusted government expenditure.
Therefore, the fiscal rule is embedded in the following equation for the cyclical component of the government balance, that is, the difference between the CAB and the actual balance of the central government. This difference boils down to the difference between cyclically adjusted and actual government revenue, which is determined by the difference between cyclically adjusted and cyclical nonmining tax revenue and social security receipts (driven by the output gap), and between cyclically adjusted and cyclical differences in private mining tax revenue, CODELCO (the government-owned copper corporation) copper transfers to the budget, and CODELCO molybdenum transfers to the budget:
where
= government CAB, | |
Bt | = actual central government balance, |
= cyclically adjusted central government revenue, | |
Rt | = actual central government revenue, |
Gt | = actual central government expenditure, |
= cyclically adjusted net nonmining tax revenues and social security receipts, | |
NMTRt | = net nonmining tax revenues and social security receipts, |
MTRt | = actual tax revenue from private mining companies, |
= cyclically adjusted tax revenue from private mining companies, | |
CRt | = actual transfers from CODELCO copper sales, |
= cyclically adjusted transfers from CODELCO copper sales, | |
MRt | = actual transfers from CODELCO molybdenum sales, |
= cyclically adjusted transfers from CODELCO molybdenum sales, and | |
t | = time period subscript. |
= government CAB, | |
Bt | = actual central government balance, |
= cyclically adjusted central government revenue, | |
Rt | = actual central government revenue, |
Gt | = actual central government expenditure, |
= cyclically adjusted net nonmining tax revenues and social security receipts, | |
NMTRt | = net nonmining tax revenues and social security receipts, |
MTRt | = actual tax revenue from private mining companies, |
= cyclically adjusted tax revenue from private mining companies, | |
CRt | = actual transfers from CODELCO copper sales, |
= cyclically adjusted transfers from CODELCO copper sales, | |
MRt | = actual transfers from CODELCO molybdenum sales, |
= cyclically adjusted transfers from CODELCO molybdenum sales, and | |
t | = time period subscript. |
Simple reordering of the identity part of equation (7.1) shows that the fiscal rule boils down to limiting actual government spending to cyclically adjusted revenue net of the CAB:
Cyclically adjusted (i.e., trend or long-term) variables are nonobservable, and therefore estimates of them are required for implementation of the fiscal rule. As discussed previously, estimates of nonobservables are outsourced annually to private sector commissions in preparation of the submission of the budget law and are finally approved by congress. Implementation of fiscal policy during the subsequent budget (i.e., calendar) year abides by the budget law and the fiscal rule.
There are three key elasticities in the fiscal rule. The first one is the output gap elasticity of nonmining tax revenue, which is explicitly reflected in equation (7.1). Until 2008, the MoF fixed this parameter at a value of 1.05, which implicitly assumes that nonmining government revenue varies almost proportionately to cyclical GDP. This aggregate elasticity was replaced in 2009 by separate elasticities for different categories of tax revenue, varying between 1.0 and 2.4 (Rodríguez, Escobar, and Joratt, 2009).
The second and third elasticities are the copper and molybdenum price elasticities of the three mining revenue items in equation (7.1). There are no explicit values attached by the MoF to the two latter elasticities. Instead, the Budget Office of the Ministry of Finance (DIPRES) produces annual estimates for mining tax and transfer receipts at actual and trend prices for both minerals.
Rule Implementation, Changes, and Budget Performance
Let’s now look at how the rule was implemented, the changes that were introduced to its definition and implementation, and the budget performance under the rule.
Although the fiscal rule has been in place since January 2001, several institutional and methodological additions and changes have subsequently been introduced (Velasco and others, 2010; Advisory Committee on Fiscal policy, 2011). During the initial phase, the following refinements were made:
The ACTG of the MoF was invited to submit growth projections (August 2001).
Methodology for CAB was published (September 2001).
The ACRCP of the MoF was invited to submit long-term copper price projections (August 2004).
Government statistics were changed from a cash basis to an accrual basis in 2004, following the 2001 IMF methodology (February 2004).
The following methodological changes were introduced into the fiscal rule in regard to the treatment of mining revenue:
Inclusion of cyclical adjustment of private mining tax revenue (August 2005);
Inclusion of cyclical adjustment of the price of molybdenum in the revenue paid by the state mining company CODELCO (December 2005);
Inclusion of cyclical adjustment of the new royalty tax on mining (January 2006);
Inclusion of cyclical adjustment of the additional tax on mining (December 2006); and
Amendment to the cyclical adjustment of the royalty tax on mining (considering monthly provisional payments) (December 2007).
The following changes were introduced into the fiscal rule, extending the principle of cyclical adjustment to other variables (beyond GDP and prices of minerals) and to temporary tax changes:
Inclusion of cyclical adjustment of interest revenue on government assets (September 2008);
Inclusion of adjustments to nonmining tax revenue considering temporary tax cuts (January 2009); and
Inclusion of cyclical adjustment to operational income and property income on nonfinancial government assets (January 2010).
On advice of the Advisory Committee on Fiscal Policy (2010, 2011), the three latter changes were reversed by the government in 2010. Therefore, these partial attempts to extend the fiscal rule from a CAB rule to a structural rule based on an estimate of permanent government income—introducing adjustments to all variables with temporary components, including tax rates and, eventually, expenditure items—reverted to the methodology that defined the rule in 2001 through 2007. Hence, following international best practice adopted by the OECD, the IMF, and the European Commission (Ter-Minassian, 2010), Chile’s fiscal rule was limited to cyclical adjustments. However, in contrast to that in most other countries, the rule adjusts for the cyclical component not only of the GDP, but also of Chile’s key commodity prices, that is, copper and molybdenum.
Trend GDP Growth and Output Gap Projection by the Ministry of Finance in 2010, 1990–2015
(Percent)
Source: Report of the Advisory Committee for Trend GDP. Note: GDP: gross domestic product.The independent ACTG of the MoF provides annual growth projections (six years ahead) for production factors, which are then used by the MoF to generate potential GDP growth and output gap projections.3 The most recent (August 2010) potential GDP growth and output gap projections by the MoF, based in part on committee input projections, are reported in Figure 7.3. These projections determine the resource envelope for the 2011 budget. Note that these figures are ex post (August 2010) estimates of Chile’s current and past output gap estimates and hence are not the actual output gap estimates used in implementing the fiscal rule in previous years (i.e., 2001 to 2010). For example, 2010 backcasts of 2001–09 potential growth rates are significantly lower than MoF potential growth rates estimated in previous years, which were at 5 percent and above. As time has passed, this has implied a significant upward correction of output gap estimates and hence a downward correction of budgeted government expenditure; that is, ceteris paribus, a contractionary fiscal policy.
Committee’s Projections, Average Actual Future GDP Growth, and Actual GDP Growth, 2002–10
(Percent)
Source: Author’s calculations based on data published in the 2011 report of the Advisory Committee for Trend GDP.Note: Committee’s projected average trend gross domestic product (GDP) growth is the average of all future projections made by the committee at the corresponding year. Average actual future growth is average GDP growth from a rolling window from year t through year t + 4.Figure 7.4 depicts for any given year current GDP growth, the ACTG’s long-term growth projection, and, to show implicit forecast errors, actual average future growth between the subsequent year and 2010. The gap between committee growth forecasts and actual average future growth rates grows from 2005 through 2009.
As noted previously, a second committee, the ACRCP, provides a point estimate for the world (London Metal Exchange) copper price over the subsequent decade. Figure 7.5 depicts for any given year the current copper price, the ACRCP’s long-term copper price projection, and, to show implicit forecast errors, the actual average future price of copper between the subsequent year and 2010. As the actual copper price has risen over time, the committee’s future trend price estimate has been adjusted upward significantly, but the gap between projected and average actual future prices through 2010 (a measure of the forecast error) has remained roughly constant over the decade. Yet the major upward correction of the long-term copper price has meant an upward correction of budgeted government expenditure, that is, ceteris paribus, an expansionary fiscal policy.
Committee’s Projected Copper Price, Average Actual Copper Price, and Actual Copper Price, 2001–11
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data published in reports of the Advisory Committee for the Reference Copper Price and by the Central Bank of Chile.Note: Committee’s long-term copper price projection is the forecast made at the corresponding year. PCu is average copper price from the corresponding year through 2010; for 2011, the actual average price from January through August of US$3/lb was used. Average actual future copper price is the average price from a rolling window from year t through year t+ 4.How much do current observations of GDP growth and the copper price affect the committees’ forecasts? Certainly a lot, as reflected by the high correlations between current or lagged growth and growth projections and between current or lagged copper price and copper price projections, which range from 0.63 to 0.77 (see Table 7.2).
Correlations between Committee Projections and Actual Future Variables, 1990–2010
Correlations between Committee Projections and Actual Future Variables, 1990–2010
Actual copper price (t – 1) and projected copper price (t) | 0.77 |
Actual copper price (t) and projected copper price (t) | 0.63 |
Actual GDP growth (t) and projected GDP growth (t) | 0.64 |
Actual GDP growth (t – 1) and projected GDP growth (t) | 0.76 |
Correlations between Committee Projections and Actual Future Variables, 1990–2010
Actual copper price (t – 1) and projected copper price (t) | 0.77 |
Actual copper price (t) and projected copper price (t) | 0.63 |
Actual GDP growth (t) and projected GDP growth (t) | 0.64 |
Actual GDP growth (t – 1) and projected GDP growth (t) | 0.76 |
A key policy variable is the target value for the CAB (B*). For the first seven years of the fiscal rule, the CAB was set at a positive 1 percent of GDP. The rationale behind this very conservative fiscal policy was the need for positive central government saving to finance government pension liabilities, recapitalize the CBC, and finance several government contingent liabilities, including the government pension subsidy.
For 2008, the CAB was reduced to 0.5 percent of GDP based on recommendations of fiscal sustainability studies (Engel, Marcel, and Meller, 2007; Velasco and others, 2007). In the face of a domestic recession due to the international crisis in January 2009, the CAB was further reduced to a balanced (0 percent of GDP) CAB in 2009. These two figures were based on the methodological changes introduced between September 2008 and January 2010, which were subsequently reversed.
Ratios of Actual and Cyclically Adjusted Central Government Balance to GDP, 1990–2010
(Percent)
Source: Chilean Budget directorate.Using the current methodology for the fiscal rule (returning to the principles applied between 2001 and 2007), the actual CAB ratios stood at −0.6 percent of GDP in 2008 and −3.0 percent of GDP in 2009. The new 2010 administration prepared a medium-term fiscal policy framework that implies a gradual correction of the large negative CAB recorded in 2009. The CAB was raised to −2.0 percent of GDP in 2010 and a budgeted −1.8 percent of GDP in 2011. The administration is committed to further fiscal adjustment toward attaining a CAB of −1.0 percent of GDP in 2014.
Figure 7.6 depicts the ratio of the CAB to GDP, the ratio of the actual balance to GDP, and their difference (the ratio of the cyclical balance to GDP) during the 1990s (without a fiscal rule) and the 2000s (with the fiscal rule in place).4 The data support the following policy conclusions:
Cyclical shocks to the government budget (reflected by the ratio of the cyclical balance to GDP) are very large.
Cyclical shocks to the budget are dominated by the volatility of copper prices, not by the volatility of GDP, as reflected by the larger cyclical components recorded in the 2001–10 period.
The fiscal rule allows for large government saving flows during cyclical booms.
Even without a fiscal rule, fiscal policy was conservative during most of the 1990s, but during domestic cyclical downturns (the 1998 and 2009 recessions), the fiscal rule provides insufficient space for a stronger countercyclical policy, leading to significant downward adjustments of the CAB. In 2008, the fiscal rule was effectively suspended by substituting for the 0.5 percent ex ante ratio of the CAB to GDP a −0.6 percent ex post ratio of the CAB to GDP, which was further reduced to a −3.0 percent ex post ratio of the CAB to GDP in 2009.
Figures 7.7 and 7.8 depict the behavior of the ratios of government revenue and expenditure to GDP and growth rates, respectively, during the 1990s (without a fiscal rule) and the 2000s (under the fiscal rule). Government revenue growth strongly reflects the copper price and domestic GDP cycles. The upward correction in long-term copper price forecasts (dominating the downward correction in trend GDP forecasts) and the downward adjustment in CAB targets explain the large rise of government expenditure growth, from 1.6 percent in 2003 to 17.8 percent in 2009. The average government spending increase attained 10 percent during the Bachelet administration (2006–09), when GDP growth was 2.7 percent. This large fiscal expansion was reflected in a 24.8 percent share of government expenditure in GDP in 2009, the largest ratio of government spending to GDP recorded in several decades. The current administration’s commitment to gradually raise the CAB toward −1.0 percent in 2014 is likely to entail government expenditure growth below GDP growth, hence reducing the share of government spending in GDP, as observed in 2010. Figure 7.9 reflects the mining and nonmining component of government revenue since 2005, confirming the greater volatility of mining revenue. Figure 7.10 shows the increase in net government assets during recent years.
Ratios of Central Government Expenditure and Revenue to GDP, 1990–2010
(Percent)
Source: Chilean budget directorate.Central Government Revenue and Expenditure Growth Rates, 1991–2010
(Percent)
Source: Chilean budget directorate.Correlations between budget variables and GDP growth and the price of copper for 1990–2010 and the subperiods before and during the fiscal rule reflect the following (see Table 7.3):
A large increase in the correlation between the price of copper and overall government revenue in the 2000s due to the larger share of mining revenue and larger volatility of copper prices observed in the 2000s
A large increase in the correlation (when quarterly data are used) between the price of copper and the actual government balance (see Table 7.4)
A reversal of a large negative correlation between the price of copper and net government assets (at −0.4 in the 1990s) to a large positive correlation between the two latter variables (at +0.9 in the 2000s)
These results suggest that adoption of the fiscal rule has made a difference for fiscal policy in Chile—a copper price shock is more likely to be saved and reflected in higher government assets than before the fiscal rule was adopted.
Correlations between Government Budget Variables, GDP Growth, and Copper Prices, 1990–2010 and Subperiods
Correlations between Government Budget Variables, GDP Growth, and Copper Prices, 1990–2010 and Subperiods
Quarterly data | 1990–2010 | 1990–2000 | 2001–2010 |
---|---|---|---|
Total revenue/GDP—GDP growth | 0.08 | 0.30 | 0.11 |
Total revenue/GDP—copper price ($US) | 0.83 | 0.19 | 0.80 |
Total expenditure/GDP—GDP growth | 0.00 | −0.01 | 0.07 |
Total expenditure/GDP—copper price ($US) | 0.47 | 0.02 | 0.34 |
Government balance/GDP—GDP growth | 0.08 | 0.26 | 0.07 |
Government balance/GDP—copper price ($US) | 0.60 | 0.15 | 0.57 |
Annual data | 1990–2010 | 1990–2000 | 2001–2010 |
Net government assets/GDP—GDP growth | −0.36 | −0.21 | −0.19 |
Net government assets/GDP—copper price ($US) | 0.71 | −0.41 | 0.91 |
Government balance/GDP—GDP growth | 0.34 | 0.78 | 0.58 |
Government balance/GDP—copper price ($US) | 0.59 | 0.77 | 0.57 |
Correlations between Government Budget Variables, GDP Growth, and Copper Prices, 1990–2010 and Subperiods
Quarterly data | 1990–2010 | 1990–2000 | 2001–2010 |
---|---|---|---|
Total revenue/GDP—GDP growth | 0.08 | 0.30 | 0.11 |
Total revenue/GDP—copper price ($US) | 0.83 | 0.19 | 0.80 |
Total expenditure/GDP—GDP growth | 0.00 | −0.01 | 0.07 |
Total expenditure/GDP—copper price ($US) | 0.47 | 0.02 | 0.34 |
Government balance/GDP—GDP growth | 0.08 | 0.26 | 0.07 |
Government balance/GDP—copper price ($US) | 0.60 | 0.15 | 0.57 |
Annual data | 1990–2010 | 1990–2000 | 2001–2010 |
Net government assets/GDP—GDP growth | −0.36 | −0.21 | −0.19 |
Net government assets/GDP—copper price ($US) | 0.71 | −0.41 | 0.91 |
Government balance/GDP—GDP growth | 0.34 | 0.78 | 0.58 |
Government balance/GDP—copper price ($US) | 0.59 | 0.77 | 0.57 |
Correlations between Macroeconomic Variables, 1990–2010
(quarterly data)
Correlations between Macroeconomic Variables, 1990–2010
(quarterly data)
Copper price | EMBI | Real exchange rate | GDP growth | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Copper price | 0.33 | −0.22 | −0.47 | 0.59 |
EMBI | −0.44 | 0.37 | 0.24 | −0.29 |
Real exchange rate | −0.61 | 0.46 | 0.3 | −0.81 |
GDP growth | −0.14 | 0 | 0.07 | 0.65 |
Correlations between Macroeconomic Variables, 1990–2010
(quarterly data)
Copper price | EMBI | Real exchange rate | GDP growth | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Copper price | 0.33 | −0.22 | −0.47 | 0.59 |
EMBI | −0.44 | 0.37 | 0.24 | −0.29 |
Real exchange rate | −0.61 | 0.46 | 0.3 | −0.81 |
GDP growth | −0.14 | 0 | 0.07 | 0.65 |
Evaluation of the Fiscal Rule and ITS Macroeconomic Impact
Several studies have provided qualitative arguments or quantitative estimates about the fiscal policy benefits and macroeconomic effects of Chile’s fiscal rule. The main fiscal policy consequences of the CAB rule, which implies an acyclical government expenditure path, have been the following: a reduction of procyclical bias in fiscal policy, delinking government expenditure from cyclical shocks and strengthening the role of government saving in buffering cyclical shocks (Larraín and Parro, 2006; Rodríguez, Tokman, and Vega, 2006; Kumhof and Laxton, 2009; Velasco and others, 2010; Frankel, 2010; Marcel, 2010; IMF, 2010; Ter-Minassian, 2010; Schmidt-Hebbel, 2010; OECD, 2010), and gains in fiscal sustainability and credibility, reflected in lower sovereign risk premiums (Fiess, 2004; Larraín and Parro, 2006; Lefort, 2006; Rodríguez, Tokman, and Vega, 2006; Kumhof and Laxton, 2009; Velasco and others, 2010; Marcel, 2010; IMF, 2010; Ter-Minassian, 2010; Schmidt-Hebbel, 2010; OECD, 2010).
Simulation studies for Chile’s fiscal rule show the following:
The rule performs well if the policymaker puts a small weight on output volatility relative to inflation volatility in his or her objective function, and a more aggressive countercyclical fiscal rule can attain a lower output volatility, but at the cost of a higher volatility in fiscal variables and in inflation (Kumhof and Laxton, 2009, using a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model for Chile); and
The efficiency frontier derived from countercyclical government spending dominates the frontier attainable when spending is cyclically neutral, as it is under the current fiscal rule. The major welfare gain of a countercyclical rule is due to lower output volatility, while spending volatility rises (García, 2011, using a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model for Chile).
Government spending volatility is increased by a broader government objective function that puts a positive weight on countercyclical spending and is lowered by a broader government objective function that puts a negative weight on large changes in government spending (Advisory Committee on Fiscal Policy, 2011, using a generalized government objective function in partial equilibrium).
Other studies argue that the rule has implied—or they have measured—the following macroeconomic effects:
Generally, lower macroeconomic uncertainty and volatility (Fiess, 2004; Larraín and Parro, 2006; Rodríguez, Tokman, and Vega, 2006; Kumhof and Laxton, 2009; Velasco and others, 2010; Marcel, 2010; IMF, 2010; Ter-Minassian, 2010; Schmidt-Hebbel, 2010; OECD, 2010);
A reduction in GDP volatility by 32 percent (Larraín and Parro, 2006);
Lower interest rate volatility (Rodríguez, Tokman, and Vega, 2006);
Lower exchange rate volatility and less real exchange rate appreciation during booms (Velasco and others, 2010);
Less dependence on foreign financing during downturns (Rodríguez, Tokman, and Vega, 2006; Velasco and others, 2010);
Better protection of social spending during cyclical downturns (Rodríguez, Tokman, and Vega, 2006; Velasco and others, 2010).
Has the response of fiscal variables and selected macroeconomic and financial variables to a copper price shock changed since the start of the fiscal rule? This question can by answered by simulating impulse responses of key fiscal, financial, and macroeconomic variables to a copper price. For this purpose, we can estimate vector autoregressions for the Chilean economy using quarterly data for 1990 to 2010 for the variables (from most exogenous to most endogenous): copper price growth, change in Emerging Markets Bond Index (EMBI) Chile sovereign risk spread, real exchange rate growth, change in actual fiscal balance ratio to GDP, and GDP growth (see Table 7.4 for correlations between these variables). Vector autoregression estimations are performed for the full 1990–2000 period and separately for the subsample before the fiscal rule (1990–2000) and since the start of the rule (2001–10).
The impulse response functions for a temporary 10 percent copper price shock (which dies off quickly one-quarter after it occurs) are depicted in Figures 7.11, 7.12, and 7.13 for the three periods, and the contrasting results for 1990 to 2000 and 2001 to 2010 are compared.
Estimated Impulse Responses to a Copper Price Shock, Full Sample, 1990–2010
Source: Author’s simulation.Note: The quarterly impulse response functions are based on vector autoregression estimations described in the text. The temporary copper price shock is a 10 percent rise in the first quarter, which is partly reversed in the second quarter (plus 2 percent) and statistically fully reversed from the third quarter onward. The figures show impulse response functions and their corresponding 90 percent confidence bands. EMBI: Emerging Markets Bond Index; GDP: gross domestic product.Estimated Impulse Responses to a Copper Price Shock, 1990–2000
(before Fiscal Rule)
Source: Author’s simulation.Note: The quarterly impulse response functions are based on vector autoregression estimations described in the text. The temporary copper price shock is a 10 percent rise in the first quarter, which is partly reversed in the second quarter (plus 2 percent) and statistically fully reversed from the third quarter onward. The figures show impulse response functions and their corresponding 90 percent confidence bands. EMBI: Emerging Markets Bond Index; GDP: gross domestic product.Estimated Impulse Responses to a Copper Price Shock, 2001–10
(during Fiscal Rule)
Source: Author’s simulation.Note: The quarterly impulse response functions are based on vector autoregression estimations described in the text. The temporary copper price shock is a 10 percent rise in the first quarter, which is partly reversed in the second quarter (plus 2 percent) and statistically fully reversed from the third quarter onward. The figures show impulse response functions and their corresponding 90 percent confidence bands. EMBI: Emerging Markets Bond Index; GDP: gross domestic product.During 1990–2000, the copper price shock does not have any impact on the sovereign risk premium and the fiscal balance, but it contributes to a temporary real exchange rate appreciation and a temporary decline in growth.
Very different results are observed for the same copper price shock in 2001–10. Now it causes a decline in the sovereign debt premium by 20 basis points, which is consistent with a rise in the government balance by an average 1 percentage point during five quarters, which leads to higher SWFs (not included in the simulation). The real exchange rate appreciates by 3 percent for one quarter, which is consistent with the EMBI-induced reduction in the cost of foreign financing. GDP growth now responds positively with a delayed increase by 0.7 percentage points in the third quarter after the copper price shock.
Therefore, the fiscal rule has made an effective and significant contribution to isolate government spending from cyclical copper price (and GDP) shocks. Government savings in SWFs has taken the role of the key buffer variable, contributing in this way to stabilizing output and the exchange rate.
Last but not least, the fiscal rule has strengthened the political economy of fiscal policy and government spending, making budget management more resilient to pressures from lobbies and interest groups to spend cyclical government revenue stemming from temporary copper windfalls and domestic income booms.
Shortcomings of Chile’s Fiscal Rule and Proposals for Reform
By and large, Chile’s fiscal rule has proven to be a successful instrument for strengthening fiscal sustainability, reducing the procyclical bias in fiscal policy and spending, contributing to macroeconomic stability, and strengthening the political economy of fiscal policy. Yet several shortcomings are still observed in the design and implementation of the fiscal rule and in Chile’s institutional framework that governs fiscal policy. Hence, the Minister of Finance of the new Piñera administration, Felipe Larraín, convened an Advisory Committee for the Design of a Fiscal Policy Based on a Second-Generation Structural Balance for Chile to assess shortcomings and propose reforms of the rule and the fiscal institutions. The committee was formed in May 2010 and met through January 2011, delivering a preliminary report in August 2010 (Advisory Committee on Fiscal Policy, 2010) and a final report in January 2011 (Advisory Committee on Fiscal Policy, 2011). On the general methodology of the fiscal rule, the committee made the following recommendations:
On the methodology for estimating the cyclically adjusted revenue associated with GDP and the methods for estimating trend GDP, the committee made the following recommendations:
On the methodology for estimating the cyclically adjusted revenue associated with mining prices and the methods for estimating long-term prices of copper and molybdenum, the committee made the following recommendations:
Regarding the institutional framework, international best practice in recent years suggests that fiscal policies and the adoption of fiscal rules are strengthened by the establishment of agencies that audit fiscal projections, assess the achievement of fiscal policy objectives, and promote policy transparency. In this regard, the committee recommended adoption of an FC with a mandate and tasks defined by a statutory law, supported by council members, staff, and consultants. The FC’s main tasks would comprise the following:
Finally, the committee made recommendations to strengthen transparency, accountability, and consistency of fiscal policy in Chile, among which the following are the most important:
Fiscal Policy Lessons for Commodity-Exporting Countries
Fiscal policy and macroeconomic performance of commodity-exporting economies are often strongly affected by commodity price booms and busts. Weak government institutions, an underdeveloped fiscal policy framework, and the absence of a fiscal rule lead to procyclical fiscal policy bias. Commodity price booms lead to excessive public and private spending, undersaving and overbor-rowing, excessive credit growth and leveraging, domestic asset price bubbles, and exchange rate overappreciation. Conversely, when the international commodity price booms are halted and end in price busts, fiscal and private sector spending is curtailed, sometimes dramatically, as a result of foreign and domestic lending reversals, leading to a domestic recession, firm bankruptcies, and job losses. The latter effects are compounded by a financial crisis such as some combination of a banking crisis, government and external debt default, and major nominal and real exchange rate depreciation.
Weak political and fiscal policy institutions have adverse effects that go well beyond Dutch disease and financial crises in commodity-exporting countries. Opaque budgetary management and external control, lack of transparent fiscal policies and budgets, and poor budgetary accountability lead to ineffective and inefficient government spending, misuse of government resources, and corruption.
Adoption of a modern institutional framework for fiscal policy can make a major contribution to lessening the adverse impact of commodity price bubbles and strengthening efficiency and good use of government resources. Such a framework is instrumental for the dual goal of fiscal policy—attaining and maintaining fiscal solvency (or budgetary sustainability) and contributing to cyclical and macroeconomic stabilization.
A large body of empirical international research shows that fiscal (and monetary) procyclicality is more likely in countries with poor fiscal governance, high levels of corruption, low fiscal credibility, domestic financial underdevelopment, and weak integration into world financial markets (Ilzetzki and Végh, 2008; Calderón and Schmidt-Hebbel, 2008; Calderón, Duncan, and Schmidt-Hebbel, 2010).
One effective way to break out of fiscal procyclicality—in both commodity-exporting and other economies—is to reform fiscal policy institutions, including by adopting a fiscal rule. Certainly this is much easier than tackling domestic and external financial underdevelopment and means working at improving fiscal governance and fiscal policy and, eventually, reducing corruption.
The international experience and Chile’s case suggest that both economics and the political economy of fiscal policy are strengthened by the following reforms of fiscal institutions and policies.
Strengthening the Institutional Framework of Fiscal Policy
Developing the institutional framework for fiscal policy and budget planning and execution comprises five components:
Fiscal responsibility law: Adopt a legal framework, specifying budgetary procedures and rules to strengthen fiscal policy transparency, accountability, and stability. Fiscal responsibility laws establish requirements for governments to state transparently their short- and medium-term policy objectives, to set short- and medium-term targets for fiscal flows and stocks, to provide transparent information on budget planning and execution to the legislature, to implement a fiscal policy conducive to fiscal stability and solvency, and to account ex post for fiscal policy execution and attainment of policy objectives.
Financial management of the budget: The core elements for efficient budgetary management by the MoF comprise granting strong powers to the MoF on legal initiatives with budgetary impact and in budget decisions regarding other ministries and government levels, commanding a high technical capacity for budgetary planning, adopting modern accounting principles, ensuring an efficient process of legislative approval of the budget that limits the possibility of congressional amendments, and developing a large capacity for monitoring budget execution.
Budget planning horizon: Extend budgetary planning from one-year to multiyear horizons.
Fiscal policy accountability and transparency of budgetary information: For both economic efficiency and political legitimacy goals, accountability of fiscal policy and transparency in provision of information of government accounts should be improved significantly.
External control and auditing: Countries should strengthen external control and auditing functions of fiscal policy, budget execution, and government accounts at three levels—congress, the government’s general comptroller or auditor, and fiscal councils and committees.
Adoption of a Fiscal Rule
Adoption of a fiscal rule based on a CAB is the key reform required to avoid a procyclical bias in fiscal policy and government spending. For noncommodity exporters, cyclical adjustment may be limited to domestic GDP shocks; for commodity exporters, however, it is key to add cyclical adjustments to price shocks for their commodities. As is the case in Chile, for most commodity exporters, the largest source of government revenue volatility is precisely the price volatility of their commodity exports, not domestic GDP volatility. Moreover, domestic GDP volatility is likely to be lowered (as has been the case in Chile) by adoption of a rule that accounts for both GDP and commodity price volatility.
A successful fiscal rule will have a positive impact on the stability of government spending and government programs, fiscal policy sustainability and credibility, and overall macroeconomic stability. To achieve success, the fiscal rule should satisfy the following conditions:
Based on calculations and formulas that are relatively stable over time;
Based on assumptions and calculations that should be made public, together with the relevant budgetary information, to be replicated by outsiders; and
Part of an institutional environment that supports independent or unbiased provision of key economic and financial forecasts (such as that by independent committees or councils).
The actual formula for the fiscal rule will be country specific, and so will be the budget balance for which it is defined (total or primary), the government level to which it applies (central or general government), the degree of spending acy-clicality or countercyclicality, and the target level for the CAB.
Establishment of a Sovereign Wealth Fund
Fiscal rules that target CABs require an SWF in which government savings are deposited during booms and withdrawn during downturns. Such funds are particularly important in commodity-exporting countries, where they are typically invested in foreign currency investments that are held abroad as government revenue comes also in foreign currency from the revenue obtained by commodity-exporting firms.
SWFs should satisfy the following conditions:
Effective and transparent corporate governance;
Transparent information on the transfers between the budget and the SWF;
Portfolio composition determined by maturity concerns (length of commodity price and GDP cycles) and the government’s degree of risk aversion; and
Efficient portfolio management set according to transparent guidelines and closely monitored by the government and the public.
Establishment of Government Committees and a Fiscal Council
Specialized government or MoF committees set up with narrow tasks, such as provision of independent forecasts of key variables for the budget or a board for the SWF, and staffed by independent members are an efficient way to bring expertise and independence to the government, thereby strengthening fiscal institutions.
Moving beyond the latter committees, several advanced economies have put in place or are establishing independent FCs that have broader mandates to improve the quality of fiscal policy assessment, budget planning, and monitoring of budget execution. It appears that no commodity-exporting country has established an FC to date. However, FCs are particularly needed in countries with weaker fiscal institutions, where such councils could make a major difference. Among their potential tasks are the following:
References
Advisory Committee on Fiscal Policy (Comité Asesor para el Diseño de una Política Fiscal de Balance Estructural de Segunda Generación para Chile), 2010, “Propuesta para Perfeccional la Regla Fiscal,” preliminary report (unpublished; Santiago: Ministry of Finance of Chile).
Advisory Committee on Fiscal Policy 2011, “Propuesta para Perfeccionar la Regla Fiscal,” final report (Santiago: Ministry of Finance of Chile).
Alesina, A., and R. Perotti, 1996, “Budget Deficits and Budget Institutions,” NBER Working Paper No. 5556 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).
Alesina, A., S. Ardagna, R. Perotti, and F. Schiantarelli, 1999, “Fiscal Policy, Profits, and Investment,” NBER Working Paper No. 7207 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).
Cáceres, C., A. Corbacho, and L. Medina, 2010, “Structural Breaks in Fiscal Performance: Did Fiscal Responsibility Laws Have Anything to Do with Them?” IMF Working Paper 10/248 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Calderón, C., and K. Schmidt-Hebbel, 2008, “The Choice of Fiscal Regimes in the World,” Working Paper No. 487 (Santiago: Central Bank of Chile).
Calderón, C., R. Duncan, and K. Schmidt-Hebbel, 2010, “Institutions and Cyclical Properties of Macroeconomic Policies in the Global Economy,” Institute of Economics Working Paper No. 372 (Santiago: Catholic University of Chile).
Calmfors, L., and S. Wren-Lewis, 2011, “What Should Fiscal Councils Do?” Discussion Paper Series, Department of Economics (Oxford, U.K.: University of Oxford).
Debrun, X., D. Hauner, and M. Kumar, 2009, “Independent Fiscal Agencies,” Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 23, No. 1, pp. 44–81.
Debrun, X., and M. S. Kumar, 2007, “The Discipline-Enhancing Role of Fiscal Institutions: Theory and Empirical Evidence,” IMF Working Paper 07/171 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Engel, E., M. Marcel, and P. Meller, 2007, “Meta Superávit Estructural: Elementos para su Análisis,” Serie de Estudios de Finanzas Públicas, Dirección de Presupestos (DIPRES), Santiago, Chile. Available via the Internet: xlink:href="http://www.dipres.gob.cl/572/articles-21746_doc_pdf.pdf">www.dipres.gob.cl/572/articles-21746_doc_pdf.pdf.
Fiess, N., 2004, “Chile’s Fiscal Rule,” Econometric Society 2004 Latin American Meetings, No. 348 (New York: Econometric Society).
Frankel, J., 2010, “A Solution to Fiscal Procyclicality: The Structural Budget Institutions Pioneered by Chile,” paper presented at the Fourteenth Annual Conference of the Central Bank of Chile: Fiscal Policy and Macroeconomic Performance, Santiago, October 21–22.
García, S., 2011, “Regla Fiscal Contracíclica, Análisis para Chile,” master’s thesis, Department of Economics, University of Chile.
Geraats, P., 2008, “ECB Credibility and Transparency,” European Economy–Economic Papers No. 330 (Brussels: European Commission).
Geraats, P., S. Eijffinnger, and C. van der Cruijsen, 2006, “Does Central Bank Transparency Reduce Interest Rates?” DNB Working Paper No. 085 (Amsterdam: Netherlands Central Bank, Research Department).
IMF (International Monetary Fund), 2009, “Fiscal Rules—Anchoring Expectations for Sustainable Public Finance,” Discussion paper (Washington).
IMF (International Monetary Fund), 2010, Fiscal Monitor, May 2010: Navigating the Fiscal Challenges Ahead, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).
International Budget Partnership, 2010, Open Budget Survey. Available via the Internet: xlink:href="http://www.internationalbudget.org/files/OBI2010-Chile.pdf">www.internationalbudget.org/files/OBI2010-Chile.pdf.
Kopits, G., and S. Szymansky, 1998, Fiscal Policy Rules, IMF Occasional Paper No. 162 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Kumhof, M., and D. Laxton, 2009, “Chile’s Structural Fiscal Surplus Rule: A Model-Based Evaluation,” IMF Working Paper 09/88 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Larraín, F., and F. Parro, 2006, “Chile Menos Volatile,” Instituto de Economía, Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile.
Lefort, G., 2006, “Política Fiscal con Meta Estructural en la Experiencia Chilena,” Second Annual Meeting of Latin American Specialists on Public Debt Managment, Cartagena, Colombia.
Levy, G., 2008, “A Parliamentary Budget Officer for Canada,” Canadian Parliamentary Review Vol. 38, No. 2, pp. 39–44.
Lienert, I., 2010, “Should Advanced Countries Adopt a Fiscal Responsibility Law?” IMF Working Paper 10/254 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Marcel, M., 2010, “La Regla de Balance Estructural en Chile: Diez Años, Diez Lecciones” (unpublished; Washington: Inter-American Development Bank).
Ministerio de Hacienda, 2009, “Gobierno lanza plan de estímulo fiscal equivalente a 2,8 puntos del PIB para potenciar la economía y defender el empleo,” press release (Santiago: Government of Chile).
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development), 2010, “Germany: Special Feature—Globalization,” OECD Economic Survey, Vol. 9, pp. 61–83.
Rivlin, A. M., 2010, “Helping Politicians Face Difficult Choices,” paper presented at the Conference on Independent Fiscal Institutions, Budapest, Hungary, March.
Rodríguez, J., C. Tokman, and A. Vega, 2006, “Política de Balance Estructural: Resultados y Desafíos tras Seis Años de Aplicación en Chile,” Serie de Estudios de Finanzas Públicas, Dirección de Presupestos (DIPRES), Santiago, Chile.
Rodríguez, J., L. Escobar, and M. Jorratt, 2009, “Los Ingresos Tributarios en el Contexto de la Política de Balance Estructural,” Serie de Estudios de Finanzas Públicas, Dirección de Presupestos (DIPRES), Santiago, Chile.
Schmidt-Hebbel, K., 2010, “Fiscal Rules and Institutions in the World and in Chile” (unpublished; Santiago: Catholic University of Chile).
Sovereign Wealth Fund Institute, 2011, Linaburg-Maduell Transparency Index. Available via the Internet: xlink:href="http://www.swfinstitute.org/statistics-research/linaburg-maduell-transparency-index/">www.swfinstitute.org/statistics-research/linaburg-maduell-transparency-index/.
Stein, E., A. Talvi, and A. Grisanti, 1998, “Institutional Arrangements and Fiscal Performance: The Latin American Experience,” NBER Working Paper No. 6358 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).
Ter-Minassian, T., 2010, “Preconditions for a Successful Introduction of Structural Fiscal Balance-Based Rules in Latin America and the Caribbean: A Framework Paper,” Discussion Paper No. IDB-DP-157 (Washington: Inter-American Development Bank).
Velasco, A., A. Arenas, L. Céspedes, and J. Rodríguez, 2007, “Compromisos Fiscales y la Meta de Superávit Estructural,” Serie de Estudios de Finanzas Públicas, Dirección de Presupestos (DIPRES), Santiago, Chile.
Velasco, A., A. Arenas, J. Rodríguez, M. Jorrat, and G. Gamboni, 2010, “El Enfoque de Balanace Estructural en la Política Fiscal en Chile: Resultados, Metodología y Aplicación al Período 2006–2009,” Serie de Estudios de Finanzas Públicas No. 15, Dirección de Presupestos (DIPRES), Santiago, Chile. Available via the Internet: xlink:href="http://www.dipres.gob.cl/572/articles-60584_doc_pdf.pdf">www.dipres.gob.cl/572/articles-60584_doc_pdf.pdf.
von Hagen, J., 2005, “Political Economy of Fiscal Institutions,” Discussion Paper No. 149 (Mannheim, Germany: Governancy and the Efficiency of Economic Systems).
Wren-Lewis, S., 2010, “Comparing the Delegation of Monetary and Fiscal Policy,” paper presented at the Conference on Independent Fiscal Institutions, Budapest, Hungary, March.
Appendix: Alternative Impulse Responses for Vector Autoregression Estimations Based on Measures of Cyclical Deviations of Variables
Estimated Impulse Responses to a Copper Price Shock, Full Sample, 1990–2010
Source: Author’s simulation.Note: The quarterly impulse response functions are based on vector autoregression estimations described in the text. The temporary copper price shock is a 10 percent rise in the first quarter, which is partly reversed in the second quarter (plus 2 percent) and statistically fully reversed from the third quarter onward. The figures show impulse response functions and their corresponding 90 percent confidence bands. EMBI: Emerging Markets Bond Index; GDP: gross domestic product.Estimated Impulse Responses to a Copper Price Shock, 1990–2000
(before Fiscal Rule)
Source: Author’s simulation.Note: The quarterly impulse response functions are based on vector autoregression estimations described in the text. The temporary copper price shock is a 10 percent rise in the first quarter, which is partly reversed in the second quarter (plus 2 percent) and statistically fully reversed from the third quarter onward. The figures show impulse response functions and their corresponding 90 percent confidence bands. EMBI: Emerging Markets Bond Index; GDP: gross domestic product.Estimated Impulse Responses to a Copper Price Shock, 2001–10
(during Fiscal Rule)
Source: Author’s simulation.Note: The quarterly impulse response functions are based on vector autoregression estimations described in the text. The temporary copper price shock is a 10 percent rise in the first quarter, which is partly reversed in the second quarter (plus 2 percent) and statistically fully reversed from the third quarter onward. The figures show impulse response functions and their corresponding 90 percent confidence bands. EMBI: Emerging Markets Bond Index; GDP: gross domestic product.This chapter was originally presented at an IMF seminar “Commodity Price Volatility and Inclusive Growth in Low-Income Countries,” Washington, D.C., September 21, 2011. Useful comments by Rabah Arezki and seminar participants are gratefully acknowledged. Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel is at the Catholic University of Chile.
The rule is only partly consistent with a permanent-income approach, namely, making government spending consistent with cyclically adjusted government revenue. Therefore, other sources of differences between temporary and permanent revenue—such as temporary changes in taxes or interest rates—are not considered in adjusted revenue estimations due to the political and economic difficulty of doing so. This partial approach to permanent-revenue estimation, limited to cyclical adjustments of government revenue and balance, is adopted by all other countries that adjust government accounts or adopt fiscal rules to account for temporary deviations of relevant budget variables.
Copper tax and transfer revenue dominates that from molybdenum by far. Mining tax revenue is paid by private mining companies, whereas mining transfers to the central government are paid by the large public mining corporation CODELCO.
The projection method and the variables projected by the committee have been refined over the years. The most recent MoF actual and potential growth methodology (Ministerio de Hacienda, 2009) is based on a simple Solow-type growth decomposition equation, based on a Cobb-Douglas Harrod-neutral production function, with capital services (capital stock adjusted by utilization), labor services (hours worked adjusted by educational attainment of the labor force), and residual total factor productivity. Trend growth is generated by filtering actual growth projections. It is important to note that the MoF, not the independent committee, estimates the levels of actual and trend output and hence the output gap.
The CAB and cyclical balance ratios depicted in Figure 7.6 for 1990–2000, when there was no fiscal rule in place, are counterfactual estimations based on the fiscal rule methodology applied since 2001.