3 Empirical Analysis of the Current Account1
Author:
Mr. Alessandro Prati
Search for other papers by Mr. Alessandro Prati in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Luca A Ricci
Search for other papers by Mr. Luca A Ricci in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Lone Engbo Christiansen
Search for other papers by Lone Engbo Christiansen in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Stephen Tokarick
Search for other papers by Mr. Stephen Tokarick in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Mr. Thierry Tressel
Search for other papers by Mr. Thierry Tressel in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

This chapter analyzes the medium-term relationship between the current account and a set of fundamentals. Following the existing literature, the estimations consist of ordinary least squares or fixed-effect regressions for an unbalanced panel of nonoverlapping, four-year averages over the period 1981–2005 with six observations for most countries.2 The variables in the regressions are generally stationary. Also, the current account needs to be stationary for the intertemporal budget constraint to hold (Ghosh and Ostry, 1997).

This chapter analyzes the medium-term relationship between the current account and a set of fundamentals. Following the existing literature, the estimations consist of ordinary least squares or fixed-effect regressions for an unbalanced panel of nonoverlapping, four-year averages over the period 1981–2005 with six observations for most countries.2 The variables in the regressions are generally stationary. Also, the current account needs to be stationary for the intertemporal budget constraint to hold (Ghosh and Ostry, 1997).

Benchmark Current Account Regressions for Low-Income Countries

The preferred current account regressions for this sample of low-income countries are reported in Table 3.1.3 In addition to country fixed effects, the regressions include traditional variables (Chinn and Prasad, 2003; Chinn and Ito, 2007; and Lee and others, 2008) such as the fiscal balance; demographic variables (old-age dependency ratio, population growth); initial net foreign assets position; the oil trade balance; and variables related to the stage of development (GDP per capita relative to the United States, and real per capita GDP growth). Most notably, in this sample of LICs, the ratio of the fiscal balance to GDP (relative to that of trading partners) and population growth remain strongly significant with the expected sign.

Table 3.1.

Medium-Term Determinants of the Current Account: Main Results

article image
Note: *** p<0.01; ** p<0.05; * p<0.1. Robust p-values in parentheses. Robust panel regressions of the current-account-to-GDP ratio on country fixed effects, a set of control variables (the fiscal-balance-to-GDP ratio, demographic variables, the initial-net-foreign-assets-to-GDP ratio, the oil-trade-balance-to-GDP ratio, income per capita relative to the United States, and per capita real GDP growth), and a set of medium-term determinants of the current account, including (1) aid flows to GDP, (2) financial and capital account liberalization, and (3) shocks (natural disasters, terms-of-trade fluctuations). The dependent variable and explanatory variables are averaged over four-year periods (except when stated otherwise) and cover 1981–2005.

The set of control variables also includes a measure of the terms of trade that has traditionally not been included in current account regressions. The findings are consistent with the interpretation that income effects resulting from terms-of-trade fluctuations have a strong impact on the current account: a temporary improvement in the terms of trade tends to improve the current account because part of the increase in income is saved to smooth consumption over time.

Columns (1) through (7) of Table 3.1 report regressions in which are introduced—one by one or in groups—the new medium-term determinants, specific to LICs, of the current account, in addition to the previous set of its medium-term determinants. Columns (8) and (9) summarize the preferred results, either when maintaining standard determinants, or when using a parsimonious specification with only significant variables.

Regarding official financing, an aggregate measure of foreign aid is significantly and negatively correlated with the current account.4 The estimated coefficient implies that, for any dollar of aid, the current account deteriorates by about 10 cents during the same period. To better understand this effect, it is useful to note that the two components of foreign aid (grants and concessional loans) are accounted for in separate parts of the balance of payments (the current account and the financial account, respectively), and hence should be expected to have effects of opposite signs on the current account. The analysis presents regressions with the two separate components in columns (2), (6), (8), and (9). The estimated coefficients imply that, on average, about 80 percent of grants are fully absorbed through an increase in net imports over a four-year period, while only 30 to 50 percent of concessional loans received are absorbed through net imports over the same horizon.5 Consistent with theoretical predictions of normative models (Matsen and Torvik, 2004), on average, a large share of aid is not immediately spent on net imports, and is indirectly saved as foreign exchange reserves. Berg and others (2007) and Prati and Tressel (2006) provide consistent evidence that macroeconomic responses to aid surges may limit the short-run absorption of aid in LICs. Overall, the negative coefficient for total aid reported in column (1) reflects similar effects for the two aid components on spending patterns but opposite accounting standards in the current and financial accounts.

Domestic financial reforms are associated with higher current accounts, suggesting that these reforms boost domestic private saving more than they boost investment. This interpretation is consistent with the McKinnon hypothesis,6 according to which liberalization of domestic banking systems in developing countries results in higher saving rates by raising the return on financial saving.7 The estimated effect implies that shifting from complete financial repression to the sample average level of liberalization would improve the current account by 1.5 percent of GDP. Evidence consistent with this interpretation is shown in Table 3.2, which suggests that real deposit rates increase when countries liberalize their domestic financial systems.8

Table 3.2.

Real Deposit Interest Rates in Selected Asian Developing Countries and the United States

article image
Sources: Fry (1995) and authors’ calculations for the United States (annual average continuously compounded rates). Data for the United States are from IMF, International Financial Statistics (lines 60lc and 64).

The opposite effects on the current account of domestic financial liberalization and of concessional loans may be explained by the fact that aid flows are typically not intermediated by the domestic financial system, as discussed in Chapter 2 (aid flows typically finance government current expenditures and public investment). In addition, part of aid flows, by being redistributed through transfers, temporarily increases private agents’ disposable income, thus raising private consumption and saving.9

Exogenous negative income shocks (as proxied by natural disasters) have a negative impact on the current account, as predicted by standard theory, but only in countries with fully open capital accounts (as indicated by the sum of the linear and the interaction terms).10 This result is consistent with standard smoothing of aggregate consumption through international borrowing in open economies.11 Because the analysis is already controlling for official capital flows, the estimates are likely to capture the effect of private capital flows.

Conversely, natural disasters are associated with current account improvements in countries with closed capital accounts. A possible explanation is that these negative shocks trigger a procyclical increase in saving (relative to investment) when there is no access to international capital markets. Kraay and Ventura (2000) suggest that negative income shocks should lead to current account surpluses (deficits) in debtor (creditor) countries because domestic investment falls more (less) than saving following such shocks.12 When interacting the natural disaster variable with the initial net foreign assets position, the analysis yields a negative and significant coefficient on the interaction term (which tends to support the prediction of the Kraay and Ventura model) and an insignificant coefficient on the shock variable itself (Table 3.1, column 5). Controlling for aid, however, weakens this estimated effect of the portfolio composition (Table 3.1, column 6).

The impact of capital account liberalization on the current account needs to be analyzed jointly with the role of shocks: as just discussed, when countries face negative income shocks, more-open capital accounts allow them to borrow on international capital markets, which is consistent with consumption smoothing. However, in good times, capital account liberalization seems to be associated with capital outflows in LICs, which is consistent with the presence of financial repression during the sample. Table 3.2 shows that 6 out of 11 developing countries covered exhibited real deposit rates below U.S. deposit rates in the 1980s.13 Turning to institutional factors, violent political events tend to improve the current account, suggesting that political unrest may trigger significant capital flight.

Robustness

The main baseline results are generally robust to the inclusion of various additional explanatory variables as shown in Table 3.3. Column (1) allows for a dynamic effect of the current account by controlling for the lagged current account: limited persistence of the current account beyond a four-year horizon is found in this sample of LICs.14 Column (2) shows that trade reforms (as measured by an index of average tariffs) have no additional explanatory power. Column (3) splits the terms-of-trade index into two components, and shows that export prices are strongly positively correlated with the current account, while import prices are weakly and negatively correlated with it. A weaker correlation for the latter is consistent with income effects and substitution effects of import price movements having opposite effects on the current account. Next, as shown in column (4), the results are robust to the inclusion of the six emerging markets that have been excluded from the LIC sample (China, Colombia, India, Indonesia, Pakistan, and Thailand). Furthermore, the results are robust to the use of a broader measure of capital account liberalization (updated version of Quinn, 1997; see the Appendix), as reported in column (5).

Table 3.3.

Medium-Term Determinants of the Current Account: Robustness

article image
Note: *** p<0.01; ** p<0.05; * p<0.1. Robust p-values in parentheses. Robust panel regressions of the current-account-to-GDP ratio on country fixed effects, a set of control variables (the fiscal-balance-to-GDP ratio, demographic variables), and a set of medium-term determinants of the current account identified in Table 3.1. The dependent variable and explanatory variables are averaged over four-year periods (except when stated otherwise) and cover 1981–2005. Additional control variables are added one at a time: a four-year lag of the medium-term current account, an index of average import tariff, price indexes for exports and imports, an alternative broader measure of capital account liberalization (based on an extension of Quinn, 1997), and interaction terms between the capital account liberalization index and (1) the fiscal balance, (2) population growth, and (3) per capita real GDP growth.

Column (4) considers a broader country sample that includes emerging markets classified as lower-middle-income countries (China, Colombia, India, Indonesia, Pakistan, and Thailand).

Columns (6), (7), and (8) of Table 3.3 consider alternative interaction terms with the index of capital account openness. Column (6) controls for an interaction between the fiscal balance and the capital account index, to test whether the effect of fiscal policy may depend on the capacity of private agents to offset fiscal policies by borrowing or lending in international markets. The analysis finds that, in this sample of LICs, the effect of fiscal policy on aggregate demand and on the current account is not significantly affected by the degree of capital account openness. However, the negative sign of the interaction term is consistent with standard theories, implying a lower effect of the fiscal balance on the current account in countries with more-open capital accounts. Column (7) considers an interaction with population growth, but again does not yield any significant effect. Still, the negative sign on the interaction term is consistent with neoclassical theories, according to which countries with younger nonactive populations are more able to borrow against future income when the capital account is open. The last column considers an interaction term with real per capita GDP growth; the positive sign of the interaction term, although not significant, would suggest that countries with more open capital accounts tend to run higher current account balances when growth is temporarily above its trend.15

Are Low-Income Countries Different?

Low-income countries are expected to differ from high-income countries because of their higher exposure to shocks, greater distortions, and different sources of external financing. Tables 3.4 and 3.5 explore the extent to which various medium-term determinants of the current account have significantly different effects on the current accounts of low-income countries and of high-income countries, by allowing for different slopes within the same regression (Table 3.4) and testing the significance of their difference (Table 3.5).

Table 3.4.

Current Account Regressions with Different Slopes for Low- and High-Income Countries

article image
Note: HICs = high-income countries; LICs = low-income countries. *** p<0.01; ** p<0.05; * p<0.1. Robust p-values in parentheses. Robust panel regression of the current-account-to-GDP ratio on a set of medium-term determinants of Table 3.1, column (8). Independent variables are interacted with dummy variables for this sample of LICs and HICs. Sample and period averages are as in Tables 3.1 and 3.2.
Table 3.5.

F-Tests of Equality (p-values) of Coefficients across Income Groups for Regressions Reported in Table 3.4

article image
Note: Null hypothesis: coefficient HIC = coefficient LIC (p-value of F-test is reported). Regressions are those reported in Table 3.4.

Among standard determinants of the current account, the analysis finds that (1) the fiscal balance, (2) the old-age dependency ratio, and (3) initial net foreign assets have significantly different impacts on the current account in LICs relative to other countries. In particular, no significant association is found between the current account and the fiscal balance in high-income countries, a finding consistent with Chinn and Prasad (2003) and Isard and Faruqee (1998). This result is consistent with the hypothesis that Ricardian equivalence is more likely to be a reasonable first-order approximation of consumption and saving decisions in high-income countries than in other countries. The negative sign of the coefficient for the initial net foreign assets position in high-income countries is consistent with the standard intertemporal approach to the current account, which predicts that initially richer countries can sustain lower current account balances in the medium term (hence, more of a dynamic effect than a steady-state relationship).

The analysis seems to find a surprising negative association between the current account and capital account openness for higher-income countries when they do not experience natural disasters (column 1)—a finding seemingly inconsistent with the standard prediction of neoclassical theory because richer countries should experience capital outflows when opening up their capital accounts. Moreover, for this group of countries, the analysis yields a positive coefficient on the interaction term between the capital account openness variable and the natural disaster variable. It is likely that this result stems from the specification in column (1) being ideal for LICs, but not for high-income countries: natural disasters (such as floods, droughts, earthquakes, and windstorms) may not really affect the current account of higher-income economies. Hence, column (2) introduces an interaction term between the capital account openness variable and GDP per capita for the whole sample as a way to test more directly the prediction of neoclassical theory that capital should flow from more-developed to less-developed countries. A positive coefficient is found for the interaction term, which is consistent with the prediction of this theory, and the total effect of capital account liberalization on the current account is positive for the richer countries.16 It is also possible that natural disasters are not relevant from a macroeconomic perspective for high-income countries (see the insignificant coefficient on this variable for the higher-income group). The regression in column (3) drops the natural disaster variable and the interaction term, and shows that the interaction of the capital account liberalization index with GDP per capita is still consistent with the prediction of standard development theory.

1

An earlier version of this chapter was published in the International Seminar on Macroeconomics, Vol. 6, No. 1, published by the University of Chicago Press. © 2009 by the National Bureau of Economic Research. All rights reserved.

2

See Chapters 1 and 2 for a discussion of the literature and of the data set. The data set is presented in detail in the Appendix. The variables in the regressions are generally stationary. Also, the current account needs to be stationary for the intertemporal budget constraint to hold (Ghosh and Ostry, 1997).

3

Most variables in the analysis are computed in relation to trading partners, and the main results are not affected if the period sample mean is also removed from other variables.

4

The analysis uses the aggregate measure of foreign aid adjusted for debt relief, in percentage of GDP, as constructed by Roodman (2006).

5

The estimated effects of aid flows on the current account are generally robust to small changes in the regression sample. However, the estimated coefficient of grants reported in the specification of column (2) becomes closer to those of columns (6), (8), and (9) when run on the same sample. See Berg, Mirzoev, and others (2010); Berg, Gottschalk, and others (2010); and Prati and Tressel (2006) for macroeconomic and policy responses to aid flows.

6

Initially formulated by McKinnon (1973), and also conceptualized by Fry (1995).

7

The findings in this paper are also consistent with the model of Gourinchas and Jeanne, 2007, who suggest that saving wedges may be more important than investment wedges in developing countries. However, the findings are less consistent with Caballero, Farhi, and Gourinchas, 2008 and with Mendoza, Quadrini, and Rios-Rull (2008), who show how the lack of financial development may result in precautionary saving, and therefore higher current account balances.

8

Real deposit rates increased between the early 1970s and the end of the 1980s in a sample of Asian countries that moved from financial repression to financial liberalization over this period (Fry, 1995).

9

Whether private agents partly save these windfall earnings is a subject for future research. The aggregate estimates in this analysis suggest that part of aid is saved over a four-year horizon, which may be caused by macroeconomic policy responses, or by private agents’ consumption-saving decisions.

10

The measure is defined as the frequency of negative income shocks over a four-year period, where natural disasters include floods, droughts, earthquakes, and windstorms. Such natural events are typical, frequent, and likely to have macroeconomic implications in LICs. In this sample, the frequency of these shocks is high, about 0.6 per four-year period.

11

In a country with a fully liberalized capital account, a natural disaster occurring at an average frequency of 0.6 during a four-year period would be associated with a deterioration in the current account equivalent to–0.7 percent of GDP.

12

Guo and Jin (2009) show that a portfolio-composition effect might dominate the income effect in past data.

13

There was, however, a large dispersion of real deposit rates in developing countries over the period 1970–90 (Gelb, 1989).

14

Controlling for lags of grant and concessional loans also does not affect the main results (regression available upon request).

15

This result is consistent with Gourinchas and Jeanne (2007), who find evidence that countries with faster productivity growth tend to attract less foreign capital. However, if the country fixed effects are omitted to test for long-run cross-country differences, the opposite sign tends to be found on this interaction term: countries with faster economic growth tend to run lower current account balances when they liberalize their capital accounts.

16

The total effect of capital account openness on the current account turns positive at a GDP per capita of about two-thirds of the U.S. GDP per capita for countries that do not experience natural disasters, and at one-third that of the U.S. GDP for countries that experience natural disasters.

Cited By

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Abiad, Abdul, Enrica Detragiache, and Thierry Tressel, 2008, “A New Database of Financial Reforms,” IMF Working Paper 08/266 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alfaro, Laura, Sebnem Kalemli-Ozcan, and Vadym Volosovych, 2007, “Capital Flows in a Globalized World: The Role of Policies and Institutions,” in Capital Controls and Capital Flows in Emerging Economies: Policies, Practices, and Consequences, ed. by Sebastian Edwards (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Ross Levine, 2000, “A New Database on Financial Development and Structure,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 14, pp. 597605 (updated April 2010). Available via the Internet: http://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/0,, contentMDK:20696167~pagePK:64214825~piPK:64214943~theSitePK:469382,00.html.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Andrew, Shekhar Aiyar, Mumtaz Hussain, Shaun K. Roache, Tokhir N. Mirzoev, and Amber Mahone, 2007, The Macroeconomics of Scaling Up Aid: Lessons from Recent Experience, IMF Occasional Paper No. 253 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Andrew, Jan Gottschalk, Rafael Portillo, and Luis-Felipe Zanna, 2010, “The Macroeconomics of Medium-Term Aid Scaling-Up Scenarios,” IMF Working Paper 10/160 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Andrew, Tokhir Mirzoev, Rafael Portillo, and Luis-Felipe Zanna, 2010, “The Short-Run Macroeconomics of Aid Inflows: Understanding the Interaction of Fiscal and Reserve Policy,” IMF Working Paper 10/65 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, 2007, “Current Account Deficits in Rich Countries,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 54, No. 2, pp. 191219.

  • Bosworth, Barry P., and Susan M. Collins, 1999, “Capital Flows to Developing Countries: Implications for Saving and Investment,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1, pp. 14380.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Broda, Christian, Nuno Limão, and David Weinstein, 2006, “Optimal Tariffs: The Evidence,” NBER Working Paper 12033 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caballero, Ricardo, Emmanuel Farhi, and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 2008, “An Equilibrium Model of ‘Global Imbalances’ and Low Interest Rates,” American Economic Review, Vol. 98, No. 1, pp. 35893.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, 1987, “Balance of Payments Crises in a Cash in Advance Economy,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol.19, No. 1, pp. 1931.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cashin, Paul, Luis F. Céspedes, and Ratna Sahay, 2004, “Commodity Currencies and the Real Exchange Rate,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 75, pp. 23968.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chen, Yu-Chin, and Kenneth Rogoff, 2003, “Commodity Currencies,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 60 (May), pp. 13360.

  • Chinn, Menzie D., and Hiro Ito, 2007, “Current Account Balances, Financial Development and Institutions: Assaying the World ‘Saving Glut,’” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 26, No. 4, pp. 54669.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chinn, Menzie D., and E. Prasad, 2003, “Medium-Term Determinants of Current Accounts in Industrial and Developing Countries: An Empirical Exploration,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 59, No. 1, pp. 47-76.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chinn, Menzie D., and Shang-Jin Wei, 2008, “A Faith-based Initiative: Does a Flexible Exchange Rate Regime Really Facilitate Current Account Adjustment?” NBER Working Paper 14420 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Choudhri, Ehsan U., and Moshin S. Khan, 2005, “Real Exchange Rates in Developing Countries: Are Balassa-Samuelson Effects Present?” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 52, No. 4, pp. 387409.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Christiansen, Lone, Lisa Kolovich, Peter Pedroni, and Stephen Tokarick, 2011, “Real Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: Some Theory and Evidence” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chudik, Alexander, and Joannes Mongardini, 2007, “In Search of Equilibrium: Estimating Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates in Sub-Saharan African Countries,” IMF Working Paper 07/90 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Gregorio, José, Alberto Giovannini, and Holger Wolf, 1994, “International Evidence on Tradables and Nontradables Inflation,” European Economic Review, Vol. 38 (June), pp. 1225244.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Delechat, Corinne, 2008, “Assessing Real Exchange Rates in Low-Income Countries” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Di Bella, Gabriel, Mark Lewis, and Aurelie Martin, 2007, “Assessing Competitiveness and Real Exchange Rate Misalignment in Low-Income Countries,” IMF Working Paper 07/201 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dimaranan, Betina V., ed., 2006, “Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 6 Data Base,” Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dixit, Avinash, and Victor Norman, 1980, Theory of International Trade: A Dual General Equilibrium Approach (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Easterly, William, Michael Kremer, Lant Pritchett, and Larry Summers, 1993, “Good Policy or Good Luck? Country Growth Performance and Temporary Shocks,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32 (December), pp. 459483.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1988, “Real and Monetary Determinants of Real Exchange Rate Behavior,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 29, pp. 31141.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1989, Real Exchange Rates, Devaluation, and Adjustment: Exchange Rate Policy in Developing Countries (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1995, “Why Are Saving Rates so Different Across Countries? An International Comparative Analysis,” NBER Working Paper No. 5097 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, and Jonathan D. Ostry, 1990, “Anticipated Protectionist Policies, Real Exchange Rates, and the Current Account: The Case of Rigid Wages,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 9 (June), pp. 20619.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1992, “Terms of Trade Disturbances, Real Exchange Rates, and Welfare: The Role of Capital Controls and Labor Market Distortions,” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 44, No.1, pp. 2034.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, and Miguel Savastano, 2000, “Exchange Rates in Emerging Economies: What Do We Know? What Do We Need to Know?” in Economic Policy Reform: The Second Stage, ed. by Anne O. Krueger (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, and Sweder van Wijnbergen, 1987, “Tariffs, the Real Exchange Rate, and the Terms of Trade,” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 39, No. 3, pp. 45864.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Elbadawi, Ibrahim, 2007, “Real Exchange Rate Misalignment in Sub-Saharan Africa: How Serious? How Dangerous?” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Engel, Charles, and Kenneth D. West, 2005, “Exchange Rates and Fundamentals,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 113, No. 3, pp. 485517.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Engel, Charles, Nelson C. Mark, and Kenneth D. West, 2008, “Exchange Rate Models Are Not as Bad as You Think,” Macroeconomics Annual 2007, ed. by Daron Acemoglu, Kenneth Rogoff, and Michael Woodford (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Faria, Andre, Philip Lane, Paolo Mauro, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2007, “The Shifting Composition of External Liabilities,” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 5, No. 2–3, pp. 48090.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey, David Parsley, and Shang-Jin Wei, 2005, “Slow Passthrough Around the World: A New Import for Developing Countries?” NBER Working Paper 11199 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Froot, Kenneth A., and Kenneth Rogoff, 1995, “Perspectives on PPP and Long-Run Real Exchange Rates,” in Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 3, ed. by Gene M. Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fry, Maxwell, 1995, Money, Interest, and Banking in Economic Development (Baltimore, Maryland: The John Hopkins University Press).

  • Gelb, Alan, 1989, “Financial Policies, Growth and Efficiency,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 202 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ghosh, Atish R., and Jonathan D. Ostry, 1997, “Macroeconomic Uncertainty, Precautionary Saving, and the Current Account,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 40, No. 1, pp. 12139.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gleditsch, Nils Petter, Peter Wallensteen, Mikael Eriksson, Margareta Sollenberg, and Hãvard Strand, 2002, “Armed Conflict 1946–2001: A New Dataset,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 39, No. 5, pp. 61537.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldfajn, Ilan, and Rodrigo Valdes, 1999, “The Aftermath of Appreciations,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114 (February), pp. 22962.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier, and Oliver Jeanne, 2007, “Capital Flows to Developing Countries: The Allocation Puzzle,” NBER Working Paper 13602 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greenwood, Jeremy, and Boyan Jovanovic, 1990, “Financial Development, Growth, and the Distribution of Income,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 5, pp. 10761107.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gruber, Joseph W., and Steven B. Kamin, 2007, “Explaining the Global Pattern of Current Account Imbalances,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 26, No. 4, pp. 50022.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guo, Kai, and Keyu Jin, 2009, “Composition and Growth Effects of the Current Account: A Synthesized Portfolio View,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 79, No. 1, pp. 3141.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Harbom, Lotta, Stina Högbladh, and Peter Wallensteen, 2006, “Armed Conflict and Peace Agreements,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 43, No. 5, pp. 61731.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hinkle, Lawrence, and Peter Montiel, 1999, Exchange Rate Misalignment: Concepts and Measurement for Developing Countries” (Oxford: Oxford University Press for the World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2009, World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys, (Washington, April).

  • Isard, Peter, and Hamid Faruqee, 1998, Exchange Rate Assessment—Extensions of the Macroeconomic Balance Approach, IMF Occasional Paper No. 167 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jaimovich, Dany, and Ugo Panizza, 2006, “Public Debt Around the World: A New Dataset of Central Government Debt,” Research Department Working Paper No. 561 (Washington: Inter-American Development Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jones, Ronald, 1965, “The Structure of Simple General Equilibrium Models,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 73 (December), pp. 55772.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ju, Jiandong, and Shang-Jin Wei, 2007, “Current Account Adjustment: Some New Theory and Evidence,” NBER Working Paper 13388 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kee, Haui Looi, Alessandro Nicita, and Marcelo Olarreaga, 2008, “Import Demand Elasticities and Trade Distortions,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 90, No. 4, pp. 66682.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin, and Morris Goldstein, 1985, “Income and Price Effects in Foreign Trade,” in Handbook of International Economics, Volume 2, ed. by Ronald Jones and Peter Kenen (New York: North Holland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin, and Jonathan D. Ostry, 1992, “Response of the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate to Real Disturbances in Developing Countries,” World Development, Vol. 20, No. 9, pp. 132534.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kindleberger, Charles P., and Peter H. Lindert, 1978, International Economics (Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwing Inc.).

  • Kireyev, Alexei, 2008, “Non-Econometric Methods for Exchange Rate Assessment in Low-Income Countries” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kohli, Ulrich, 1991, Technology, Duality, and Foreign Trade: The GNP Function Approach to Modeling Imports and Exports (Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kraay, Aart, and Jaume Ventura, 2000, “Current Accounts in Debtor and Creditor Countries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115, No. 4, pp. 113766.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lane, Phillip, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2002a, “External Wealth, the Trade Balance, and the Real Exchange Rate,” European Economic Review, Vol. 46, No. 6, pp. 104971

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lane, Phillip, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2002b, “Long Term Capital Movements,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lane, Phillip, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2003, “International Financial Integration,” IMF Working Paper 03/86 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lane, Phillip, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2004, “The Transfer Problem Revisited: Net Foreign Assets and Real Exchange Rates,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 86, No. 4, pp. 84157.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lane, Phillip, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2007, “The External Wealth of Nations Mark II: Revised and Extended Estimates of Foreign Assets and Liabilities, 1970-2004,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 73, No. 2, pp. 22350.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lee, Jaewoo, Gian-Maria Milesi-Ferretti, Jonathan D. Ostry, Alessandro Prati, and Luca A. Ricci, 2008, Exchange Rate Assessments: CGER Methodologies, IMF Occasional Paper No. 261 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lee, Jaewoo, and Man-Keung Tang, 2007, “Does Productivity Growth Lead to Appreciation of the Real Exchange Rate?” Review of International Economics, Vol. 15, No. 1, pp. 16487.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, Ross, 1997, “Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 2, pp. 688726.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Loayza, Norman, Romain Ranciere, Luis Serven, and Jaume Ventura, 2007, “Macroeconomic Volatility and Welfare in Developing Countries: An Introduction,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 21, No. 3, pp. 34357.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Loayza, Norman, Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, and Luis Servén, 2000, “What Drives Private Saving Across the World?” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 82, No. 2, pp. 16581.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lucas, Robert, 1988, “On the Mechanics of Economic Development,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 342.

  • MacDonald, Ronald, and Luca Antonio Ricci, 2007, “Real Exchange Rates, Imperfect Substitutability, and Imperfect Competition,” Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 29, No. 4, pp. 63964.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Maeso-Fernandez, Francisco, Chiara Osbat, and Bernd Schnatz, 2004, “Towards the Estimation of Equilibrium Exchange Rates for CEE Acceding Countries: Methodological Issues and a Panel Cointegration Perspective,” Working Paper No. 353 (Frankfurt: European Central Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Martin, Philippe, and Helene Rey, 2006, “Globalization and Emerging Markets: With or Without Crash?” American Economic Review, Vol. 96, No. 5, pp. 1631651.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul R., Tam Bayoumi, and Hossein Samiei, 1998, “International Evidence on the Determinants of Private Saving,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 12, No. 3, pp. 483501.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Matsen, Egil, and Ragnar Torvik, 2004, “Optimal Dutch Disease,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 78, No. 2, pp. 494515.

  • McKinnon, Ronald, 1973, Money and Capital in Economic Development (Washington: The Brookings Institution).

  • Meese, Richard A., and Kenneth Rogoff, 1983, “Empirical Exchange Rate Models of the Seventies: Do They Fit out of Sample?” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 14, No. 1–2, pp. 324.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, Enrique G., 1995, “The Terms of Trade, the Real Exchange Rate, and Economic Fluctuations,” International Economic Review, Vol. 36, No. 1, pp. 10137.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, Enrique G., Vincenzo Quadrini, and Jose-Victor Rios-Rull, 2008, “Financial Integration, Financial Development and Global Imbalances,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 117, No. 3, pp. 371416.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Modigliani, Franco, 1986, “Life Cycle, Individual Thrift, and the Wealth of Nations,” American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 3, pp. 297313.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mongardini, Johannes, and Brett Rayner, 2009, “Grants, Remittances, and the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate in Sub-Saharan African Countries,” IMF Working Paper 09/75 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Montiel, Peter, 1999, “Determinants of the Long-Run Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate: An Analytical Model,” in Exchange Rate Misalignment: Concepts and Measurements for Developing Countries, ed. by L. Hinkle and P. Montiel (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obtsfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff, 1999, Foundations of International Macroeconomics (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Ogaki, Masao, Jonathan D. Ostry, and Carmen M. Reinhart, 1996, “Saving Behavior in Low-and Middle-Income Developing Countries: A Comparison,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 43, No. 1, pp. 3871.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Orcutt, Guy, 1950, “Measurement of Price Elasticities in International Trade,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 32 (May), pp. 11732.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., 1988, “The Balance of Trade, The Terms of Trade, and the Real Exchange Rate: An Intertemporal Optimizing Framework,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 35, No. 4, pp. 54173.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., 1990, “Tariffs and the Current Account: The Role of Initial Distortions,” Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 23 (May), pp. 34856.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., 1991, “Tariffs, Real Exchange Rates, and the Trade Balance in a Two-Country World,” European Economic Review, Vol. 35, No. 5, pp. 1127142.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., 1994, “Government Purchases and Relative Prices in a Two-Country World,” Economic Record, Vol. 70, No. 209, pp. 14961.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan D., and Carmen M. Reinhart, 1992, “Private Savings and Terms of Trade Shocks: Evidence from Developing Countries,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 39, No. 3, pp. 495517.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pedroni, Peter, 1999, “Critical Values for Cointegration Tests in Heterogeneous Panels with Multiple Regressors,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 61, No. 4, pp. 65370.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pedroni, Peter, 2004, “Panel Cointegration: Asymptotic and Finite Sample Properties of Pooled Time Series Tests with an Application to the PPP Hypothesis,” Econometric Theory, Vol. 20, No. 3, pp. 597625.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pesaran, Hashem, 2007, “A Simple Panel Unit Root Test in the Presence of Cross-Section Dependence,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 22, No. 2, pp. 265312.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Prasad, Eswar, Raghuram Rajan, and Arvind Subramanian, 2007, “Foreign Capital and Economic Growth,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 38 (2007–1), pp. 153230.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Prati, Alessandro, and Thierry Tressel, 2006, “Aid Volatility and Dutch Disease: Is There a Role for Macroeconomic Policies?” IMF Working Paper 06/145 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Quinn, Dennis, 1997, “The Correlates of Change in International Financial Regulation,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 91 (September), pp. 53151.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Razin, Assaf, and Lars Svensson, 1983, “The Terms of Trade and the Current Account: The Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Effect,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91, No. 1, pp. 97125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinhart, Carmen, and Kenneth Rogoff, 2004, “The Modern History of Exchange Rate Arrangements: A Reinterpretation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 129, No. 1, pp. 148.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ricci, Luca Antonio, Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, and Jaewoo Lee, 2008, “Real Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A Cross-Country Perspective,” IMF Working Paper 08/13 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rogoff, Kenneth, 1996, “The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 34 (June), pp. 64768.

  • Roodman, David, 2006, “An Index of Donor Performance,” Working Paper No. 67 (Washington: Center for Global Development).

  • Rose, Andrew K., Supaat Saktiandi, and Jacob Braude, 2009, “Fertility and the Real Exchange Rate,” Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 42, No. 2, pp. 496518.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roudet, Stéphane, Magnus Saxegaard, and Charalambos G. Tsangarides, 2007, “Estimation of Equilibrium Exchange Rates in the WAEMU: A Robustness Approach,” IMF Working Paper 07/194 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, Jeffrey, and Andrew Warner, 1995, “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 26 (1995–1), pp. 1118.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schmidt-Hebbel, Klaus, Steven B. Webb, and Giancarlo Corsetti, 1992, “Household Saving in Developing Countries: First Cross-Country Evidence,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 6, No. 3, pp. 52947.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Senhadji, Semlali, 1997, “Time-Series of Structural Import Demand Equations—A Cross Country Analysis,” IMF Working Paper 97/132 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stern, Robert, Jonathan Francis, and Bruce Schumacher, 1976, Price Elasticities in International Trade—An Annotated Bibliography (London: Macmillan).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tokarick, Stephen, 2010, “A Method for Calculating Export Supply and Import Demand Elasticities,” IMF Working Paper 10/180 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Torvik, Ragnar, 2001, “Learning by Doing and the Dutch Disease,” European Economic Review, Vol. 45, No. 2, pp. 285306.

  • United Nations, 2006, World Fertility Data, United Nations Population Division/DESA.) Available via the Internet: www.un.org/esa/population/publications/WFD%202008/Main.html.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Van Wijnbergen, S., 1984, “The ‘Dutch Disease’: A Disease After All?” Economic Journal, Vol. 94, No. 373, pp. 4155.

  • Vegh, Carlos, forthcoming, Open Economy Macroeconomics in Developing Countries (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Wacziarg, Romain, and Karen Horn Welch, 2003, “Trade Liberalization and Growth: New Evidence,” NBER Working Paper No. 10152 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Weil, Philippe, 1989, “Overlapping Families of Infinitely Lived Agents,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 38 (March), pp. 18398.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Woodland, Alan, 1982, International Trade and Resource Allocation (Amsterdam; New York: North-Holland).

  • World Bank, 2008, World Development Indicators (Washington: World Bank).