Summary
The asset allocation decisions of investors are at the core of financial flows between markets, currencies, and countries. This chapter aims to identify the fundamental drivers for these decisions and determine whether their influence has been altered by the global financial crisis and the subsequent low interest rate environment in advanced economies. In particular, the chapter investigates whether changes in investor behavior pose downside risks for global financial stability.
To set the stage, the longer-term developments in global asset allocation show three main trends: (i) a gradual broadening of the distribution of assets across countries, implying a globalization of portfolios with a slowly declining home bias; (ii) a long-term decline in the share of assets held by pension funds and insurance companies in favor of asset management by investment companies; and (iii) the increasing importance of the official sector in global asset allocation through sovereign wealth funds and managers of international reserves.
The analysis shows that private asset allocation is driven most strongly by positive growth prospects and falling risks in the recipient countries, while interest rate differentials between countries play a lesser role. The analysis does not, however, imply that capital flows in general do not respond to interest rate differentials, since other components, including investment flows of short-term leveraged investors (such as those from the carry trade)—which this chapter does not examine—might still be affected by changes in interest rates.
Beyond these longer-term trends and investment drivers, the empirical results and survey responses indicate that asset allocation strategies of private and official institutional investors have changed since the onset of the global financial crisis. Most importantly, investors are more risk conscious, including regarding the risks associated with liquidity and sovereign credit. Also, the structural trend of investing in emerging market assets has accelerated following the crisis; and with many first-time investors taking advantage of the relatively better economic performance of these countries, the risk of a reversal cannot be discounted if fundamentals (such as growth prospects or country or global risk) change. For larger shocks, the impact of such reversals could be of the same magnitude as the pullback in flows experienced during the financial crisis.
In touching on the potential effect of regulation on the asset allocation of institutional investors, the chapter suggests that initiatives like Solvency II for European insurance companies may push these institutions away from their traditional role of taking on longer-term risky assets, potentially dampening the positive impact of one class of “deep pocket” investors.
Regarding sovereign wealth funds and reserves management, the chapter suggests that sovereign asset allocation may provide a counterweight for changing private sector behavior. As heightened risk awareness and regulatory initiatives push private investors to hold “safer” assets, sovereign asset managers may take on some of the longer-term risks that private investors now avoid.
This chapter aims to describe recent changes in the global asset allocation of long-term investors, explain the drivers of those changes, offer an assessment of the associated risks that may be building up in the context of the current extraordinary economic and policy environment, and investigate their more lasting implications. In particular, it will explore to what extent the persistence of low interest rates in advanced economies has fundamentally altered global asset allocation and associated investment decisions of long-term unleveraged investors and whether any changes in behavior of those investors hold downside risks for global financial stability.
In this context, the chapter will focus on the following questions:
-
What are the trends in global asset allocation in the past decade, and what are their determinants? Do trends and determinants differ by country or region?
-
Have the financial crisis, the sovereign debt crisis in Europe, and low interest rates in advanced economies fundamentally altered investment decisions, perhaps pressing long-term investors toward riskier investments to augment their poor returns in advanced economies? Are there growing risks for a reversal of investment flows to emerging economies, and if so, how would that affect capital flows? In the longer term, is financial stability compromised as a result of these developments?
The chapter takes as its point of departure the asset allocation decision of the individual investor. This sets it apart from much of the existing literature, which focuses on investment flows from the macroeconomic point of view, and derives most of its analysis from balance of payments flow data.1 In this chapter’s more integrated view, changes in asset allocation over time are the fundamental driver of financial flows into and out of markets, currencies, and countries. We focus on unleveraged (real money) investors, including individuals, public and private pension funds, insurance companies, and managers of sovereign wealth, which together are a sizable source of underlying capital flows.
An extensive literature links asset allocation to an investor’s objectives and the risk and return characteristics of individual assets (Annex 2.1). It is assumed that investors behave predictably when such characteristics change: when the return of an asset increases without changes in its riskiness, investors are expected to want to hold more of that asset. Similarly, when an asset is seen as more risky (because its return is more variable, for example, or the risk of default increases) without offering a higher return, investors would want to hold less of it.
The financial crisis has raised the possibility that some of the parameters in these relationships—or even investors’ objectives themselves—have changed. Anecdotal evidence abounds, and can sometimes seem contradictory. For example, investors, spooked by the financial turmoil, are said to have become much more sensitized to risk, including to “tail events,” that is, events with a small probability but with large (adverse) effects, and are seeking to protect themselves against associated potential losses. Similarly, after disruptions in some markets during the height of the financial turmoil, investors are more focused on market liquidity, which is the ease with which an asset can be sold. These structural changes interact with cyclical factors: despite increased sensitivity to risk, persistent low interest rates may push some investors (especially those with the need to earn a certain minimum return to match expected payouts on their liabilities) to take on additional risk in alternative assets and in smaller, potentially less liquid markets to increase returns on their assets.
The question from the perspective of financial stability is whether any such changes in investor behavior, especially by real-money investors, could be making financial institutions, markets, or economies more vulnerable to unexpected shocks. Such vulnerabilities could result in (i) unexpected large losses for institutional investors (if pension funds and insurance companies take additional risk on their balance sheets), (ii) the risk of disruptions in financial markets (if the demand for assets suddenly changes, thereby affecting prices and market liquidity), or (iii) the risk of economic disruption (if there are large capital flows in or out of countries). These disruptions might be especially acute in less liquid emerging markets. Awareness of such potential outcomes is important for investors so they can adequately protect themselves, as well as for policymakers so they can establish measures to reduce threats to financial stability.
This chapter looks at these issues in detail, using available public and private data, the views of investors and other market participants, and the results of a recent survey conducted by the IMF (Annex 2.2). First, the chapter uses these data sources to look at the two broad categories of investors—private and official holders—focusing on long-term trends from a database of $60 trillion in institutional investments. It also looks at developments in sovereign asset allocation, which covers some $14 trillion in assets. That segment has been growing rapidly in size—and therefore in importance for the overall assessment of implications for financial stability. A detailed database of a subset of equity and bond funds is then used to investigate the fundamental determinants of global asset allocation by private investors, such as economic growth, interest rates, and measures of risk. The chapter also looks at evidence of a shift in investor behavior since the crisis. It then uses the results of the econometric estimates for a “stress test” of investment flows across countries, estimating the effects of large changes in underlying factors on asset allocation flows. The chapter ends with implications of our findings for investors and policymakers.
Longer-Term Trends in Global Asset Allocation
Stylized Facts on Private Sector Institutional Investment
Existing aggregated data do not provide a comprehensive view of asset allocation on a truly global scale, but a dataset from the OECD is useful for analysis of the longer-term trends in the global allocations flowing from advanced economies.2 The OECD data cover consistent data for assets under management by institutional investors domiciled in 17 OECD countries.3 They show that after strong growth in the second half of the 1990s and stagnation in the early 2000s, assets almost doubled between 2002 and 2007, to $63 trillion (Table 2.1 and Figure 2.1). During the financial crisis, they declined to about $53 trillion at end-2008 before rebounding to $60 trillion at end-2009 (compared with $72 trillion in total bank assets).4 As a share of GDP, total assets under management rose some 75 percentage points, to over 180 percent of GDP, between 1995 and 2007. They fell to 143 percent of GDP by end-2008, with the largest relative drop in assets for pension funds (which have the largest share of assets in equities).
Assets under Management by Institutional Investors
Investment funds include closed-end and managed investment companies, mutual funds, and unit investment trusts.
Assets under Management by Institutional Investors
1995 | 2000 | 2005 | 2006 | 2007 | 2008 | 2009 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(In trillions of U.S. dollars) | |||||||
Institutional Investors | 21.9 | 33.5 | 49.0 | 56.6 | 62.8 | 52.5 | 60.3 |
Investment funds1 | 6.3 | 12.1 | 18.2 | 21.5 | 24.9 | 20.6 | 24.0 |
Insurance companies | 8.0 | 10.4 | 16.3 | 18.1 | 19.9 | 18.3 | 20.0 |
Autonomous pension funds | 7.2 | 10.8 | 14.3 | 16.5 | 17.7 | 13.3 | 15.9 |
Other institutional investors | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.6 | 0.7 | 0.6 | 0.7 |
(In percent of GDP) | |||||||
Institutional Investors | 103.0 | 147.6 | 162.0 | 178.1 | 181.7 | 143.3 | 173.7 |
Investment funds1 | 29.8 | 53.4 | 60.3 | 67.8 | 72.1 | 56.3 | 69.2 |
Insurance companies | 37.7 | 45.6 | 53.9 | 57.1 | 57.5 | 50.0 | 57.7 |
Autonomous pension funds | 33.8 | 47.4 | 47.3 | 51.8 | 51.2 | 36.3 | 45.9 |
Other institutional investors | 2.5 | 2.2 | 1.6 | 1.9 | 1.9 | 1.6 | 2.0 |
Investment funds include closed-end and managed investment companies, mutual funds, and unit investment trusts.
Assets under Management by Institutional Investors
1995 | 2000 | 2005 | 2006 | 2007 | 2008 | 2009 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(In trillions of U.S. dollars) | |||||||
Institutional Investors | 21.9 | 33.5 | 49.0 | 56.6 | 62.8 | 52.5 | 60.3 |
Investment funds1 | 6.3 | 12.1 | 18.2 | 21.5 | 24.9 | 20.6 | 24.0 |
Insurance companies | 8.0 | 10.4 | 16.3 | 18.1 | 19.9 | 18.3 | 20.0 |
Autonomous pension funds | 7.2 | 10.8 | 14.3 | 16.5 | 17.7 | 13.3 | 15.9 |
Other institutional investors | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.6 | 0.7 | 0.6 | 0.7 |
(In percent of GDP) | |||||||
Institutional Investors | 103.0 | 147.6 | 162.0 | 178.1 | 181.7 | 143.3 | 173.7 |
Investment funds1 | 29.8 | 53.4 | 60.3 | 67.8 | 72.1 | 56.3 | 69.2 |
Insurance companies | 37.7 | 45.6 | 53.9 | 57.1 | 57.5 | 50.0 | 57.7 |
Autonomous pension funds | 33.8 | 47.4 | 47.3 | 51.8 | 51.2 | 36.3 | 45.9 |
Other institutional investors | 2.5 | 2.2 | 1.6 | 1.9 | 1.9 | 1.6 | 2.0 |
Investment funds include closed-end and managed investment companies, mutual funds, and unit investment trusts.
Asset Allocation of Institutional Investors
(In trillions of U.S. dollars)
Sources: OECD: and IMF staff estimates.Note: Data based on the assets under management by institutional investors in 17 OECD countries (see Table 2.1 for list). “Other” includes commercial loans and credits: financial derivatives: short-term investments: investments in hedge funds, private equities, and commodities: and miscellaneous assets.Investors domiciled in the United States still account for almost half of all assets under management in the 17 OECD countries, although their share is declining (Figure 2.2). The most marked change among countries with large investment holdings has been a large drop in the share of Japanese investors. Also, asset concentration has declined, with investments domiciled in the five countries with the largest holdings declining from about 90 percent of total assets in 1995 to about 80 percent in 2009.
Assets of Institutional Investors by Country
(In percent of total assets under management)
Sources: OECD; and IMF staff estimates.Note: Data based on the assets under management by institutional investors in 17 OECD countries (see Table 2.1 for list). Percentages may not sum to 100 due to rounding.The share of assets under management by type of institutional investor has changed considerably over the 1995-2009 period (Figure 2.3). During that time, the share of pension funds and insurance companies declined markedly, while investment funds saw their share increase from 29 percent to 40 percent of total assets under management. This is likely due in part to the long-run shift from (generally corporate) defined benefit to (generally individual) defined contribution pension systems (especially in the United States). Assets in defined contribution plans are increasingly managed by investment funds.
Assets under Management by Type of Institutional Investor
(In percent of total)
Sources: OECD; and IMF staff estimates.Note: Data based on the assets under management by institutional investors in 17 OECD countries (see Table 2.1 for list).1Investment funds include closed-end and managed investment companies, mutual funds, and unit investment trusts.By asset class, the value of securities other than shares (mostly bonds) has risen fairly steadily, while the value of equities has fluctuated more strongly (see Figure 2.1). Equity price declines dominated the decline in the total value of assets under management between 1999 and 2001 and again in 2008. Over the full 1995-2009 period, the proportion of shares and other equities rose to more than two-fifths, and the proportion of loans declined.
The asset allocation of institutional investors differs markedly by country (Figure 2.4). U.S. investors hold about equal shares of equities and bonds, while investors in France hold a majority of assets in bonds and those in Germany hold almost one-third of their assets in currency and deposits. Although the shares by asset class have changed over the past decade and a half, the main stylized facts by country remain mostly intact.
Global Asset Allocation of Institutional Investors by Selected Country
(In percent)
Sources: OECD: and IMF staff estimates.Note: Data based on the assets under management by institutional investors in 17 OECD countries (see Table 2.1 for list). Data exclude assets classified in “other” category.The diversity in asset allocation across countries reflects in part differing investment structures, but not differences in holdings by type of investor, which are similar across countries (Figure 2.5). For example, in France, savings for retirement are concentrated in insurance products, and insurance companies globally tend to invest heavily in fixed income securities. In contrast, autonomous pension funds hold more than one-third of institutional assets in the United States, and they generally invest more heavily in equities.
Assets under Management by Type of Institutional Investor and Selected Country, 2009
(In percent)
Sources: OECD: and IMF staff estimates.Note: Data based on the assets under management by institutional investors in 17 OECD countries (see Table 2.1 for list). Percentages may not sum to 100 due to rounding.1Investment funds include closed-end and managed investment companies, mutual funds, and unit investment trusts.Stylized Facts on Official Sector Investment Vehicles
While the overwhelming majority of financial assets is owned and managed by private investors, sovereign investors have grown to become important players in international capital markets. Sovereign wealth funds (SWFs) hold some $4.7 trillion in assets (SWF Institute, 2011; see Table 2.2 for a selection of SWFs), while international foreign exchange reserves amount to $10 trillion (Figure 2.6).5 Taken together, the value of assets in SWFs and foreign exchange reserves is equal to about one-fourth of the assets under management of private institutional investors.
Assets of Selected Sovereign Wealth Funds
(In billions of U.S. dollars)
Assets of Selected Sovereign Wealth Funds
(In billions of U.S. dollars)
Country | Sovereign Wealth Fund | End-2007 | End-2010 |
---|---|---|---|
Australia | The Future Fund | 44.9 | 70.3 |
Canada | Alberta Heritage Savings Trust Fund | 16.7 | 15.5 |
Chile | Economic and Social Stabilization Fund | 14.0 | 12.7 |
Chile | Pension Reserve Fund | 1.5 | 3.8 |
China | China Investment Corporation | 200.0 | 409.6 |
Ireland | National Pensions Reserve Fund | 31.1 | 30.3 |
Korea | Korea Investment Corporation | 15.5 | 37.6 |
New Zealand | New Zealand Superannuation Fund | 10.7 | 14.0 |
Norway | Government Pension Fund-Global | 373.1 | 525.1 |
Singapore | Temasek | 134.1 | 153.0 |
Timor-Leste | Petroleum Fund of Timor-Leste | 2.1 | 6.9 |
Trinidad and Tobago | Heritage and Stabilization Fund | 1.8 | 4.0 |
United States | Alaska Permanent Fund | 39.4 | 38.8 |
Assets of Selected Sovereign Wealth Funds
(In billions of U.S. dollars)
Country | Sovereign Wealth Fund | End-2007 | End-2010 |
---|---|---|---|
Australia | The Future Fund | 44.9 | 70.3 |
Canada | Alberta Heritage Savings Trust Fund | 16.7 | 15.5 |
Chile | Economic and Social Stabilization Fund | 14.0 | 12.7 |
Chile | Pension Reserve Fund | 1.5 | 3.8 |
China | China Investment Corporation | 200.0 | 409.6 |
Ireland | National Pensions Reserve Fund | 31.1 | 30.3 |
Korea | Korea Investment Corporation | 15.5 | 37.6 |
New Zealand | New Zealand Superannuation Fund | 10.7 | 14.0 |
Norway | Government Pension Fund-Global | 373.1 | 525.1 |
Singapore | Temasek | 134.1 | 153.0 |
Timor-Leste | Petroleum Fund of Timor-Leste | 2.1 | 6.9 |
Trinidad and Tobago | Heritage and Stabilization Fund | 1.8 | 4.0 |
United States | Alaska Permanent Fund | 39.4 | 38.8 |
Foreign Exchange Reserves, Excluding Gold
(In trillions of U.S. dollars)
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.The asset allocation of SWFs varies widely depending on their specific objectives. A typical classification of SWFs by objective includes fiscal stabilization funds, national savings funds, pension reserve funds, and reserve investment corporations (IMF, 2007; see also Table 2.23 in Annex 2.3). Equities constitute a significant proportion of the holdings in national savings funds, pension reserve funds, and reserve investment corporations, and those SWFs are likely to have investment objectives similar to private investors. Stabilization funds tend to avoid riskier assets and focus instead on fixed income and cash. Still, specific factors—including the age of the SWF, its investment horizon, its funding source, and varying expectations of the relative performance of asset classes—lead to differences in asset allocations even among SWFs with similar objectives (Figure 2.7).
Selected Sovereign Wealth Funds: Asset Allocation by Type of Fund, December 2010
(In percent)
Sources: Sovereign wealth fund websites: and IMF staff estimates.Note: Data for China, December 2009. For Australia, excluding Telstra: for Ireland, excluding directed investments.1Economic and Social Stabilization Fund.2Norway’s Government Pension Fund has also been classified as a pension reserve fund.3Pension Reserve Fund.International reserves are held for monetary policy and balance of payments purposes, and therefore reserve managers typically have a much more conservative asset allocation strategy than do SWF managers (Box 2.1). The objectives of reserve managers are traditionally safety, liquidity, and return, in that order (IMF, 2001a). The requirement that reserves be available at short notice and at low cost to meet balance of payments needs and financial stability objectives leads to an allocation that is traditionally dominated by short-term government bonds issued by only a few countries.
However, global foreign exchange reserve holdings (excluding gold) have grown so fast in recent years that their size for many countries now exceeds that needed for balance of payments and monetary purposes. After having expanded almost fourfold between 2000 and 2008, reserve levels declined briefly during the global financial crisis and then rebounded quickly. Today, reserve levels in several emerging and developing economies well exceed levels traditionally considered adequate (IMF, 2011a).
Therefore, an increasing share of reserves could be available for potential investment in less liquid and longer-term risk assets. A new IMF estimate puts core reserves needed for balance of payments purposes in emerging market economies at $3.0-$4.4 trillion, leaving $1.0-$2.3 trillion potentially available to be invested beyond the traditional mandate of reserve managers, in a manner more like that of SWFs.6 Some central banks have facilitated this distinction by splitting their reserves into a “liquidity tranche” and an “investment tranche,” with the latter aiming to generate a higher return over the long run (Borio and others, 2008). To date, taken together, however, these investment tranches are still small, and government bonds remain the dominant asset class in reserves.
Overall, the above analysis of private and public long-term investors suggests the following longer-term trends in asset allocation: (i) global assets are being more widely distributed across countries; (ii) in relative terms, assets are being moved from pension funds and insurance companies in favor of management by investment companies; and (iii) the official sector is becoming increasingly important in global asset allocation through SWFs and managers of international reserves. These trends will be explored in more detail in the sections below.
Determinants of Private Asset Allocation
The Role of Private Asset Managers
Private asset managers play a key role in global asset allocation. The real-money managers on which this chapter places its focus (as distinct from managers of leveraged money, such as hedge funds and carry traders) include private wealth managers, mutual fund managers, insurance fund managers, and pension fund managers. They manage institutional money (such as from pension funds and insurance companies) as well as retail funds and private wealth. They allocate investments to equities, fixed income instruments, and a host of alternative investment classes, such as real estate, commodities, and hedge funds.7
Private fund managers provide a range of services for their real-money investing clients. Beyond offering a range of investment funds with predefined mandates, their services may include: (i) advice to inform clients’ own investment decisions; (ii) fulfilling a broad individual investment mandate for large investors; and (iii) providing “stock picking” services within a more narrowly defined mandate. Thus, their approach to asset allocation ranges from the strategic, or long term, to the tactical, or short term.
Asset Allocation of Reserve Managers
Available data are used to investigate to what extent reserve managers respond to market-based incentives when deciding on the currency composition of international reserves.
The objectives of reserve managers are typically different from those of other investors because reserves are explicitly held for balance of payments or monetary policy purposes. The asset allocation and management of reserves are traditionally driven by safety, liquidity, and return, in that order (IMF, 2001a). Further, trade links and the composition of foreign debt may influence currency preferences of international reserve managers.
Despite these differences in their behavior relative to other investors, reserve managers could nevertheless respond to some of the same incentives that motivate private investors, such as investment returns and measures of risk. For example, in principle, reserve managers can hold their assets in any of several reserve currencies that have deep and liquid exchange markets and that can quickly be converted into a different currency if necessary. Given the dominance of short-term government bonds in reserve managers’ portfolios, short-term interest rate differentials between major reserve currency countries could therefore affect their asset allocation.
Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange Reserves
(In percent)
Source: IMF, Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange Reserves database.Note: The figure displays allocated reserves only. Over the observation period, unallocated reserves have roughly doubled as a share of total reserves, from 23 percent in early 1999 to nearly 45 percent at end-2010.Considering that the currency composition of reserves is equivalent to their country destination, the question of whether reserve managers allocate assets on the same basis as their private sector counterparts can be examined using the IMF’s Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange Reserves (COFER) database. The database contains country-level data on currency composition from the 1960s to the present. The COFER information is submitted by IMF member countries on a confidential and voluntary basis; at present, the database covers 56 percent of total world foreign reserves. The COFER data show that, in the aggregate, the currency composition of reserves changed with the introduction of the euro but has been fairly stable in recent years despite large swings in exchange rates (see figure).
The investigation here uses quarterly data from 1999 to 2010 for 102 countries. The data include a number of the variables used in the main text for the analysis of private mutual fund data; they also include variables to measure the conventional objectives of reserve managers, including debt-to-GDP ratios and export and import propensities. The four dependent variables used here are the shares of total reserves allocated to the four major reserve currencies—the U.S. dollar, the euro, the pound sterling, and the Japanese yen—which constitute more than 90 percent of total reserve holdings for most of the countries in our sample.
The analysis produced the following key results:
-
Reserve managers appear to respond to U.S. interest rates: increases in the U.S. dollar interest rate are associated with a rebalancing away from the euro and toward the dollar (first row of the table).
-
An increase in the volatility of the euro/dollar exchange rate tends to favor the dollar as a reserve currency at the expense of the euro.
-
The shares of the other two main reserve currencies, the pound and the yen, appear to be unaffected by interest rates or exchange rate volatility.
-
Economic growth differentials (which are found to be important for private asset allocation) appear not to be important for the currency composition of international reserves.
-
At the start of the global financial crisis (summer of 2007), there was a drop in the share of the U.S. dollar in international reserves that was not related to the other explanatory variables in the regression.
Regression Results for the Currency Composition of Reserves
Regression Results for the Currency Composition of Reserves
U.S. Dollar Share | Euro Share | Pound Sterling Share | Yen Share | |
---|---|---|---|---|
U.S. policy rate | 0.0048*** | -0.0029** | -0.0008 | 0.0003 |
Euro policy rate | -0.0016 | 0.0026 | -0.0003 | -0.0011 |
U.K. policy rate | -0.0036 | 0.0018 | 0.0011 | 0.0009 |
Japan policy rate | 0.0146 | -0.0112 | -0.0015 | 0.0014 |
Euro-U.S. exchange rate volatility | 0.0109*** | -0.0061** | -0.0008 | 0.0009 |
U.K.-U.S. exchange rate volatility | -0.0058 | 0.0015 | 0.0016 | 0.0002 |
Japan-U.S. exchange rate volatility | 0.0020 | -0.0002 | -0.0008 | 0.0007 |
U.S. GDP forecasts | -0.0006 | -0.0012 | 0.0001 | 0.0003 |
Euro GDP forecasts | 0.0010 | -0.0029 | 0.0002 | -0.0002 |
U.K. GDP forecasts | -0.0012 | 0.0021 | 0.0007 | 0.0001 |
Japan GDP forecasts | 0.0011 | -0.0002 | -0.0003 | 0.0002 |
Crisis dummy 1 | -0.0158** | 0.0013 | 0.0031 | 0.0029 |
Crisis dummy 2 | -0.0046 | -0.0012 | -0.0003 | 0.0043** |
Regression Results for the Currency Composition of Reserves
U.S. Dollar Share | Euro Share | Pound Sterling Share | Yen Share | |
---|---|---|---|---|
U.S. policy rate | 0.0048*** | -0.0029** | -0.0008 | 0.0003 |
Euro policy rate | -0.0016 | 0.0026 | -0.0003 | -0.0011 |
U.K. policy rate | -0.0036 | 0.0018 | 0.0011 | 0.0009 |
Japan policy rate | 0.0146 | -0.0112 | -0.0015 | 0.0014 |
Euro-U.S. exchange rate volatility | 0.0109*** | -0.0061** | -0.0008 | 0.0009 |
U.K.-U.S. exchange rate volatility | -0.0058 | 0.0015 | 0.0016 | 0.0002 |
Japan-U.S. exchange rate volatility | 0.0020 | -0.0002 | -0.0008 | 0.0007 |
U.S. GDP forecasts | -0.0006 | -0.0012 | 0.0001 | 0.0003 |
Euro GDP forecasts | 0.0010 | -0.0029 | 0.0002 | -0.0002 |
U.K. GDP forecasts | -0.0012 | 0.0021 | 0.0007 | 0.0001 |
Japan GDP forecasts | 0.0011 | -0.0002 | -0.0003 | 0.0002 |
Crisis dummy 1 | -0.0158** | 0.0013 | 0.0031 | 0.0029 |
Crisis dummy 2 | -0.0046 | -0.0012 | -0.0003 | 0.0043** |
Many other institutional investors (including those that determine their own strategic asset allocation) use private asset managers to manage all or part of their portfolio. Consequently, the assets under management of private asset managers include a substantial share of those from pension funds and insurance companies and a small but growing proportion of sovereign assets (Table 2.3).
Asset Managers’ Assets under Management: Origin of Funds
(In percent)
Asset Managers’ Assets under Management: Origin of Funds
(In percent)
2006 | 2008 | 2010 | |
---|---|---|---|
Pension funds | 24.6 | 26.2 | 25.8 |
Endowments | 2.4 | 2.4 | 2.4 |
Insurance companies | 15.5 | 17.2 | 18.0 |
Sovereigns | 0.9 | 1.2 | 1.5 |
Retail | 36.2 | 32.9 | 33.0 |
Exchange traded funds | 0.2 | 0.1 | 0.4 |
Banks | 2.9 | 2.7 | 2.7 |
Unspecified | 17.3 | 17.2 | 16.3 |
Asset Managers’ Assets under Management: Origin of Funds
(In percent)
2006 | 2008 | 2010 | |
---|---|---|---|
Pension funds | 24.6 | 26.2 | 25.8 |
Endowments | 2.4 | 2.4 | 2.4 |
Insurance companies | 15.5 | 17.2 | 18.0 |
Sovereigns | 0.9 | 1.2 | 1.5 |
Retail | 36.2 | 32.9 | 33.0 |
Exchange traded funds | 0.2 | 0.1 | 0.4 |
Banks | 2.9 | 2.7 | 2.7 |
Unspecified | 17.3 | 17.2 | 16.3 |
Factors Determining Private Asset Allocation
What determines the longer-term trends in asset allocation revealed by the OECD data, particularly their geographical destination? The OECD data-set itself is less useful for answering that question because of its annual frequency, slower updates, smaller set of origin countries, and lack of information on the destination country for investments. For our empirical investigation, we use a dataset compiled by Emerging Portfolio Fund Research (EPFR). EPFR provides global fund flows and asset allocation data from some 20,000 equity funds and 10,000 bond funds with $14 trillion in total assets. The investors are a mix of retail and institutional investors; EPFR estimates that 70 percent of assets are institutional, mainly from pension funds and insurance companies. It covers funds registered in most major developed market jurisdictions and off-shore domiciles. EPFR samples a subset of funds to give insights into the destination countries for equity and bond investments. Data at a monthly frequency are used below, covering the period from January 2005 to May 2011. EPFR has widened its coverage of fund flows over time, which may raise data consistency issues; the period of study was chosen to minimize these concerns.
Using the EPFR data, this section addresses the following questions: (i) What global and domestic factors have driven the asset allocation of international bond and equity fund investors? and (ii) Has their investment behavior changed fundamentally after the global financial crisis? To capture the truly global picture, a panel regression is estimated covering 50 advanced and emerging market economies for which we have complete and consistent data. The regressions are run separately for equity funds and bond funds, and are estimated for the whole sample and for five geographic groupings separately.8
On the basis of theoretical underpinnings (Annex 2.4), the following factors are used in the regression analysis to explain global asset allocation.
-
Return factors: (i) policy rate differentials of countries relative to the simple G-4 average; and (ii) the one-year-ahead GDP growth forecast from Consensus Economics.
-
Volatility factors: these represent the variance of returns as measured by (i) the volatility of host country expected inflation; (ii) the volatility of GDP growth; and (iii) the volatility of the exchange rate.
-
Risk tolerance: perceptions of risk are (i) country risk, as proxied by the measure of country risk compiled by the International Country Risk Group; and (ii) global risk, as proxied by the Chicago Board Options Exchange Market Volatility Index (VIX).
-
Other variables of interest: (i) an IMF measure of capital controls (both on inflows and outflows);9 (ii) the covariance between country returns and world portfolio returns (to capture the diversification effect); (iii) the covariance between country returns and changes in world portfolio returns (to capture intertemporal hedging demand); and (iv) dummies to account for any structural changes in investor behavior that may have occurred after the global financial crisis.10
The analysis yields the following main results about the drivers of flows into equity and bond funds (Table 2.4):
Summary of Panel Regression Results on Equity and Bond Flows
Summary of Panel Regression Results on Equity and Bond Flows
Non-G-7 | ||||||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Hypothesized | Europe, Middle | Advanced | ||||||||||||
Signs | World | Asia | Latin America | East, and Africa | G-7 Countries | Countries | ||||||||
Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | |
Expected return indicators (first moment) | ||||||||||||||
Policy rate differential (host-G-4 average) | -/+ | + | - | - | - ** | - | - | - | + | - *** | + | - | + *** | + |
GDP growth forecast | + | + | + *** | + *** | + ** | + | + ** | + *** | + ** | + *** | + ** | + *** | + *** | + *** |
Volatility indicators (second moment) | ||||||||||||||
Inflation volatility | - | - | - | - ** | - ** | - ** | + | + | + | - * | - * | - ** | - ** | - ** |
GDP growth volatility | - | - | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | + | - *** | - *** | - *** |
Exchange rate volatility | - | - | - *** | - *** | - ** | - *** | - | - | - *** | - *** | - *** | - ** | - *** | - *** |
Covariance indicators | ||||||||||||||
Return covariance (cross-country) | - | - | - | - *** | + | - *** |
|
- *** | - *** | - *** | + | - *** | + | - *** |
Return covariance (intertemporal) | - | - | - | + | + |
|
- *** | - *** |
|
+ | - * | + | - *** | - |
Risk indicators | ||||||||||||||
Country risk | - | - | - * | - *** | - ** | - *** | - | - | - | - *** | - | - | - | + |
VIX Index | - | - | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** |
Control variables | ||||||||||||||
Capital control index | - | - | - | - *** | - *** | - | + |
|
+ | - | - * | - *** | - | - *** |
Crisis dummy 1 | -/+ | -/+ | - *** | - *** | - ** | - *** | + | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** |
Crisis dummy 2 | -/+ | -/+ | - * | - *** | + | - *** | + *** | - *** | - | - *** | - *** | - | - *** | - ** |
Summary of Panel Regression Results on Equity and Bond Flows
Non-G-7 | ||||||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Hypothesized | Europe, Middle | Advanced | ||||||||||||
Signs | World | Asia | Latin America | East, and Africa | G-7 Countries | Countries | ||||||||
Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | |
Expected return indicators (first moment) | ||||||||||||||
Policy rate differential (host-G-4 average) | -/+ | + | - | - | - ** | - | - | - | + | - *** | + | - | + *** | + |
GDP growth forecast | + | + | + *** | + *** | + ** | + | + ** | + *** | + ** | + *** | + ** | + *** | + *** | + *** |
Volatility indicators (second moment) | ||||||||||||||
Inflation volatility | - | - | - | - ** | - ** | - ** | + | + | + | - * | - * | - ** | - ** | - ** |
GDP growth volatility | - | - | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | + | - *** | - *** | - *** |
Exchange rate volatility | - | - | - *** | - *** | - ** | - *** | - | - | - *** | - *** | - *** | - ** | - *** | - *** |
Covariance indicators | ||||||||||||||
Return covariance (cross-country) | - | - | - | - *** | + | - *** |
|
- *** | - *** | - *** | + | - *** | + | - *** |
Return covariance (intertemporal) | - | - | - | + | + |
|
- *** | - *** |
|
+ | - * | + | - *** | - |
Risk indicators | ||||||||||||||
Country risk | - | - | - * | - *** | - ** | - *** | - | - | - | - *** | - | - | - | + |
VIX Index | - | - | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** |
Control variables | ||||||||||||||
Capital control index | - | - | - | - *** | - *** | - | + |
|
+ | - | - * | - *** | - | - *** |
Crisis dummy 1 | -/+ | -/+ | - *** | - *** | - ** | - *** | + | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** | - *** |
Crisis dummy 2 | -/+ | -/+ | - * | - *** | + | - *** | + *** | - *** | - | - *** | - *** | - | - *** | - ** |
-
Interest rate differentials in most cases have no statistically significant effect on flows into equity and bond funds. These results are generally invariant to using policy rate differentials relative to the G-4 (as used in the baseline regression), nominal policy rates, nominal or real long-term interest rates (for countries where long-term rates are available), nominal or real long-term interest rate differentials relative to the G-4, and lagged policy rate differentials.11 The implications of this finding are discussed further below.
-
Asia (excluding Australia, Japan, New Zealand): China, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand
-
Europe, Middle East, and Africa (EMEA): Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Egypt, Hungary, Nigeria, Poland, Romania, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Slovenia, South Africa, Turkey
-
Latin America: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Venezuela
-
G-7: Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, United Kingdom, United States
-
Non-G-7: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Greece, Ireland, Israel, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland
-
Improving GDP growth prospects in general positively affect flows. Globally, an increase in the forecast GDP growth rate in the investment destination country leads to an increase in bond and equity investments. GDP growth is important for equity investors because higher GDP would lead to higher corporate earnings growth, making equities more attractive. It could also affect bond investors if higher GDP growth reduces credit risk, making bond investments more attractive.
-
A rise in country risk generally reduces flows. The regression analysis confirms that, in many cases, an increase in country risk in emerging markets reduces their attractiveness for equity and bond investors. The effect is not statistically significant in advanced economies, perhaps partly because these showed little variation in country risk until recently.
-
A rise in global risk generally reduces flows. Globally and for all regions, an increase in global risk (proxied by the VIX variable) discourages flows into equities and bonds.
-
Lower return covariance generally leads to increased flows. In many cases, lower covariance of a country’s equities and bonds leads to higher flows into these investments. This is as expected, since an asset that tends to have low covariance to other assets in the portfolio reduces the risk of the overall portfolio.
-
Higher uncertainty tends to reduce flows. Uncertainty about future exchange rates and GDP growth, measured by changes in the volatility of exchange rates and GDP forecasts, are found in general to reduce flows into equities and bonds.
-
Capital control measures show only weak effects. Capital control measures negatively affect bond flows on a global scale but not in most of the regressions for emerging markets. This weak finding may result in part because such controls are usually placed on money market and exchange rate instruments and not on longer-term equity and bond investments, where the interests of real-money investors lie; this is consistent with findings in other IMF studies.12 Also, there is evidence that controls tend to lose effectiveness as market participants find ways to circumvent them, which occurs as long as the return on the controlled transaction exceeds the cost of circumvention.
-
The crisis appears to have had an enduring effect on investor behavior. We find structural breaks in investor behavior after the global financial crisis. After the initial stage of the crisis (June 2007 to August 2008), there was a general slowdown in both equity and bond flows to all regions. However, after the second stage (beginning in September 2008), there was an increase in equity flows to Latin America (although there was no statistically significant effect on Asian equity investments). There is for now no firm evidence that these effects have faded.13
The above findings show the main “pull” and “push” factors for these investors’ asset allocations. The main pull factor is the long-term growth prospects in destination countries, which may be diminished to some extent by rising country risk. The main push factor is the risk appetite of global investors. These factors are robust over the period studied (2005—11).14
The most notable of the above findings is that interest rate differentials do not significantly affect real-money investor flows. Neither bond nor equity flows respond to changes in interest rate differentials, globally and for nearly all regions. This result is not fully in line with previous findings (see, for example, IMF, 2011b).15 A few of the possible explanations are the following:16
-
The result applies only to real-money flows in and out of bond and equity investment funds. Short-term flows, usually seen as more interest sensitive, are less likely to be invested through these funds; leveraged flows (including from the carry trade), which are not captured in these data, may still respond to differentials in policy rates and other interest rates.
-
The EPFR data include bond funds that hold bonds with a wide range of maturities, which respond differently to changes in rates at different points along the yield curve. Therefore, the effect of short-term rates on bond flows, presumably concentrated on short-term bonds, is obscured by possible differing (and perhaps opposing) effects on long-term bonds. The converse appears also to be true, as using long-term rates in the regressions does not change the results. Thus, whereas different interest rates along the yield curve may affect flows into bonds of different maturities, their effect on total flows into bonds of all maturities is not statistically significant in these data.
The finding of this study that interest rate differentials do not affect bond and equity flows should not be extended to capital flows in general, for two reasons. First, flows in and out of bond and equity investments may come out of domestic funds, and to the extent that they do, they would not directly affect capital flows. Second, as noted, capital flows may be dominated by other types of investments, including flows from leveraged investors (such as the carry trade), which this analysis does not cover. Still, for some countries (especially emerging markets, which may have a smaller domestic investor base and are traditionally underweighted in portfolios of international investors), flows in and out of bond and equity funds may to a considerable extent lead to corresponding cross-border flows.17
The Risk of Sudden Reversals
The regressions in the previous section found that a number of variables had significant effects on asset allocation, but the question remains, how economically important are these effects? This is important in the context of the potential for sudden reversals of flows. If there are unexpected changes in the risk or return factors that were found in the regressions to be important for global asset allocation, trends in investment flows may reverse. If these reversing flows are large, they may be disruptive to asset markets, and—to the extent that flows out of bonds and equities also exit the country—they would affect the balance of payments.
The econometric results from the previous section allow an examination of this issue through explicit sensitivity analyses, or “stress tests,” of investment flows to emerging market regions. In these tests, we apply shocks as follows: (i) a negative shock to the one-year-ahead forecast of the GDP growth rate (a drop in growth expectations), (ii) a positive shock to the variances of the growth forecasts (an increase in the uncertainty to the growth outlook), and (iii) a positive shock to the VIX (an increase in global risk). Besides calculating the effects of these three shocks separately, we also calculate (iv) the impact if all three shocks occur simultaneously.18 Case (i) could simulate a number of macroeconomic scenarios, including a convergence of global growth rates through a drop in the expected growth rate in emerging economies (leading to a shift of investments away from emerging markets). The shocks are calibrated using historical data by region and are set equal to two standard deviations of the available time series covering 1996—2011, putting them among the 5 percent most severe during that period.19
The estimated effects of the simulated shocks are sizeable (Table 2.5 and Figure 2.8). The shocks to growth and global risk each result in annualized monthly flows out of equity funds of around 1 percent of GDP in two of the three regions, and the shock to growth uncertainty has even larger effects. For bonds, the shocks are somewhat smaller than for equities—although still sizeable. In a number of cases, the three shocks examined individually are each of roughly the same order of magnitude as the largest monthly flows out of bond and equity funds during the crisis. A combined shock to growth, uncertainty, and global risk would lead to flows out of equity funds of between about 2 and 4 percent, larger than (and in some cases a multiple of) the largest outflows that were experienced during the crisis.
Simulated Effects of Shocks on Regional Flows: Emerging Markets
(Monthly flows in billions of U.S. dollars)
For Asia, the parameter was not significantly different from zero.
Simulated Effects of Shocks on Regional Flows: Emerging Markets
(Monthly flows in billions of U.S. dollars)
Equity Funds | |||
Asia | Latin America | Europe, Middle East, and Africa | |
Simulated Effects | |||
Growth shock | -7.3 | -3.2 | -2.9 |
Growth uncertainty shock | -21.8 | -6.9 | -4.1 |
Global risk shock | -9.1 | -3.6 | -1.2 |
Sum of the above shocks | -38.3 | -13.7 | -8.2 |
Largest Actual, January 2005-May 2011 | |||
Largest net outflows | -11.9 | -4.0 | -4.4 |
(month) | (January 2008) | (February 2011) | (June 2006) |
Largest net inflows | 12.8 | 5.5 | 4.0 |
(month) | (October 2007) | (October 2010) | (January 2006) |
Bond Funds | |||
Asia | Latin America | Europe, Middle East, and Africa | |
Simulated Effects | |||
Growth shock1 | … | -1.0 | -2.6 |
Growth uncertainty shock | -4.5 | -3.6 | -2.0 |
Global risk shock | -0.6 | -0.8 | -1.1 |
Sum of the above shocks | -5.1 | -5.4 | -5.6 |
Largest Actual, January 2005-May 2011 | |||
Largest net outflows | -1.9 | -3.3 | -2.6 |
(month) | (October 2008) | (October 2008) | (October 2008) |
Largest net inflows | 2.4 | 2.7 | 2.3 |
(month) | (April 2010) | (October 2010) | (October 2010) |
For Asia, the parameter was not significantly different from zero.
Simulated Effects of Shocks on Regional Flows: Emerging Markets
(Monthly flows in billions of U.S. dollars)
Equity Funds | |||
Asia | Latin America | Europe, Middle East, and Africa | |
Simulated Effects | |||
Growth shock | -7.3 | -3.2 | -2.9 |
Growth uncertainty shock | -21.8 | -6.9 | -4.1 |
Global risk shock | -9.1 | -3.6 | -1.2 |
Sum of the above shocks | -38.3 | -13.7 | -8.2 |
Largest Actual, January 2005-May 2011 | |||
Largest net outflows | -11.9 | -4.0 | -4.4 |
(month) | (January 2008) | (February 2011) | (June 2006) |
Largest net inflows | 12.8 | 5.5 | 4.0 |
(month) | (October 2007) | (October 2010) | (January 2006) |
Bond Funds | |||
Asia | Latin America | Europe, Middle East, and Africa | |
Simulated Effects | |||
Growth shock1 | … | -1.0 | -2.6 |
Growth uncertainty shock | -4.5 | -3.6 | -2.0 |
Global risk shock | -0.6 | -0.8 | -1.1 |
Sum of the above shocks | -5.1 | -5.4 | -5.6 |
Largest Actual, January 2005-May 2011 | |||
Largest net outflows | -1.9 | -3.3 | -2.6 |
(month) | (October 2008) | (October 2008) | (October 2008) |
Largest net inflows | 2.4 | 2.7 | 2.3 |
(month) | (April 2010) | (October 2010) | (October 2010) |
For Asia, the parameter was not significantly different from zero.
Simulated Effects of Shocks on Regional Flows: Emerging Markets
(In percent, annualized flows relative to nominal GDP in 2010)
Sources: EPFR; and IMF staff estimates.Note: For explanation and details, see Table 2.5.1 For Asia, the parameter was not significantly different from zero.Effects of the Crisis
The empirical results show that investors’ asset allocation behavior changed at the time of the crisis. The dummies included in the regressions to capture the effects of the crisis show that globally, and for most regions separately, investors changed their behavior toward equities and bonds in a way not captured by the regular drivers (that is, the other independent variables in the regression). This “crisis effect” began, first, at the onset of the crisis, in mid-2007, and continued around the time of the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy, in September 2008. These were statistically significant changes in behavior, but were they large enough to matter? A useful metric is the Z-score, which relates the size of the change in asset allocation at the time of the crisis to shocks that would normally have been experienced before the crisis.20 Under the assumption of a normal distribution for shocks to investment flows, a Z-score of about 2 indicates that the shock would be classified as among the 5 percent most severe.
The Z-scores indicate that the crisis effect was quite large for bonds and advanced economy equities (Table 2.6). For bonds, the Z-score was in many cases close to or greater than 2, so that the outflows from bond funds during the crisis were among the 5 percent most severe compared to the precrisis period. For equities, there is a distinction between emerging markets and advanced markets. In emerging markets, although the coefficients for the first dummy (June 2007—August 2008) were generally significantly negative, the effects were small (i.e., in line with usual volatility in the precrisis period). In addition, the coefficients on the second crisis dummy (beginning in September 2008) were not significantly different from zero, except for Latin America, where the coefficient was positive and significant. In these cases, the low Z-scores imply that investors in emerging market equities continued during and after the crisis to let themselves be guided by the established drivers of asset allocation. Not so in advanced markets, where the “crisis” effect on equity funds was large, with Z-scores around 2, meaning that the crisis-induced outflows from equity funds in advanced markets were among the 5 percent most severe compared to the precrisis period.
Evaluating the Economic Significance of Crisis Indicator Coefficients
Evaluating the Economic Significance of Crisis Indicator Coefficients
Europe, Middle East, and | Non-G-7 Advanced | |||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
World | Asia | Latin America | Africa | G-7 Countries | Countries | |||||||
Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | |
Crisis dummy 1 | -0.723*** | -2.388*** | -0.516** | -2.216*** | 0.205 | -2.758*** | -0.617*** | -2.536*** | -0.848*** | -1.602*** | -1.023*** | -2.309*** |
(-7.155) | (-16.002) | (-2.375) | (-8.895) | (0.927) | (-6.505) | (-3.102) | (-6.603) | (-4.152) | (-4.147) | (-13.087) | (-9.220) | |
Crisis dummy 2 | -0.513* | -2.308*** | 0.327 | -3.597*** | 1.033*** | -4.119*** | -1.285 | -3.632*** | -0.823*** | -0.203 | -0.741*** | -0.906** |
(-1.914) | (-6.899) | (0.843) | (-7.363) | (5.464) | (-6.103) | (-1.104) | (-5.847) | (-3.295) | (-0.391) | (-8.102) | (-2.079) | |
Precrisis mean | 0.61 | 1.03 | 0.83 | 1.16 | 0.95 | 1.65 | 0.45 | 1.32 | 0.38 | 0.34 | 0.58 | 0.65 |
Precrisis standard deviation | 1.71 | 1.74 | 1.41 | 1.72 | 2.43 | 1.34 | 2.52 | 2.36 | 0.61 | 1.14 | 0.67 | 1.13 |
Z-score for crisis period 1 | -0.78 | -1.97 | -0.96 | -1.96 | … | -3.30 | -0.43 | -1.64 | -2.00 | -1.70 | -2.40 | -2.63 |
Z-score for crisis period 2 | … | -1.92 | … | -2.76 | 0.04 | -4.32 | … | -2.10 | -1.96 | … | -1.98 | -1.38 |
Evaluating the Economic Significance of Crisis Indicator Coefficients
Europe, Middle East, and | Non-G-7 Advanced | |||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
World | Asia | Latin America | Africa | G-7 Countries | Countries | |||||||
Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | |
Crisis dummy 1 | -0.723*** | -2.388*** | -0.516** | -2.216*** | 0.205 | -2.758*** | -0.617*** | -2.536*** | -0.848*** | -1.602*** | -1.023*** | -2.309*** |
(-7.155) | (-16.002) | (-2.375) | (-8.895) | (0.927) | (-6.505) | (-3.102) | (-6.603) | (-4.152) | (-4.147) | (-13.087) | (-9.220) | |
Crisis dummy 2 | -0.513* | -2.308*** | 0.327 | -3.597*** | 1.033*** | -4.119*** | -1.285 | -3.632*** | -0.823*** | -0.203 | -0.741*** | -0.906** |
(-1.914) | (-6.899) | (0.843) | (-7.363) | (5.464) | (-6.103) | (-1.104) | (-5.847) | (-3.295) | (-0.391) | (-8.102) | (-2.079) | |
Precrisis mean | 0.61 | 1.03 | 0.83 | 1.16 | 0.95 | 1.65 | 0.45 | 1.32 | 0.38 | 0.34 | 0.58 | 0.65 |
Precrisis standard deviation | 1.71 | 1.74 | 1.41 | 1.72 | 2.43 | 1.34 | 2.52 | 2.36 | 0.61 | 1.14 | 0.67 | 1.13 |
Z-score for crisis period 1 | -0.78 | -1.97 | -0.96 | -1.96 | … | -3.30 | -0.43 | -1.64 | -2.00 | -1.70 | -2.40 | -2.63 |
Z-score for crisis period 2 | … | -1.92 | … | -2.76 | 0.04 | -4.32 | … | -2.10 | -1.96 | … | -1.98 | -1.38 |
How has the crisis changed investors’ attitude toward asset allocation—what underlies the structural shifts we found in our analysis? The IMF recently conducted a Survey on Global Asset Allocation of 122 of the largest asset management companies and pension funds and plan sponsors, which collectively had about $20 trillion under management (Annex 2.2). The questions covered subjects such as the trends in total assets, geographical distribution of assets, shifts between asset classes, use of derivatives, the effects of the low interest rate environment, and the outlook for risks and returns. Combining the results of the survey with views gathered from discussions with asset managers offers insights into a number of crisis-related developments in the asset allocation of institutional investors.
The traditional (so-called mean-variance) approach toward a diversified risk-minimizing, return-maximizing portfolio of mainly traditional asset classes is viewed as having been unable to avoid losses during the crisis. As correlations between most traditional asset classes rose toward 1, the benefits of diversification diminished greatly, and most investment strategies suffered large losses. Investors are now looking for other strategies, including those that rely on underlying risk factors rather than directly on asset classes for asset allocation decisions (Box 2.2).
However, no consensus on a preferred alternative allocation approach has emerged, and many real-money investors continue to use their traditional approach. Still, investors are planning to add other investment classes to help diversify their portfolios, attributing their lack of diversification in the crisis to their narrow set of investments and short time horizon. These real-money investors (including pension funds and insurance companies) are now more inclined to request asset allocation advice from professional asset managers, and investors’ investment mandates are allowing more discretion around strategic allocations.
The precrisis trend toward improved risk management for asset allocation has clearly accelerated recently. Asset managers are paying closer attention to the market risk and credit risk of their portfolios, the value of the positions taken by their traders, and the procedures for countering excessive risks. For their part, investors are paying more attention to the risk management capabilities of their asset managers and are asking for more detailed attribution analysis (the contribution of various factors to losses or gains relative to the benchmark indices). Some investors are also more conscious of tail risk events (those with a low probability but a high impact) and the imprecision with which risks are measured. They are looking for more protection against tail risks, although such protection is difficult to engineer and can be costly. Many investors are avidly interested in it, but so far only a few are willing to pay for it.
Investors have become much more sensitized to the credit risk of sovereign issuers and are discriminating within this previously much more homogeneous asset class. This is particularly true for sovereigns in Europe, and especially in the euro area. Most private and institutional real-money investors exited the sovereign debt markets of the euro area countries seen to have the weakest fundamentals soon after the onset of the sovereign debt crisis, although they continue to be concerned about the implications of the crisis through cross-country and financial institution spillovers for their other investments. At the same time, within the context of improved risk-management systems, some investors (mainly insurers and pension funds) have chosen to hold more emerging market sovereign debt that offers better returns, including the prospect of currency appreciation. Other investors (for example, reserve managers) saw a reinforcement of the practice of holding only the highest quality sovereigns.
Investors with a longer horizon appear to have become so sensitive to liquidity risk that they do not want to take on their traditional role of providing market liquidity. Having suffered losses from forced sales during the crisis, many managers of retail mutual funds feel a need to keep them fairly liquid to guard against fire sales. Even long-term real-money investors, who should be able to capture a significant liquidity premium—that is, hold illiquid assets that earn a higher return because of their illiquidity—are hesitant to hold such assets. As noted below, this tendency is also aggravated by solvency regulations and accounting standards.
The crisis has also spurred a “back to basics” approach that seeks a better understanding of the risks involved with derivatives and other hedging instruments. Investors are requesting more information about counterparty risks, and some have limited their asset managers to the use of specific lists of acceptable counterparties. Use of assets as collateral is also being monitored and restricted. Derivatives that are traded or cleared through centralized counterparties are also viewed more favorably, as are more standardized over-the-counter contracts such as currency forwards and swaps. Many of these trends mean that hedging has become more expensive—although most institutional investors are willing to pay for this protection (see Table 2.20, in Annex 2.2).
A New Asset Allocation Framework Using Risk Factors
Some institutional investors are using a new method of asset allocation, described here.
Asset allocation based on risk factors is gaining recognition among institutional investors. After the financial crisis, some institutional investors started to group investments on the basis of their risk and return profiles rather than according to traditional asset classes such as equities, bonds, and alternative assets. By doing so, asset managers say they are seeking to better understand the risks they are taking and therefore to better manage portfolio risk.
One case in point is the “new alternative asset classification” of the California Public Employees’ Retirement System (CalPERS), which became effective in July 2011. The new asset classification consists of five categories—income, growth, real, inflation-linked, and liquidity (see first table). Compared with the traditional classification, this approach provides more information about the risk exposures of the pension fund. The new classification has not immediately changed the overall asset allocation except that the target share of real estate in the portfolio is 3 percentage points higher, cash 2 percentage points higher, and fixed income assets 4 percentage points lower.
Another case of note is that of the Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation, which in 2009 moved away from traditional asset classifications to group its investments by their risk and return profiles (see second table). The fund did not change the long-term target of achieving a 5 percent real rate of return on the assets in which the fund invests, but it judged that the new classification could help it better understand the risk profile of its portfolio. For example, corporate bonds and stocks are grouped together, given that in adverse economic conditions they may perform similarly to each other. Under the new framework, the share of emerging Asia in the stock portfolio has risen (see figure). Cash was added as an asset class in the fiscal year 2010 allocation so that during periods of market turmoil the fund could avoid the need to sell other assets at fire sale prices to meet expected liquidity needs, especially the annual dividend payment.
CalPERS Alternative Asset Classification
CalPERS Alternative Asset Classification
Share (In percent) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Risk Class | Translating into Asset Class | Purpose | June 2009 | July 2011 |
Income | Global fixed income | Deliver stable income | 20 | 16 |
Growth | Public and private equity | Positively exposed to economic growth | 63 | 63 |
Real | Real estate, infrastructure, and forestland | Help preserve the real value of the pension fund | 10 | 13 |
Inflation-linked | Commodities and inflation-linked bonds | Provide hedging against inflation | 5 | 4 |
Liquidity | Cash and nominal government bonds | Supply liquidity when needed | 2 | 4 |
CalPERS Alternative Asset Classification
Share (In percent) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Risk Class | Translating into Asset Class | Purpose | June 2009 | July 2011 |
Income | Global fixed income | Deliver stable income | 20 | 16 |
Growth | Public and private equity | Positively exposed to economic growth | 63 | 63 |
Real | Real estate, infrastructure, and forestland | Help preserve the real value of the pension fund | 10 | 13 |
Inflation-linked | Commodities and inflation-linked bonds | Provide hedging against inflation | 5 | 4 |
Liquidity | Cash and nominal government bonds | Supply liquidity when needed | 2 | 4 |
Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation Asset Allocation
Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation Asset Allocation
Risk Class | Translating into Asset Class | Purpose | Share, FY2010 (In percent) |
---|---|---|---|
Cash | Short-term liquid investments | Meet expected liabilities and manage liquidity needs | 2 |
Interest rates | U.S. government bonds and international government bonds of other advanced economies | Provide insurance against severe equity market corrections | 6 |
Company exposure | U.S. and non-U.S. stocks, corporate investment-grade and high-yield bonds, bank loans and private equity | Benefit in times of growth | 53 |
Real assets | Real estate, infrastructure, and Treasury inflation protected securities | Protect the fund’s real value over time | 18 |
Special opportunities | Absolute return, real return mandate, distressed debt, structured credit, and other strategies as they arise | Take advantage of perceived market opportunities | 21 |
Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation Asset Allocation
Risk Class | Translating into Asset Class | Purpose | Share, FY2010 (In percent) |
---|---|---|---|
Cash | Short-term liquid investments | Meet expected liabilities and manage liquidity needs | 2 |
Interest rates | U.S. government bonds and international government bonds of other advanced economies | Provide insurance against severe equity market corrections | 6 |
Company exposure | U.S. and non-U.S. stocks, corporate investment-grade and high-yield bonds, bank loans and private equity | Benefit in times of growth | 53 |
Real assets | Real estate, infrastructure, and Treasury inflation protected securities | Protect the fund’s real value over time | 18 |
Special opportunities | Absolute return, real return mandate, distressed debt, structured credit, and other strategies as they arise | Take advantage of perceived market opportunities | 21 |
Alaska Permanent Fund: Regional Asset Allocation
(In percent)
Source: Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation.1Excluding Japan.2Excluding United States.Despite expectations that the low interest rate environment will be prolonged (Table 2.7), investors are reluctant to acquire more risky assets to increase yield.21 Given their fixed liabilities, pension funds and insurance companies are feeling the pressure most, as many are still using high expected return targets that cannot be met without taking on higher-risk assets (see Box 2.3). Still, the IMF survey indicates that only about one-fifth of pension funds surveyed expect higher risk exposure in their portfolios in the next three years (see Table 2.18, in Annex 2.2). In addition, survey respondents indicate that the most important factor in cross-border investment decisions is not the “search for yield,” which comes third after diversification and growth prospects (Table 2.8).
Expected Period before Policy Rate Rise
(In percent of respondents)
Expected Period before Policy Rate Rise
(In percent of respondents)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |
---|---|---|
In 1 year | 0.0 | 0.0 |
In 2 years | 14.1 | 12.2 |
In 3 years | 50.0 | 55.1 |
In 5 years | 20.3 | 18.4 |
Beyond 5 years | 15.6 | 14.3 |
Expected Period before Policy Rate Rise
(In percent of respondents)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |
---|---|---|
In 1 year | 0.0 | 0.0 |
In 2 years | 14.1 | 12.2 |
In 3 years | 50.0 | 55.1 |
In 5 years | 20.3 | 18.4 |
Beyond 5 years | 15.6 | 14.3 |
Top Five Factors Considered in Cross-Border Investment since End-2006
(Ranked by scores)
Top Five Factors Considered in Cross-Border Investment since End-2006
(Ranked by scores)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Rank | Factors | Score | Factors | Score |
1 | Diversification | 115 | Diversification | 106 |
2 | Longer-term growth prospects | 113 | Longer-term growth prospects | 100 |
3 | Search for yield | 93 | Search for yield | 40 |
4 | Sovereign or country risk | 60 | Range of investments available | 33 |
5 | Market liquidity | 58 | Volatility | 32 |
Top Five Factors Considered in Cross-Border Investment since End-2006
(Ranked by scores)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Rank | Factors | Score | Factors | Score |
1 | Diversification | 115 | Diversification | 106 |
2 | Longer-term growth prospects | 113 | Longer-term growth prospects | 100 |
3 | Search for yield | 93 | Search for yield | 40 |
4 | Sovereign or country risk | 60 | Range of investments available | 33 |
5 | Market liquidity | 58 | Volatility | 32 |
Investing in emerging markets is seen as potentially increasing portfolio returns without taking on excessive risk. A number of factors contribute to this view, including (i) underweighting of emerging markets in most portfolios (although exposure was already increasing before the crisis), so that emerging market assets can help diversify portfolios (see Table 2.9); (ii) low returns and increasing risk in advanced economies; (iii) a favorable view of the liquidity available in most large emerging markets; and (iv) an improvement in economic outcomes and a decline in policy risk in emerging markets.
Regional Allocation
(In percent)
Regional Allocation
(In percent)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | |||||
2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | |
Own country of domicile | 61.0 | 60.1 | 47.5 | 44.8 | 78.1 | 75.7 | 55.5 | 50.3 |
East Asia/Pacific | 3.4 | 3.6 | 8.5 | 9.0 | 1.8 | 2.4 | 8.6 | 10.1 |
Europe | 27.2 | 27.1 | 28.2 | 27.1 | 11.7 | 11.4 | 22.1 | 21.4 |
Latin America | 0.8 | 0.8 | 1.8 | 2.6 | 0.3 | 0.9 | 0.8 | 2.5 |
Middle East/North Africa | 0.1 | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 0.3 | 0.2 | 0.4 |
North America | 7.1 | 7.7 | 11.7 | 13.0 | 7.9 | 8.9 | 11.6 | 13.1 |
South/Central Asia | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.8 | 2.1 | 0.1 | 0.4 | 1.1 | 2.0 |
Sub-Saharan Africa | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.1 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.3 |
Regional Allocation
(In percent)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | |||||
2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | |
Own country of domicile | 61.0 | 60.1 | 47.5 | 44.8 | 78.1 | 75.7 | 55.5 | 50.3 |
East Asia/Pacific | 3.4 | 3.6 | 8.5 | 9.0 | 1.8 | 2.4 | 8.6 | 10.1 |
Europe | 27.2 | 27.1 | 28.2 | 27.1 | 11.7 | 11.4 | 22.1 | 21.4 |
Latin America | 0.8 | 0.8 | 1.8 | 2.6 | 0.3 | 0.9 | 0.8 | 2.5 |
Middle East/North Africa | 0.1 | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 0.3 | 0.2 | 0.4 |
North America | 7.1 | 7.7 | 11.7 | 13.0 | 7.9 | 8.9 | 11.6 | 13.1 |
South/Central Asia | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.8 | 2.1 | 0.1 | 0.4 | 1.1 | 2.0 |
Sub-Saharan Africa | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.1 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.3 |
The trend toward increased investment in emerging market equities was interrupted during the crisis, but is generally seen as ongoing (Figure 2.9). Investors were already adding significantly to their holdings in non-G-7 regions before the crisis, before pulling back in 2008. For bond investments, a pullback from all non-G-7 regions to the G-7 had already taken place before the crisis, and the trend toward further diversification is yet to resume fully: today, the non-G-7 share for bonds remains well below its peak in early 2006. However, since the crisis, diversification into the other regions has resumed for equity investments, which are more diversified today than they were before 2008.
The Low Interest Rate Environment and Pension Funds
A protracted period of low interest rates has significant negative effects on the funding status of defined-benefit pension plans and could thus eventually have a financial impact on plan sponsors and beneficiaries.
One measure of the funding status, or solvency, of a defined-benefit (DB) pension plan is the ratio of the current market value of plan assets to its obligations. The obligations are the plan’s actuarial liabilities, representing the present discounted value of all future retirement benefits earned to date. If the ratio is less than 1, the plan is underfunded.1
Declines in interest rates affect the asset and liability sides of a pension plan, as follows:
-
They generate capital gains in existing bond holdings and thus increase asset values.2
-
They lower the discount rate used to calculate the net present value of future benefit payments (typically the yield on long-term, high-quality domestic corporate bonds for accounting, and often long-term government bond yields for prudential regulation purposes) and thus increase the plan’s liabilities.
Hence, all other things equal, the net effect of changes in interest rates on the funding ratio depends on the maturity mismatch between assets and liabilities. As the liability side of pension plans generally has a longer average duration than the asset side, funding ratios tend to deteriorate with declines in interest rates.3
In general, declines in long-term interest rates worsen the funding ratio significantly, as illustratively shown in the following sensitivity analysis based on data from the United Kingdom (starting from a base of 100 for both assets and liabilities): a mere 0.1 percentage point decline in the discount rate increases pension liabilities by 2 percent while having only a negligible effect on the asset side (see shaded cells in the table, top panel). A similar effect on the funding ratio would result from a much larger—5 percent—decline in stock prices (shaded cells, bottom panel).
Declines in interest rates also have an income effect: as the higher-yielding bonds mature, they will be replaced with those having a lower yield.
In many major economies, the long-term decline in interest rates and improving life expectancy (the liability effect) have increased liabilities much faster than assets and thus have put downward pressure on funding ratios. Short-term fluctuations correlate with equity price swings (the asset effect), as witnessed by the sharp drop in pension assets in 2008 and subsequent rebound in 2009 (see first figure).
Impact of Changes in Gilt Yields on U.K. Defined-Benefit Pension Assets and Liabilities from a Base of 100
Impact of Changes in Gilt Yields on U.K. Defined-Benefit Pension Assets and Liabilities from a Base of 100
-0.3% | -0.2% | -0.1% | Base | +0.1% | +0.2% | +0.3% | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
On assets (A) | 101 | 101 | 100 | 100 | 100 | 99 | 99 |
On liabilities (B) | 105 | 103 | 102 | 100 | 98 | 97 | 95 |
A minus B | -4 | -2 | -2 | 0 | 2 | 2 | 4 |
For comparison: impact of changes in equity prices on defined-benefit pension assets from a base of 100 | |||||||
-7.5% | -5.0% | -2.5% | Base | +2.5% | +5.0% | +7.5% | |
On assets | 96 | 98 | 99 | 100 | 101 | 102 | 104 |
Impact of Changes in Gilt Yields on U.K. Defined-Benefit Pension Assets and Liabilities from a Base of 100
-0.3% | -0.2% | -0.1% | Base | +0.1% | +0.2% | +0.3% | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
On assets (A) | 101 | 101 | 100 | 100 | 100 | 99 | 99 |
On liabilities (B) | 105 | 103 | 102 | 100 | 98 | 97 | 95 |
A minus B | -4 | -2 | -2 | 0 | 2 | 2 | 4 |
For comparison: impact of changes in equity prices on defined-benefit pension assets from a base of 100 | |||||||
-7.5% | -5.0% | -2.5% | Base | +2.5% | +5.0% | +7.5% | |
On assets | 96 | 98 | 99 | 100 | 101 | 102 | 104 |
Defined-Benefit Pension Funds: Assets, Liabilities, and Funding Indicator for Major Economies1
(1998=100)
Sources: TheCityUK; and Towers Watson.1 Australia, Canada, France, Germany, Hong Kong SAR, Ireland, Japan, the Netherlands, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.Assets divided by liabilities.Ten-Year Government Bond Yields
(In percent)
Source: Bloomberg L.P.Countries differ considerably in the stringency of their funding regulations for pension plans and hence in how much time and flexibility are allowed for addressing the underfunding of plans. The differences partly reflect how pension plans are linked financially to their sponsoring employers.4 Where pension funds are more detached from sponsoring employers, such as in the Netherlands, relatively higher minimum funding ratios are required, as are quicker recovery plans in the event of underfunding. Where benefits are underwritten by sponsoring employers, such as in Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States, longer recovery plans are allowed, but unresolved underfunding would eventually require increased contributions from employers.
Against this background, pension funds may change their asset allocation to hedge against market risks or to augment yields to improve their funding status. The sponsors may also shift their financial risks to the beneficiaries by closing the DB plan to new employees, or by moving existing staff (if possible) to a defined contribution scheme.
In an environment of persistently low interest rates, plan sponsors commonly hedge interest rate risk on the liability side by increasing asset allocations to bonds and extending their duration, thus decreasing the extent of the maturity mismatch. However, although this strategy helps mitigate adverse effects of further declines in interest rates, it does not necessarily improve an already worsened funding status.
To address worsened funding ratios, long-term institutional investors may potentially be more inclined to “search for yield.” That could mean a shift from bonds to equities and a likely increase in the volatility of the value of the portfolio. However, flow-of-funds data for pension funds and insurance companies in the G-4 economies over the past decade show instead a gradual but continuous increase in the bond holding ratio, after accounting for the effects of valuation changes (see second figure).5 In other words, rather than trying to enhance yields at the expense of having more volatility risk on the asset side, these investors as a whole seem to have been putting more emphasis on duration matching to address the effects of low interest rates on their liabilities.
Pension Funds and Insurance Companies: Asset Allocation for Selected Advanced Economies
(In percent of total financial assets, adjusted for effects of valuation changes)
Sources: National flow-of-funds data; and IMF staff estimates.Note: For the United States and the euro area, the bond and equity holdings consist of both domestic and foreign securities. Government bonds for the United States include Treasury bills.Although emerging market assets are becoming more acceptable as a standard class to add to portfolios, a concern remains about their liquidity during a crisis and about other country risks. These concerns are likely to be more of an issue in the fixed income markets than in equities, although some stocks became illiquid in the crisis and could do so again. However, the trend toward better risk management also prevails in this case, with many investors discriminating between different emerging markets rather than seeing them as a homogeneous asset class. Nonetheless, investors retain some home or regional bias.
Besides emerging markets, alternative assets are drawing interest, but actual allocations currently show little evidence of a significant shift toward them (Table 2.10). The diversification offered by traditional asset classes provided limited protection during the financial crisis. In isolation, alternative assets (commodities, real estate, private equity, infrastructure, and hedge funds) may well carry higher risks, but their low (or even negative) correlation with other assets means that they may actually lower the risk in the overall portfolio, and the more sophisticated investors understand this mechanism. Still, the low liquidity of some of the alternative asset types is a concern, as investors may not be able to exit easily in times of turmoil.
Asset Allocation by Asset Class
(In percent)
Asset Allocation by Asset Class
(In percent)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
2006 | 2008 | 2010 | 2006 | 2008 | 2010 | |
Traditional asset classes | ||||||
Cash | 6.9 | 8.9 | 6.5 | 1.7 | 2.1 | 2.4 |
Equities | 39.7 | 31.2 | 34.5 | 51.4 | 40.3 | 44.9 |
Bonds | 41.9 | 46.6 | 46.7 | 36.0 | 41.9 | 37.1 |
Subtotal | 88.5 | 86.7 | 87.7 | 89.1 | 84.3 | 84.4 |
Alternative asset classes | ||||||
Real estate | 4.4 | 5.2 | 4.7 | 5.2 | 6.7 | 5.6 |
Hedge funds | 1.7 | 2.1 | 1.4 | 1.5 | 2.2 | 2.2 |
Private equity | 0.5 | 0.6 | 0.6 | 2.7 | 4.5 | 4.6 |
Commodities | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.4 | 0.6 | 1.0 |
Other | 4.8 | 5.4 | 5.5 | 1.0 | 1.7 | 2.1 |
Subtotal | 11.5 | 13.3 | 12.3 | 10.9 | 15.7 | 15.6 |
Asset Allocation by Asset Class
(In percent)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
2006 | 2008 | 2010 | 2006 | 2008 | 2010 | |
Traditional asset classes | ||||||
Cash | 6.9 | 8.9 | 6.5 | 1.7 | 2.1 | 2.4 |
Equities | 39.7 | 31.2 | 34.5 | 51.4 | 40.3 | 44.9 |
Bonds | 41.9 | 46.6 | 46.7 | 36.0 | 41.9 | 37.1 |
Subtotal | 88.5 | 86.7 | 87.7 | 89.1 | 84.3 | 84.4 |
Alternative asset classes | ||||||
Real estate | 4.4 | 5.2 | 4.7 | 5.2 | 6.7 | 5.6 |
Hedge funds | 1.7 | 2.1 | 1.4 | 1.5 | 2.2 | 2.2 |
Private equity | 0.5 | 0.6 | 0.6 | 2.7 | 4.5 | 4.6 |
Commodities | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.4 | 0.6 | 1.0 |
Other | 4.8 | 5.4 | 5.5 | 1.0 | 1.7 | 2.1 |
Subtotal | 11.5 | 13.3 | 12.3 | 10.9 | 15.7 | 15.6 |
Effects of New Regulatory Initiatives
Regulation geared toward institutional investors may have significant effects on their asset allocation. Previous studies have suggested a possible shift in asset allocation to bonds from equity as a consequence of a shift toward fair value accounting of pension schemes and related changes in solvency regulations in advanced economies in the mid-2000s (see OECD, 2005; Boeri and others, 2006; and Committee on the Global Financial System, 2007, 2011). Recent other examples of such regulations are the Basel III proposals for banks by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision and the Solvency II proposals governing capital requirements for insurance companies in the European Economic Area. Both of these initiatives take a risk-based approach to minimum capital requirements.
In discussions as background for this chapter, some insurance companies indicated that Solvency II would encourage investment strategies opposite to those needed if their industry is to return to financial health. They noted that the risk-based capital charges imposed by Solvency II would discourage equity investments in favor of high-quality fixed-income securities, reducing returns and the flow of funds into new equity and riskier longer-term investments. This was seen as potentially detrimental to the interest of the holders of insurance products, to the extent that this effect is not entirely offset by reducing the portfolio risk for insurance company assets. Although Basel III has less direct effects on real-money investors, there are indirect effects in that these investors will be less inclined to invest in bank debt or equity, which will likely have lower returns due to higher capital and liquidity buffers.
Implementation of Solvency II and other regulatory incentives that aim to make individual institutions “safer” could also affect financial stability in a number of possible ways:
-
First, some insurance companies fear that they will have insufficient time to prepare for prescribed changes because of uncertainty about the final content of the regulations. Given the likely long phase-in period, however, the risk of a rush to adjust asset allocations, with potential disruptive effects to asset markets, is probably small, but given the large assets under management in European insurance companies, it cannot be completely discounted.
-
Second, pushing insurance companies toward higher-quality fixed-income securities and away from less liquid equities makes them more like other short-term investors, a development reinforced by mark-to-market accounting rules.22 This lessens the diversity of investor types and raises the risk of similar responses to shocks and could therefore carry financial stability concerns.
-
Third, the pressure to enhance yields in the low interest rate environment is growing, and the requirement for insurance companies to hold the bulk of their assets in safe, low-yielding assets may push them to become more aggressive with the remainder of their portfolio and may shorten their investment perspective.23 Their investment behavior regarding this risky part of their portfolio might well become more volatile, leading to a risk of sudden reversals in some less liquid markets, including in emerging economies.
Conclusions and Policy Implications
The analysis in this chapter suggests that asset allocation by long-term real-money investors is driven most strongly by positive growth prospects and falling risks in the recipient countries; interest rate differentials play a lesser role. For flows into both equities and bonds, investors are focused mostly on growth potential when choosing investment destination countries, although country risk has a clear negative effect. As expected, a decline in global risk aversion increases investment in equities and bonds to all emerging market regions. Investment flows from real-money investors into bonds and equities are generally not significantly affected by differentials in interest rates. Care should be taken, however, not to extend this result to capital flows in general, which have a number of components not covered in this analysis. In particular, the investment flows of short-term leveraged investors (such as those from the carry trade)—which this chapter does not examine—might still be affected by changes in policy rates and other interest rates in the economy.
The implications of these findings for policymakers are that asset-allocation decisions are grounded mostly in the responsiveness and consistency of economic policy, not in specific policy actions. Policies geared toward macroeconomic stability and low inflation will enhance growth, reduce volatility in macroeconomic outcomes, and lower country risk, which the regression analysis in this chapter shows affects real-money investor flows positively. Yet the additional investment flows attracted by macroeconomic stability and strong growth prospects could have potentially destabilizing effects over the longer run, including asset price bubbles and credit booms. Monitoring and possible management of these flows should therefore be part of the larger framework of growth-enhancing policies.24
While the trend toward longer-term investment in emerging markets is likely to continue, shocks to growth prospects or other drivers of private investment could lead to large investment reversals. The structural trend of investing in emerging market assets accelerated following the crisis, driven mostly by relatively good economic and investment outcomes. Still, the sensitivity analysis in this chapter showed that a negative shock to growth prospects in emerging markets could potentially lead to flows out of emerging market equities and bonds. These flows could reach a scale similar to—or even larger than—the outflows these countries experienced during the financial crisis. Adverse dynamics are possible in such cases: if countries react with policies that are perceived to raise country or policy risk, this would tend to increase the desire for investors to exit. In addition, the reactions of other types of investors (including those that are leveraged—see Chapter 1) would likely compound these investment outflows, or even initiate them.
Policymakers should prepare for the possibility of a pullback from their markets in order to mitigate the risk of potentially disruptive liquidity problems, especially if market depth may not be sufficient to avoid large price swings. Emerging market policymakers should take advantage of periods of macroeconomic and financial stability to reinforce the resilience of their financial systems. Also, they should prepare contingency plans to maintain liquidity in asset markets during periods of market turmoil, perhaps using sovereign asset managers as providers of liquidity as other investors exit, as some did during the crisis (Box 2.4). Coordination between sovereign wealth managers would be important in these situations, to avoid a repeat of what happened during the crisis, when some reserve managers acted procyclically by moving out of unsecured bank deposits.
The global financial crisis changed longer-term asset-allocation strategies, chiefly by making investors more risk conscious and prompting a greater focus on portfolio risk management. The disruption of liquidity during the crisis and the recent sovereign risk concerns have made investors especially mindful of market liquidity risks and the importance of credit risk in sovereign bond markets—even in the most developed economies. There is strong anecdotal evidence that these events have altered asset allocation frameworks in a structural and lasting way. This structural shift can also be seen in the data: the regressions in this chapter show significant downward shifts in investment flows for the full period after the start of the crisis in mid-2007, reflecting an adjustment of portfolio flows to the new assessment of risks. There is no evidence so far that this effect is fading. This may be evidence that risk aversion of institutional investors has fundamentally changed.25
Sovereign Asset Management and the Global Financial Crisis
Sovereign wealth funds were affected by, and responded to, the global financial crisis.
The global financial crisis affected all sovereign wealth funds (SWFs). Those that were more heavily invested in equities suffered especially large losses—in some cases, more than 30 percent—from the sharp downturn in prices of risky assets (see first figure). Key to the subsequent recovery of such funds was their ability and willingness to stay invested in risky assets and “ride out” the financial turmoil. As financial market conditions started to improve in early 2009, that longer-term approach paid off.
Governments used SWF assets during the crisis to support their economic, fiscal, and financial stability objectives. The new functions given to SWFs—some in line with their original mandate, others beyond it—included:
-
Stimulus support: Assets of some SWFs financed stimulus packages to support economic activity.
-
Deficit financing: Assets were drawn upon to finance rising fiscal deficits.
-
Financial stability: Some SWFs were directed to deposit assets in domestic banks as a way to provide liquidity support, while others contributed assets to bank recapitalization. In some cases, SWF assets were earmarked to support deposit insurance schemes or were used to purchase domestic equities to boost markets and investor confidence.
The actions of sovereign wealth managers during the crisis were not always optimal, as some reserve managers acted procyclically by rapidly moving out of bank deposits (see second figure). Surveys, conducted annually by Central Banking Publications, and other studies (Pihlman and van der Hoorn, 2010) confirm that the risk aversion of reserve managers increased and that reserve managers participated in the global flight to quality and liquidity. Those developments were seen most clearly in the flight from unsecured bank deposits: the proportion of total reserves (including gold at market prices) invested in this asset class dropped rapidly from its peak of 17.2 percent in July 2007 to less than 5 percent in June 2010. That large move raised concerns that, by acting procyclically, reserve managers may have inadvertently contributed to the severity of the crisis (Niedermayer, 2009; Pihlman and van der Hoorn, 2010; Mminele, 2011). There have been calls recently to formally address this issue, for example through an update of the IMF’s Guidelines for Foreign Exchange Reserve Management.
Sovereign Wealth Funds: Shares in Equities and Returns, 2008 and 2009
(In percent)
Sources: Sovereign wealth fund websites; and IMF staff calculations.Note: For Australia, excluding Telstra; for Ireland, excluding directed investments; for China, the share of equity as of end-2008.1Pension Reserve Fund.2Economic and Social Stabilization Fund.Instrument Composition of Official Reserves, Including Gold
(In percent)
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics and Data Template on International Reserves and Foreign Currency Liquidity.The asset allocation of SWFs in the aftermath of the crisis—and therefore the extent to which they may take on the risks that may now be avoided by private institutional investors—is subject to contesting influences.
-
Like many private investors, SWFs’ severe losses in the crisis have likely made them more aware of, and perhaps more averse to, various types of risk. In addition, changing mandates that could now include fiscal, economic, and financial stabilization objectives may require assets to be safer or more liquid.
-
By contrast, however, the crisis and postcrisis experience showed sovereign asset managers that (i) additional diversification (including into assets that by themselves may be considered risky) may further reduce portfolio risk, especially in a crisis; and (ii) longer-term strategies, if maintained in times of turmoil, may significantly reduce portfolio damage.
-
In addition, as with private investors, SWFs may be pushed toward riskier investments in part to generate higher returns under a potentially prolonged low interest rate environment.
The postcrisis adjustments in the asset allocations of SWFs show that the balance of these factors is pushing SWFs in the direction of providing more risk capital (see third figure). Like private asset managers, SWF managers have enhanced their efforts to diversify portfolios by increasing investments in equities and alternative assets (with some introducing such investment classes for the first time). These new investments have been financed by cash and, to a lesser extent, fixed income holdings. Also, mirroring private trends, many SWFs have increased investments in emerging markets.1
Sovereign Wealth Funds: Change in Asset Allocation by Type of Fund, December 2007- December 2010
(In percent)
Sources: Sovereign wealth fund websites; and IMF staff calculations.Note: For Trinidad & Tobago, the change is between September 30, 2007 and December 31, 2010; for Australia, the change is between January 31, 2008 and December 31, 2010; for China, the change is between December 31, 2008 and December 31, 2009. For Australia, excluding Telstra; for Ireland, excluding directed investments.1Economic and Social Stabilization Fund.2Norway’s Government Pension Fund, Global is also classified as a pension reserve fund.3Pension Reserve Fund.The low interest rate environment in advanced economies since the crisis has not yet pushed investors into riskier investments to enhance yields but may do so if—as expected—interest rates in advanced economies stay low for an extended period. The results of the IMF Survey on Global Asset Allocation and other information about recent allocations indicate that investors have in general not yet moved into riskier assets to enhance yields.26 Still, the pressure to do so is already strong and growing, especially for those institutional investors that need to earn a minimum absolute return (such as insurance companies that have sold products with minimum guaranteed returns and pension funds that are underfunded). As the low interest rate environment is expected to last for a number of years, such investors will be increasingly compelled to take on more investment risk as their financial situation continues to be unfavorable.
These financial incentives now facing institutional investors may interact with recent regulatory initiatives in a way that carry risks to financial stability. Initiatives like Solvency II and Basel III aim to make individual financial institutions safer, but may make institutional investors more like other short-term investors. As a result, they would be less likely to act as the “deep pockets” of financial markets that support riskier, long-term investment and are willing to hold such illiquid assets through market downturns. This would lessen their traditional role in fostering financial stability. Also, the requirement for insurance companies to hold the bulk of their assets in safe, low-yielding assets may push them to become more aggressive with the remainder of their portfolio to try to enhance portfolio returns. This may lead them to invest more aggressively in (smaller) emerging markets or alternative assets (commodities, real estate, private equity, infrastructure, and hedge funds). Investment returns on this risky part of their portfolio might well appear more variable under mark-to-market accounting rules (despite the improved diversification at the portfolio level over the longer run). Increased variability of returns may make asset allocation more volatile, leading to a risk of sudden reversals that may adversely affect financial stability, especially in less liquid markets.
As heightened risk awareness and regulatory initiatives are pushing private investors to hold “safer” assets, there may be a role for sovereign investors to take on some of the longer-term risks that private investors now avoid. Although the assets of SWFs are less than one-tenth of the total assets of pension funds and insurance companies, their role is likely to expand as sovereign assets grow. Their original purposes should remain intact, but as their assets grow beyond that needed for their original purpose, authorities could consider how their sovereign investment policies and financial markets can benefit from accommodating the supply of long-term investments. Sovereign asset allocation can also help foster longer-term financial stability, including by offsetting potentially destabilizing private investment behavior, especially during crises. That said, the extent to which SWFs and noncore reserves can be invested in longer-term, less liquid assets should be considered within a comprehensive framework for sovereign assets and liabilities management. Such a framework would link the asset allocation of sovereign investment (including its liquidity, duration, and market risks) to its investment objectives, taking into account its explicit or contingent liabilities.
Monitoring of trends in asset allocation is an additional useful tool to identify potential risks to financial stability, but its effective use will require more accurate, comprehensive, and timely data. Changes in asset allocation by investors are at the core of capital flows between institutions, markets, and countries. Direct monitoring of these changes will contribute to a more thorough understanding of the resulting flows and allow policymakers to identify more clearly any emerging risks to financial stability. However, relevant public data (mostly from national flow-of-funds accounts) are scarce, available with sometimes significant delays, and with differing methodologies. Private data are more timely and frequent but cover mostly investment funds and fail to capture most bank and official flows. Effective monitoring requires a major compilation effort to create a truly global dataset of higher frequency (at least quarterly, but preferably monthly) that includes asset allocation by type of investor, source and destination of funds, asset class, and maturity.27
Annex 2.1. Asset Allocation: Theory and Practice1
Markowitz (1952) changed the way both academics and practitioners look at the portfolio selection problem. Markowitz’s mean-variance approach became the basis for modern portfolio theory and the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) as well as for the application of continuous-time mathematics to the portfolio choice problem.
Formally, portfolio shares in the generic mean-variance model represent the solution to the optimization problem
subject to
and other constraints, where w is a column vector of portfolio shares, r is a column vector of expected returns, and Σ is the covariance matrix of returns; w and r are of dimension n x 1; Σ is of dimension n x n; and wmin is the vector of portfolio shares that minimizes the volatility of the portfolio with expected return
Starting in the 1970s, the mean-variance approach became the workhorse of most of those who allocate assets. In applied work using this approach, returns were generally assumed to come from a normal statistical distribution, where the mean and variance are sufficient to completely describe the shape of the distribution. The properties of the normal distribution made it easier to calculate various risk measures and simplified some of the mathematics of the model. At a minimum, it provided a benchmark against which other asset allocation models could be compared.
However, as the mean-variance model became widely adopted for strategic asset allocation, a number of weaknesses to the approach gradually came to the fore.
First, expected returns and the covariance matrix of returns for all assets have to be either estimated or derived from analyst estimates. But investors typically have firm ideas about the returns of only a subset of assets. For another set of assets, they might have less precise ideas, and for the remainder, they might not have formed any idea about expected returns. To avoid having to establish a full set of expected returns, many investors simply used historical returns when other estimates were not available. In the case of fixed income assets, yields were often used as the estimate of expected returns. A significant problem is that historical estimates and yields have proved to be bad indicators of future returns. Similarly, although estimates of the matrix of return covariances were initially deemed fairly stable, recent statistical advances have shown that they are time-varying.2
A second, more fundamental problem appeared in many applications. When correlations between asset returns were high and they had similar volatilities, small changes in expected returns among them generated dramatic changes in the model-based portfolio allocations that were far greater than most users expected and, if implemented, would have imposed potentially large transaction costs. Those cases showed that mean-variance optimization algorithms do not discriminate well among such assets.
Users dealt with these drawbacks mainly by imposing constraints such as limiting certain assets to a much smaller share than the optimization algorithm would suggest. Although such procedures introduced a degree of arbitrariness, they were more in line with the standard practice that combines investment experience with quantitative methods.3
The Black-Litterman (BL) approach seeks to address these issues.4 It derives a vector of implied expected returns from the existing weights of the market portfolio. Those returns become the starting point for further analysis, to which the investor’s own return forecasts and confidence in those forecasts can be added. Further, return forecasts can be formulated on a relative basis (that is, the expected return of asset A is assumed only to be higher than that of asset B) to arrive at the optimal BL asset allocation. In many applications of the BL model, the weights of only those assets for which returns were modified would change appreciably upon recalculation.
Although the BL model alleviates some significant shortcomings of the mean-variance approach, its underlying distributional assumptions still pose particular challenges. These challenges were brought to the fore by ongoing market developments:
-
Many assets—for example, options and credit-dependent bonds and derivatives—have returns that cannot be reasonably approximated by a normal distribution. The nonlinear payoff structures of many instruments (including derivatives) made it progressively harder to justify allocation algorithms based on linear approximations.
-
A number of events focused attention on “tail risks,” which, within the framework of a normal distribution, have an extremely small probability of occurring, but are realized more frequently than predicted by normality (including during the global financial crisis).5 Also, many standard asset return distributions displayed asymmetry, or “skewness.” These observations made the assumption of a normal distribution hard to maintain, and models that incorporate this assumption lead to unexpectedly large losses.
Hence, the global financial crisis weakened investors’ trust in the mean-variance model. However, although advances have been made on the quantitative and statistical fronts, and more reliance is being placed on investment experience, no consensus approach has yet emerged to take the place of the mean-variance model.
Annex 2.2. Results of the IMF Survey on Global Asset Allocation1
In April and May 2011, the IMF asked the approximately 300 largest asset management companies and 200 largest pension funds and plan sponsors in the world to participate in a survey of perceived longer-term trends in global asset allocation.2 A total of 122 firms participated: 68 asset management companies (hereafter, asset managers) and 54 pension funds or plan sponsors (pension funds). Their responses are summarized below. Survey participants are listed at the end of this annex (Table 2.22).
Survey Participants’ Assets under Management
(In billions of U.S. dollars)
Survey Participants’ Assets under Management
(In billions of U.S. dollars)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
2002 | 2006 | 2008 | 2010 | 2002 | 2006 | 2008 | 2010 | |
Assets under management | 6,014 | 13,055 | 12,501 | 16,248 | 1,509 | 2,807 | 2,862 | 3,368 |
Number of respondents | 51 | 63 | 67 | 68 | 52 | 53 | 53 | 54 |
Survey Participants’ Assets under Management
(In billions of U.S. dollars)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
2002 | 2006 | 2008 | 2010 | 2002 | 2006 | 2008 | 2010 | |
Assets under management | 6,014 | 13,055 | 12,501 | 16,248 | 1,509 | 2,807 | 2,862 | 3,368 |
Number of respondents | 51 | 63 | 67 | 68 | 52 | 53 | 53 | 54 |
Asset Managers’ Assets under Management: Origin of Funds
(In percent)
Asset Managers’ Assets under Management: Origin of Funds
(In percent)
2006 | 2008 | 2010 | |
---|---|---|---|
Pension funds | 24.6 | 26.2 | 25.8 |
Endowments | 2.4 | 2.4 | 2.4 |
Insurance companies | 15.5 | 17.2 | 18.0 |
Sovereigns | 0.9 | 1.2 | 1.5 |
Retail | 36.2 | 32.9 | 33.0 |
Exchange traded funds | 0.2 | 0.1 | 0.4 |
Banks | 2.9 | 2.7 | 2.7 |
Unspecified | 17.3 | 17.2 | 16.3 |
Asset Managers’ Assets under Management: Origin of Funds
(In percent)
2006 | 2008 | 2010 | |
---|---|---|---|
Pension funds | 24.6 | 26.2 | 25.8 |
Endowments | 2.4 | 2.4 | 2.4 |
Insurance companies | 15.5 | 17.2 | 18.0 |
Sovereigns | 0.9 | 1.2 | 1.5 |
Retail | 36.2 | 32.9 | 33.0 |
Exchange traded funds | 0.2 | 0.1 | 0.4 |
Banks | 2.9 | 2.7 | 2.7 |
Unspecified | 17.3 | 17.2 | 16.3 |
Asset Allocation by Asset Class
(In percent)
Asset Allocation by Asset Class
(In percent)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
2006 | 2008 | 2010 | 2006 | 2008 | 2010 | |
Traditional asset classes | ||||||
Cash | 6.9 | 8.9 | 6.5 | 1.7 | 2.1 | 2.4 |
Equities | 39.7 | 31.2 | 34.5 | 51.4 | 40.3 | 44.9 |
Bonds | 41.9 | 46.6 | 46.7 | 36.0 | 41.9 | 37.1 |
Subtotal | 88.5 | 86.7 | 87.7 | 89.1 | 84.3 | 84.4 |
Alternative asset classes | ||||||
Real estate | 4.4 | 5.2 | 4.7 | 5.2 | 6.7 | 5.6 |
Hedge funds | 1.7 | 2.1 | 1.4 | 1.5 | 2.2 | 2.2 |
Private equity | 0.5 | 0.6 | 0.6 | 2.7 | 4.5 | 4.6 |
Commodities | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.4 | 0.6 | 1.0 |
Others | 4.8 | 5.4 | 5.5 | 1.0 | 1.7 | 2.1 |
Subtotal | 11.5 | 13.3 | 12.3 | 10.9 | 15.7 | 15.6 |
Asset Allocation by Asset Class
(In percent)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
2006 | 2008 | 2010 | 2006 | 2008 | 2010 | |
Traditional asset classes | ||||||
Cash | 6.9 | 8.9 | 6.5 | 1.7 | 2.1 | 2.4 |
Equities | 39.7 | 31.2 | 34.5 | 51.4 | 40.3 | 44.9 |
Bonds | 41.9 | 46.6 | 46.7 | 36.0 | 41.9 | 37.1 |
Subtotal | 88.5 | 86.7 | 87.7 | 89.1 | 84.3 | 84.4 |
Alternative asset classes | ||||||
Real estate | 4.4 | 5.2 | 4.7 | 5.2 | 6.7 | 5.6 |
Hedge funds | 1.7 | 2.1 | 1.4 | 1.5 | 2.2 | 2.2 |
Private equity | 0.5 | 0.6 | 0.6 | 2.7 | 4.5 | 4.6 |
Commodities | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.4 | 0.6 | 1.0 |
Others | 4.8 | 5.4 | 5.5 | 1.0 | 1.7 | 2.1 |
Subtotal | 11.5 | 13.3 | 12.3 | 10.9 | 15.7 | 15.6 |
Regional Allocation
(In percent)
Regional Allocation
(In percent)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | |||||
2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | |
Own country of domicile | 61.0 | 60.1 | 47.5 | 44.8 | 78.1 | 75.7 | 55.5 | 50.3 |
East Asia/Pacific | 3.4 | 3.6 | 8.5 | 9.0 | 1.8 | 2.4 | 8.6 | 10.1 |
Europe | 27.2 | 27.1 | 28.2 | 27.1 | 11.7 | 11.4 | 22.1 | 21.4 |
Latin America | 0.8 | 0.8 | 1.8 | 2.6 | 0.3 | 0.9 | 0.8 | 2.5 |
Middle East/North Africa | 0.1 | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 0.3 | 0.2 | 0.4 |
North America | 7.1 | 7.7 | 11.7 | 13.0 | 7.9 | 8.9 | 11.6 | 13.1 |
South/Central Asia | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.8 | 2.1 | 0.1 | 0.4 | 1.1 | 2.0 |
Sub-Saharan Africa | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.1 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.3 |
Regional Allocation
(In percent)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | |||||
2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | |
Own country of domicile | 61.0 | 60.1 | 47.5 | 44.8 | 78.1 | 75.7 | 55.5 | 50.3 |
East Asia/Pacific | 3.4 | 3.6 | 8.5 | 9.0 | 1.8 | 2.4 | 8.6 | 10.1 |
Europe | 27.2 | 27.1 | 28.2 | 27.1 | 11.7 | 11.4 | 22.1 | 21.4 |
Latin America | 0.8 | 0.8 | 1.8 | 2.6 | 0.3 | 0.9 | 0.8 | 2.5 |
Middle East/North Africa | 0.1 | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 0.3 | 0.2 | 0.4 |
North America | 7.1 | 7.7 | 11.7 | 13.0 | 7.9 | 8.9 | 11.6 | 13.1 |
South/Central Asia | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.8 | 2.1 | 0.1 | 0.4 | 1.1 | 2.0 |
Sub-Saharan Africa | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.1 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.3 |
Top 10 Investment Destinations
(Ranked by scores)
Top 10 Investment Destinations
(Ranked by scores)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Rank | Country | Score | Country | Score |
1 | United States | 225 | United States | 226 |
2 | United Kingdom | 115 | United Kingdom | 159 |
3 | Germany | 100 | Japan | 112 |
4 | France | 97 | Germany | 52 |
5 | Japan | 77 | France | 48 |
6 | Italy | 52 | Canada | 37 |
7 | Canada | 42 | Switzerland | 27 |
8 | Switzerland | 28 | Australia | 15 |
9 | Australia | 23 | Sweden | 14 |
10 | Brazil | 22 | Denmark | 10 |
Top 10 Investment Destinations
(Ranked by scores)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Rank | Country | Score | Country | Score |
1 | United States | 225 | United States | 226 |
2 | United Kingdom | 115 | United Kingdom | 159 |
3 | Germany | 100 | Japan | 112 |
4 | France | 97 | Germany | 52 |
5 | Japan | 77 | France | 48 |
6 | Italy | 52 | Canada | 37 |
7 | Canada | 42 | Switzerland | 27 |
8 | Switzerland | 28 | Australia | 15 |
9 | Australia | 23 | Sweden | 14 |
10 | Brazil | 22 | Denmark | 10 |
Top Five Factors Considered in Country Allocation
(Ranked by scores)
Top Five Factors Considered in Country Allocation
(Ranked by scores)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Rank | Factors | Score | Factors | Score |
1 | Economic growth prospects | 190 | Economic growth prospects | 137 |
2 | Sovereign debt issues | 87 | Liquidity of relevant markets | 71 |
3 | Inflation prospects | 78 | Inflation prospects | 48 |
4 | Interest rate differentials between countries | 73 | Sovereign debt issues | 43 |
5 | Industry- or sector-specific characteristics | 62 | Interest rate differentials between countries | 34 |
Top Five Factors Considered in Country Allocation
(Ranked by scores)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Rank | Factors | Score | Factors | Score |
1 | Economic growth prospects | 190 | Economic growth prospects | 137 |
2 | Sovereign debt issues | 87 | Liquidity of relevant markets | 71 |
3 | Inflation prospects | 78 | Inflation prospects | 48 |
4 | Interest rate differentials between countries | 73 | Sovereign debt issues | 43 |
5 | Industry- or sector-specific characteristics | 62 | Interest rate differentials between countries | 34 |
Top Five Factors Considered in Cross-Border Investment since End-2006
(Ranked by scores)
Top Five Factors Considered in Cross-Border Investment since End-2006
(Ranked by scores)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Rank | Factors | Score | Factors | Score |
1 | Diversification | 115 | Diversification | 106 |
2 | Longer-term growth prospects | 113 | Longer-term growth prospects | 100 |
3 | Search for yield | 93 | Search for yield | 40 |
4 | Sovereign or country risk | 60 | Range of investments available | 33 |
5 | Market liquidity | 58 | Volatility | 32 |
Top Five Factors Considered in Cross-Border Investment since End-2006
(Ranked by scores)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Rank | Factors | Score | Factors | Score |
1 | Diversification | 115 | Diversification | 106 |
2 | Longer-term growth prospects | 113 | Longer-term growth prospects | 100 |
3 | Search for yield | 93 | Search for yield | 40 |
4 | Sovereign or country risk | 60 | Range of investments available | 33 |
5 | Market liquidity | 58 | Volatility | 32 |
Experience and Expectations of Portfolio Risk Exposures and Returns
(In percent of respondents)
Experience and Expectations of Portfolio Risk Exposures and Returns
(In percent of respondents)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
In the next | In the next | |||
Changes in risk exposure and return | Since end-2006 | 3 years | Since end-2006 | 3 years |
Higher risk exposure and… | ||||
…higher return | 6.3 | 9.5 | 16.3 | 16.3 |
…same return | 4.8 | 3.2 | 12.2 | 2.0 |
…lower return | 6.3 | 3.2 | 4.1 | 2.0 |
Same risk exposure and… | ||||
…higher return | 3.2 | 14.3 | 2.0 | 6.1 |
…same return | 20.6 | 41.3 | 18.4 | 34.7 |
…lower return | 27.0 | 7.9 | 18.4 | 10.2 |
Lower risk exposure and… | ||||
…higher return | 0.0 | 3.2 | 2.0 | 0.0 |
…same return | 11.1 | 7.9 | 4.1 | 6.1 |
…lower return | 20.6 | 9.5 | 22.4 | 22.4 |
Experience and Expectations of Portfolio Risk Exposures and Returns
(In percent of respondents)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
In the next | In the next | |||
Changes in risk exposure and return | Since end-2006 | 3 years | Since end-2006 | 3 years |
Higher risk exposure and… | ||||
…higher return | 6.3 | 9.5 | 16.3 | 16.3 |
…same return | 4.8 | 3.2 | 12.2 | 2.0 |
…lower return | 6.3 | 3.2 | 4.1 | 2.0 |
Same risk exposure and… | ||||
…higher return | 3.2 | 14.3 | 2.0 | 6.1 |
…same return | 20.6 | 41.3 | 18.4 | 34.7 |
…lower return | 27.0 | 7.9 | 18.4 | 10.2 |
Lower risk exposure and… | ||||
…higher return | 0.0 | 3.2 | 2.0 | 0.0 |
…same return | 11.1 | 7.9 | 4.1 | 6.1 |
…lower return | 20.6 | 9.5 | 22.4 | 22.4 |
Expected Period before Policy Rate Rise
(In percent of respondents)
Expected Period before Policy Rate Rise
(In percent of respondents)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |
---|---|---|
In 1 year | 0.0 | 0.0 |
In 2 years | 14.1 | 12.2 |
In 3 years | 50.0 | 55.1 |
In 5 years | 20.3 | 18.4 |
Beyond 5 years | 15.6 | 14.3 |
Expected Period before Policy Rate Rise
(In percent of respondents)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |
---|---|---|
In 1 year | 0.0 | 0.0 |
In 2 years | 14.1 | 12.2 |
In 3 years | 50.0 | 55.1 |
In 5 years | 20.3 | 18.4 |
Beyond 5 years | 15.6 | 14.3 |
Use of Hedging Instruments
(In percent of respondents)
Use of Hedging Instruments
(In percent of respondents)
Among Users, Change in Use since End-2006 | |||
---|---|---|---|
Instruments | Currently Using | Increased | Decreased |
Asset Managers | |||
Currency forwards | 88.9 | 73.2 | 7.1 |
Futures | 88.9 | 67.9 | 12.5 |
Options/swaptions | 76.2 | 56.3 | 20.8 |
Interest rate swaps | 69.8 | 59.1 | 9.1 |
Credit default swaps | 57.1 | 58.3 | 22.2 |
Currency swaps | 47.6 | 50.0 | 26.7 |
Correlation hedging | 42.9 | 63.0 | 3.7 |
Forward rate agreement | 38.1 | 50.0 | 12.5 |
Cross-currency swaps | 36.5 | 52.2 | 17.4 |
Short sales | 27.0 | 47.1 | 5.9 |
Political risk insurance | 6.3 | 0.0 | 25.0 |
Pension Funds | |||
Currency forwards | 69.2 | 69.4 | 13.9 |
Futures | 59.6 | 74.2 | 6.5 |
Interest rate swaps | 51.9 | 70.4 | 18.5 |
Options/swaptions | 46.2 | 79.2 | 8.3 |
Credit default swaps | 38.5 | 70.0 | 10.0 |
Forward rate agreement | 32.7 | 70.6 | 0.0 |
Currency swaps | 32.7 | 64.7 | 5.9 |
Cross-currency swaps | 19.2 | 90.0 | 0.0 |
Correlation hedging | 17.3 | 55.6 | 11.1 |
Short sales | 11.5 | 83.3 | 0.0 |
Political risk insurance | 1.9 | 0.0 | 0.0 |
Use of Hedging Instruments
(In percent of respondents)
Among Users, Change in Use since End-2006 | |||
---|---|---|---|
Instruments | Currently Using | Increased | Decreased |
Asset Managers | |||
Currency forwards | 88.9 | 73.2 | 7.1 |
Futures | 88.9 | 67.9 | 12.5 |
Options/swaptions | 76.2 | 56.3 | 20.8 |
Interest rate swaps | 69.8 | 59.1 | 9.1 |
Credit default swaps | 57.1 | 58.3 | 22.2 |
Currency swaps | 47.6 | 50.0 | 26.7 |
Correlation hedging | 42.9 | 63.0 | 3.7 |
Forward rate agreement | 38.1 | 50.0 | 12.5 |
Cross-currency swaps | 36.5 | 52.2 | 17.4 |
Short sales | 27.0 | 47.1 | 5.9 |
Political risk insurance | 6.3 | 0.0 | 25.0 |
Pension Funds | |||
Currency forwards | 69.2 | 69.4 | 13.9 |
Futures | 59.6 | 74.2 | 6.5 |
Interest rate swaps | 51.9 | 70.4 | 18.5 |
Options/swaptions | 46.2 | 79.2 | 8.3 |
Credit default swaps | 38.5 | 70.0 | 10.0 |
Forward rate agreement | 32.7 | 70.6 | 0.0 |
Currency swaps | 32.7 | 64.7 | 5.9 |
Cross-currency swaps | 19.2 | 90.0 | 0.0 |
Correlation hedging | 17.3 | 55.6 | 11.1 |
Short sales | 11.5 | 83.3 | 0.0 |
Political risk insurance | 1.9 | 0.0 | 0.0 |
Use of Derivatives to Enhance Yields
(In percent of respondents)
Use of Derivatives to Enhance Yields
(In percent of respondents)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |
---|---|---|
Not at time of survey | ||
Never | 33.8 | 49.1 |
Not any more | 1.5 | 0.0 |
Yes at time of survey and change since end-2006 | ||
Less use | 6.2 | 1.9 |
No change | 16.9 | 9.4 |
More use | 41.5 | 39.6 |
Use of Derivatives to Enhance Yields
(In percent of respondents)
Asset Managers | Pension Funds | |
---|---|---|
Not at time of survey | ||
Never | 33.8 | 49.1 |
Not any more | 1.5 | 0.0 |
Yes at time of survey and change since end-2006 | ||
Less use | 6.2 | 1.9 |
No change | 16.9 | 9.4 |
More use | 41.5 | 39.6 |
Survey Participants
Survey Participants
Asset Managers | Pension Funds |
---|---|
Allianz Global Investors | Arizona State Retirement System |
APG All Pensions Group | Barclays Plc. |
Arca Sgr SpA | Canada Pension Plan Investment Board |
Artio Global Management LLC | Colorado Public Employees’ Retirement Association |
Aviva Plc | Doctors Pension Funds Services |
Banco Itau Unibanco | Emergency Services & State Super (ESSSuper) |
Bank of Montreal Financial Group | Exxon Mobil Corporation |
BayernInvest Kapitalanlagegesellschaft mbH | Första AP-Fonden |
BNP Paribas | GE Asset Management |
Caisse de dépôt et placement du Québec | Government Pension Investment Fund |
Caixa Gestão de Activos | Healthcare of Ontario Pension Plan |
Colonial First State Global Asset Management | International Business Machines (IBM) |
Credit Suisse AG | Illinois Municipal Retirement Fund |
Cutwater Asset Management | Illinois Teachers Retirement System |
Danske Capital | National Grid Plc. |
DekaBank | Novartis |
Delaware Investments | Pension Fund Association for Local Government Officials |
Deutsche Asset Management | Public Employees’ Retirement System of Nevada |
Edmond de Rothschild Asset Management | Retirement Systems of Alabama |
F&C Investments | Retirement Systems of Georgia |
Fiera Sceptre Inc. | South Carolina Retirement System Investment Commission |
HarbourVest Partners | State of Wisconsin Investment Board |
Helaba Invest Kapitalanlagegesellschaft mbH | Stichting Pensioenfonds Metaal en Techniek |
HSBC Asset Management | Strathclyde Pension Fund |
Investment Solutions Limited | Sunsuper |
Legal & General Group Plc | Texas Municipal Retirement System |
MEAG MUNICH ERGO Asset Management | The State Pension Fund |
Mitsubishi UFJ Financial Group Inc. | United Parcel Service |
Mondrian Investment Partners Limited | United Technologies Corporation |
Nikko Asset Management | Versorgungsanstalt des Bundes und der Länder |
Nordea Investment Management AB | Verizon Investment Management Corp. |
Pioneer Investments | |
PNC Financial Services Group Inc. | |
Rabobank | |
SEB Wealth Management | |
Stone Harbor Investment Partners LP | |
Sun Life Financial | |
Swiss Life | |
TD Asset Management Inc. | |
Tokio Marine & Nichido Fire Insurance Co., Ltd. | |
UBS Global Asset Management | |
Union Asset Management Holding | |
Union Bancaire Privée, UBP SA | |
van Lanschot Bankiers | |
William Blair & Company |
Survey Participants
Asset Managers | Pension Funds |
---|---|
Allianz Global Investors | Arizona State Retirement System |
APG All Pensions Group | Barclays Plc. |
Arca Sgr SpA | Canada Pension Plan Investment Board |
Artio Global Management LLC | Colorado Public Employees’ Retirement Association |
Aviva Plc | Doctors Pension Funds Services |
Banco Itau Unibanco | Emergency Services & State Super (ESSSuper) |
Bank of Montreal Financial Group | Exxon Mobil Corporation |
BayernInvest Kapitalanlagegesellschaft mbH | Första AP-Fonden |
BNP Paribas | GE Asset Management |
Caisse de dépôt et placement du Québec | Government Pension Investment Fund |
Caixa Gestão de Activos | Healthcare of Ontario Pension Plan |
Colonial First State Global Asset Management | International Business Machines (IBM) |
Credit Suisse AG | Illinois Municipal Retirement Fund |
Cutwater Asset Management | Illinois Teachers Retirement System |
Danske Capital | National Grid Plc. |
DekaBank | Novartis |
Delaware Investments | Pension Fund Association for Local Government Officials |
Deutsche Asset Management | Public Employees’ Retirement System of Nevada |
Edmond de Rothschild Asset Management | Retirement Systems of Alabama |
F&C Investments | Retirement Systems of Georgia |
Fiera Sceptre Inc. | South Carolina Retirement System Investment Commission |
HarbourVest Partners | State of Wisconsin Investment Board |
Helaba Invest Kapitalanlagegesellschaft mbH | Stichting Pensioenfonds Metaal en Techniek |
HSBC Asset Management | Strathclyde Pension Fund |
Investment Solutions Limited | Sunsuper |
Legal & General Group Plc | Texas Municipal Retirement System |
MEAG MUNICH ERGO Asset Management | The State Pension Fund |
Mitsubishi UFJ Financial Group Inc. | United Parcel Service |
Mondrian Investment Partners Limited | United Technologies Corporation |
Nikko Asset Management | Versorgungsanstalt des Bundes und der Länder |
Nordea Investment Management AB | Verizon Investment Management Corp. |
Pioneer Investments | |
PNC Financial Services Group Inc. | |
Rabobank | |
SEB Wealth Management | |
Stone Harbor Investment Partners LP | |
Sun Life Financial | |
Swiss Life | |
TD Asset Management Inc. | |
Tokio Marine & Nichido Fire Insurance Co., Ltd. | |
UBS Global Asset Management | |
Union Asset Management Holding | |
Union Bancaire Privée, UBP SA | |
van Lanschot Bankiers | |
William Blair & Company |
Assets under Management and Allocation Trend3
At year-end 2010, the asset managers in the survey had $16 trillion in assets under management, and the surveyed pension funds had $3 trillion (Table 2.11).3 The participating asset managers, acting in various capacities, covered a wide range of investor types (Table 2.12).4
In terms of asset class allocation, shares for equities declined markedly between end-2006 and end-2010 for the asset managers and pension funds surveyed, while the shares for fixed income rose.5 Shares for alternative investments (real estate, hedge funds, private equity, and commodities) increased marginally for pension funds after 2006 (Table 2.13).
Global Asset Allocation and Underlying Factors
By region, assets were predominantly concentrated in advanced economies, particularly in the G-7 (Tables 2.14 and 2.15). However, allocations to emerging market economies increased noticeably, albeit from very low levels for some regions.
In general, both asset managers and pension funds put substantial importance on economic growth prospects when determining country allocations; in contrast, interest rate differentials between countries were not a dominant factor (Table 2.16). Also, asked specifically what factors led to changes in asset allocations into cross-border investments between end-2006 and end-2010, respondents cited the desire for portfolio diversification as playing a key role (Table 2.17).
The Low Interest Rate Environment and Risk-Return Profiles
After end-2006, a majority of asset managers and pension funds put more emphasis on controlling risk than on enhancing returns, and some even lowered their exposures to risky assets and accepted lower returns (Table 2.18).
A majority of asset managers and pension funds expected policy rates in advanced economies to remain below end-2007 levels for at least the next three years (Table 2.19).
Use of Derivatives
The hedging instruments most frequently used by asset managers and pension funds were currency forwards and futures, followed by options/swaptions and interest rate swaps (Table 2.20). Asset managers used a wider set of instruments more extensively than pension funds and used them more to enhance yields than did pension funds (Table 2.21). Consistent with the trend mentioned above to reduce risk exposures, usage of most hedging instruments increased since end-2006 for both asset managers and pension funds.
Annex 2.3. Defining Foreign Exchange Reserves and Sovereign Wealth Funds1
Foreign Exchange Reserves
The IMF’s primary definition of reserve assets is contained in its BoP/IIP manual (IMF, 2009, Chapter VI, paragraph 6.64) as follows:
Reserve assets are those external assets that are readily available to and controlled by monetary authorities for meeting balance of payments financing needs, for intervention in exchange markets to affect the currency exchange rate, and for other related purposes (such as maintaining confidence in the currency and the economy, and serving as a basis for foreign borrowing).
The IMF further defines reserve assets by stating that they “must be both denominated and settled in foreign currency” (paragraph 6.71) and “must be denominated and settled in convertible foreign currencies” (paragraph 6.72); and that “reserve assets, other than gold bullion, must be claims on nonresidents” (paragraph 6.65). These definitions place few restrictions on the asset classes that can be used for reserve asset investments. The main constraints are that they must be liquid (“readily available”) and that they must constitute claims on “nonresidents” in “convertible foreign currencies.”
Sovereign Wealth Funds
The International Working Group of Sovereign Wealth Funds (2008) defines sovereign wealth funds (SWFs) as “special-purpose investment funds or arrangements that are owned by the general government” (p. 3). “Created by the general government for macroeconomic purposes, SWFs hold, manage, or administer assets to achieve financial objectives, and employ a set of investment strategies that include investing in foreign financial assets” (p. 3). In addition, SWFs “are commonly established out of balance of payments surpluses, official foreign currency operations, the proceeds of privatizations, fiscal surpluses, and/or receipts resulting from commodity exports” (p. 3, note 7). This definition excludes, among other things, “foreign currency reserve assets held by monetary authorities for the traditional balance of payments or monetary policy purposes, state-owned enterprises (SOEs) in the traditional sense, government-employee pension funds, or assets managed for the benefit of individuals” (p. 3, note 6).
The above definition of SWFs covers three key elements: ownership, type of investments, and purposes and objectives.
-
Ownership: SWFs are owned by the general government, which includes both central government and subnational governments.2
-
Investments: The investment strategies include investments in foreign financial assets, and excludes those funds that invest solely in domestic assets.
-
Purposes and objectives (Table 2.23): SWFs are created to invest government funds to achieve financial objectives, and (may) have liabilities that are only broadly defined, thus allowing SWFs to employ a wide range of investment strategies with a medium- to long-term timescale. The objective of SWFs is different than that of, for example, reserve portfolios held only for traditional balance of payments purposes. Under the definition, SWFs may include reserve assets, but reserve assets are generally not intended to be a part of SWFs.3
Sovereign Wealth Fund Classification
Sovereign Wealth Fund Classification
Source | Year | Policy Purpose | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Established | Country | Macro Stabilization | Saving | Pension Reserve | Reserve Investment | |
Oil/Natural gas | 1953 | Kuwait | Kuwait Investment Authority, | Kuwait Investment Authority, | ||
General Reserve Fund | Future Generations Fund | |||||
1976 | Canada | Alberta Heritage Savings Trust | ||||
Fund | ||||||
1976 | United Arab Emirates | Abu Dhabi Investment Authority | ||||
1976 | United States | Alaska Permanent Fund | ||||
1980 | Oman | State General Reserve Fund | ||||
1983 | Brunei Darussalam | Brunei Investment Agency | ||||
1996 | Norway | Government Pension Fund, Global | Government Pension Fund, Global | Government Pension Fund, Global | ||
1999 | Azerbaijan | State Oil Fund | State Oil Fund | |||
2000 | Iran, Islamic Republic of | Oil Stabilization Fund | ||||
2000 | Mexico | Oil Revenues Stabilization Fund | ||||
2000 | Qatar | Qatar Investment Authority | ||||
2000 | Trinidad and Tobago | Heritage and Stabilization Fund | Heritage and Stabilization Fund | |||
2001 | Kazakhstan | National Fund | National Fund | |||
2002 | Equatorial Guinea | Fund for Future Generations of Equatorial Guinea | ||||
2004 | São Tomé and Príncipe | National Oil Account | ||||
2005 | Timor Leste | Petroleum Fund | Petroleum Fund | |||
2006 | Bahrain | The Future Generations Reserve Fund | The Future Generations Reserve Fund | |||
2006 | Libya | Libyan Investment Authority | ||||
2008 | Russian Federation | Reserve Fund | National Wealth Fund | |||
Other commodity | 1956 | Kiribati | Kiribati, Revenue Equalization Fund | |||
1996 | Botswana | Botswana, Pula Fund | ||||
2006 | Chile | Pension Reserve Fund | ||||
2007 | Chile | Economic and Social Stabilization Fund | ||||
Fiscal surpluses | 1974 | Singapore | Singapore, Temasek | |||
1981 | Singapore | Government of Singapore | ||||
Investment Corporation | ||||||
1993 | Malaysia | Khazanah Nasional BHD | ||||
2000 | Ireland | Ireland, National Pensions Reserve | ||||
Fund | ||||||
2001 | New Zealand | New Zealand Superannuation Fund | ||||
2006 | Australia | Australia, Future Fund | ||||
2005 | Korea, Republic of | Korea Investment Corporation | ||||
Foreign exchange | 1981 | Singapore | Government of Singapore | |||
reserves | Investment Corporation | |||||
2005 | Korea, Republic of | Korea Investment Corporation | ||||
2007 | China | China Investment Corporation |
Sovereign Wealth Fund Classification
Source | Year | Policy Purpose | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Established | Country | Macro Stabilization | Saving | Pension Reserve | Reserve Investment | |
Oil/Natural gas | 1953 | Kuwait | Kuwait Investment Authority, | Kuwait Investment Authority, | ||
General Reserve Fund | Future Generations Fund | |||||
1976 | Canada | Alberta Heritage Savings Trust | ||||
Fund | ||||||
1976 | United Arab Emirates | Abu Dhabi Investment Authority | ||||
1976 | United States | Alaska Permanent Fund | ||||
1980 | Oman | State General Reserve Fund | ||||
1983 | Brunei Darussalam | Brunei Investment Agency | ||||
1996 | Norway | Government Pension Fund, Global | Government Pension Fund, Global | Government Pension Fund, Global | ||
1999 | Azerbaijan | State Oil Fund | State Oil Fund | |||
2000 | Iran, Islamic Republic of | Oil Stabilization Fund | ||||
2000 | Mexico | Oil Revenues Stabilization Fund | ||||
2000 | Qatar | Qatar Investment Authority | ||||
2000 | Trinidad and Tobago | Heritage and Stabilization Fund | Heritage and Stabilization Fund | |||
2001 | Kazakhstan | National Fund | National Fund | |||
2002 | Equatorial Guinea | Fund for Future Generations of Equatorial Guinea | ||||
2004 | São Tomé and Príncipe | National Oil Account | ||||
2005 | Timor Leste | Petroleum Fund | Petroleum Fund | |||
2006 | Bahrain | The Future Generations Reserve Fund | The Future Generations Reserve Fund | |||
2006 | Libya | Libyan Investment Authority | ||||
2008 | Russian Federation | Reserve Fund | National Wealth Fund | |||
Other commodity | 1956 | Kiribati | Kiribati, Revenue Equalization Fund | |||
1996 | Botswana | Botswana, Pula Fund | ||||
2006 | Chile | Pension Reserve Fund | ||||
2007 | Chile | Economic and Social Stabilization Fund | ||||
Fiscal surpluses | 1974 | Singapore | Singapore, Temasek | |||
1981 | Singapore | Government of Singapore | ||||
Investment Corporation | ||||||
1993 | Malaysia | Khazanah Nasional BHD | ||||
2000 | Ireland | Ireland, National Pensions Reserve | ||||
Fund | ||||||
2001 | New Zealand | New Zealand Superannuation Fund | ||||
2006 | Australia | Australia, Future Fund | ||||
2005 | Korea, Republic of | Korea Investment Corporation | ||||
Foreign exchange | 1981 | Singapore | Government of Singapore | |||
reserves | Investment Corporation | |||||
2005 | Korea, Republic of | Korea Investment Corporation | ||||
2007 | China | China Investment Corporation |
Furthermore, the statement of the International Working Group of Sovereign Wealth Funds (2008) that SWFs are “commonly established out of balance of payments surpluses, official foreign currency operations, the proceeds of privatizations, fiscal surpluses, and/or receipts resulting from commodity exports” (p. 3) reflects both the traditional origin of SWFs—the revenues received from mineral wealth—and the more recent approach of transferring excess reserves.
Reserve assets and assets held by an SWF can overlap, in that reserve assets can be held within an SWF. However, such overlap can occur only when the SWF is “permitted to transact in such assets only on terms specified by the monetary authorities or only with their express approval” (IMF, 2009, Chapter VI, paragraph 6.67).
Annex 2.4. Theoretical Foundation of the Regression Specification and Detailed Regression Results1
In the generic mean-variance (or Markowitz) model, an investor will choose portfolio shares for assets that minimize the variance of the portfolio’s value for a given portfolio return.2 The solution to that problem yields optimal portfolio shares that minimize the variance across all possible combinations of returns. Each investor can then choose a variance-return combination that maximizes the investor’s welfare (which will depend on the investor’s risk aversion). Later versions of the mean-variance model have used various “utility” functions (that is, functions that conveniently summarize the investor’s preferences) derived from microeconomic principles. We employ the widely used constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility function U, which is time separable, that is, where total welfare is a simple sum of welfare in each separate period. This can be represented by the following:
where Ct+i denotes consumption at time t + i; γ is the coefficient of relative risk aversion, which is assumed not to depend systematically on the investor’s wealth; δi is a discount factor; and Et is the expectations operator, taking into account all information up through period t. The intertemporal budget constraint of the investor is given by
where Rp, t+1 is the portfolio return between period t and t + 1, and Wt+1 is wealth in period t + 1. Suppose portfolio returns depend on N risky assets and one risk-free asset. Rt+1 is a vector of risky returns with N elements. It has a mean vector EtRt+1, and a variance-covariance matrix Σt+1. αt is a vector of allocations to the risky asset. The riskless asset has return rf, t+1 from time t to t + 1.3 The portfolio manager optimally chooses αt to maximize utility subject to the budget constraint.
For this problem, no closed-form solution exists that will yield explicit portfolio weights based on the other variables. However, based on a linearized approximation to the intertemporal budget constraint (see Campbell and Viceira, 2002, for details) we can derive the following solution to the portfolio problem:
where ι is a unit vector, and σht is the vector of covariances of each risky asset return with revisions in expected future portfolio returns:
where ρ is a parameter for the linearization. When the consumption-to-wealth ratio is constant, the covariance, σht can be interpreted as the ratio of reinvested wealth to total wealth. One transformation of equation (2) allows us to restate σht as the covariance of the risky asset return with the value function, vt: (σht = Covt (rt+1, -vt+1). This shows that the intertemporal component of asset demand is determined by the covariance of the risky asset’s return with the investor’s utility per unit wealth, which varies over time with investment opportunities.
Equation (3) illustrates that the demand for a risky asset depends on the weighted average of the risk premium (relative to its variance) and the asset’s covariance with the revisions in the expectations of future portfolio returns (again relative to its variance), that is, an intertemporal term. The weights on these terms are proportional to the investor’s risk tolerance (1/). This result, which assumes independently and identically distributed returns, therefore predicts that an investor will choose to allocate more portfolio wealth in a given asset i when it:
-
offers high expected returns, that is, Etrt+1 –rf, t+1ι + α2t /2 is high;
-
has low variance, that is, the ith diagonal term in Σ is low;
-
has low covariance with other assets in the portfolio, that is, the applicable nondiagonal terms in Σ are low; and
-
offers a hedge against future declines in portfolio returns, that is, σ ht is high.
When risk aversion increases, investors will bias their portfolio toward the risk-free asset. Therefore, in periods of elevated risk aversion, funds should flow out of risky bonds and equities to “risk free” instruments (which, from the perspective of a long-term investor, is an asset that approximates a long-term inflation-indexed bond with low default risk).
The independent variables in the regression in the chapter proxy for the various determinants in equation (3) above, as shown in the table below.
Table 2.24 gives the detailed regression results.
Model determinant | Equities | Bonds | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Empirical equivalent | Proxy in regressions | Empirical equivalent | Proxy in regressions | |
Expected returns | Capital gains | Real GDP growth | Coupon payments | 3-month interest rate |
Dividends | Real GDP growth | Default/credit risk | Real GDP growth | |
Country risk | Country risk | Country risk | Country risk | |
Variance | Stock market volatility | Real GDP volatility | Inflation risk | Inflation risk |
Covariance | Covariance with world | Covariance of country | Covariance with world | Covariance of country |
(diversification | returns | equity returns with | returns | bonds returns with |
effect) | world portfolio returns | world portfolio returns | ||
Intertemporal | Covariance with | Covariance of country | Covariance with | Covariance of country bond |
hedge | change in world | equity returns with changes | change in world | returns with changes |
returns | in world portfolio returns | returns | in world portfolio returns |
Model determinant | Equities | Bonds | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Empirical equivalent | Proxy in regressions | Empirical equivalent | Proxy in regressions | |
Expected returns | Capital gains | Real GDP growth | Coupon payments | 3-month interest rate |
Dividends | Real GDP growth | Default/credit risk | Real GDP growth | |
Country risk | Country risk | Country risk | Country risk | |
Variance | Stock market volatility | Real GDP volatility | Inflation risk | Inflation risk |
Covariance | Covariance with world | Covariance of country | Covariance with world | Covariance of country |
(diversification | returns | equity returns with | returns | bonds returns with |
effect) | world portfolio returns | world portfolio returns | ||
Intertemporal | Covariance with | Covariance of country | Covariance with | Covariance of country bond |
hedge | change in world | equity returns with changes | change in world | returns with changes |
returns | in world portfolio returns | returns | in world portfolio returns |
Determinants of Equity and Bond Flows: Panel Regression Results
Determinants of Equity and Bond Flows: Panel Regression Results
Europe, Middle East, and | Non-G-7 Advanced | |||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
World | Asia | Latin America | Africa | G-7 Countries | Countries | |||||||
Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | |
Policy rate differential | -0.042 | -0.145 | -0.362** | -0.499 | -0.068 | -0.003 | 0.081 | -0.636*** | 0.053 | -0.519 | 0.412*** | 0.410 |
(host-G-4 average) | (-0.597) | (-1.542) | (-2.391) | (-1.073) | (-0.840) | (-0.056) | (0.457) | (-3.246) | (0.152) | (-1.120) | (3.807) | (1.454) |
GDP growth forecast | 0.418*** | 0.775*** | 0.274** | 0.168 | 0.506** | 0.564*** | 0.483** | 1.265*** | 0.359** | 0.452*** | 0.256*** | 0.604*** |
(4.389) | (5.557) | (2.426) | (0.790) | (2.509) | (5.189) | (2.364) | (5.479) | (2.054) | (3.418) | (3.376) | (2.777) | |
Inflation volatility | -0.095 | -0.634** | -0.534** | -0.883** | 0.293 | 0.147 | 0.654 | -0.548* | -0.327* | -1.955** | -0.436** | -1.439** |
(-0.478) | (-2.145) | (-2.015) | (-2.058) | (1.441) | (0.218) | (1.065) | (-1.676) | (-1.890) | (-2.441) | (-2.501) | (-2.175) | |
GDP growth volatility | -1.908*** | -4.654*** | -2.835*** | -7.134*** | -2.997*** | -5.597*** | -2.423*** | -3.405*** | 0.171 | -3.410*** | -1.029*** | -3.463*** |
(-4.958) | (-8.389) | (-3.110) | (-8.558) | (-5.029) | (-7.783) | (-2.983) | (-3.356) | (0.419) | (-4.256) | (-3.287) | (-5.481) | |
Exchange rate volatility | -0.389*** | -0.835*** | -0.485** | -1.161*** | -0.268 | -0.080 | -0.556*** | -1.104*** | -0.361*** | -0.850** | -0.334*** | -1.063*** |
(-3.630) | (-3.026) | (-2.165) | (-4.641) | (-0.677) | (-0.135) | (-4.177) | (-3.864) | (-2.805) | (-2.422) | (-5.757) | (-9.843) | |
Return covariance | -0.054 | -0.462*** | 0.025 | -0.656*** | 0.235*** | -0.422*** | -0.129*** | -0.275*** | 0.002 | -0.644*** | 0.019 | -0.574*** |
(cross-country) | (-1.484) | (-6.532) | (0.721) | (-9.542) | (4.034) | (-10.262) | (-3.506) | (-2.989) | (0.036) | (-5.005) | (0.599) | (-13.405) |
Return covariance | -0.002 | 0.034 | 0.001 | 0.198*** | -0.456*** | -0.289*** | 0.120* | 0.049 | -0.136* | 0.077 | -0.173*** | -0.030 |
(intertemporal) | (-0.028) | (0.784) | (0.037) | (3.791) | (-6.069) | (-3.367) | (1.673) | (1.033) | (-1.867) | (1.167) | (-6.011) | (-0.690) |
Country risk | -0.052* | -0.147*** | -0.157** | -0.351*** | -0.066 | -0.282 | -0.080 | -0.151*** | -0.019 | -0.058 | -0.023 | 0.005 |
(-1.833) | (-2.996) | (-2.296) | (-4.957) | (-0.963) | (-1.594) | (-0.963) | (-2.981) | (-0.304) | (-0.796) | (-0.836) | (0.051) | |
VIX index | -0.047*** | -0.071*** | -0.084*** | -0.073*** | -0.096*** | -0.079*** | -0.044*** | -0.117*** | -0.022*** | -0.047*** | -0.024*** | -0.051*** |
(-8.368) | (-7.792) | (-10.264) | (-8.984) | (-6.437) | (-4.972) | (-3.892) | (-5.074) | (-9.109) | (-6.170) | (-6.977) | (-4.224) | |
Capital control index | -1.154 | -3.897*** | -7.776*** | -1.605 | 0.364 | 5.839** | 0.981 | -3.070 | -9.775* | -11.491*** | -0.902 | -8.481*** |
(-1.125) | (-2.625) | (-3.342) | (-0.561) | (0.176) | (1.988) | (0.517) | (-0.951) | (-1.902) | (-2.915) | (-1.113) | (-5.989) | |
Crisis dummy 1 | -0.723*** | -2.388*** | -0.516** | -2.216*** | 0.205 | -2.758*** | -0.617*** | -2.536*** | -0.848*** | -1.602*** | -1.023*** | -2.309*** |
(-7.155) | (-16.002) | (-2.375) | (-8.895) | (0.927) | (-6.505) | (-3.102) | (-6.603) | (-4.152) | (-4.147) | (-13.087) | (-9.220) | |
Crisis dummy 2 | -0.513* | -2.308*** | 0.327 | -3.597*** | 1.033*** | -4.119*** | -1.285 | -3.632*** | -0.823*** | -0.203 | -0.741*** | -0.906** |
(-1.914) | (-6.899) | (0.843) | (-7.363) | (5.464) | (-6.103) | (-1.104) | (-5.847) | (-3.295) | (-0.391) | (-8.102) | (-2.079) | |
Time trend | 0.000 | 0.071*** | -0.026*** | 0.105*** | -0.034*** | 0.088*** | 0.033 | 0.099*** | 0.014** | 0.033*** | 0.003 | 0.043*** |
(0.052) | (10.724) | (-3.253) | (10.226) | (-4.048) | (6.367) | (1.575) | (9.091) | (2.361) | (3.651) | (1.227) | (5.639) | |
Constant | 0.932 | -7.071*** | 8.375*** | -11.554*** | 4.979*** | -12.243*** | -4.228 | -11.027*** | -0.227 | -2.464** | 0.352 | -3.551*** |
(1.240) | (-6.913) | (4.193) | (-4.710) | (3.203) | (-9.145) | (-1.542) | (-5.524) | (-0.392) | (-1.990) | (1.385) | (-3.795) | |
Number of countries | 50 | 50 | 9 | 9 | 6 | 6 | 13 | 13 | 7 | 7 | 15 | 15 |
Number of observations | 2,966 | 2,845 | 504 | 504 | 395 | 397 | 527 | 461 | 490 | 485 | 1,050 | 998 |
R-squared (within) | 0.160 | 0.472 | 0.271 | 0.510 | 0.147 | 0.490 | 0.214 | 0.615 | 0.295 | 0.526 | 0.400 | 0.475 |
R-squared (between) | 0.047 | 0.003 | 0.493 | 0.288 | 0.068 | 0.003 | 0.370 | 0.173 | 0.073 | 0.351 | 0.121 | 0.210 |
R-squared (overall) | 0.083 | 0.303 | 0.004 | 0.477 | 0.145 | 0.418 | 0.212 | 0.502 | 0.054 | 0.293 | 0.388 | 0.428 |
Determinants of Equity and Bond Flows: Panel Regression Results
Europe, Middle East, and | Non-G-7 Advanced | |||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
World | Asia | Latin America | Africa | G-7 Countries | Countries | |||||||
Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | Equities | Bonds | |
Policy rate differential | -0.042 | -0.145 | -0.362** | -0.499 | -0.068 | -0.003 | 0.081 | -0.636*** | 0.053 | -0.519 | 0.412*** | 0.410 |
(host-G-4 average) | (-0.597) | (-1.542) | (-2.391) | (-1.073) | (-0.840) | (-0.056) | (0.457) | (-3.246) | (0.152) | (-1.120) | (3.807) | (1.454) |
GDP growth forecast | 0.418*** | 0.775*** | 0.274** | 0.168 | 0.506** | 0.564*** | 0.483** | 1.265*** | 0.359** | 0.452*** | 0.256*** | 0.604*** |
(4.389) | (5.557) | (2.426) | (0.790) | (2.509) | (5.189) | (2.364) | (5.479) | (2.054) | (3.418) | (3.376) | (2.777) | |
Inflation volatility | -0.095 | -0.634** | -0.534** | -0.883** | 0.293 | 0.147 | 0.654 | -0.548* | -0.327* | -1.955** | -0.436** | -1.439** |
(-0.478) | (-2.145) | (-2.015) | (-2.058) | (1.441) | (0.218) | (1.065) | (-1.676) | (-1.890) | (-2.441) | (-2.501) | (-2.175) | |
GDP growth volatility | -1.908*** | -4.654*** | -2.835*** | -7.134*** | -2.997*** | -5.597*** | -2.423*** | -3.405*** | 0.171 | -3.410*** | -1.029*** | -3.463*** |
(-4.958) | (-8.389) | (-3.110) | (-8.558) | (-5.029) | (-7.783) | (-2.983) | (-3.356) | (0.419) | (-4.256) | (-3.287) | (-5.481) | |
Exchange rate volatility | -0.389*** | -0.835*** | -0.485** | -1.161*** | -0.268 | -0.080 | -0.556*** | -1.104*** | -0.361*** | -0.850** | -0.334*** | -1.063*** |
(-3.630) | (-3.026) | (-2.165) | (-4.641) | (-0.677) | (-0.135) | (-4.177) | (-3.864) | (-2.805) | (-2.422) | (-5.757) | (-9.843) | |
Return covariance | -0.054 | -0.462*** | 0.025 | -0.656*** | 0.235*** | -0.422*** | -0.129*** | -0.275*** | 0.002 | -0.644*** | 0.019 | -0.574*** |
(cross-country) | (-1.484) | (-6.532) | (0.721) | (-9.542) | (4.034) | (-10.262) | (-3.506) | (-2.989) | (0.036) | (-5.005) | (0.599) | (-13.405) |
Return covariance | -0.002 | 0.034 | 0.001 | 0.198*** | -0.456*** | -0.289*** | 0.120* | 0.049 | -0.136* | 0.077 | -0.173*** | -0.030 |
(intertemporal) | (-0.028) | (0.784) | (0.037) | (3.791) | (-6.069) | (-3.367) | (1.673) | (1.033) | (-1.867) | (1.167) | (-6.011) | (-0.690) |
Country risk | -0.052* | -0.147*** | -0.157** | -0.351*** | -0.066 | -0.282 | -0.080 | -0.151*** | -0.019 | -0.058 | -0.023 | 0.005 |
(-1.833) | (-2.996) | (-2.296) | (-4.957) | (-0.963) | (-1.594) | (-0.963) | (-2.981) | (-0.304) | (-0.796) | (-0.836) | (0.051) | |
VIX index | -0.047*** | -0.071*** | -0.084*** | -0.073*** | -0.096*** | -0.079*** | -0.044*** | -0.117*** | -0.022*** | -0.047*** | -0.024*** | -0.051*** |
(-8.368) | (-7.792) | (-10.264) | (-8.984) | (-6.437) | (-4.972) | (-3.892) | (-5.074) | (-9.109) | (-6.170) | (-6.977) | (-4.224) | |
Capital control index | -1.154 | -3.897*** | -7.776*** | -1.605 | 0.364 | 5.839** | 0.981 | -3.070 | -9.775* | -11.491*** | -0.902 | -8.481*** |
(-1.125) | (-2.625) | (-3.342) | (-0.561) | (0.176) | (1.988) | (0.517) | (-0.951) | (-1.902) | (-2.915) | (-1.113) | (-5.989) | |
Crisis dummy 1 | -0.723*** | -2.388*** | -0.516** | -2.216*** | 0.205 | -2.758*** | -0.617*** | -2.536*** | -0.848*** | -1.602*** | -1.023*** | -2.309*** |
(-7.155) | (-16.002) | (-2.375) | (-8.895) | (0.927) | (-6.505) | (-3.102) | (-6.603) | (-4.152) | (-4.147) | (-13.087) | (-9.220) | |
Crisis dummy 2 | -0.513* | -2.308*** | 0.327 | -3.597*** | 1.033*** | -4.119*** | -1.285 | -3.632*** | -0.823*** | -0.203 | -0.741*** | -0.906** |
(-1.914) | (-6.899) | (0.843) | (-7.363) | (5.464) | (-6.103) | (-1.104) | (-5.847) | (-3.295) | (-0.391) | (-8.102) | (-2.079) | |
Time trend | 0.000 | 0.071*** | -0.026*** | 0.105*** | -0.034*** | 0.088*** | 0.033 | 0.099*** | 0.014** | 0.033*** | 0.003 | 0.043*** |
(0.052) | (10.724) | (-3.253) | (10.226) | (-4.048) | (6.367) | (1.575) | (9.091) | (2.361) | (3.651) | (1.227) | (5.639) | |
Constant | 0.932 | -7.071*** | 8.375*** | -11.554*** | 4.979*** | -12.243*** | -4.228 | -11.027*** | -0.227 | -2.464** | 0.352 | -3.551*** |
(1.240) | (-6.913) | (4.193) | (-4.710) | (3.203) | (-9.145) | (-1.542) | (-5.524) | (-0.392) | (-1.990) | (1.385) | (-3.795) | |
Number of countries | 50 | 50 | 9 | 9 | 6 | 6 | 13 | 13 | 7 | 7 | 15 | 15 |
Number of observations | 2,966 | 2,845 | 504 | 504 | 395 | 397 | 527 | 461 | 490 | 485 | 1,050 | 998 |
R-squared (within) | 0.160 | 0.472 | 0.271 | 0.510 | 0.147 | 0.490 | 0.214 | 0.615 | 0.295 | 0.526 | 0.400 | 0.475 |
R-squared (between) | 0.047 | 0.003 | 0.493 | 0.288 | 0.068 | 0.003 | 0.370 | 0.173 | 0.073 | 0.351 | 0.121 | 0.210 |
R-squared (overall) | 0.083 | 0.303 | 0.004 | 0.477 | 0.145 | 0.418 | 0.212 | 0.502 | 0.054 | 0.293 | 0.388 | 0.428 |
References
Black, Fischer, and Robert Litterman, 1990, “Asset Allocation: Combining Investors Views with Market Equilibrium.” Fixed Income Research, Goldman, Sachs & Company.
Black, Fischer, and Robert Litterman, 1992. “Global Portfolio Optimization.” Financial Analysts Journal, Vol. 48 (September/October), pp. 28–43.
Boeri, Tito, Lans Bovenberg, Benoît Coeuré, and Andrew Roberts, 2006, “Dealing with the New Giants: Rethinking the Role of Pension Funds,” Geneva Reports on the World Economy (Geneva: International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies).
Borio, Claudio, Jannecke Ebbesen, Gabriele Galati, and Alexandra Heath, 2008, “FX Reserve Management: Elements of a Framework,” BIS Papers No 38 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements). www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap38.pdf.
Campbell, John, and Luis Viceira, 2002, Strategic Asset Allocation: Portfolio Choice for Long-Term Investors (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Committee on the Global Financial System, 2007, “Institutional Investors, Global Savings and Asset Allocation,” Working Group Report No. 27 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements). www.bis.org/publ/cgfs27.pdf.
Committee on the Global Financial System, 2011, “Fixed Income Strategies of Insurance Companies and Pension Funds,” Working Group Report No. 44 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements). www.bis.org/publ/cgfs44.pdf.
Financial Times, 2011, “CIC Seeks More Funds Out of China Reserves,” January 16. www.ft.com/cms/s/0/a657ba86-219a-11e0-9e3b-00144feab49a.html#axzz1QV97Fico.
Forbes, Kristin, and Francis E. Warnock, 2011, “Capital Flow Waves: Surges, Stops, Flight and Retrenchment,” unpublished (May).
Idzorek, Thomas M., 2005, “A Step-By-Step Guide to the Black-Litterman Model: Incorporating User-Specified Confidence Levels” (Chicago: Ibbotson Associates).
Impavido, Gregorio, 2011, “Stress Tests for Defined Benefit Pension Plans—A Primer,” IMF Working Paper 11/29 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
International Monetary Fund, 2001a, Guidelines for Foreign Exchange Reserve Management (Washington, September). www.imf.org/external/np/mae/ferm/eng/index.htm.
International Monetary Fund, 2001b, Government Finance Statistics Manual (Washington, October). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfs/manual/.
International Monetary Fund, 2007, Global Financial Stability Report, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington, April). www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/GFSR/2007/01/index.htm.
International Monetary Fund, 2009, Balance of Payments and International Investment Position Manual (Washington, 6th ed.). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/bop/2007/bopman6.htm.
International Monetary Fund, 2010, Global Financial Stability Report, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington, April). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2010/01/index.htm.
International Monetary Fund, 2011a, “Assessing Reserve Adequacy” (Washington, February). www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2011/021411b.pdf.
International Monetary Fund, 2011b, World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington, April). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2011/01/index.htm.
International Monetary Fund, 2011c, “Recent Experiences in Managing Capital Inflows—Cross-Cutting Themes and Possible Policy Framework” (Washington, February). www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2011/021411a.pdf.
International Working Group of Sovereign Wealth Funds, 2008, Sovereign Wealth Funds: Generally Accepted Principles and Practices—“Santiago Principles” (Washington). www. iwg-swf.org/pubs/eng/santiagoprinciples.pdf.
Kunzel, Peter, Yinqiu Lu, Iva Petrova, and Jukka Pihlman, 2010, “Investment Objectives of Sovereign Wealth Funds: A Shifting Paradigm,” in Economics of Sovereign Wealth Funds: Issues for Policymakers, ed. by U.S. Das, A. Mazarei, and H. van der Hoorn (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Also published as IMF Working Paper 11/19; www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2011/wp1119.pdf.
Markowitz, Harry, 1952, “Portfolio Selection,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. 7, No. 1, pp. 77–91.
Mminele, Daniel, 2011, “Opening Remarks at the World Bank Treasury’s RAMP-Africa Workshop in Cape Town,” June 13.
Niedermayer, Ludĕk, 2009, “When Liquidity and Reserve Management Collide,” in RBS Reserve Management Trends 2009, ed. by Robert Pringle and Nick Carver (London: Central Banking Publications).
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2005, “Ageing and Pension System Reform: Implication for Financial Markets and Economic Policies,” OECD Financial Market Trends, Volume 2005, Supplement 1 (Paris). www.oecd.org/dataoecd/1/35/35810991.pdf.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2011, “Pension Markets in Focus,” Issue 8 (Paris, July). www.oecd.org/dataoecd/63/61/48438405.pdf.
Ostry, Jonathan D., Atish R. Ghosh, Karl Habermeier, Marcos Chamon, Mahvash S. Qureshi, and Dennis B.S. Reinhardt, 2010, “Capital Inflows: The Role of Controls,” IMF Staff Position Note 10/04 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1004.pdf.
Pihlman, Jukka, and Han van der Hoorn, 2010, “Procyclicality in Central Bank Reserve Management: Evidence from the Crisis,” IMF Working Paper 10/150 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2010/wp10150.pdf.
Pugh, Colin, and Juan Yermo, 2008, “Funding Regulations and Risk Sharing,” OECD Working Papers on Finance Insurance and Private Pensions No. 17 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development).
SWF Institute, 2011, Sovereign Wealth Fund Rankings. www.swfinstitute.org/fund-rankings/.
TheCityUK, 2010 “Fund Management 2010.” www.thecityuk.com/research/our-work/reports-list/fund-management-2010/.
Towers Watson, 2010a, “The World’s 500 Largest Asset Managers—Year End 2009.” www.towerswatson.com/hong-kong/research/2942.
Towers Watson, 2010b, “P&I/TW 300 Analysis Year End 2009.” www.towerswatson.com/assets/pdf/2728/PI-TW-300-survey.pdf.
Towers Watson, 2011, “Towers Watson’s 2011 Insurer Investment Practices Survey.” http://www.towerswatson.com/assets/pdf/mailings/2011-Insurer-Survey-Report-for-Survey-Participants-06-15-2011.pdf.
World Economic Forum, 2011, “The Future of Long-Term Investing.” www.weforum.org/reports/future-long-term-investing-1.
Yermo, Juan, and Clara Severinson, 2010, “The Impact of the Financial Crisis on Defined Benefit Plans and the Need for Counter-Cyclical Funding Regulations,” OECD Working Papers on Finance Insurance and Private Pensions No. 3 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development).
Note: This chapter was written by S. Erik Oppers (team leader), Ruchir Agarwal, Serkan Arslanalp, Ken Chikada, Pascal Farahmand, Gregorio Impavido, Peter Lindner, Yinqiu Lu, Tao Sun, and Han van der Hoorn. Research support was provided by Yoon Sook Kim.
See, for example, Forbes and Warnock, 2011; and IMF, 2011b and 2011c.
National flow-of-funds data are useful, but higher-frequency data are available for only a few jurisdictions, and methodologies are not fully consistent. The OECD publishes a consistent set covering its membership (OECD Annual Statistics on Institutional Investors’ Assets), based mostly on flow-of-funds data. The frequency is only annual, and the data are often published with a delay due to the necessary consistency checks and manipulations. Also, the OECD set covers only investment flows originating in OECD countries and does not show the destination of these flows. Private databases covering mutual fund investments at much higher frequency are useful for statistical analysis (see the section below on Determinants of Private Asset Allocation), but the series are of limited length, and their coverage may change over time as individual funds are added to the database.
The OECD dataset does not indicate the effect of valuation changes, but national flow-of-funds data from the G-4 suggest that most of the decline in total assets under management during the crisis was due to valuation changes (especially in equities).
This metric for reserve adequacy is developed in IMF (2011a); the suggested adequacy range is 100—150 percent of the metric based on 2009 data, leading to the ranges given here.
Hedge funds are not covered in our investigation directly as asset managers, although they are considered as an “investment class” for private asset managers.
The regressions are run on flow data, since the stock data are generally nonstationary. The dependent variables are defined for each country as the valuation-adjusted flows into equity and bond funds in the country, divided by the stock at the beginning of the month. All variables are used at a monthly frequency. For variables of higher frequency, the end-of-month value is used. All regressions include country fixed effects to account for any country-specific factors not identified by the other explanatory variables. Dropping country fixed effects does not alter the signs or statistical significance of the results.
The model employs a six-month lagged capital control measure, for two reasons. First, capital control measures are expected to take effect with a time lag. Second, large flows could in fact prompt the imposition of capital controls, forcing an opposite (positive) sign in the regression; the lagged capital control variable addresses this concern of reverse causality.
Two crisis dummies are included, one for the period between June 2007 and August 2008 (global credit crunch) and one for the period starting in September 2008 (Lehman Brothers bankruptcy).
Because policymakers may use policy rates to dampen undesirable capital flows (which may partly flow into bond and equity investments), the regression may suffer from an “endo-geneity” problem. To get around this issue, a regression was run with lagged policy rate differentials. Expected changes in foreign exchange rates (proxied by the forward less the spot rate) are not included in the regression because any expected change would be captured by the interest rate differential through covered interest parity.
For a detailed discussion see IMF (2010), Chapter 4, “Global Liquidity Expansion: Effects on ‘Receiving’ Economies and Policy Response Options.”
Specifically, the explanatory power of the second crisis dummy variable does not improve significantly if it is terminated before the end of the sample, suggesting that the structural breaks in the regression at the time of the crisis continue through the end of the sample.
The push and pull factors that are found to be important accord with those indicated in the IMF Survey on Global Asset Allocation that accompanied the development of this chapter. The survey is discussed below and in Annex 2.2.
Although Forbes and Warnock (2011) also found weak evidence for the effect of global interest rates on gross capital flows using balance of payments data.
One possible explanation was not borne out in the data. Countries with high interest rate differentials may carry risks of large and sudden devaluations (the “peso problem”). There may therefore be a heterogeneous impact of policy rate differentials on bond flows that may increase the standard error of the estimated coefficient, rendering it insignificant. To try to solve this potential problem, the regression was rerun including an interaction term defined as the product of the policy rate differential and the county risk. Whereas the interest rate differential was positively associated with bond flows when the interaction term is included for the global sample, the results in the regional regressions were unchanged, with bond flows not significantly positively responsive to interest rate differentials.
Specifically, reducing their underweighting in international capital market indices may lead to increased portfolio flows into emerging markets, with corresponding capital inflows.
To do so, we make the considerably simplifying assumption that the shocks have independent effects and are therefore additive.
Regional standard deviations are as follows:
(1) Growth rate—for Asia, 1.98 percent; for Latin America, 1.38 percent; and for the Eastern Europe, Middle East, and Africa group, 1.73 percent.
(2) Forecast variance—0.57 percent, 0.50 percent, and 0.49 percent, respectively.
(3) VIX: 8.08 points for all regions.
The shocks are set equal to two standard deviations of the time series.
The Z-score is the size of the change implied by the dummy coefficient, minus the precrisis mean, divided by the precrisis standard deviation. Note that the Z-score is meaningless if the dummy is not statistically significant, as in such cases there is no statistically significant change at all in asset allocation at the time of the crisis.
This may apply predominantly to pension and insurance companies, which are often required by regulation to follow conservative strategies (see also the section below, “Effects of New Regulatory Initiatives”). See Chapter 1 for a summary of developments for other types of investors.
See Committee on the Global Financial System (2011) and World Economic Forum (2011).
For example, a Towers Watson Survey in June 2011 found that 46 percent of responding insurers were expecting to be more aggressive in their investment strategy in the next year (Towers Watson, 2011).
Risk aversion is a concept that is considered innate, underpinning an investor’s preferences. Changes in risk aversion would affect asset allocation only to the extent that they are not already reflected in shifts because of changes in actual and expected risks and returns. In the regressions, changes in risk aversion could therefore be loosely interpreted as shifts in asset allocation that cannot be explained by the explanatory variables, that is, as a structural break in the regressions.
See, for example, OECD (2011).
The IMF is contributing to this effort, including through the G-20 Data Gaps Initiative. See www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/102909.pdf.
Prepared by Peter Lindner.
Time-varying covariance matrices also presented a problem. However, covariance matrices that are estimated on the basis of a GARCH (generalized autoregressive conditional hetero- skedasticity) model can accommodate changing volatilities and correlations.
Doing so allows practitioners to incorporate elements like trading and market impact costs and the potential for market intervention by regulators, which are often hard to model.
See Black and Litterman (1990 and 1992) and Idzorek (2005).
For some assets, datasets, and data frequencies, models calculated probabilities on the order of 1 in 1 trillion for some observed returns—too small to be realistic.
Prepared by Ken Chikada.
The potential participants were identified with data in Towers Watson (2010a and 2010b) and other relevant information.
The combined amount represented about one-fourth of the world total. The latest available data show that the global fund management industry had $71 trillion in total assets under management at year-end 2009 (TheCityUK, 2010).
To a large extent, asset allocations of asset managers were driven by their clients’ demands. Only 17 percent of asset managers replied that their asset allocations were not at all affected by client demands.
The survey aimed to collect quantitative data since 2002, but many participants could not provide consistent data for 2002. We focus here on the data since 2006.
Prepared by Peter Lindner.
Note that the use of the word arrangements as an alternative to funds allows for a flexible interpretation of the legal arrangement through which the assets can be invested. SWFs vary in their institutional arrangements, and the way they are recorded in the macroeconomic accounts may differ depending on their individual circumstances. See also IMF (2001b).
Likewise, the intention is not to exclude all assets on the books of central banks: SWFs can be on the books of central banks if they are held for other than balance of payments purposes (for example, intergenerational wealth transfer).
Prepared by Ruchir Agarwal, Serkan Arslanalp, and Tao Sun.
Lowercase r refers to log returns: r = log(1 + R).