Chapter 10: Making Banks Safer: Can Volcker and Vickers Do It?1
Author:
Mr. Julian T Chow
Search for other papers by Mr. Julian T Chow in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
and
Jay Surti https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Jay Surti in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

This chapter assesses proposals to redefine the scope of activities of systemically important financial institutions (SIFIs). Alongside reform of prudential regulation and oversight, these have been offered as solutions to the too-important-to-fail (TITF) problem. It is argued that although the more radical of the proposals, such as narrow utility banking, do not adequately address the key policy objectives that emerged from the global financial crisis, two concrete policy proposals—the Volcker Rule in the United States and retail ring-fencing in the United Kingdom—are more promising, although they still entail significant implementation challenges. A risk factor common to all the measures is the potential for activities identified as too risky for retail banks to migrate to the unregulated parts of the financial system. Since such a migration could lead to the accumulation of systemic risk if left unchecked, it appears unlikely that any structural engineering will lessen the policing burden on prudential authorities and on the banks.

INTRODUCTION

This chapter assesses proposals to redefine the scope of activities of systemically important financial institutions (SIFIs). Alongside reform of prudential regulation and oversight, these have been offered as solutions to the too-important-to-fail (TITF) problem. It is argued that although the more radical of the proposals, such as narrow utility banking, do not adequately address the key policy objectives that emerged from the global financial crisis, two concrete policy proposals—the Volcker Rule in the United States and retail ring-fencing in the United Kingdom—are more promising, although they still entail significant implementation challenges. A risk factor common to all the measures is the potential for activities identified as too risky for retail banks to migrate to the unregulated parts of the financial system. Since such a migration could lead to the accumulation of systemic risk if left unchecked, it appears unlikely that any structural engineering will lessen the policing burden on prudential authorities and on the banks.

The rest of the chapter is organized as follows. The next section discusses the rationale for restricting or redefining the scope of activities of SIFIs. The following sections discuss, in turn, narrow banking, the Volcker Rule, and the retail ring-fencing proposals by reviewing their content and the operational challenges and potential costs of their implementation. The chapter concludes with some reflections on policy implications.

WHY REDEFINE SCORE?

The business of banking involves leveraged intermediation managed by people subject to limited liability and, typically, to profit-sharing contracts. This combination is well known to generate incentives for risk taking that may be excessive from the perspective of bank creditors. Creditor guarantees such as deposit insurance are known to exacerbate this incentive problem because they weaken creditors’ incentive to monitor and discipline management.

These issues are magnified in the case of SIFIs. Owing to their size, interconnectedness, complexity, or the nonsubstitutability of the services they provide, the negative externalities emanating from financial distress at SIFIs make them a source of systemic risk, leading them to be perceived as TITF. Consequently, the market implicitly—and often correctly—assumes that apart from explicit deposit insurance, creditor guarantees of a much wider nature would be extended when such firms are threatened by imminent failure.

This serves to weaken the mitigating force of market discipline. Prior to the crisis, the high likelihood of public support assumed in a distress situation contributed to the ability of SIFIs to carry thinner capital buffers at lower cost, acquire complex business models, and accumulate systemic risk. This trend was reinforced by the diversification premiums attributed to universal banks by market participants and prudential authorities enabling them to integrate the provision of retail, investment, and wholesale banking services without erecting significant firewalls between them. These developments resulted in networks of financial interconnections within and across internationally active SIFIs that proved to be difficult, time consuming, and costly to unravel. This made it seemingly less costly, during the crisis, to allocate taxpayer resources to preventing SIFI failures than to allowing them, with the subsequent resolution and restructuring of their businesses.

Diversification of business lines could serve to better protect a universal bank against idiosyncratic shocks that adversely impact individual lines of business. At the same time, the free flow of capital and liquidity and the associated growth in intragroup exposures would also increase the likelihood of intrafirm contagion in the event of an exogenous shock. Unlike investment banking clients, retail banking customers typically have few options other than their banks for conducting vital financial transactions. Ensuring the business continuity of services to such clients, therefore, serves a clear and important social welfare objective. But complex business models and high levels of intragroup exposures present a barrier to quickly spinning off the retail parts of a universal bank which can ensure such business continuity.

Restricting the scope of a regulated bank’s business activities could, therefore, serve a number of important policy objectives. From a financial stability perspective, it limits contagion within and across firms. From the perspective of consumer protection, it could ensure a more efficient provision of the assurance of the continuity of retail banking services. And, by more credibly restricting the ambit of taxpayer-funded creditor guarantees to depositors, it could furnish these benefits more efficiently and cheaply from a social cost perspective.

Accordingly, the official response to the crisis has, besides recognizing the need for strengthened regulation and oversight of SIFIs, also included complementary proposals to redesign and refocus their business activities. A number of concrete proposals have been made, including:

  • Narrow utility banking—essentially a reversion of deposit-funded banks into traditional payment function outfits, with lending (and investment banking) being carried out by independent finance companies funded by nondeposit means.

  • The Volcker Rule—prohibiting banks from carrying out certain types of investment banking activities if they are to continue to seek deposit funding and retain banking licenses.

  • A retail ring-fence—that, although not prohibiting banks from providing both retail and wholesale banking services, mandates legal subsidiarization of certain retail activities, prohibits this subsidiary from undertaking other businesses and risks, and establishes minimum capital and liquidity standards for it on a solo basis. Although not limiting capital and liquidity benefits to the retail subsidiary from other affiliates when necessary, the ring-fence limits capital and liquidity transfers in the opposite direction, to non-ring-fenced affiliates. Such functional subsidiarization could enable the continuation of retail operations under distress or during failure of a SIFI’s other businesses.

The more radical proposals discussed under the narrow banking umbrella involve strict limits on what retail banks’ permissible activities ought to be, and they could entail significant dead-weight costs if implemented as recommended. By contrast, the design and motivation for the Volcker Rule and retail ring-fence proposals are more precisely targeted at the problems arising from the integrated business models used by the SIFIs before the crisis.

The challenge facing these latter proposals lies in the feasibility and cost of their implementation. In the case of the Volcker Rule, for example, it will be challenging for prudential authorities to tell apart the permissible activities (market making and underwriting) from the prohibited ones (proprietary trading) when assessing banks’ exposures to securities markets. Similar difficulties will be faced by supervisors assessing the nature and purpose of hedging tools and contracts utilized by ring-fenced banks. This presents policymakers with a dilemma. Should they invest the financial cost and time toward gathering more contemporaneous information in order to create better filters and limit loopholes? Or, on the other hand, if this is viewed as being too costly or simply inefficient, should they move to outright prohibition of all activities related to securities markets?

The danger with the second option lies in generating incentives to push risk taking beyond the borders of the regulated financial system. If there are indeed no direct financial linkages between retail financial firms and such shadow banking entities, such risk taking may cease being a problem of regulation. However, systemic risk would continue to accumulate in the shadow banks, and because the participants in the regulated and shadow systems are the same, or are generally linked, a crisis in the shadow sector will continue to exercise a contagion impact on the regulated banking sector.

NARROW BANKING IDEAS

The Utility Banking Proposals

Utility banking proposals seek to define institutional and regulatory boundaries along functional lines, distinguishing—somewhat arbitrarily—“nonrisky” utility banking services from “risky” nonutility activities. The available literature does not make the idea of utility banking precise, but presumably inclusion is limited to those services that facilitate real sector activity and sustainable economic growth.

In the aftermath of the global financial crisis, utility banking proponents have emphasized the need for lowering asset-liability mismatches and leverage risks via drastic restrictions on what lines of business regulated, deposit-funded banks can pursue (Figure 10.1 and Table 10.1). The most radical of these proposals envisage institutional separation between banks serving payments function needs and companies engaged in commercial lending and other activities. Utility banks are envisaged as licensed, regulated, deposit-funded entities, constrained to invest in high-credit-quality, liquid securities, and would alone qualify for public creditor guarantees where these are extended. Lending, where permitted, would be restricted to a few sectors such as consumer and mortgage credit, whereas the majority of commercial lending and investment banking would be carried out by legally separate finance companies funded by debt and equity.2 Holding company structures, wherein both types of institutions could coexist as subsidiaries, would be permitted, albeit legal, financial, and managerial separation would be strictly enforced.

Figure 10.1.
Figure 10.1.

Transformation of Universal Banking into Utility Banking

1 Besides rescoping of business represented by balance sheet adjustments, also entails prohibition on the provision of a number of financial services (e.g., trading of securities on own account and investment banking services such as prime brokerage, market making, and securities underwriting, among others).2 Includes interbank exposures.3 Includes funding vehicles such as asset backed commercial paper, repo/securities lending, among others.
TABLE 10.1

Utility Banking Proposals

article image
Sources: 1 Litan (1987) and Pierce (1991); 2 Bryan (1991) and Kay (2009); 3 Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2002).

To the extent that practical implementation of the utility banking proposals yields an accurate functional separation of utility from nonutility activities, a number of benefits could ensue to the economy and the financial system.3 Leverage in deposit-funded institutions would be lowered by jettisoning investment banking activities such as trading, investment funds, and securitization. Asset-liability matching would be enhanced by restricting the class of permissible assets to liquid, high-credit-quality securities. Restricting access to the payments system to utility banks would isolate the systemic risk of losses at nonutility finance companies, thus protecting banks from credit, liquidity, and settlement risks. Finally, the restriction of public creditor guarantees to utility banks alone would sharpen creditor incentives in monitoring manager-owners of nonutility institutions. In theory, this would alleviate the moral hazard problem and lessen the pressure on supervisory agencies. Measured against a set of criteria ranging from macro-financial stability to financial costs, the economic impact of narrow banking would be substantial (Table 10.2).

TABLE 10.2

Impact Analysis of Utility Banking

article image

Separation of Lending from Deposit Taking May Impose Significant Social Cost

The rationale for the institutional separation implied by utility banking appears to arise from the observation that the coexistence of lending based on risky leverage and asset-liability maturity mismatches with deposit-funding translates into an increase in contagion risk to traditional banking and worsens the moral hazard problem. It seems to provide support to market assumptions that the boundary of public creditor protection is flexible beyond deposits. In turn, this leads to weaker market discipline which promotes the further accumulation of systemic risk.

Even if one were to grant the foregoing hypothesis, the implication that there should be institutional separation between deposit funding and payments system access from all credit intermediation remains elusive. Maturity transformation financed by deposit-based leverage is the traditional business of commercial banks in the same manner as (re)discounting of securities and managing payments between clients and to other banks. Asset securitization—especially of subprime mortgages, mortgage-backed securities, and their derivatives—resulted in borrowing costs that may not have reflected underlying borrower credit risk and encouraged very high levels of leverage in the financial system. But incentives to maintain tighter underwriting standards and higher capital buffers for loans that remain on banks’ balance sheets are substantially stronger.

In other words, it is difficult to make a case based on events leading up to the crisis for banks to give up their deposit-based funding of loans. This fact becomes more apparent when, while considering the scope of a bank’s utility-enhancing activities, one considers the informational advantage of banks in overcoming adverse selection in the lending process (relationship lending). Moreover, there is synergy between deposit-taking and lending activities when they are viewed as alternative, imperfectly correlated manifestations of liquidity provision by banks, which gives rise to efficiencies in the joint provision of these services using a single balance sheet.4

Successful Implementation Would Require Overcoming Significant Operational Challenges

A number of operational challenges related to prevention of regulatory arbitrage appear to limit the scope for utility banking in practice.

  • Cross-border regulatory arbitrage may thwart national utility banking reform. The proposal needs consistent application across jurisdictions to be effective. Even if regulators could successfully prescribe a list of nonutility banking activities, harmonization of regulatory regimes in different countries may be a challenge due to differences in the level and pace of financial development. Absent such coordination, however, universal banks could relocate their listing status to jurisdictions with less strict regulations, thus leaving the TITF problem unaddressed.

  • Utility banks might constrain the moral hazard of bank management, but investor temptation to take risk would remain and could result in the accumulation of systemic risk outside of the regulated banking system. Utility banks would appeal to depositors during times of financial distress, since they are protected, but the lure of higher returns during normal economic times could prompt savers to put their money into shadow banks, which are beyond the boundary of government regulation. This would reduce the role of utility banks in periods of prolonged moderation, thereby shifting risk to shadow banks in such magnitude that, when another crisis hits, the losses would be high enough to warrant the use of public funds to rescue failing shadow banking entities.

  • Narrowing the perimeter of regulation need not follow from utility banking. An argument that is often made in favor of utility banking in existing studies is the potential relaxation of inefficient regulatory and intrusive supervisory constraints, which would have the added benefit of lowering the social cost of policing banks. However, because systemic risk can still build up through shadow banks, affecting retail investors and the real economy, the case for extending the regulatory perimeter around these institutions remains despite the transition to utility banking.

  • Utility banking will not eliminate market risk. Although the default risk on a 30-year U.S. Treasury note may be very low, a steepening of the treasury curve would result in large mark-to-market losses for deposit-funded banks. Therefore, caps on the duration of tradable fixed-income securities would be necessary to minimize market risk. Alternatively, the universe of eligible assets for utility banks would need to be further restricted to variable-interest securities or short-term notes.

Adjustment Costs Could Be Significant

Adjustment costs related to unwinding and decoupling integrated businesses are likely to be high. The proposal could be particularly costly in Europe where the universal banking business model is more widely prevalent. Moreover, implementing the proposal in countries with underdeveloped financial sectors may be infeasible because of the paucity of high-credit-quality, liquid securities.

  • Unwinding a complex universal bank is a costly and time-consuming process. This is especially so in the case of European TITF institutions, which are predominantly universal banks. Interlinkages between various parts of a bank holding company (BHC) may be difficult to unwind, let alone for the entire organization to be restructured. For instance, structured finance may involve deposit funding coupled with derivatives, structured internally by structuring desks and in turn “manufactured” and hedged by trading desks. The hedging of these derivatives may be done with an external counterparty or another internal unit within the bank, which makes it difficult to “unbundle” the complicated relationships.

  • Utility banking presents implementation challenges for emerging markets and low income countries as well. It presumes deep and liquid secondary markets for government and private debt securities. Moreover, the funding needs of finance companies in many of these countries hinge largely on domestic capital markets, without which the functioning of credit intermediation would be severely disrupted.

Narrow Funding Banks

The Proposal

The fundamental goal behind the narrow funding bank (NFB) proposal put forward by Gorton and Metrick (2010) is to bring securitization within the regulatory perimeter by housing the purchase of asset-backed securities (ABSs) within licensed and regulated institutions.

Under the proposal, NFBs are envisioned as chartered institutions subject to prudential requirements associated with ceilings on leverage, market, and liquidity risks, restrictions on eligible assets collateralizing the purchased ABSs, and on portfolio quality and concentration.5 NFBs would be subjected to periodic examinations and would gain access to the central bank’s discount window facilities.6

(Equity) capital would be raised through issuance of medium-term notes (MTNs) with scheduled maturity points which are extendible in the event that the institution has breached regulatory capital requirements at the time of maturity. The institution would, in such cases, switch to a no growth mode or a natural amortization mode, wherein risk reduction would be undertaken by rebuilding the capital base via prohibition on dividend payouts to equity holders (no growth) and, in addition, to the fund managers (natural amortization). Capital, therefore, takes on a debt-like structure during normal times and reverts to an equity-like structure during times of stress. Nonequity funding would be raised through nondeposit means via issuance of commercial paper, MTNs and bonds, and through repos. NFBs are viewed as engaged in a pure spread business, and would be barred from making loans or exposing own-funds to proprietary trading and derivatives businesses.7 Their sole business activity would be to purchase ABSs, though they would be allowed to invest in other high-grade assets and treasury securities, presumably for liquidity management purposes.

In terms of legal and economic organization, NFBs would be structured as stand-alone, separately ring-fenced legal entities with no direct cross-ownership linkages to commercial banks. Taken together with the prudential requirements described above, this is seen as promoting more efficient bank recovery and resolution.

Assessment

Independent, regulated, and separately capitalized securitization firms would promote ring-fencing of regulated banks’ retail operations in times of stress. Moreover, the conversion of (part of) NFB debt into equity during times of stress may provide stronger market incentives to limit borrower leverage in the housing market. However, credit risk may become more concentrated in NFBs. Moreover, other incentive problems associated with the precrisis securitization model still remain and must be directly addressed by other, complementary, measures.

  • Concentration risk: Since NFBs assume the function of ABS conduits and structured investment vehicles from banks, the concentration of securitization risk may render them vulnerable during times of deteriorating credit conditions. Although access to the Federal Reserve’s discount window may alleviate short-term liquidity problems, solvency risk continues to depend on the performance of the credits underlying the ABS portfolio.

  • Resolving incentive problems embedded in the originate-to-distribute securitization model: More fundamentally, therefore, the chartering of NFBs under the specified prudential constraints will not be sufficient by itself to remedy the incentive problems in the precrisis originate-to-distribute model of securitization in the United States. NFBs do not address incentive problems related to the quality of loan underwriting arising from low credit risk retention by originators and securitization deal sponsors. Similarly, the NFB proposal is not designed to, and therefore will not, address coordination problems arising from conflicts of interest between senior and junior lien holders of the assets collateralizing the ABSs. Finally, changes to originator-servicers’, mortgage bond trustees’, and underwriters’ remuneration contracts and to securitization waterfall structures are necessary complements to the chartering of NFBs. Without such changes, it is difficult to foresee the mere introduction of NFBs as sufficient to reduce either the scope for misrepresentations by originators and underwriters or the scope for mortgage defaults and foreclosures and the associated potential dead-weight costs incurred during macro-financial dislocations.

FULL INSTITUTIONAL SEPARATION OF FUNCTIONS: THE VOLCKER RULE

Rationale for the Rule

The Volcker Rule of the Dodd-Frank Act in the United States separates some investment banking activities from commercial banking. The motivation for this type of institutional separation is the increased scope for conflicts of interest and risk taking when banks are allowed to combine lending, securities underwriting, and market making with proprietary trading and investment on their own account.

Banks exposed to a corporation through the lending channel may have an interest in marketing and underwriting the firm’s securities to the clients it may be serving in an asset management or advisory capacity. Although not necessarily a problem in itself, a serious conflict of interest may arise when the said capital is raised to retire the bank’s credit exposure at a time when the firm’s finances are worsening.

Legislators and regulators have emphasized—in the past and currently—the systemic risk inherent in the direct involvement of commercial banks in securities markets through proprietary trading or hedge and investment funds acquisition.8 For example, the Group of Thirty point to “unanticipated and unsustainably large losses in proprietary trading, heavy exposure to structured credit products, and … hedge funds” as having placed the viability of other businesses of the banks and the system at large at risk.9 Moreover, it is apparent that these activities are quite distinct from the individual customer service and relationship lending that characterizes deposit management and credit intermediation.

Capital arbitrage by banks between trading and banking books became prevalent over the decade preceding the global financial crisis. Capital charged against trading book exposures was relatively light compared to that charged against the banking book, encouraging banks to place credit exposures in the trading book. As regulators have reported in the aftermath of the crisis, while trading books were, earlier, typically composed of plain-vanilla currency and interest-rate derivatives and government bonds, the last decade saw an increasing inflow of credit derivatives and subprime securities (Financial Stability Board, 2010a; United Kingdom Financial Supervisory Authority, 2009).

An additional problem was that standards of disclosure and transparency for investors and creditors as applied to investment banking activity were relatively poor when compared to commercial banking, at least in the United States. The problem was exacerbated by the limited reach of financial regulation and oversight over activity in key markets, such as private-label ABSs and their derivatives, and the weakening of market discipline imposed by credit ratings agencies (CRAs) owing to apparent conflicts of interest and modeling gaps.

The preceding discussion on the motivation for the Volcker Rule calls for at least three—possibly complementary—solutions:

  • Imposition of higher capital requirements on commercial deposit-taking banks with high levels of trading activity, where a “high level of activity” could be measured in terms of contribution to the overall level and volatility of returns.

  • Extending the perimeter of regulation and endowing supervisors with the authority to demand information from shadow banks. Giving supervisors cease-and-desist and enforcement powers on the basis of information collected from weakly supervised or unsupervised entities can also achieve the same goals as setting firm functional boundaries between commercial and investment banks.

  • Imposing a separation of business lines into different sets of institutions, as has been attempted via the Volcker Rule in the United States and by the Independent Commission on Banking (ICB) in the United Kingdom.

What Businesses Must Commercial Banks Give Up?

The Volcker Rule—barring a number of exemptions—essentially prohibits deposit-funded, licensed commercial banks in the United States or BHCs with U.S. banking affiliates from engaging in proprietary trading and investing in or sponsoring hedge funds and private equity funds (Figure 10.2 and Table 10.3).

Figure 10.2.
Figure 10.2.

Rescoping of Banks’ Businesses under the Volcker Rule

1 Besides adjustments to the balance sheet entailed by the rule, certain activities (e.g., prime brokerage) are permitted, as is contracting with counterparties to hedge risks arising from banking business including permitted services outlined here (e.g., derivatives transactions).
TABLE 10.3

Volcker Rule of the Dodd-Frank Act

article image
Source: U.S. House of Representatives (2010).

Trading account is defined under the rule as an account used for acquiring or taking positions in securities and instruments listed above primarily for the purpose of selling or unwinding them in the near future to profit for interim price movements.

Sponsoring a hedge fund includes performing the following functions: (i) serving as general partner, managing member, or trustee; (ii) to select or control (or have employees, officers, directors who constitute) a majority of the directors, trustees, or managers of the fund; or (iii) to share with a fund for marketing, corporate, or promotional purposes, the same or similar name.

A limited exemption is available to prime brokerage agreements between a bank serving as investment advisor or sponsor to a fund and another private equity/hedge fund in which the said fund takes an equity, partnership, or ownership interest under qualified circumstances.

The rule has a long phase-in period for implementation. It becomes effective on the earlier date of either two years after enactment of the Act (i.e., July 21, 2012), or within nine months of the issuance of accompanying regulations (released on October 11, 2011). Compliance is required from eligible institutions two years hence (so by July 21, 2014), albeit the Federal Reserve may provide up to three one-year extensions to institutions, upon application, beyond 2014.10

The Volcker Rule vs. Glass-Steagall11

The obvious parallel to the Volcker Rule are the Glass-Steagall restrictions placed on U.S. banking firms starting 1933 which also involved separation of commercial banking from investment banking and largely ended universal banking in the United States. The Volcker Rule prohibits fewer activities for commercial banks than Glass-Steagall did. However, the number of exemptions granted under the Volcker Rule is also significantly less than eventually offered under Glass-Steagall.

  • Proprietary trading: The set of exempt bank-eligible securities is now much narrower. Prior to Gramm-Leach-Bliley, exempt securities included, for national banks (besides those mentioned in Table 10.3), obligations of certain foreign governments and international development banks and highly rated debt and ABSs. Under the 1956 Bank Holding Companies Act, BHCs were free to engage in the proprietary trading of debt and equity securities provided they did not acquire more than 5 percent of the voting rights of any issuer. Overseas banks that had U.S. branches or subsidiaries were not subject to any such restrictions.

  • Funds investing: Under Glass-Steagall, BHCs were permitted to invest in U.S. hedge and private equity funds so long as they held less than 5 percent of voting rights and less than a controlling stake in them. Under the 1978 International Banking Act and Regulation K, they were allowed to invest in foreign funds so long as they held less than 20 percent of voting rights. Provided that funds investing was carried out by non-U.S. affiliates, Glass-Steagall restrictions did not apply to foreign banks.

Assessment

Distinguishing Proprietary Trades From Permissible Transactions Will Be Challenging

Exemptions based on the intent of transactions are sensible in principle, but it is difficult to find practical rules to filter out prohibited transactions.

  • Given the stated motivation behind introduction of the Volcker Rule, the exemptions to it are often coherently built on the economic purpose behind the transaction. For example, with regard to proprietary trading, the rule exempts transactions related to market making or underwriting (if in response to client demand), hedge transactions, and transactions undertaken in an agency capacity.

  • Prohibiting trading undertaken explicitly by dedicated desks (so called bright line cases) is relatively straightforward. Anticipating this, a number of U.S. BHCs have spun off their trading desks.

  • But identifying prohibited proprietary trading transactions dressed up as exempt hedging or market-making transactions is substantially more difficult. Banks often do not hedge individual positions or transactions but deploy hedging strategies at the portfolio level. Since hedges are often incomplete, residual exposures—equity, interest rate, or option—often expose bank capital to risk. It is difficult for regulators to consistently tell apart legitimate incomplete hedges from exposures that are undertaken purposefully. Similarly, market making by banks inevitably entails putting up own capital at risk for varying periods of time, depending on the liquidity of the relevant securities or derivatives.

  • A study by the U.S. Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC, 2011), acknowledging this problem, has proposed developing suitable metrics based on granular supervisory information to assist supervisors in filtering prohibited transactions from exempt ones (Table 10.4). Moreover, recognizing the limitations of statistical approaches in carrying out this task, the FSOC has also recommended that banks adopt a programmatic regime involving regular internal audits and declarations of compliance from banks’ chief executive officers.

  • The Financial Stability Board (FSB, 2010a) raised the possibility of developing a methodology based on the U.K. FSA’s analysis of major trading activities in London for the period 2006–08. Based on the frequency distribution of daily trading profits, it made a distinction between banks with predominantly modest profits and small tails of large profits or losses and banks with large profits and losses occurring more frequently. The FSB asked whether an identification scheme sorting the first set of banks as market makers and the rest as proprietary traders would be sensible. A limitation of using the results of such an analysis is that it is based on an aggregate of individual transactions and is more suited to an ex post imposition of charges for noncompliance with the rule’s requirements rather than as an ex ante or concurrent identification device for supervisors. In other words, it is not designed to tell individual market making or hedging transactions apart from opportunistic proprietary trades.

TABLE 10.4

Quantitative Metrics Proposed by the Financial Stability Oversight Council

article image
Source: Financial Stability Oversight Council (2011).

Purely rules-based identification methodologies may be susceptible to gaming or be too coarse and therefore entail inefficient decision making. Since regulation may be expected to permit securities investments made for the banking book but prohibit the same for the trading book, the burden on supervision to prevent gaming the rules will increase. In particular, mechanical holding-period thresholds (e.g., a minimum 30-day holding period) for eligibility to include securities markets exposures in the banking book may be susceptible to manipulation. On the other hand, idiosyncratic liquidity shocks or other unavoidable circumstances may precipitate unanticipated early sales of certain securities in the buy-and-hold portfolio. Therefore, rules will need to be supplemented by discretionary supervisory judgment in order to avoid inefficient decision making.

Unintended Costs and Competitive Distortions Need to Be Guarded Against

U.S. residents can no longer be offered funds that U.S. insured depositories, BHCs, and foreign banking groups invest in or sponsor. Funds can still be offered through investment banks or nonbank finance companies located in the United States or outside, or in the case of clients of their trust or fiduciary businesses, by banks. The narrowing of the set of eligible suppliers of investment vehicles may result in a new pricing-to-market that is disadvantageous to U.S. investors.

U.S. banks and BHCs will also be placed at a disadvantage relative to non-U.S. BHCs, since the latter can continue proprietary trading or fund investing so long as it occurs outside the United States by non-U.S. affiliates. On the other hand, since U.S. banks and BHCs are allowed to acquire U.S. government and agency securities for their trading books but not foreign government securities, this could imply a disproportionate liquidity and capital supply impact on the market for some non-U.S. sovereign and private sector debt.

The Volcker Rule will be costly to private firms for whom proprietary trading of their debt by banks has been an important factor enhancing the market liquidity of their securities and lowering their cost of capital. Such non-exempt securities include corporate bonds and private-issue ABSs. Since the rule will effectively increase the liquidity risk premium applied by investors to such securities, external financing costs to nonfinancial firms and borrowing costs to household mortgage borrowers not qualifying for conventional conforming loans are likely to increase.

Systemic Risk May Migrate to the Shadow Banking Sector

Banning proprietary trading is likely to amplify risk shifting to the shadow banking sector (which comprises hedge funds, mutual funds, and special purpose entities, among others). This would increase the accumulation of unmonitored systemic risk which could manifest itself quickly and unexpectedly during times of financial distress with spillover effects adversely impacting the real economy in the same manner as a banking crisis. In fact, the manifestation of risk may be even greater as shadow banking entities are not subject to capital adequacy standards and in many areas their operations remain opaque due to relatively poor disclosure practices.

FUNCTIONAL SUBSIDIARIZATION: RETAIL RING-FENCING

Why Ring-Fence Retail Banking?

An alternative way to redesign the scope of activities of banking institutions has been proposed by the Independent Commission on Banking (ICB) in the United Kingdom (U.K. ICB, 2011). ICB’s ring-fencing of retail operations from investment banking operations does not entail full institutional separation between retail and investment banking activity, allowing universal banks to continue to avail themselves of any diversification benefits emanating from the integrated business model. However, the proposals place strict limits on the magnitude and nature of the commingling of retail and investment banking operations within a single entity. In doing so, it recognizes the increased potential for contagion risk that could threaten the provision of banking services to retail depositors and small businesses that cannot afford even a temporary interruption.12

Accordingly, the objectives of the ring-fence are:

  • To make it easier to restructure and resolve both retail and nonretail banks without extensive recourse to public funds.

  • To insulate vital banking services, on which households and small businesses depend, from exogenous shocks.

  • And, thereby, to credibly restrict the reach of public creditor guarantees to those for whom it is explicitly predefined.

Broadly speaking, the ICB proposals fall into two categories. First, the placement of activities either within or outside the ring-fence (the location of the fence). Second, and within the broader business group structure, the placement of restrictions on financial interconnections between the ring-fenced and non-ring-fenced entities (the height of the fence). This is achieved by the placement of ceilings on, and risk-based pricing of, intragroup transactions and by specifying minimum capital standards for ring-fenced banks.13

Implementation

What Ring-Fenced Banks Must Do, Can Do … and What They Cannot Do

As a first step, implementation requires the identification of banking activities that are to be ring-fenced. Equally important is determining the type of separation applying to a given business line. In its report (2011), the ICB has proposed distinguishing between the following four types of activities.

  • Services that must be offered within the ring-fence. These include retail deposits and the provision of overdrafts to individuals and small and medium-sized enterprises. Private banking customers are not included among the set of such individuals given that they are likely to have a wider set of options to meet their banking needs.

  • Activities that are permitted within the ring-fence. These include, besides the mandatory ones described above, all nonprohibited services such as loans to consumers and small and medium-sized enterprises, mortgages, credit cards, corporate lending, leasing and factoring, and wealth management advisory services, among others. The ICB does not place restrictions on the mode and mix of on-balance-sheet instruments that ring-fenced banks may use for funding their businesses so long as these do not result in the assumption of market risk by the firm.14

  • Activities that are excluded from the ring-fence. These include services provided outside the European Economic Area (EEA); transactions with non-ring-fenced financial firms that are not affiliates of the ring-fenced bank (with the exception of regulator approved payments services transactions); services that would result in either a trading book asset or in the requirement to hold capital against market and counterparty credit risks; and services relating to secondary market activity such as the purchase of loans or securities. These prohibitions preclude ring-fenced banks from engaging in securities underwriting, market making, mergers and acquisition advisory services, loans and ABS warehousing, and sponsoring securitization deals.

  • Activities necessary to support permitted services may also be performed. Ring-fenced banks’ permitted business operations entail assumption of credit, market, and liquidity risk which they would need to hedge. Accordingly, it is reasonable to expect ring-fenced banks to engage in derivatives contracts with non-ring-fenced banks which would entail assumption of market and counterparty credit risks. Ring-fenced banks must also undertake investment in assets that are liquid by virtue of either an active secondary market or by them being eligible for repurchase by the central bank. However, the proposals exclude contracting with counterparties outside of the ring-fenced banks’ own financial group that are offering prohibited services. It would appear, therefore, that risks must be managed, possibly in a synthetic fashion, by combining intragroup contracting with the sale and purchase of marketable securities and their derivatives.

Shielding Ring-Fenced Banks from Contagion

Whereas the retail ring-fence proposal allows universal banking groups to continue maintenance of ring-fenced and other businesses under one roof, it mandates that measures be put in place to protect the ring-fence from contagion risk. This has the following implications for the legal corporate structure of such groups and for the economic linkages between their ring-fenced and non-ring-fenced affiliates.

Ring-fenced banks are to be set up as separate legal entities within their financial groups. In a branch-based structure, monitoring compliance with prudential rules related to capital, liquidity, and intragroup exposures applied on a solo basis to the ring-fence could be prohibitively difficult. Moreover, in order to ensure that ring-fenced operations can be spun off in a group-wide restructuring or resolution, a number of other criteria must be satisfied. Arrangements whereby the ring-fenced bank continues to have access to all operations, staff, data, and services essential to its operations are necessary. For example, a ring-fenced bank ought to be a member of relevant payments systems or should have, as its agents, other ring-fenced banks. In terms of group organization, ring-fenced banks cannot (partially) own affiliates that offer services prohibited within the ring-fence.

Subsidiarization should be functional and not merely legal and operational. This entails three important considerations.

  • Ring-fenced banks must have an operationally independent management and board. Without this, continuity of business operations when the rest of the group is in distress or under resolution may be difficult to ensure. Boards are expected to strive to maintain the integrity of the ring-fence, albeit the compliance protocols under the Volcker Rule are not imposed by the ICB.

  • Ring-fenced banks must be independently and separately capitalized reflecting minimum regulatory standards assessed on a solo basis. The ICB recommends applying solo equity and leverage standards to the ring-fenced subsidiary (Table 10.5). There are no limits on the transfer of capital and liquidity from a financial group’s non-ring-fenced affiliates into the ring-fence, but the scope for transfers in the opposite direction, including of dividend payments, is explicitly constrained.

  • Restrictions on intragroup transactions. The ICB proposals place no restrictions, beyond those already embedded in the prudential framework for banks, on intragroup exposures between ring-fenced affiliates. Turning to financial interconnections with non-ring-fenced affiliates, their focus is on ensuring appropriate risk pricing of such transactions instead of placing tougher quantitative limits on them. Accordingly, such transactions should necessarily be on a third-party basis and conducted on a commercial basis at market prices or imputed fair values (Figure 10.3).15

Figure 10.3.
Figure 10.3.

Rescoping of Banks’ Businesses under the ICB Ring-Fence

Note: EEA = European Economic Area.1 Understood to include proprietary trading, securitization deal sponsorships and services such as securities underwriting, market making, prime brokerage, and loans/securities warehousing, among others.2 Funding raised from/exposures to non-EEA clients and funding raised/exposures through non-EEA affiliates.
TABLE 10.5

Prudential Capital Constraints Applying to Ring-Fenced Banks

article image
Source: United Kingdom Independent Commission on Banking (2011). Note: RWA = risk-weighted assests.

Assessment

Diversification benefits entailed by universal banking are preserved under the proposals, albeit potentially with limitations. Ring-fenced banks can, when necessary, continue to benefit from capital and liquidity surpluses elsewhere in the group and can, to a limited degree, extend this benefit to affiliates. Limits on the ability to do the latter also protect retail operations from contagion, more credibly restrict the penumbra of public creditor guarantees to retail creditors, and ensure continuity of that part of the firm in a crisis.

Subsidiarization—in the legal, operational, and functional senses—is necessary for the proposals to succeed in achieving their goals. However, the practical achievement of this remains challenging despite the final report adding substantial additional operational guidance relative to the interim April report (ICB, 2011).

  • Risk management and intragroup exposures. Since exposures to non-ring-fenced banks or finance companies outside of their own financial group are prohibited, risk management and hedging within the ring-fence may have to rely exclusively on contracting within the group.16 So long as arms-length contracting is in place, there appear to be no further constraints—besides regulatory limits on intragroup or single party exposures—on ring-fenced banks transacting with group affiliates to hedge risk. In order for subsidiarization to ensure isolation and continuity of the ring-fenced operations, however, prudential rules and oversight will need to ensure that backup arrangements that survive distress or failure of the wider group are in place for the ring-fenced bank to avail itself of. Moreover, in the case of some types of transactions, such as master netting in repurchase agreements, this will require first arranging the transfer of existing contracts, and subsequently, the maintenance of separate contracts with clients, payments and settlement systems, and risk management counterparties. This could entail, besides significant adjustment costs, a permanent increase in the cost of provision of banking services. Intensification of supervision to ensure institutional compliance may be expected and will imply a similar increase in implementation costs for prudential authorities.

  • Filtering prohibited from permissible transactions will be as challenging under the ring-fence as under the Volcker Rule. The location of the ICB ring-fence is more restrictive than the Volcker Rule (Table 10.6). However, ring-fenced institutions must maintain (i.e., buy, hold, and sell) a portfolio of securities, engage in secured lending transactions, and be counterparties to derivatives contracts. Like the Volcker Rule, ring-fenced institutions can engage in these only to support permitted services and transactions but the same identification and implementation challenges described earlier will also arise for U.K. ring-fenced banks. Whether the additional prohibitions on market making, underwriting, and sponsorship of securitization deals make this hurdle less costly to surmount under the ICB proposals remains to be seen.

  • Reconciling limits on market and counterparty risks with limits on intragroup contagion may be challenging. Ring-fenced banks’ need to hedge financial risks necessitates exposures to financial markets and counterparties which must be from within their own financial groups. This increases the risk of raising intragroup exposures across the ring-fence to beyond a desirable level from the perspective of spinning off the ring-fenced business and maintaining business continuity when the need arises.

TABLE 10.6

Comparing the Volcker Rule and the ICB Proposals

article image
Sources: Financial Stability Oversight Council (2011); U.S. House of Representatives (2010); and U.K. ICB (2011).

Since offering retail banking services requires a banking license, such activities are necessarily ring-fenced under the Volcker Rule.

Organization of Global Retail Banking

If a U.K. banking group has retail operations in other jurisdictions, the ICB proposals do not compel the group to ring-fence such businesses. This could be the case, however, if the group preferred a corporate structure wherein retail businesses were organized in a separate subsidiary. An interesting question is whether retail operations ought to be organized in a separately capitalized subsidiary with independent management and, if so, should such subsidiarization be organized along national boundaries? One argument supporting affirmative answers to these questions is that retail banking is likely to be geographically separate and independent, whereby enforcement of ring-fencing of a global bank’s retail operations can be performed by national prudential authorities.17 From the authorities’ perspectives, a clear advantage of adopting this form of organization is that the benefits ensuing from tax payer cost outlay to ensure continuity of the business would be ring-fenced for the benefit of retail customers of the domestic subsidiary.

POLICY IMPLICATIONS

The three proposals described in this chapter provide alternative roadmaps for the transition of SIFI business models from universal banking toward the separate provision of deposit-taking, lending, and payments functions on the one hand, and investment or wholesale banking on the other. Although the proposals share a number of common elements, there are important differences between them. A summary comparison is presented in Figure 10.4. We define two separate dimensions in which banks’ businesses will be constrained: the number of prohibited services and the degree of interaction permitted with the providers of such services, and compare the relative constraints imposed by the proposals in each of these dimensions. For example, although the ICB proposes to prohibit more activities than the Volcker Rule (and less so than utility banking), it permits greater intragroup transactions/ exposure to non-ring-fenced entities.

Figure 10.4.
Figure 10.4.

Comparing the Proposals: A Summary

1 Rankings for each proposal are relative to other proposals. “Number of restrictions” corresponds to number of prohibited activities; “severity” refers to potential for within-group transactions/interconnections to firms engaging in prohibited activities.

Redesigning the business models of SIFIs will not work without complementary measures to strengthen the prudential framework. Restrictions on proprietary trading and risky lending are tools that are largely complementary to strengthened regulation, more intensive oversight, and more effective recovery and resolution frameworks, all of which are targeted at mitigating the TITF problem.

Enhancing the oversight of the shadow banking sector is essential to prevent migration of systemic risk in response to tighter constraints on regulated banks’ business models. The proposals discussed in this chapter will be limited in their ability to reduce systemic risk if corresponding reforms are not made with respect to the shadow banking sector. Although regulated banks may be on safer ground, the shift in excessive risk-taking incentives toward the unregulated parts of the financial system could render quasi-banks susceptible to distress. To the extent that these shadow banks become systemic and maintain links with regulated banks, systemic risk will continue to exist. Thus, any policy framework aimed at addressing the issue of systemic risk should encompass the shadow banking system. In addition, prudential supervision may need to be extended to this sector to improve the transparency and disclosure of information, to capture the activities of special purpose vehicles and their linkages, and identify the set of stake-holders involved.

The loss of any diversification benefits could represent a significant cost and careful assessment is required in selecting a rescoping model that will limit it. Reduction in diversification benefits due to the separation of investment from commercial banking may entail significant costs that may not be balanced by gains if—as a result—risky activities move to the shadow banking system. In our view, this applies more to the narrow banking and Volcker Rule proposals than to retail ring-fencing, since the latter would still permit the preservation of diversification gains and risk taking, albeit to a limited degree, within a universal bank combining retail and wholesale businesses.

Operational challenges specific to each proposal may limit their effectiveness, implying that they be introduced in combination with some of the other tools assessed in this chapter. Specifically:

  • The separation of utility and nonutility banking—necessary to the success of narrow banking—may be prohibitively difficult to achieve in practice, with important utility components leaking out to the shadow banking system, ultimately defeating the raison d’être of the proposal. For this reason, efforts to extend the perimeter of regulation and oversight remain vitally important.

  • Since the identification and separation of proprietary trading transactions from hedging or market-making transactions will be difficult in practice, reliance on higher capital surcharges—overall and on the trading book—will be important complementary measures.

  • Structural measures to limit the scope of SIFI activities, while providing a direct way of dealing with the TITF problem, have not gained international support, and therefore, could be difficult to implement and adopt on a globally consistent basis. Harmonization of the regulatory toolkit in countries housing TITF activities will be important to avoid competitive distortions and arbitrage opportunities. As a corollary, and given their role as global financial centers, careful assessment of the opportunities for regulatory arbitrage potentially generated by differences between the Volcker Rule and the ICB ring-fence and their implementing regulations will be warranted.

  • Riskier activities could be limited through other prudential measures that are in train, such as higher risk weights on trading and securitization (under Basel) or the buffering of common equity with contingent capital instruments, which has the additional potential advantage of sharpening investor incentives for monitoring bank management. Ultimately, however, success will be predicated upon improved governance frameworks and strong supervision.

DISCUSSION

There is conditional support for the importance of trading. A positive association exists between susceptibility to distress and the importance of trading income as a revenue generator for U.S. and European banks. However, similar results do not hold for Asia, with sample banks there showing only a weak association at best. This could indicate a number of possible factors:

  • (i) Regional effects underpinned by economic fundamentals may have a role—Asian economies were more resilient during the crisis, thus underpinning the financial health of the banking systems and the systemic players therein.

  • (ii) Quality of assets and earnings—low Asian exposure to toxic assets—such as subprime mortgages, residential mortgage backed securities (RMBS), and their derivatives—may be important factors that underscore banks’ resilience to stress.

Proprietary trading may be only a part of the problem. Risk could emanate from losses attributed to nonproprietary trading activities, such as market making, investment banking, and hedging.

The divergence from the results for European and U.S. banks of the sample of Asian banks also raises a question of whether the problem could be cyclical rather than structural, because Asia is in a different economic phase compared to the United States and Europe. If this is true, then prescribing a structural policy remedy, such as prohibiting banks’ proprietary trading altogether, could lead to a suboptimal outcome when viewed through the cycle. In theory, controlled levels of trading with proper risk management, governance, and monitoring could promote more efficient price discovery and add to the depth of the securities and structured products markets.

The following caveats underpinning this analysis must, in particular, be borne in mind:

  • Economic vs. accounting considerations. The underlying data is reported on an accounting basis rather than an economic one. This gives rise to the question of whether trading losses at a particular bank arise because of intentionally unhedged exposure (as in the case of proprietary trading) or because of non-trading exposures. For example, basis risk arising from incomplete hedging of credit or option risk undertaken in the banking book could result in trading book losses if the hedges are booked there. Alternatively, losses on credit exposures booked as trading exposures in order to exploit capital arbitrage could also result in bloated trading loss figures during the crisis.

  • Data constraints. Proprietary trading is often a high frequency business. The appropriate volatility measure should be an average of the daily volatility of trading income rather than annual total trading income, as is the case in the filter.

APPENDIX 10.1. DO TRADING ACTIVITIES INCREASE THE VULNERABILITY OF BANKS?

Increasing involvement by banks in highly risky and leveraged proprietary trading activities in the lead-up to the global financial crisis has been seen as a key factor in generating financial distress. To ascertain if banks with a high share of total trading income18 precrisis were indeed the ones that experienced distress and needed official support,19 a filter rule test20 is applied on 79 SIFIs across Asia, Europe, and the United States. The sample includes commercial, investment, and universal banks. The test on Asian banks serves as a control to gauge if the vulnerabilities to distress, as defined by the filter rule assumptions, hold for a region that remained relatively resilient during the 2008–09 financial crisis.

Filter Rule Test

The filter rule results seem to indicate that in both Europe and the United States, a significant majority of banks requiring assistance were institutions whose trading income-to-total revenue ratios were both in the tails of the historical distribution. Similar results, however, were not observed among Asian banks. Therefore, the support for the hypothesis that banking distress during the recent global financial crisis was a function of trading seems to be conditional. As such, it alludes to the need for further consideration of other factors.

Results from Filter 1

Based on one standard deviation (SD), 72 percent of the European SIFIs identified as “vulnerable” required official assistance (Table 10.7). In the sample of U.S. banks, the corresponding matches between “vulnerable” according to the filter rule and requiring official bank assistance was 67 percent. Thus, at first pass, the results seem to concur with the view that high exposure of revenues from trading activities increases the vulnerability of a banking institution to failure.

TABLE 10.7

Results for U.S., European, and Asian SIFIs

article image
Sources: Bloomberg LP; and IMF staff computations. Note: Europe includes the United Kingdom; Asia includes Australia and Japan. Sample taken from 1999–2007 (United States: 15 SIFIs with 234 data points; Europe: 46 SIFIs with 708 data points; Asia: 18 SIFIs with 163 data points); SD refers to standard deviation.

In Asia, the filter rule results yielded rather different outcomes, with only one out of eight banks predicted by the rule receiving official support, although this was also the only bank that received state assistance.

Results from Filter 2

Repeating the analysis using 2*SD (so as to capture the effects further into the tail of the distribution) confirms the above observations with little change in the predictive ability for European banks and overall improvements for U.S. and Asian banks.

Our Filter 2 results also confirm the significant association between trading ratios at extreme tails and the need for state assistance for U.S. and European banks during the recent crisis, but in the case of Asia only a weak association is obtained, at best.

1

The authors are grateful to Ashok Bhatia, Phil de Imus, Aditya Narain, İnci Ötker-Robe, Zoltan Pozsar, and Constant Verkoren for comments on earlier drafts. An earlier version of this chapter appeared as an IMF Working Paper (WP/11/236) on October 1, 2011.

2

Lending activity is never risk-free. The important issue, however, is not the presence of risk per se, but instead the provision of incentives for proper underwriting of this risk. Such incentives are generally more likely to be preserved when banks’ bottom lines depend on good loan performance. On the other hand, the ability to pad such transactions with excessive leverage obtained at low cost may yield levels of risk that are prohibitively costly for taxpayers to backstop. The experience with subprime mortgage lending in the United States prior to the financial crisis suggests that complementary reform measures—that are in train—on the regulation of securitized lending may be necessary to make banks safer through the rescoping of the business lines.

3

With the separation of utility and nonutility banks, the choice of “portfolio allocation” rests with the individual investor/depositor. A more risk-averse individual may choose to deposit his or her savings fully in utility banks at a lower deposit rate in return for safety. Conversely, a less risk-averse individual may reduce the extent of deposits with utility banks in favor of potentially higher returns from investment in equities/debentures issued by nonutility financial affiliates, albeit at a higher risk profile.

4

Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2002) demonstrate using both theoretical and empirical analyses that imperfect correlation between the demand for liquidity by depositors and that by borrowers lowers the cost of joint provision of both services relative to separate institutional provision.

5

Constraints on portfolio quality are measured by the minimum proportions of assets to be held above given ratings thresholds.

6

The proposal, as originally constructed, was applied to NFBs chartered in the United States under the regulatory and supervisory purview of the Federal Reserve Banks and eligible for the Federal Reserve’s discount window facility.

7

NFBs could undertake repo transactions with private investors and entities with full disclosure of risk.

8

With reference to the U.S. Banking Act of 1933 (wherein sections 16 and 32 introduce the Glass-Steagall separation of investment and commercial banking), see the discussion in Benston (1990) and Kroszner and Rajan (1994). For the Volcker Rule (section 619 of the 2010 Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act), see Group of Thirty (2009).

9

Appendix 10.1 provides some statistical analysis that offers qualified support for an association between trading activity, returns volatility, and increasing correlation with the business cycle. The results described in Appendix 10.1 are consistent with those obtained by Stiroh and Rumble (2006) and with the assessment of relative risk in banks’ different lines of business by Standard and Poor’s (2011).

10

In addition, illiquid fund investments undertaken prior to May 1, 2010, are eligible for a single five-year extension upon application to the Federal Reserve.

11

Glass-Steagall restrictions are understood to mean restrictions in place prior to the passage of the U.S. Financial Modernization Act of 1999 (the so-called Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act).

12

Temporary interruptions would, when occurring in an environment of increasing macro-financial distress, threaten systemic stability via confidence effects and via the knock-on impact on the payments system, besides causing direct loss of welfare.

13

This would be in addition to U.K. banks’ wholesale and investment banking activities remaining subject to capital standards agreed internationally.

14

Such as would result, for example, if the combined funding mix and asset allocation of the ringfenced bank exposes it to losses emanating from interest rate fluctuations or currency rate movements.

15

Large/single-exposure counterparty limits applicable to third-party transactions also apply to intragroup transactions.

16

Indeed, this raises the important question of how stand-alone retail banks can hedge their risks. The compliance and supervision costs associated with ensuring that market products purchased by such firms to hedge risk are not targeted at exposing own-capital to market or counterparty credit risk could be quite high.

17

Fiechter and others (2011) note, in fact, that the subsidiary structure may work well for retail banks because it may benefit from a local management team that is fully accountable for the performance of an affiliate focused on local retail operations. On the other hand, the subsidiary structure may be less suitable for universal and investment banking activities because it could constrain the ability of such businesses to manage liquidity globally and to serve large corporate clients. Large Spanish banks with a retail focus, as well as the U.K. global bank HSBC, largely operate with a subsidiary-based structure.

18

As a majority of banks do not segregate between proprietary trading and hedging activities in trading income, we took the reported “total trading income” as an approximation for proprietary trading. Trading income in banks’ financial statements comprises revenues from revaluation of securities held in the “Trading Book,” net realized gains/losses from proprietary trading activities and disposal of “Available-for-Sale” (AFS) securities and mark-to-market valuation of derivatives for “hedging.” Thus, the proportion of total trading income to total revenue measures the degree of a bank’s overall revenue source that is susceptible to market fluctuations rather than exposure from proprietary trading alone.

19

Official support includes government capital/liquidity injection, nationalization, restructuring, and, in extremis, bankruptcy. Official support may not necessarily mean bankruptcy but without such support, the liquidity problem faced by the banks in question could escalate into a solvency problem which could eventually lead to bankruptcy.

20

The objective of the statistical filter rule is to test the hypothesis that “banks with high shares of trading income to total revenue precrisis were most vulnerable to public bailout.” The methodology includes computation of means and standard deviations (SDs) of trading income-to-total revenue ratios for the period between 1999 and 2007 with the filter rule defined as: mean ± k*SD where k = 1 in Filter 1 and k = 2 in Filter 2. Any bank whose share of trading income-to-total revenue ratio in 2008 exceeds the filters is screened as “vulnerable.” Vulnerable banks are then compared with those receiving official support in 2008/2009 to gauge the predictive ability of the filter rule.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Reforms in the Wake of the Global Crisis
  • Admati, A., P. DeMarzo, M. Hellwig, and P. Pfleiderer, 2010, “Fallacies, Irrelevant Facts, and Myths in the Discussion of Capital Regulation: Why Bank Equity Is Not Expensive,Research Paper 2065R (Stanford: Stanford University Graduate School of Business).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adrian, T., and H. Shin, 2009, “The Shadow Banking System: Implications for Financial Regulation,Banque de France Financial Stability Review Vol. 13, pp. 110.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adrian, T., and H. Shin, 2010, “The Changing Nature of Financial Intermediation and the Financial Crisis of 2007—09,Annual Review of Economics, No.2, pp. 60318.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alessandri, P., and A.G. Haldane, 2009, “Banking on the State” (London: Bank of England). http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/speeches/2009/speech409.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Amel D., C. Barnes, F. Panetta, and C. Salleo, 2004, “Consolidation and Efficiency in the Financial Sector: A Review of the International Evidence,Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 28, pp. 2493519.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andritzky, J., J. Kiff, L. Kodres, P. Madrid, A. Maechler, A. Narain, N. Sacasa, and J. Scarlata, 2009, “Policies to Mitigate Procyclicality,IMF Staff Position Note 09/09 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2009/spn0909.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Asociación Española de Banca, 2010, Spanish Banks’ “Subsidiary Model” (unpublished), Madrid.

  • Association for Financial Markets in Europe (AFME), 2010, “The Systemic Safety Net: Pulling Failing Firms Back From the Edge” (London, August).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank of England, 2010, Financial Stability Report, No. 28 (December).

  • Bank for International Settlements (BIS), 1998, 68th Annual Report (Basel).

  • Bank for International Settlements (BIS), 2004, Foreign Direct Investment in the Financial Sector of Emerging Market Economies—Central Bank Papers Submitted by Working Group Members, Consultative Group on Financial Stability Publication 22 (Basel).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements (BIS), 2010a, “The Group of Governors and Heads of Supervision Reach Broad Agreement on Basel Committee Capital and Liquidity Reform Package.Press release, July 26, 2010. http://www.bis.org/press/p100726.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements (BIS), 2010b, “Group of Governors and Heads of Supervision Announces Higher Global Minimum Capital Standards,Press release, September 12.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements (BIS), 2010c, 80th Annual Report (Basel, June).

  • Bank for International Settlements (BIS), 2011, “Basel Committee Issues Final Elements of the Reforms to Raise the Quality of Regulatory Capital,Press release, January 13.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barclays Capital, 2010, European Banks: “Too Big to Fail” (London: Equity Research).

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 1996, “The Supervision of Cross Border Banking” (Basel: Bank for International Settlements). http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs27.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 1997, “Core Principles of Effective Banking Supervision” (Basel: Bank for International Settlements). http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs30a.pdf).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2003, “Markets for Bank Subordinated Debt and Equity in Basel Committee Member Countries,BCBS Working Paper No. 12 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2006, Core Principles for Effective Banking Supervision (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, October).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2009a, Adjustments to the Basel II Market Risk Framework (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, July). http://www.bis.org/press/p100618.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2009b, International Framework for Liquidity Risk Measurement, Standards, and Monitoring (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, December). http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs165.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2009c, “Revision to the Framework for Market RWA,Consultative Document (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, July).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2009d, Revisions to the Basel II Market Risk Framework, Final Version (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, July). http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs158.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2009e, Strengthening the Resilience of the Banking Sector (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, December). http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs164.htm; and subsequent Appendix. http://www.bis.org/press/p100726.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2010a, “An Assessment of the Long-Term Economic Impact of Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements” (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, August). http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs173.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2010b, “Basel III: A Global Regulatory Framework for More Resilient Banks and Banking Systems” (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, December).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2010c, “The Group of Governors and Heads of Supervision Reach Broad Agreement on Basel Committee Capital and Liquidity Reform Package,Press release of the governors and heads of supervision of the member countries (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, July 26). http://www.bis.org/press/p100726.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2010d, The Joint Forum Review of the Differentiated Nature and Scope of Financial Regulation (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, January).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2010e, “Proposal to Ensure the Loss Absorbency of Regulatory Capital at the Point of Non-Viability,Consultative Document (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, August). http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs174.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2010f, Report and Recommendations of the Cross-Border Bank Resolution Group (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, March).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Benston, G., 1990, The Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

  • Blanchard, O.J., G. Dell’Ariccia, and P. Mauro, 2010, “Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy,IMF Staff Position Note 10/03 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1003.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bolton, P., and F. Samama, 2010, “Contingent Capital and Long Term Investors: A Natural Match?Unpublished (New York: Columbia Business School).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boot, A., S. Greenbaum, and A. Thakor, 1993, “Reputation and Discretion in Financial Contracting,American Economic Review Vol. 83, pp. 116583.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bovenzi, J.F., 2010, “Another View: Why Banks Need ‘Living Wills,’New York Times, Investment Banking (July 8). http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2010/07/08/another-view-why-banks-need-living-wills/

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brennan, M., 2010, “Bank Hybrid Capital Criteria: Methodology and Assumptions,Standard & Poor’s Ratings Direct on the Global Credit Portal, December 6.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brennan, M., and B. de Longevialle, 2010, “Potential $1 Trillion Bank Contingent Capital-Style Issuance Faces Uncertain Investor Interest,Standard & Poor’s Ratings Direct on the Global Credit Portal, December 8.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brunnermeier, M. K., 2009, “Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007–08,Journal of Economic Perspectives Vol. 23, No. 1, pp. 77100.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brunnermeier, M., A. Crockett, C. Goodhart, A. Persaud, and H. Shin, 2009, The Fundamental Principles of Financial Regulation, Geneva Reports on the World Economy, Vol. 11 (Geneva: International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bryan, Lowell L., 1991, “Core Banking,McKinsey Quarterly, Vol. 1, pp. 6174.

  • Cárdenas, J., J.P. Graf, and P. O’Dogherty, 2004, “Foreign Banks Entry in Emerging Market Economies: A Host Country Perspective,Paper prepared for the CGFS Working Group on FDI in the financial sector. www.bis.org/publ/cgfs22mexico.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carvajal, A., R. Dodd, M. Moore, E. Nier, I. Tower, and L. Zanforlin, 2009, “The Perimeter of Financial Regulation,IMF Staff Position Note 09/07 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2009/spn0907.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carvajal, A., and J. Elliott, 2007, “Strengths and Weaknesses in Securities Market Regulation: A Global Analysis,IMF Working Paper No. 07/259 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cerutti, E., G. Dell-Ariccia, and S. Martínez Pería, 2007, “How Banks Go Abroad: Branches or Subsidiaries?Journal of Banking and Finance Vol. 31, pp. 166992.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cerutti, E., A. Ilyina, Y. Makarova, and C. Schmieder, 2010, “Bankers Without Borders? Implications of Ring-Fencing for European Cross-Border Banks,” IMF Working Paper No. 10/247 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chance, Clifford, 2009, “Contingent Capital—The New Hybrid Capital?Client briefing note (London: Clifford Chance LLP, November).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cho, D., 2009, “Banks ‘Too Big to Fail’ Have Grown Even Bigger,Washington Post (August 28).

  • Chow, J., and J. Surti, 2011, “Making Banks Safer: Can Volcker and Vickers Do It?IMF Working Paper 11/236 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cihak, M., and A.F. Tieman,The Quality of Financial Sector Regulation and Supervision around the World,IMF Working Paper 08/190 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Claessens, S., G. Dell’Ariccia, D. Igan, and L. Laeven, 2010, “Lessons and Policy Implications from the Global Financial Crisis,IMF Working Paper 10/44 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Claessens, S., M. Dooley, and A. Warner, 1995, “Portfolio Capital Flows: Hot or Cold?World Bank Economic Review Vol. 9, pp. 15374.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clarke, G., R. Cull, L. D’Amato, and A. Molinari, 2000, “On the Kindness of Strangers? The Impact of Foreign Bank Entry on Domestic Banks in Argentina,in The Internationalization of Financial Services, ed. by S. Claessens and M. Jansen (London: Kluwer Law International).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cline, W., 2010, Financial Globalization, Economic Growth, and the Crisis of 2007–09, (Washington: Peterson Institute for International Economics).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS), 2010a, “Long-Term Issues in International Banking,CGFS Paper No. 41 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements). http://www.bis.org/publ/cgfs41.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS), 2010b, “Macroprudential Instruments and Frameworks: A Stocktaking of Issues and Experiences,CGFS Publication No. 38 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements). http://www.bis.org/publ/cgfs38.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS), 2010c, “The Role of Margin Requirements and Haircuts in Procyclicality,CGFS Publication No. 36 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements). http://www.bis.org/publ/cgfs36.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Larosiére, J., 2009, “Report of the High-level Group on Financial Supervision in the EU” (Brussels: European Union, February 25).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dell’Ariccia, G., and R. Marquez, 2010, “Risk and the Corporate Structure of Banks,Journal of Finance Vol. 65 (June), pp. 107596. http://www.afajof.org/journal/forth_abstract.asp?ref=567

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Martino, G., M. Libertucci, M. Marangoni, and M. Quagliariello, 2010, “Countercyclical Contingent Capital (CCC): Possible Use and Ideal Design,Banca d’Italia Occasional Paper (Rome).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Young, R., D. Evanoff, and P. Molyneux, 2009, “Mergers and Acquisitions of Financial Institutions: A Review of the Post—2000 Literature,Journal of Financial Services Research Vol. 36, pp. 87110.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dickson, J., 2009, “Remarks at the INSOL Eight World Quadrennial Congress” (Vancouver: International Association of Restructuring, Insolvency, and Bankruptcy Professionals), June 21.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Duffie, D., 2010, “A Contractual Approach to Restructuring Financial Institutions,” in Ending Government Bailouts as We Know Them, ed. by G. Schultz, K. Scott, and J. Taylor (Stanford: Hoover Institute Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC), 2006, “Directive 2006/48/EC of the European Parliament” (Brussels). http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/bank/regcapital/index_en.htm#crd

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC), 2007, “Supervision of Branches under MiFID,Internal Markets and Services DG (Brussels). http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/securities/docs/isd/mifid-branches_en.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC), 2009, “An EU Framework for Cross-Border Crisis Management in the Banking Sector,Communication of the European Commission (COM) No. 561 (Brussels, October 20).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC), 2010a, “An EU Framework for Crisis Management in the Financial Sector,Communication of the European Commission (COM) No. 579 final (Brussels, October 20). http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/bank/docs/crisis-management/framework/com2010_579_en.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC), 2010b, “Study on the Feasibility of Reducing Obstacles to the Transfer of Assets Within a Cross-Border Banking Group During a Financial Crisis, Final Report” (Brussels, April). http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/bank/windingup/index_en.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC), 2011, “Technical Details of a possible EU Framework for Bank Recovery and Resolution,DG Internal Market and Services Working Document (Brussels: January). http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/consultations/docs/2011/crisis_management/consultation_paper_en.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fiechter, J., I. Ötker-Robe, A. Ilyina, M. Hsu, A. Santos, and J. Surti, 2011, “Subsidiaries or Branches: Does One Size Fit All?IMF Staff Discussion Note 11/4 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, March). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2011/sdn1104.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Stability Board (FSB), 2010a, “Constraints on Business Activity,Standing Committee on Regulation and Supervisory Coordination (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, May 12).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Stability Board (FSB), 2010b, “Financial Stability Board Meets in Seoul,Press release (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, October 20). http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/press/pr_101020.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Stability Board (FSB), 2010c, FSB Report on Progress Since the Washington Summit (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, November). http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_101111b.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Stability Board (FSB), 2010d, “G-20 Leaders Endorse FSB Policy Framework for Addressing Systemically Important Financial Institutions,Press release, November 12 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements). http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/press/pr_101111a.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Stability Board (FSB), 2010e, Intensity and Effectiveness of SIFI Supervision: Recommendations for Enhanced Supervision, prepared in consultation with the IMF (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, November 1). http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_101101.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Stability Board (FSB), 2010f, “Letter to G-20 Leaders on Progress of Financial Regulatory Reforms,Press release, November 9 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements). http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_101109.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Stability Board (FSB), 2010g, Reducing the Moral Hazard Posed by Systemically Important Financial Institutions (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, November 11). http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_101111a.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • FSB and Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2010, “Assessing the Macroeconomic Impact of the Transition to Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements,Macroeconomic Assessment Group (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, August). http://www.bis.org/publ/othp10.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Stability Forum (FSF), 2009, FSF Principles for Sound Compensation Practices (Basel: Bank for International Settlements, April 2). http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_0904b.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC), 2011, Study and Recommendations on Prohibitions on Proprietary Trading and Certain Relationships with Hedge Funds and Private Equity Funds (Washington, January 19). http://www.treasury.gov/initiatives/Pages/FSOC-index.aspx

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • FINMA (Swiss Financial Market Supervisory Authority), 2011, “Addressing ‘Too Big to Fail’: The Swiss SIFI Policy” (Bern, June 23).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flannery, M., 2009, “Market-Valued Triggers Will Work for Contingent Capital Instruments,Solicited Submission to U.S. Treasury Working Group on Bank Capital (November).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flannery, M., 2010, “Stabilizing Large Financial Institutions with Contingent Capital Certificates,Carefin Working Paper 4 (Milan: Centre for Applied Research in Finance).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • French, K., M. Baily, J. Campbell, J. Cochrane, D. Diamond, D. Duffie, A. Kashyap, F. Mishkin, R. Rajan, D. Scharfstein, R. Shiller, H.S. Shin, M. Slaughter, J. Stein, and R. Stulz, 2010, The Squam Lake Report: Fixing the Financial System (Princeton: Princeton University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, M., and N. Véron, 2011, “Too Big to Fail: The Transatlantic Debate,Working Paper Series 11–2. (Washington: Peterson Institute for International Economics). http://www.iie.com/publications/interstitial.cfm?ResearchID=1745

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goodhart, C., 2010a, “Are CoCos from Cloud Cuckoo-Land?VoxEU.

  • Goodhart, C., 2010b, “How Should We Regulate Bank Capital and Financial Products? What Role for ‘Living Wills’?” in The Future of Finance: The LSE Report, ed. by A. Turner, A. Haldane, P. Woolley, S. Wadhwani, C. Goodhart, A. Smithers, A. Large, J. Kay, M. Wolf, P. Boone, S. Johnson, and R. Layard (London: London School of Economics Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gorton, G. and A. Metrick, 2010, “Regulating the Shadow Banking System,Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2 (Fall), pp. 261312.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Group of Thirty (G-30), 2009, Financial Reform: A Framework for Financial Stability (Washington, January). http://www.group30.org/pubs/reformreport.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Group of Twenty (G-20), 2008, Declaration Issued at the Summit on Financial Markets and the World Economy, Washington, November 15. http://www.canadainternational.gc.ca/g20/summit-sommet/g20/declaration_111508.aspx

  • Group of Twenty (G-20), 2009a, “Declaration on Strengthening the Financial System,Statement issued at the April 2009 G-20 Summit, London.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Group of Twenty (G-20), 2009b, “Leader’s Statement of the Pittsburgh Summit,Statement issued at the October 2009 G-20 Summit, Pittsburgh.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haldane, A., 2010, “The $100 Billion Question,Speech to Institute of Regulation and Risk, Hong Kong (March 30). http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/news/2010/036.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haldane, A., S. Brennan, and V. Madouros, 2010, “What Is the Contribution of the Financial Sector: Miracle or Mirage?” in The Future of Finance: The LSE Report (London: London School of Economics Press). http://futureoffinance.org.uk/

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Henriques, Roberto, C. Leukers, and E. Longato, 2010a, “Applying the Swiss Finish,J.P. Morgan (October 28).

  • Henriques, Roberto, C. Leukers, and E. Longato, 2010b, “European Bank Bail-In Survey Results,J.P. Morgan, Europe Credit Research (October 14).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Henriques, Roberto, C. Leukers, and E. Longato, 2010c, “The Future of Hybrid Bank Capital?J.P. Morgan, Europe Credit Research (October 6).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Herring, R., 2009, “Wind-Down Plans as an Alternative to Bailouts,Briefing Paper 15 (Washington: Pew Financial Reform Project). http://www.pewfr.org/admin/project_reports/files/Wind-down-plans.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Huertas, Thomas F., 2010, “Living Wills: How Can the Concept Be Implemented?Speech at the Wharton School of Management (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania), February 12. http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pages/Library/Communication/Speeches/2010/0212_th.shtml

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hull, L., 2002, “Foreign-Owned Banks: Implications for New Zealand’s Financial Stability,Discussion Paper No. 2002/05 (Wellington: Reserve Bank of New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ineke, J., L. Street, and F. Simpson, 2010, “European Banks: €49 Billion of Swiss CoCos,Morgan Stanley Research (October 4).

  • Ineke, J., L. Street, F. Simpson, and N. Blackman, 2010, “European Banks Tier 1: A New Paradigm,Morgan Stanley Research (November 4).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Institute of International Finance, 2010, A Global Approach to Resolving Failing Financial Firms: An Industry Perspective (Washington, May).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Institute of International Finance, 2011, The Cumulative Impact on The Global Economy of Changes in the Financial Regulatory Framework (September). www.iif.com/download.php?id=oXT67gHVBJk=

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Association of Insurance Supervisors, 2003, “Insurance Core Principles and Methodology” (Basel, October).

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2004a, “Financial Sector Regulation: Issues and Gaps” (Washington: August).

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2004b, “Financial Sector Regulation: Issues and Gaps,Background Paper (Washington, August).

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2008a, Global Financial Stability Report (Washington, October). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2008/02/index.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2008b, “Implementation of the Basel Core Principles for Effective Banking Supervision—Experience with Assessments and Implications for Future Work” (Washington, September).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2009, Lessons of the Financial Crisis for Future Regulation of Financial Institutions and Markets and for Liquidity Management (Washington). http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2009/020409.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2010a, Central Banking Lessons from the Crisis (Washington). http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2010/052710.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2010b, Cross-Cutting Themes in Economies with Large Banking Systems (Washington). http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2010/041610.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2010c, “Draft Final Report for the Group of Twenty Ministers on a Fair and Substantial Contribution by the Financial Sector” (Washington, May 28).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2010d, A Fair and Substantial Contribution by the Financial Sector, Report to the G-20 (Washington, June). http://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/062710b.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2010e, Global Financial Stability Report (Washington, April). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2010/01/index.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2010f, Global Financial Stability Report (Washington, October). http://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/GFSR/2010/02/pdf/text.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2010g, Resolution of Cross-Border Banks: A Proposed Framework for Enhanced Coordination (Washington). http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2010/061110.pdf

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2010h, “Systemic Liquidity Risk: The Resilience of Institutions and Markets,Chapter 2 in Global Financial Stability Report (Washington, October). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2010/02/pdf/chap2.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2010i, Understanding Financial Interconnectedness (Washington).

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2011, Global Financial Stability Report (Washington, April). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2011/01/index.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF and the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), 2009, “Guidance to Assess the Systemic Importance of Financial Institutions, Markets, and Instruments: Initial Consideration,Report to the G-20 (Washington, October). http://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/100109.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF and Financial Stability Board (FSB), 2009, “The Financial Crisis and Information Gaps,Report to the G-20 (Washington, October). http://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/102909.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF and Financial Stability Board (FSB), 2010, “Financial Crisis and Information Gaps,Progress Report, Action Plans and Timetables, prepared by IMF Staff and the FSB Secretariat. http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_100510.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF, Bank for International Settlements (BIS), and FSB, 2009, “Guidance to Assess the Systemic Importance of Financial Institutions, Markets, and Instruments: Initial Consideration, Report with the Bank for International Settlements to the G-20,Report to the G-20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund and the Bank for International Settlements, and the Secretariat of the Financial Stability Board (Washington and Basel, October). http://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/100109.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF, Bank for International Settlements (BIS), and FSB, 2010, “Capital and Liquidity Surcharges and Financial Levies and Taxes: Coherence and Consistency: A Note by the FSB, IMF, and BCBS” (Washington and Basel, April 18).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF, Bank for International Settlements (BIS), and FSB, 2011, “Macroprudential Policy Tools and Frameworks: Update to G-20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors (Washington, February).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Organization of Securities Commissions, 2003, “Objectives and Principles of Securities Regulation” (May).

  • Johnson, S., and J. Kwak, 2010, 13 Bankers: The Wall Street Takeover and the Next Financial Meltdown (New York: Random House).

  • Johnston, R. B., E. Psalida, P. de Imus, J. Gobat, M. Goswami, C. Mulder, and F. Vazquez, 2009, “Addressing Information Gaps,IMF Staff Position Note 09/06 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2009/spn0906.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kashyap, A., R. Rajan, and J. Stein, 2002, “Banks as Liquidity Providers: An Explanation for the Coexistence of Lending and Deposit-Taking,Journal of Finance Vol. 57, pp. 3373.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kay, J., 2009, “Narrow Banking: The Reform of Banking Regulation,Unpublished. http://www.johnkay.com/wp-content/uploads/2009/12/JK-Narrow-Banking.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kodres, L., and A. Narain, 2010, “Redesigning the Contours of the Future Financial System,IMF Staff Position Note 10/10 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1010.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kroszner, R., and R. Rajan, 1994, “Is the Glass-Steagall Act Justified? A Study of the U.S. Experience with Universal Banking Before 1933,American Economic Review Vol. 84, pp. 81032.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Landier, A., and K. Ueda, 2009, “The Economics of Bank Restructuring: Understanding the Options,IMF Staff Position Note, SPN/09/12 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laeven, L., and R. Levine, 2007, “Is There a Diversification Discount in Financial Conglomerates?Journal of Financial Economics Vol. 85, pp. 33167.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Litan, R., 1987, What Should Banks Do? (Washington: The Brookings Institution).

  • Ludwig, E.A., 2011, “A Fragmented Bank Isn’t a Safer One,American Banker Vol. 176, No. 11 (January 20).

  • Mengle, D., 2010, “Concentration of OTC Derivatives among Major Dealers,ISDA Research Notes, Issue 4. www2.isda.org/attachment/MTY3OA==/ConcentrationRN_4-10.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Miles, D., J. Yang, and G. Marcheggiano, 2011, “Optimal Bank Capital,Discussion Paper 31 (London: Bank of England, External MPC Unit), January.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mishkin, Frederic S.,Financial Consolidation: Dangers and Opportunities,Journal of Banking and Finance Vol. 23 (February), pp. 67591.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nier, E.W., 2009, “Financial Stability Frameworks and the Role of Central Banks: Lessons from the Crisis.IMF Working Paper No. 09/70 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2009/wp0970.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ötker-Robe, I., A. Narain, A. Ilyina, and J. Surti, with A. Buffa di Perrero, J. Chow, M. Dobler, S. Iorgova, T. Kisinbay, M. Moore, J. Podpiera, K. Seal, V. Tulin, and J. Zhou, 2011, “The Too-Important-to-Fail Conundrum: Impossible to Ignore and Difficult to Resolve,IMF Staff Discussion Note No. 11/12 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=24873.0

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ötker-Robe, I., and C. Pazarbasioglu, with A. Buffa di Perrero, S. Iorgova, T. Kişinbay, V. Le Leslé, F. Melo, J. Podpiera, N. Sacasa, and A. Santos, 2010, “Impact of Regulatory Reforms on Large Complex Financial Institutions,IMF Staff Position Note 10/16 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=24314.0

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Palmer J., 2009, “Can We Enhance Financial Stability on a Foundation of Weak Financial Supervision?Revista de Estabilidad Financiera No. 17 (Madrid: Banco de España, November).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pazarbasioglu, C., J. Zhou, V. Le Leslé, and M. Moore, 2011, “Contingent Capital: Economic Rational and Design Features,IMF Staff Discussion Note No. 11/01 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2011/sdn1101.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pierce, J., 1991, The Future of Banking (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press).

  • Polk, Davis, 2010, “Summary of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act,July 21. http://www.google.com/url?q=http://www.davispolk.com/files/Publication/7084f9fe-6580-413b-b870-b7c025ed2ecf/Presentation/PublicationAttachment/1d4495c7-0be0-4e9a-ba77-f786fb90464a/070910_Financial_Reform_Summary.pdf&sa=U&ei=DPq7TqqsPOm60AG_sODXCQ&ved=0CBIQFjAB&usg=AFQjCNFNcGrEeq_edxuYVNHB6hkoW48zEQ

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pozsar, Z., T. Adrian, A. Ashcraft, and H. Boesky, 2010, “Shadow Banking,Staff Report No. 458, Federal Reserve Bank of New York (New York, July). http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr458.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reserve Bank of New Zealand, 2011, “Statement of Principles – Bank Registration and Supervision,Document BS1 (September 2011). (http://www.rbnz.govt.nz/finstab/banking/regulation/3272066.pdf)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roth, J.-P., 2007, “Highly Leveraged Institutions and Financial Stability—A Case for Regulation,” in Law and Economics of Risk in Finance, ed. by Peter Nobel and Marina Gets (Zurich: Schulthess).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schmid, M. M., and I. Walter, 2009, “Do Financial Conglomerates Create or Destroy Economic Value?Journal of Financial Intermediation Vol. 18, pp. 193216.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Seelig, S. A., and A. Novoa, 2009, “Governance Practices at Financial Regulatory and Supervisory Agencies,IMF Working Paper No. 09/135 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Senior Supervisors Group (SSG), 2008, “Observations on Risk Management Practices during the Recent Market Turbulence” (New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, March).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Senior Supervisors Group (SSG), 2009, “Risk Management Lessons from the Global Banking Crisis of 2008” (New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, October).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Senior Supervisors Group (SSG), 2010, “Risk Management Lessons from the Global Banking Crisis of 2008” (New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, October).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shecter, B., 2011, “Post-Crisis, Bank Risk on Rise Again Financial Post,Calgary Herald (March 29). http://www.calgaryherald.com/story_print.html?id=4517378&sponsor=curriebarracks

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Song, I., 2004, “Foreign Bank Supervision and Challenges to Emerging Market Supervisors,IMF Working Paper No. 04/82 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Standard and Poor’s, 2011, “Industry Risk for Investment Banking Is Generally Higher than for Other Financial Institutions” (January 6).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stiroh, K. J., and A. Rumble, 2006, “The Dark Side of Diversification: The Case of U.S. Financial Holding Companies,Journal of Banking and Finance Vol. 30, pp. 2131161.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Strauss-Kahn, D., 2010, “Reject Ad-Hoc, National Financial Reforms,Op-ed, Financial Times, February 17.

  • Sundaresan, S., and Z. Wang, 2010, “Designing of Contingent Capital with a Stock Price Trigger for Mandatory Conversion,Staff Paper No. 448 (New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Swiss Financial Market Supervisory Authority, 2011, “Addressing ‘Too Big To Fail’: The Swiss SIFI Policy” (June 23).

  • Tarullo, D., 2009, “Confronting Too Big to Fail,Speech at the Exchequer Club, Washington, D.C., October 21 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System). http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/tarullo20091021a.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tirole, J., 2006, Theory of Corporate Finance (Princeton: Princeton University Press).

  • UNCITRAL, 2009a, “Treatment of Enterprise Groups in insolvency,Working Group document No. A/CN.9WG.V/WP90, 37th session (November). http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/commission/working_groups/5Insolvency.html

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • UNCITRAL, 2009b, UNCITRAL Practice Guide on Cross-Border Insolvency Cooperation.

  • United Kingdom, Financial Services Authority (U.K.-FSA), 2009, The Turner Review: A Regulatory Response to the Global Banking Crisis (London, March). www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/turner_review.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Kingdom, Independent Commission on Banking, 2011, Interim Report: Consultation on Reform Options (London, April).

  • United States House of Representatives, 2009, Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010, §1609(a)(1)(L) (Passed by the House of Representatives on December 11) (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States House of Representatives, 2010, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, H.R. Bill No. 4173, 111th Congress of the United States (July 21) (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States Senate, 2010, Restoring American Financial Stability Act of 2010, §210(a)(1)(N), (Washington, May).

  • van Lelyveld, I., and K. Knot, 2009, “Do Financial Conglomerates Create or Destroy Value? Evidence for the EU,Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 33, pp. 2312321.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Viñals, J., 2011, “Do’s and Don’ts of Macroprudential Policy,Speech delivered at European Commission and ECB Conference on Financial Integration and Stability, Brussels, May 2. https://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2011/050211.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Vinãls, J., J. Fiechter, A. Narain, J. A. Elliott, I. Tower, P. Bologna, and M. Hsu, 2010a, “The Making of Good Supervision: Learning to Say ‘No’,IMF Staff Position Note 2010/08 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1008.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Viñals, J., J. Fiechter, C. Pazarbasioglu, L. Kodres, A. Narain, and M. Moretti, 2010b, “Shaping the New Financial System,IMF Staff Position Note No. 10/15 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=24204.0

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wheelock, D., and P. Wilson, 2009, “Are U.S. Banks Too Large?,Working Paper No. 2009-054B (St. Louis: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, December).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation