A. Introduction
18.1 The economic approach differs from the fixed-basket, axiomatic, and stochastic approaches outlined in Chapters 16 and 17 in an important respect: Quantities are no longer assumed to be independent of prices. Consider a price index for the output produced by establishments. If, for example, it is assumed that the establishments behave as (export) revenue maximizers, it follows that they would switch production to commodities with higher relative price changes. This behavioral assumption about the firm allows something to be said about what a “true” index number formula should be and the suitability of different index number formulas as approximations to it. For example, the Laspeyres price index uses fixed-period (export) revenue shares to weight its price relatives and ignores the substitution of production toward products with higher relative price changes. The Laspeyres price index will thus understate aggregate price changes—be biased downward against its true index. The Paasche price index uses fixed current-period weights and will thus overstate aggregate price changes—be biased upward against its true index.
18.2 Alternatively, exporters may try to anticipate demand changes by producing less of products with above-average price changes. A Laspeyres price index will thus overstate aggregate price changes—be biased upward against its true index and a Paasche price index will understate aggregate price changes—be biased downward against its true index.
18.3 Consider a price index for the (imported) intermediate inputs to establishments. If, for example, it is assumed that firms behave as cost minimizers, it follows that they would purchase more of products with below-average price changes and again the behavioral assumption would have implications for the nature of substitution bias in Laspeyres and Paasche price index number formulas. The economic approach can be very powerful, because it has identified a type of bias in Laspeyres and Paasche indices not apparent from other approaches: substitution bias.
18.4 The approach from the economic theory of production is thus first to develop theoretical index number formulas based on what are considered to be reasonable models of economic behavior on the part of the producer. A mathematical representation of the production activity—whereby capital and labor conjoin to turn intermediate inputs into outputs—is required. An assumption of optimizing behavior (cost minimization or revenue maximization) is also required. A theoretical index is then derived that is “true” for both the form of the representation of the production activity and behavioral assumption. The economic approach then examines practical index number formulas such as Laspeyres, Paasche, Fisher, and Törnqvist, and considers how they compare with the “true” formulas defined under different assumptions. Important findings are that (1) Laspeyres and Paasche price indices act as bounds on their true indices and, under certain conditions, also are bounds for more generally applicable theoretical true indices that adequately incorporate substitution effects; (2) such generally applicable theoretical indices fall between the Laspeyres and Paasche price indices arguing for an index that is a symmetric mean of the two—the Fisher price index formula is the only symmetric average of Laspeyres and Paasche that satisfies the time reversal test; (3) index number formulas correspond exactly to specific functional forms of the mathematical representation of the revenue/cost functions—for example, the Törnqvist index is exact for a revenue function represented by a translogarithmic functional form; and (4) a class of superlative index number formulas exist that are exact for flexible functional forms giving strong support to their use, because flexible functional forms incorporate substitution behavior. The Fisher, Törnqvist, and Walsh index formulas are all superlative.
18.5 Section B sets the stage for the analysis. First, two approaches are distinguished, each serving different analytical purposes, the resident’s and nonresident’s approaches. The resident’s approach identifies exports as outputs from domestic economic producers—the behavioral assumption would be one of revenue maximization and the Laspeyres price index would be expected to be biased downward against its true index and the Paasche price index biased upward against its true index. The nonresident’s approach identifies exports from the domestic economy as imports to the rest of the world and the perspective taken is the importer’s whose behavioral assumption is cost minimization: The biases in the Laspeyres and Paasche price index number formulas would be reversed. The resident’s approach to imports as inputs to the domestic economic may take cost minimization as its behavioral assumption—Laspeyres would be expected to be biased upward against its true index and the Paasche index biased downward, with the position reversed from the nonresident’s perspective.
18.6 The use of a symmetric means of Laspeyres and Paasche price index formulas would accord with both the resident’s and nonresident’s perspectives because their mean is unaffected by the direction of the bounds. Thus for deliberations of the nature of the bias in Laspeyres and Paasche price indices it is necessary to consider the behavioral assumption of the economic agents which in turn require consideration of the perspective from which exports and imports are regarded.
B. Economic Theory and the Resident’s and Nonresident’s Approach
18.7 This chapter considers two perspectives on export and import price indices (XMPIs):
-
Nonresident perspective: Exports of an economic territory are viewed from the nonresident establishment or household user’s perspective as an input, and imports of an economic territory are viewed from the nonresident producer’s or supplier’s perspective as an output—see Dridi and Zieschang (2004) for details; and
-
Resident perspective: Exports of an economic territory are viewed from the resident producer’s or supplier’s perspective as an output, and imports of an economic territory are viewed from the resident establishment or household user’s perspective as an input.
18.8 The 2008 System of National Accounts (2008 SNA) adopts a “non-residents’ perspective” to the treatment of exports and imports in external account of goods and services. Exports and imports are treated as “uses” and “resources/supply” respectively. Exports are the nonresidents’ use of goods and services produced by residents, and imports are the nonresidents’ supply of goods and services to the residents of an economic territory. Thus the appropriate economic theory underlying imports and exports in the 2008 SNA’s external account of goods and services should be based on this nonresident perspective and, as such, would carry over to be the appropriate economic theory for the price indices used to deflate these aggregates.1 The behavioral assumptions for the economic theory of such price indices would be of cost-minimizing nonresident economic agents, including establishments, households, and government; purchasing exports; and revenue-maximizing nonresident economic agents supplying imports.
18.9 However, a “resident’s perspective” would have the exports of an economic territory viewed from the resident producer’s or supplier’s perspective as an output, and imports of an economic territory viewed from the resident establishment or household user’s perspective as an input. The resident’s perspective would be appropriate for import and export price and volume series used for the analysis of (the resident country’s) productivity change, changes in the terms of trade, and transmission of inflation. The counterpart aggregates to such price and volume measures would be for imports as uses to the residents, and exports as supply. The 2008 SNA’s production account includes intermediate consumption from the resident producer’s perspective and a component of this is served by imports. The 2008 SNA’s production account also includes output as a supply, some of which is a supply to domestic markets and some to nondomestic markets—that is, exports—again from the resident producer’s perspective. Thus the appropriate economic theory underlying imports and exports for the analysis of (the resident country’s) productivity change, changes in the terms of trade, and transmission of inflation would be based on this resident’s perspective and, as such, would carry over to be the appropriate economic theory for the price indices used to deflate these aggregates. The behavioral assumptions for the economic theory of such price indices would be of cost-minimizing resident economic agents purchasing imports and revenue-maximizing resident economic agents supplying exports.
18.10 The perspective taken dictates the behavioral assumptions applied. Section D1 of this chapter demonstrates how the behavior assumptions in turn dictate the direction of the substitution bias in terms of the relationship between Laspeyres and its theoretical “true” counterpart and the Paasche price index in relation to its theoretical “true” counterpart.
18.11 The analysis equates cost-minimizing behavior with purchasers substituting away from commodities with above-average price increases and revenue-maximizing behavior with producers substituting output toward commodities with above-average price increases. However, these general patterns need not hold for all commodities. It may well be that, for example, some resident exporters produce more of commodities with relatively low or falling price changes owing to changes in preferences and technological change that allow producers to both cut prices and increase demand. The strength of the economic analysis is that it identifies a type of bias and demonstrates how answers to questions as to its nature and extent depend on assumptions as to the behavior of exporting and importing economic agents.
18.12 Section C sets the stage for the economic analysis by defining the economic agents involved and some assumptions implicit in the analysis. The analysis proceeds from the resident’s perspective. This is for two reasons: First, the treatment from the nonresident’s perspective is well documented in Dridi and Zieschang (2004). Second, the distinguishing feature of the two approaches for the purpose of economic theory is the behavioral assumptions. There are essentially two sets of theory—those from cost-minimizing behavioral assumptions and those from revenue-maximizing assumptions. As is apparent from Table 18.1, the findings for exports from the resident’s approach apply to those of imports from the nonresident’s approach, and findings for imports from the resident’s approach apply to those of exports from the nonresident’s approach. There is simply no need to replicate the outline of the theory from one perspective given that it has been undertaken from the other. As is demonstrated in Sections D1 and F2 for exports and imports respectively, the nature of these assumptions affects the results for the direction of the bounds on the theoretical “true” indices. However, the behavioral assumptions, and thus distinction between resident’s and nonresident’s perspectives, do not affect the validity of superlative indices; as averages of these bounds it does not matter which direction they take.
Behavioral Assumptions for Resident’s and Nonresident’s Approaches
Behavioral Assumptions for Resident’s and Nonresident’s Approaches
Exports | Imports | |
---|---|---|
Resident’s approach | Revenue maximizer | Cost minimizer |
Nonresident’s approach | Cost minimizer | Revenue maximizer |
Behavioral Assumptions for Resident’s and Nonresident’s Approaches
Exports | Imports | |
---|---|---|
Resident’s approach | Revenue maximizer | Cost minimizer |
Nonresident’s approach | Cost minimizer | Revenue maximizer |
18.13 Sections D2 and E2 respectively demonstrate how Fisher and Törnqvist price indices can be justified as appropriate export price index number formulas using economic theory. Section E outlines the justification for superlative export price index number formulas and Section F considers the economic theory of import price index number formulas.
C. Setting the Stage
C.1 The production accounts of the 2008 SNA
18.14 In the remainder of this chapter, the resident approach is pursued, though as noted above in Table 18.1, there is an immediately apparent correspondence to the results from this perspective and those from the nonresident’s perspective; details are available in Dridi and Zieschang (2004). Establishments undertake the basics of international goods and services trade but, as Chapter 15 notes, households may undertake trade for final consumption in the form of cross-border shopping and of rentals of housing units, and general government units also undertake international procurements and asset sales.2 The economic approach to the XMPIs thus begins not at the industry or institutional sector level, but at the establishment and household level. Readers of the Producer Price Index Manual (ILO and others, 2004b) will note in its Chapter 17 a parallel approach to the economic index number theory of input and output price indices for the part of trade flows establishments undertake. Similarly, readers of the Consumer Price Index Manual (ILO and others, 2004a) will note in its Chapter 17 a parallelism with the economic theory of price indices for consumption for the part of trade flows households undertake. As outlined in Chapter 15, in order to provide a coherent theoretical framework for implementing the resident approach, it turns out that the main production accounts in the 2008 SNA require some elaboration.
18.15 There are a number of reasons why the main production accounts in the 2008 SNA require some modifications so that the modified accounts can provide a theoretical framework for XMPIs. The main reason is that exports and imports enter the main supply and use tables (Table 15.1) as additions (or subtractions) to total net supply or to total domestic final demand in the familiar C + I + G + X – M setup, where C and G are household and government final consumption expenditures, I is gross capital formation, X is exports, and M is imports. This means that Table 15.1 in the main production accounts of the 2008 SNA does not elaborate on which industries are actually using the imports or on which industries are actually doing the exporting by commodity.3 Hence, for XMPI Manual purposes, the main additions to the 2008 SNA, Chapter 15, are tables for the main production accounts that provide industry by commodity detail on exports and imports. With these additional tables on the industry by commodity allocation of exports and imports, the resident’s approach to collecting XMPIs can be embedded in the Commission of the European Communities and others (2008) 2008 SNA framework.
18.16 A second main reason for expanding the existing SNA production accounts is that the present set of accounts does not allow the XMPIs to be related to the producer price index (PPI) for gross outputs and the PPI for intermediate imports by industry. Thus for the purposes of this chapter a modification of the SNA production accounts is considered so that export price indices by industry become subindices of the gross output PPI for that industry and import price indices by industry become subindices of the intermediate input PPI for that industry and thus the augmented accounts provide an integrated approach to all of the price indices that affect producers.
18.17 The 2008 SNA distinguishes between market and nonmarket goods and services. As noted in Chapter 15, market goods and services are transacted at “economically significant prices,” largely covering their cost of production, whereas nonmarket goods and services are transacted at lower prices, including zero. Nonmarket goods and services are defined to include both “output produced for own final use” (SNA transaction code P.12) and “other non-market output” (SNA transaction code P.13). The former is output retained by households for own consumption or by establishments for capital formation, and is not traded internationally and thus of no concern to XMPIs. Other nonmarket goods and services include those produced by government or nonprofit institutions serving households that are supplied free or at a price of no economic significance. These, for the large part, will be aimed at residents, though government, for example, may have as its output some goods and services that benefit nonresidents and these will be exports. Because the share of nonmarket output in exports and imports is generally small, our theory focuses on market output. For any relevant nonmarket output the SNA values production by imputing the prices of similarly dated market transactions in comparable goods and services.
18.18 As foreshadowed at the beginning of this section, the XMPIs cover both household and establishment units in both their production and consumption activities. XMPIs thus comprise subindices of the output, intermediate consumption, final consumption, and capital formation price indices of units resident in the economic territory. Our theory of international trade price indices thus is a theory of international trade sub-indices of the consumer price index and PPI, as well as the other price indices for the supply and use of goods and services mentioned in Chapter 15.
C.2 The price data
18.19 There are two major problems with making the definition of an establishment operational. The first is that many production units at specific geographic locations do not have the capability of providing basic accounting information on inputs used and outputs produced. These production units may be only a division or single plant of a large firm, and detailed accounting information on prices may be available only at the head office (or not at all). If this is the case, the definition of an establishment is modified to include production units at a number of specific geographic locations in the country instead of just one location. The important aspect of the definition of an establishment is that it be able to provide accounting information on prices and quantities.4 A second problem is that while the establishment may be able to report accurate quantity information, its price information may be based on transfer prices set by a head office. These transfer prices are imputed prices and may not be very closely related to market prices.5 Potentially large shares of international trade occur between related enterprises resident in different countries at such transfer prices. This problem is deferred until Chapter 19, which addresses the issue squarely.
18.20 Thus the problems involved in obtaining the correct commodity prices for establishments are generally more difficult than the corresponding problems associated with obtaining market prices for households. However, in this chapter, these problems are ignored for the most part, and it is assumed that representative market prices are available for each output produced by an establishment and for each intermediate input used by the same establishment for at least two accounting periods.6 Price indices for the supply aggregates of goods and services (output price indices) follow valuation at basic prices, which is what the producer would receive for output excluding taxes on products and including subsidies on products.
18.21 For price indices of the aggregates for the establishment and household users of goods and services (input price indices), the economic approach to price indices requires that input prices follow valuation at purchasers’ prices, adding taxes to, and subtracting subsidies on, products from the basic prices producers receive. The indirect taxes are included because users pay them, even though the producing establishments may collect them for government. The subsidies on products are excluded because the cost of goods and services purchased by establishments and households is lowered by these payments. Chapter 15 and Section B in this chapter consider in more detail these national accounting and microeconomic conventions on the treatment of indirect taxes and subsidies on production.
18.22 In this chapter, an export price index and an import price index are defined for a single establishment or household from the economic perspective of a producer in Sections D and F. Household import and export price indices are defined in Section F.2.
18.23 Note it is assumed that the list of commodities produced by the establishment and the list of inputs used by the establishment remain the same over the two periods of a price comparison. In real life, the list of commodities used and produced by an establishment does not remain constant over time. New commodities appear and old commodities disappear. The reasons for this churning of commodities include the following:
-
(1) Producers substitute new technologies for older ones that may reduce the prices of exiting varieties, but may also enable some new varieties to be (technologically and/or economically) feasible and some old ones to be no longer so. Such “technologies” may involve new capital formation, a change in the way production is organized, and/or a change in the primary and intermediate inputs used to generate the outputs. The introduction of new technologies may be in response to changes in relative prices, households’ tastes, or strategic marketing.
-
(2) Existing processes are sufficiently flexible to produce newly differentiated varieties in addition to, or as a replacement for, existing varieties. The introduction of new varieties may be in response to changes in relative prices, households’ tastes, or strategic marketing.
-
(3) Seasonal fluctuations in the demand (or supply) of commodities cause some commodities to be unavailable in certain periods of the year.
18.24 The introduction of new commodities or different varieties of existing ones is dealt with in Chapters 8, 9, and 22 and the problems associated with seasonal commodities are dealt with in Chapter 23. In the present chapter, these complications are ignored, and it is assumed that the list of commodities remains the same over the two periods under consideration. It also is assumed that all establishments are present in both periods under consideration; that is, there are no new or disappearing establishments.7 When convenient, the notation is simplified to match the notation used in Chapters 16 and 17.
18.25 To most practitioners in the field, our basic framework, which assumes that detailed price and quantity data are available for each of the possibly millions of establishments in the economy, will seem to be utterly unrealistic. However, two responses can be directed at this very valid criticism:
-
The spread of the computer and the ease of storing transaction data have made the assumption that the statistical agency has access to detailed price and quantity data less unrealistic. With the cooperation of businesses, it is now possible to calculate price and quantity indices of the type studied in Chapters 16 and 17 using very detailed data on prices and quantities.8
-
Even if it is not realistic to expect to obtain detailed price and quantity data for every transaction made by every establishment in the economy on a monthly or quarterly basis, it is still necessary to accurately specify the universe of transactions in the economy. Once the target universe is known, sampling techniques can be applied in order to reduce data requirements. The principles and practice of sampling establishments for XMPIs are outlined in Chapter 6.
C.3 An overview of the chapter
18.26 This subsection gives a brief overview of the contents of this chapter. In Chapters 15 and 20 the present system of production accounts in the 2008 SNA is extended to accommodate exports and imports in the resident framework. With this expanded system of production accounts in hand, in Section D, economic approaches to the export price index for a single establishment are developed. These approaches are basically an adaptation of the theory of the output price index from Fisher and Shell (1972) and Archibald (1977) and it follows closely the exposition of the export price index made by Alterman, Diewert, and Feenstra (1999). Section E follows up on this material with Diewert’s (1976) theory of superlative indices. A superlative index can be evaluated using observable price and quantity data, but under certain conditions it can give exactly the same answer as does the theoretical output price index. Section F.1 presents an economic approach to an import price index for a single establishment. This theory is again from Alterman, Diewert, and Feenstra (1999). It can also be regarded as an adaptation of the theory of the intermediate input price index for an establishment that was developed in Chapter 17 of the Producer Price Index Manual (ILO and others, 2004b) and, in fact, the establishment import price index can simply be regarded as a subindex of the entire intermediate input price index for an establishment, using the expanded system of production accounts that is explained in Section B below. Section F.2 concludes by developing an economic approach to the household import price index for imported goods and services that do not pass through the domestic production sector. This theory is an adaptation of the standard cost-of-living index theory that originated with Konüs (1924).9 Thus the theories of the XMPIs that are developed in Sections C through E are substantially the same as corresponding theories developed in the Producer Price Index Manual and Consumer Price Index Manual.
18.27 In the previous two chapters, the Fisher (1922) ideal price index and the Törnqvist (1936) price index emerged as very good choices because they are supported by both the test and stochastic approaches to index number theory. These two indices also emerge as very good choices from the economic perspective, as shown later in this chapter. However, a practical drawback to their use is that current-period information on quantities is required, and the statistical agency usually does not have this information on a current-period basis. An important recommendation of this Manual is that if responding establishments or administrative sources can provide current-period quantity/value share data in a timely manner, they should be used to enable the compilation of such indices.
D. The Export Price Index for a Single Establishment
D.1 The export price index and observable bounds
18.28 In this subsection, an outline of the theory of the export price index is presented for a single establishment. This theory, which was developed by Alterman, Diewert, and Feenstra (1999, pp. 10–16), was in turn based on the theory of the output price index developed by Fisher and Shell (1972) and Archibald (1977). This theory is the producer theory counterpart to the theory of the cost-of-living index for a single consumer (or household) that was first developed by the Russian economist, A.A. Konüs (1924). These economic approaches to price indices rely on the assumption of (competitive) optimizing behavior on the part of economic agents (consumers or producers). Thus in the case of the export price index, given a vector of output or export prices that the agent faces in a given time period t, it is assumed that the corresponding period t quantity vector is the solution to a revenue maximization problem that involves the producer’s production function f or production possibilities set. The export price index considered in this section is defined using the theory of the producer and is referred to as an export (output) price index to reinforce the fact that the approach takes a resident producer’s perspective.
18.29 In contrast to the axiomatic approach to index number theory, the economic approach does not assume that the two export quantity vectors pertaining to periods 0 and 1 are independent of the corresponding two export price vectors. In the economic approach, the period 0 export quantity vector is determined by the producer’s period 0 production function and the period 0 vector of export prices that the producer faces, and the period 1 export quantity vector is determined by the producer’s period 1 production function and the period 1 vector of export prices.
18.30 Before the export price index for an establishment can be defined, it is first necessary to describe the establishment’s technology in period t. In the economics literature, it is traditional to describe the technology of a firm or industry in terms of a production function, which tells the maximum amount of output that can be produced using a given vector of inputs. However, because most establishments produce more than one output, it is more convenient to describe the establishment’s technology in period t by means of a production possibilities set, St. The set St describes what output vectors [y, x] can be produced in period t if the establishment has at its disposal the vector of inputs [z, m, v] where y is a vector of domestic outputs produced by the establishment, x is a vector of exports produced by the establishment, z is a vector of domestic intermediate inputs utilized by the establishment, m is a vector of imported intermediate inputs utilized by the establishment, and v is a vector of primary inputs utilized by the establishment. Thus if [y, x, z, m, v] belongs to St, then the nonnegative output vectors y and z can be produced by the establishment in period t if it can utilize the non-negative vectors z, m, and v of inputs. Note the relationship of this establishment production structure with the industrial structure that was explained in Section B above; the only differences are that primary inputs are now introduced into the establishment production possibilities sets and establishments have replaced industries.
18.31 Let px ≡ (px1,…, pxN) denote a vector of positive export prices that the establishment might face in period t10 and let y be a vector of domestic outputs that the establishment is asked to produce, z be a vector of domestic intermediate inputs that the establishment has available during the period, m be a vector of imports that the establishment can utilize during the period, and v be a vector of primary inputs that are available to the establishment. Then the establishment’s conditional export revenue function using period t technology is defined as the solution to the following revenue maximization problem:
Thus Rt (px, y, z, m, v) is the maximum value of exports,
18.32 The period t revenue function Rt can be used to define the establishment’s period t technology export output price index Pt between any two periods, say period 0 and period 1, as follows:
where
18.33 Note that there are a wide variety of price indices of the form (18.2) depending on which reference technology t and reference input vector v are chosen. Thus there is not a single economic price index of the type defined by (18.2): There is an entire family of indices.
18.34 In order to simplify the notation in what follows, define the composite vector of reference quantities u as follows:
As an additional notational simplification, let pt denote the vector of export prices, pxt for periods t = 0, 1.
18.35 Usually, interest lies in two special cases of the general definition of the export price index (18.2): (1) P0(p0, p1, u0), which uses the period 0 technology set and the reference quantity vector u0 ≡ (y0, z0, m0, v0) that was actually produced and used by the establishment in period 0 and (2) P1(p0, p1, u1), which uses the period 1 technology set and the reference quantity vector u1 ≡ (y1, z1, m1, v1) that was actually produced and used by the establishment in period 1. Let x0 and x1 be the observed export vectors for the establishment in periods 0 and 1 respectively. If there is revenue–maximizing behavior on the part of the establishment in periods 0 and 1, then observed revenue in periods 0 and 1 should be equal to R0(P0, u0) and R1(p1, u1) respectively; that is, the following equalities should hold:
18.36 Under these revenue-maximizing assumptions, Alterman, Diewert, and Feenstra (1999, p. 11), adapting the arguments of Fisher and Shell (1972, pp. 57–58) and Archibald (1977, p. 66), have shown that the two theoretical indices, P0(p0, p1, u0) and P1(p0, p1, u1), described above, satisfy the following inequalities (18.5) and (18.6):
where PL is the Laspeyres (1871) price index. Similarly,
where PP is the Paasche (1874) price index. Thus the inequality (18.5) says that the observable Laspeyres index of output prices PL is a lower bound to the theoretical export output price index P0(p0, p1, u0) and the inequality (18.6) says that the observable Paasche index of export output prices PP is an upper bound to the theoretical export output price index p1(p0, p1, u1). Note that these inequalities are in the opposite direction compared to their counterparts in the theory of the true cost-of-living index.13
18.37 It is possible to illustrate the two inequalities (18.4) and (18.5) if there are only two commodities; see Figure 18.1, which is based on diagrams by Hicks (1940, p. 120) and Fisher and Shell (1972, p. 57).
Laspeyres and Paasche Bounds to the Output Price Index
18.38 First, the inequality (18.5) is illustrated for the case of two exports that are both produced in both periods. The solution to the period 0 export revenue maximization problem is the period 0 export vector x0 and the straight line through B represents the revenue line that is just tangent to the period 0 export production possibilities set, S0(u0) ≡ {(x1, x2, u0) belongs to S0}. The curved line through x0 and A is the frontier to the producer’s period 0 export production possibilities set, S0(u0). The solution to the period 1 revenue maximization problem is the vector x1 and the straight line through H represents the export revenue line that is just tangent to the period 1 export production possibilities set, S1(u1) ≡ {(x1, x2, u1) belongs to S1}. The curved line through x1 and F is the frontier to the producer’s period 1 export production possibilities set, S1(u1). The point x0* solves the hypothetical maximization problem of maximizing export revenues when facing the period 1 price vector p1 = (p11 p21) but using the period 0 technology and reference quantity vector u0. This hypothetical export revenue is given by R0(p1, u0) = p11x10* + p21x20* and the dashed line through D is the corresponding isorevenue line p11x1 + p21x2 = R0(p1, u0). Note that the hypothetical export revenue line through D is parallel to the actual period 1 revenue line through H.
From equation (18.5), the hypothetical export price index, P0(p0, p1, u0), is R0(p1, u0)/[p10x10 + p20x20] while the ordinary Laspeyres export price index is [p11x10 + p21x20]/[p10x10 + p20x20]. Because the denominators for these two indices are the same, the difference between the indices is due to the differences in their numerators. In Figure 18.1, this difference in the numerators is expressed by the fact that the revenue line through C lies below the parallel revenue line through D. Now if the producer’s period 0 export production possibilities set were block shaped with the vertex at x0, then the producer would not change his or her production pattern in response to a change in the relative export prices of the two commodities while using the period 0 technology and inputs. In this case, the hypothetical vector x0* would coincide with x0, the dashed line through D would coincide with the dashed line through C, and the true export price index P0(p0, p1, u0) would coincide with the ordinary Laspeyres export price index. However, block-shaped production possibilities sets are not generally consistent with producer behavior; that is, when the price of a commodity increases, producers generally supply more of it. Thus in the general case, there will be a gap between points C and D. The magnitude of this gap represents the amount of substitution bias between the true index and the corresponding Laspeyres index; that is, the Laspeyres index will generally be less than the corresponding true export price index, P0(p0, p1, u0).
18.39 Figure 18.1 can also be used to illustrate the inequality (18.6) for the two export cases. Note that technical progress or increases in input availability have caused the period 1 export production possibilities set S1(u1) ≡ {(x1, x2): (x1, x2, u1) belongs to S1} to be much bigger than the corresponding period 0 export production possibilities set S0(u0) ≡ {(x1, x2): (x1, x2, u0) belongs to S0}.14 Second, note that the dashed lines through E and G are parallel to the period 0 isorevenue line through B. The point x1* solves the hypothetical revenue maximization problem of maximizing export revenue using the period 1 technology and inputs when facing the period 0 export price vector P0 = (p10, p20). This is given by R1(p0, u1) = p10x11* + p20x21* and the dashed line through G is the corresponding isorevenue line p11x1 + p21x2 = R1(p0, u1). From equation (18.6), the theoretical export price index using the period 1 technology and inputs is [p11x11 + p21 x21]/R1(p0, u1) while the ordinary Paasche export price index is [p11x11 + p21x21]/[p10x11 + p20x21]. Because the numerators for these two indices are the same, the difference between the indices is due to the differences in their denominators. In Figure 18.1, this difference in the denominators is expressed by the fact that the revenue line through E lies below the parallel cost line through G. The magnitude of this difference represents the amount of substitution bias between the true index and the corresponding Paasche index; that is, the Paasche index will generally be greater than the corresponding true export price index using current-period technology and inputs, p1(p0, p1, u1). Note that this inequality goes in the opposite direction to the previous inequality (18.5). This change in direction occurs because one set of differences between the two indices takes place in the numerators of the two indices (the Laspeyres inequalities) while the other set takes place in the denominators of the two indices (the Paasche inequalities).
18.40 There are two problems with the inequalities (18.5) and (18.6):
-
There are two equally valid economic price indices, P0(p0, p1, u0) and P1(p0, p1, u1), that could be used to describe the amount of price change that took place between periods 0 and 1 whereas the public will demand that the statistical agency produce a single estimate of price change between the two periods.
-
Only one-sided observable bounds to these two theoretical price indices15 result from this analysis but two-sided bounds are required for most practical purposes.
The following subsection shows how a possible solution to these two problems can be found.
D.2 The Fisher ideal index as an approximation to an economic export output price index
18.41 It is possible to define a theoretical export price index that falls between the observable Paasche and Laspeyres export price indices. To do this, first define a hypothetical export revenue function, R(p, α), that corresponds to the use of an α weighted average of the technology sets S0 and S1 for periods 0 and 1 as the reference technology and that uses an α weighted average of the period 0 and period 1 reference input and export output vectors u0 and u1 as the reference quantity vector:
Thus the revenue maximization problem in equation (18.7) corresponds to the use of a weighted average of the period 0 and 1 reference quantity vectors u0 and u1 where the period 0 vector gets the weight 1 – α and the period 1 vector gets the weight α and an “average” is used of the period 0 and period 1 technology sets where the period 0 set gets the weight 1 – α and the period 1 set gets the weight α, where a is a number between 0 and 1.16 The meaning of the weighted average technology set in definition (18.7) can be explained in terms of Figure 18.1 as follows. As α changes continuously from 0 to 1, the export output production possibilities set changes in a continuous manner from the set S0(u0) (whose frontier is the curve that ends in the point A) to the set S1(u1) (whose frontier is the curve that ends in the point F). Thus for any α between 0 and 1, a hypothetical establishment export output production possibilities set that lies between the base-period set S0(u0) and the current-period set S1(u1) is obtained. For each α, this hypothetical output production possibilities set can be used as the constraint set for a theoretical export output price index.
18.42 The new revenue function defined by equation (18.7) is now used in order to define the following family (indexed by α) of theoretical net export output price indices:
The important advantage that theoretical export output price indices of the form defined by equation (18.2) or (18.8) have over the traditional Laspeyres and Paasche export output price indices PL and PP is that these theoretical indices deal adequately with substitution effects; that is, when an export output price increases, the producer supply should increase, with inputs and the technology held constant.17
18.43 Diewert (1983a, pp. 1060–61) showed that, under certain conditions,18 there exists an α between 0 and 1 such that the theoretical export output price index defined by equation (18.8) lies between the observable (in principle) Paasche and Laspeyres export output indices, PP and PL; that is, there exists an α such that
18.44 The fact that the Paasche and Laspeyres export output price indices provide upper and lower bounds to a “true” export output price P(p0, p1, α) in equation (18.8) is a more useful and important result than the one-sided bounds on the “true” indices that were derived in equations (18.5) and (18.6). If the observable (in principle) Paasche and Laspeyres indices are not too far apart, then taking a symmetric average of these indices should provide a good approximation to an economic export output price index where the reference technology is somewhere between the base- and current-period technologies. The precise symmetric average of the Paasche and Laspeyres indices was determined in Section C.1 of Chapter 16 above on axiomatic grounds and led to the geometric mean, the Fisher price index, PF:
Thus the Fisher ideal price index receives a fairly strong justification as a good approximation to an unobservable theoretical export output price index.19
18.45 The bounds given by equations (18.5), (18.6), and (18.9) are the best bounds that can be obtained on economic export output price indices without making further assumptions. In the next subsection, further assumptions are made on the two technology sets S0 and S1 or equivalently, on the two revenue functions, R0(p, u) and R1(p, u). With these extra assumptions, it is possible to determine the geometric average of the two theoretical export output price indices that are of primary interest, P0(p0, p1, u0) and p1(p0, p1, u1).
D.3 The Törnqvist index as an approximation to an economic export output price index
18.46 An alternative to the Laspeyres and Paasche or the Fisher index defined by equation (18.10) is to use the Törnqvist Theil (Törnqvist 1936, 1937; and Theil, 1967) price index PT, whose natural logarithm is defined as follows:
where
18.47 Recall the definition of the period t revenue function, Rt(p, u), defined earlier by equation (18.1). Now assume that the period t revenue function has the following translog functional form:20 for t = 0, 1,21
where the αnt coefficients satisfy the restrictions:
and the αnjt and the βnmt coefficients satisfy the following restrictions:22
The restrictions (18.14) through (18.15) are necessary to ensure that Rt(p, u) is linearly homogeneous in the components of the export price vector p, which is a property that a revenue function must satisfy.23 Note that at this stage of the argument, the coefficients that characterize the technology in each period (the α’s, β’s, and γ’s) are allowed to be completely different in each period. It should also be noted that the translog functional form is an example of a flexible functional form;24 that is, it can approximate an arbitrary technology to the second order.
18.48 A result in Caves, Christensen, and Diewert (1982b, p. 1410) can now be adapted to the present context: If the quadratic price coefficients in equation (18.12) are equal across the two periods of the index number comparison (i.e., αnj0 = αnj1 for all n, j), then the geometric mean of the economic export price index that uses period 0 technology and the period 0 reference vector u0, P0(p0, p1, u0), and the economic export price index that uses period 1 technology and the period 1 reference quantity vector u1, p1(p0, p1, u1), is exactly equal to the Törnqvist export output price index PT defined by equation (18.11); that is,
where P0(p0, p1, u0) takes the form here as the period 0 export sales share-weighted geometric mean of price relatives and p1(p0, p1, u1) the period 1 export sales share-weighted geometric mean of price relatives. The assumptions required for this result seem rather weak; in particular, there is no requirement that the technologies exhibit constant returns to scale in either period and our assumptions are consistent with technological progress occurring between the two periods being compared. Because the index number formula PT is exactly equal to the geometric mean of two theoretical economic export output price indices and it corresponds to a flexible functional form, the Törnqvist export output price index number formula is said to be superlative, following the terminology used by Diewert (1976).
18.49 For the reader who has read Chapter 17 in the Producer Price Index Manual (ILO and others, 2004b), the above economic theories of the export price index for an establishment will seem very similar to the economic approaches to the gross output price index that appeared in that manual. In fact, the theories are exactly the same; only some of the terminology has changed. Also, another way of viewing the establishment export price index is as a subindex of a gross output price index that encompasses both domestically produced outputs as well as outputs that are exported. Thus once the commodity by industry production accounts for the SNA are expanded along the lines suggested in Chapter 15 and Section B above, the establishment export output price index can be viewed as a subindex of a more complete system of industry by commodity output price indices.
18.50 In the following section, additional superlative export output price formulas are derived. However, this section concludes with a few words of caution on the applicability of the economic approach to export price indices. The above economic approaches to the theory of export price indices have been based on the assumption that producers take the prices of their exports as given fixed parameters that they cannot affect by their actions. However, a monopolistic exporter of a commodity will be well aware that the average price that can be obtained in the market for their commodity will depend on the number of units supplied during the period. Thus under noncompetitive conditions when outputs are monopolistically supplied (or when intermediate inputs are monopsonistically demanded), the economic approach to producer price indices breaks down. The problem of modeling noncompetitive behavior does not arise in the economic approach to consumer price indices because, usually, a single household does not have much control over the prices it faces in the marketplace. The economic approach to producer output price indices can be modified to deal with certain monopolistic situations. The basic idea, developed by Frisch (1936, pp. 14–15), involves linearizing the demand functions a producer faces in each period around the observed equilibrium points in each period and then calculating shadow prices that replace market prices. Alternatively, one can assume that the producer is a markup monopolist and simply adds a markup or premium to the relevant marginal cost of production.25 However, in order to implement these techniques, econometric methods will usually have to be employed and hence, these methods are not really suitable for use by statistical agencies, except in very special circumstances when the problem of noncom-petitive behavior is thought to be very significant and the agency has access to econometric resources.
18.51 The approach is a conditional one; it is assumed that the output of similar commodities to domestic and foreign markets is independent of changes in the relative prices of these similar commodities between the two markets. A revenue-maximizing producer would, for example, shift output to the export market if the price in that market relative to the domestic market increased. However, the expectation is that such a response may be “sticky” because changes in relative prices may be due to exchange rate changes, which may be relatively volatile. Further, costs will be attached to shifting output between markets, including the loss of customer loyalty.
E. Superlative Export Output Price Indices
18.52 Section D.2 demonstrated that the Paasche and Laspeyres export output price indices provide upper and lower bounds to a “true” export output price, P(p0, p1, α), in equation (18.8). Given no preference for Laspeyres and Paasche, or their theoretical counterparts P0(p0, p1, u0) and p1(p0, p1, u1), a symmetric average of Laspeyres and Paasche was advocated as an approximation to a true index. More particularly, the Fisher price index, as a geometric mean of Laspeyres and Paasche price indices, was justified on the basis of its axiomatic properties, which are superior to other symmetric averages. In this section economic theory is used to justify the Fisher index formula as one of a class of superlative index number formulas. An index number is said to be exact when it equals its theoretical true counterpart defined for a particular functional form of its reference quantity vector, u ≡ (y, z, m, v). A superlative index is defined as an index that is exact for a flexible functional form that can provide a second order approximation to other twice-differentiable functions around the same point. Flexible functional forms allow different outputs to be realized in response to relative price changes and thus a more realistic representation of revenue-maximizing behavior is realized: Producers substitute away from commodities with below-average price increases. To develop an economic theory of superlative indices it is first necessary to outline in Section E.1 separability conditions that allow an aggregate export output price index to be defined. Two results are then required that enable specific functional forms for the aggregator function to be related to specific index number formulas; Wold’s Identity and Hotelling’s Lemma are outlined in Section E.2. Fisher as a superlative index number formula is derived in Section E.3 and other superlative formulas are derived in Section E.4, and their properties for two-stage aggregation are considered in Section E.5.
E.1 Homogeneous separability and the export output price index
18.53 Instead of representing the period t technology by a set St, the period t technology is now represented by a factor requirements function Ft; that is, v1 = Ft(x, y, z, m, v2, v3,…, vK) is set equal to the minimum amount of primary input 1 that is required in period t in order to produce the vector of exports x and domestic outputs y, given that the vector of imports m and the amounts v2, v3, …, vK of the remaining primary inputs are available for use. It is assumed that a linearly homogeneous aggregator function f exists for exports; that is, assume that functions f and Gt exist such that26
In technical terms, period t exports are said to be homogeneously weakly separable from the other commodities in the technology.27 The intuitive meaning of the separability assumption that is defined by equation (18.17) is that an export aggregate Q ≡ f(x1,…, xN) exists; that is, a measure of the aggregate contribution to production of the amounts x1 of the first export, x2 of the second export, … , and xN of the N th export is the number Q = f(x1, x2,…, xN). Note that it is assumed that the linearly homogeneous output aggregator function f does not depend on t. These assumptions are quite restrictive from the viewpoint of empirical economics28 but strong assumptions are required in order to obtain the existence of export aggregates from the viewpoint of this variant of economic approach.29
18.54 It turns out that the export aggregator function f has a corresponding unit revenue function, r, defined as follows:
where p ≡ [p1,…, pN] and x ≡ [x1,…, xN]. Thus r(p) is the maximum export revenue that the establishment can make, given that it faces the vector of export prices p and is asked to produce a combination of exports [x1,…, xN] = x that will produce a unit level of aggregate exports.30
18.55 Let Q > 0 be an aggregate level of exports. Then it is straightforward to show that31
Thus r(p)Q is the maximum export revenue that the establishment can make, given that it faces the vector of output prices p and is asked to produce a combination of exports [x1,…, xN] = x that will produce the level Q of aggregate exports.
18.56 Now recall the export revenue maximization problem defined by equation (18.1). Using the factor requirements function defined by equation (18.17) in place of the period t production possibilities set St, this revenue maximization problem can be rewritten as follows:
where the last equality follows using equation (18.19). Now make assumptions (18.4); that is, that the observed period t export vector qt solves the period t export revenue maximization problems, which are given by equation (18.20) under our separability assumption (18.17), with (p, u) = (pt, ut) for t = 0,1. Using equation (18.20), the following equalities result:
18.57 Consider the following export revenue maximization problem that uses the period 0 technology, the period 1 export price vector p1, and conditions on the period 0 reference quantity vector u0:
18.58 Now using the first equality in equation (18.22) and the last equality in equation (18.23) in order to evaluate the base-period version of the theoretical export price index, P0(p0, p1, u0), defined in equation (18.5):
Note that the base-period export price index P0(p0, p1, v0) no longer depends on the base-period reference quantity vector u0; it is now simply a ratio of export unit revenue functions evaluated at the period 1 prices p1 in the numerator and at the period 0 prices P0 in the denominator. This is the simplification that the separability assumptions on the technologies for the two periods imply.
18.59 Using the same technique of proof that was used to establish equation (18.23), it can be shown that under the separability assumptions (18.17),
18.60 Now the second equality in equations (18.22) and (18.25) can be used in order to evaluate the current-period version of the theoretical export price index P1(p0, p1, u1) defined above in equation (18.6):
Again, the current-period export price index p1(p0, p1, u1) no longer depends on the current-period reference quantity vector u1; it is again the ratio of unit export revenue functions evaluated at the period 1 prices p1 in the numerator and at the period 0 prices P0 in the denominator.
18.61 Note that under the present homogeneous weak separability assumptions, both theoretical export price indices defined in equations (18.5) and (18.6) collapse down to the same thing, the ratio of unit export revenues pertaining to the two periods under consideration, r(p1)/r(p0).32
18.62 Under the separability assumptions (18.17) on the establishment technologies for periods 0 and 1, the following decompositions for establishment export revenues in periods 0 and 1 can be obtained:
The ratio of unit revenues, r(p1)/r(p0), has already been identified as the economic output price index under our separability assumptions, (18.17), so if the ratio of establishment export revenues in period 1 to revenues in period 0,
Thus under the separability assumptions, the economic export quantity index is found to be equal to f(x1)/f(x0).33
18.63 Now a position has been reached to apply the theory of exact index numbers. In the following subsections, some specific assumptions are made about the functional form for the export unit revenue function r(p) or the export aggregator function f(x)34 and these specific assumptions enable price index number formulas that are exactly equal to the theoretical output price index, r(p1)/r(p0), to be determined. However, it is first necessary to develop the mathematics of the revenue maximization problems for periods 0 and 1 in a bit more detail. This is done in the next subsection.
E.2 The mathematics of the revenue maximization problem
18.64 In subsequent material, two additional results from economic theory will be needed: Wold’s Identity and Hotelling’s Lemma. These two results follow from the assumption that the establishment is maximizing export revenue during the two periods under consideration subject to the constraints of technology. Wold’s Identity tells us that the partial derivative of an export aggregator function with respect to an export quantity is proportional to its export price while Hotelling’s Lemma tells us that the partial derivative of an export unit revenue function with respect to an export price is proportional to the equilibrium export quantity. These two results enable specific functional forms for the aggregator function f(q) or for the unit revenue function r(p) to be related to bilateral price and quantity indices, P(p0, p1, q0, q1) and Q(p0, p1, q0, q1), that depend on the observable price and quantity vectors pertaining to the two periods under consideration. In particular, Wold’s Identity, equation (18.31), is used to establish equations (18.41) in Section E.3 and (18.54) in Section E.4 while Hotelling’s Lemma, (18.33), is used to establish equations (18.37) in Section E.2 and (18.58) in Section E.4. The less mathematically inclined reader can simply note these results and skip to Section E.3.
18.65Wold’s Identity (1944, pp. 69–71; and 1953, p. 145) is the following:35 Assume that the establishment technologies satisfy the separability assumptions (18.17) for periods 0 and 1. Assume in addition that the observed period t export vector qt solves the period t export revenue maximization problems, which are defined by equation (18.20) under our separability assumptions, with (p, u) = (pt, ut) for t = 0, 1. Finally, assume that the export aggregator function f(q) is differentiable with respect to the components of q at the points q0 and q1. Then it can be shown36 that the following equations hold:
where ∂f(qt)/∂qn denotes the partial derivative of the export revenue function f with respect to the n th export quantity qn evaluated at the period t quantity vector qt.
18.66 Because the export aggregator function f(q) has been assumed to be linearly homogeneous, Wold’s Identity (equation 18.30) simplifies into the following equations, which will prove to be very useful:37
In words, equation (18.31) says that the vector of period t establishment export prices pt divided by period t establishment export revenues
18.67 Under assumptions (18.4) and our separability assumptions (18.17), qt solves the following export revenue maximization problem:
where Qt ≡ f(qt) and the last equality follows using equation (18.22). Consider the period t export revenue maximization problem defined by equation (18.20). Hotelling’s Lemma (1932, p. 594) is the following: If the unit export revenue function r(pt) is differentiable with respect to the components of the price vector p, then the period t export quantity vector qt is equal to the period t export aggregate Qt times the vector of first order partial derivatives of the unit export revenue function with respect to the components of p evaluated at the period t price vector pt; that is,
To explain why equation (18.33) holds, consider the following argument. Because it is being assumed that the observed period t export quantity vector qt solves the export revenue maximization problem that corresponds to r(pt)Qt, then qt must be feasible for this maximization problem so it is necessary that f(qt) = Qt. Thus qt is a feasible solution for the following export revenue maximization problem where the general export price vector p has replaced the specific period t export price vector pt:
where the inequality follows from the fact that qt ≡ (q1t,…, qNt) is a feasible (but usually not optimal) solution for the export revenue maximization problem in equation (18.34). Now for each strictly positive export price vector p, define the function g(p) as follows:
where as usual, p ≡ (p1,…, pN). Using equations (18.32) and (18.34), it can be seen that g(p) is maximized (over all strictly positive price vectors p) at p = pt. Thus the first order necessary conditions for maximizing a differentiable function of N variables hold, and simplify to equation (18.33).
18.68 Combining equations (18.21), (18.27), and (18.28) yields the following:
Combining equations (18.33) and (18.36) yields the following system of equations:
In words, equation (18.37) says that the vector of period t establishment exports qt divided by period t establishment export revenues
18.69 Note the symmetry of equations (18.37) with equations (18.31). It is these two sets of equations that shall be used in subsequent material.
E.3 Superlative indices: The Fisher ideal index
18.70 Suppose the producer’s export aggregator function has the following functional form:
Differentiating the f(q) defined by equation (18.38) with respect to qi yields the following equations:
where fi (q) ≡ ∂f(qt)/∂qi. In order to obtain the first equation in (18.39), the symmetry conditions, aik = aki, are needed. Now evaluate the second equation in (18.39) at the observed period t quantity vector qt ≡ (q1t,…, qNt) and divide both sides of the resulting equation by f(qt). We obtain the following equation:
Assume export revenue–maximizing behavior for the producer in periods 0 and 1. Because the aggregator function f defined by equation (18.38) is linearly homogeneous and differentiable, equation (18.31) will hold (Wold’s Identity). Now recall the definition of the Fisher ideal price index, PF, defined by equation (18.10) above. If the period 1 export revenues are divided by the period 0 export revenues and then this value ratio is divided by PF, then the Fisher ideal quantity index, QF, results:
for t = 0
for t = 1
Thus under the assumption that the producer engages in export revenue–maximizing behavior during periods 0 and 1 and has technologies in periods 0 and 1 that satisfy the separability assumptions (18.17), then the Fisher ideal quantity index QF is exactly equal to the true quantity index, f(q1)/f(q0).38
18.71 As was noted in earlier chapters, the price index that corresponds to the Fisher quantity index QF using the product test is the Fisher price index PF defined by equation (18.10). Let r(p) be the export unit revenue function that corresponds to the homogeneous quadratic export aggregator function f defined by equation (18.38). Then using equations (18.27), (18.28), and (18.41), one can see that
Thus under the assumption that the producer engages in export revenue–maximizing behavior during periods 0 and 1 and has production technologies that satisfy the separability assumptions (18.17) during periods 0 and 1, then the Fisher ideal export price index PF is exactly equal to the true price index, r(p1)/r(p0).
18.72 A twice continuously differentiable function f(q) of N variables q ≡ (q1,…, qN) can provide a second order approximation to another such function f*(q) around the point q* if the level and all of the first and second order partial derivatives of the two functions coincide at q*. It can be shown39 that the homogeneous quadratic function f defined by equation (18.38) can provide a second order approximation to an arbitrary f* around any (strictly positive) point q* in the class of linearly homogeneous functions. Thus the homogeneous quadratic functional form defined by equation (18.38) is a flexible functional form.40 Diewert (1976, p. 117) termed an index number formula QF (p0, p1, q0, q1) that was exactly equal to the true quantity index f(q1)/f(q0) (where f is a flexible functional form) a superlative index number formula.41 equation (18.41) and the fact that the homogeneous quadratic function f defined by equation (18.38) is a flexible functional form shows that the Fisher ideal quantity index QF is a superlative index number formula. Because the Fisher ideal price index PF also satisfies equation (18.42) where r(p) is the unit export revenue function that is generated by the homogeneous export quadratic aggregator function, PF is also a superlative index number formula.
18.73 It is possible to show that the Fisher ideal price index is a superlative index number formula by a different route. Instead of starting with the assumption that the producer’s export aggregator function is the homogeneous quadratic function defined by equation (18.38), start with the assumption that the producer’s unit export revenue function is a homogeneous quadratic.42 Thus suppose that the producer has the following unit export revenue function:
where the parameters bik satisfy the following symmetry conditions:
Differentiating r(p) defined by equation (18.43) with respect to pi yields the following equations:
where ri(p) ≡ ∂r(pt)/∂pi. In order to obtain the first equation in (18.45), it is necessary to use the symmetry conditions in equation (18.44). Now evaluate the second equation in (18.45) at the observed period t price vector pt ≡ (p1t,…,pNt) and divide both sides of the resulting equation by r(pt). The following equations result:
As export revenue–maximizing behavior is assumed for the producer in periods 0 and 1 and because the unit export revenue function r defined by equation (18.43) is differentiable, equation (18.37) will hold (Hotelling’s Lemma). Now recall the definition of the Fisher ideal price index, PF, defined by equation (18.10):
for t = 0
Thus under the assumption that the producer engages in revenue–maximizing behavior during periods 0 and 1 and has technologies that satisfy the separability assumptions (18.17) and the functional form for the unit revenue function that corresponds to the output aggregator function f(q) given by equation (18.43), then the Fisher ideal price index PF is exactly equal to the true price index, r(p1)/r(p0).43
18.74 Because the homogeneous quadratic unit revenue function r(p) defined by equation (18.43) is also a flexible functional form, the fact that the Fisher ideal price index PF exactly equals the true export price index r(p1)/r(p0) means that PF is a superlative index number formula.44
18.75 Suppose that the bik coefficients in equation (18.43) satisfy the following restrictions:
where the N numbers bi are nonnegative. In this special case of equation (18.43), it can be seen that the unit export revenue function simplifies as follows:
Substituting equation (18.49) into Hotelling’s Lemma (equation 18.33) yields the following expressions for the period t quantity vectors, qt:
Thus if the producer has the export aggregator function that corresponds to the unit export revenue function defined by equation (18.43) where the bik satisfy the restrictions (18.48), then the period 0 and 1 quantity vectors are equal to a multiple of the vector b ≡ (b1,…,bN); that is, q0 = bQ0 and q1 = bQ1. Under these assumptions, the Fisher, Paasche, and Laspeyres indices, PF, PP, and PL, all coincide. However, the export aggregator function f(q) which corresponds to this unit export revenue function is not consistent with normal producer behavior because the output production possibilities set in this case are block shaped and hence the producer will not substitute toward producing more expensive commodities from cheaper commodities if relative prices change going from period 0 to 1.
E.4 Quadratic mean of order r superlative indices
18.76 It turns out that there are many other superlative index number formulas; that is, there exist many export quantity indices Q(p0, p1, q0, q1) that are exactly equal to f(q1)/f(q0) and many export price indices P(p0, p1, q0, q1) that are exactly equal to r(p1)/r(p0) where the export aggregator function f or the export unit revenue function r is a flexible functional form. Two families of superlative indices are defined below.
18.77 Suppose that the producer’s output aggregator function is the following quadratic mean of order r aggregator function:45
where the parameters aik satisfy the symmetry conditions aik = aki for all i and k and the parameter r satisfies the restriction r ≠ 0. Diewert (1976, p. 130) showed that the aggregator function fr defined by equation (18.51) is a flexible functional form; that is, it can approximate an arbitrary twice continuously differentiable linearly homogeneous functional form to the second order. Note that when r = 2, fr equals the homogeneous quadratic function defined by equation (18.38) above.
18.78 Define the quadratic mean of order r export quantity index Qr by
where
18.79 Using exactly the same techniques as were used in Section E.3 above, it can be shown that Qr is exact for the aggregator function fr defined by equation (18.51); that is,
Thus under the assumption that the producer engages in export revenue–maximizing behavior during periods 0 and 1 and has technologies that satisfy assumptions (18.17) where the output aggregator function f(q) is defined by equation (18.51), then the quadratic mean of order r quantity index QF is exactly equal to the true quantity index, fr(q1)/fr(q0).46 Because Qr is exact for fr and fr is a flexible functional form, the quadratic mean of order r quantity index Qr is a superlative index for each r ≠ 0. Thus there are an infinite number of superlative quantity indices.
18.80 For each quantity index Qr, the product test can be used in order to define the corresponding implicit quadratic mean of order r price index Pr*:
where rr* is the unit revenue function that corresponds to the aggregator function f r defined by equation (18.51) above. For each r ≠ 0, the implicit quadratic mean of order r price index Pr* is also a superlative index.
18.81 When r = 2, Qr defined by equation (18.52)
simplifies to QF, the Fisher ideal quantity index, and Pr* defined by equation (18.54) simplifies to PF, the Fisher ideal price index. When r = 1, Qr defined by equation (18.52) simplifies to
where PW is the Walsh price index defined by equation (16.19) in Chapter 16. Thus p1* is equal to PW, the Walsh price index, and hence it is also a superlative price index.
18.82 A quadratic mean of order r unit revenue function is given by47
where the parameters bik satisfy the symmetry conditions bik = bki for all i and k and the parameter r satisfies the restriction r ≠ 0. Diewert (1976, p. 130) showed that the unit revenue function rr defined by equation (18.56) is a flexible functional form; that is, it can approximate an arbitrary twice continuously differentiable linearly homogeneous functional form to the second order. Note that when r = 2, rr equals the homogeneous quadratic function defined by equation (18.43).
18.83 Define the quadratic mean of order r price index Pr by
where
18.84 Using exactly the same techniques as were used in Section D.3 above, we can show that Pr is exact for the unit revenue function rr defined by equation (18.56); that is,
Thus under the assumption that the producer engages in export revenue–maximizing behavior during periods 0 and 1 and has technologies that satisfy assumptions (18.17) where the output aggregator function f(q) corresponds to the unit revenue function rr(p) defined by equation (18.56), then the quadratic mean of order r price index Pr is exactly equal to the true export price index, rr(p1)/rr(p0).48 Because Pr is exact for rr and rr is a flexible functional form, that the quadratic mean of order r price index Pr is a superlative index for each r ≠ 0. Thus there are an infinite number of superlative price indices.
18.85 For each price index Pr, the product test (equation 16.3 in Chapter 16) can be used in order to define the corresponding implicit quadratic mean of order r quantity index Qr*:
where fr* is the aggregator function that corresponds to the unit revenue function rr defined by equation (18.56).49 For each r ≠ 0, the implicit quadratic mean of order r quantity index Qr* is also a superlative index.
18.86 When r = 2, Pr defined by equation (18.57) simplifies to PF, the Fisher ideal price index, and Qr* defined by equation (18.59) simplifies to QF, the Fisher ideal quantity index. When r = 1, Pr defined by equation (18.57) simplifies to
where QW is the Walsh quantity index defined previously by equation (16.34) in Chapter 16. Thus Q1* is equal to QW, the Walsh (1901, 1921a) quantity index, and hence it is also a superlative quantity index.
18.87 Essentially, the economic approach to index number theory provides reasonably strong justifications for the use of the Fisher price index PF, the Törnqvist Theil price index PT defined by equation (16.48) or (18.11), the implicit quadratic mean of order r price indices Pr* defined by equation (18.54) (when r = 1, this index is the Walsh price index defined by equation (16.19) in Chapter 16), and the quadratic mean of order r price indices Pr defined by equation (18.57). It is now necessary to ask if it matters which one of these formula is chosen as “best.”
E.5 The approximation properties of superlative indices
18.88 The results in Sections E.2, E.3, E.3, and E.4 provide a large number of superlative index number formulas that appear to have good properties from the viewpoint of the economic approach to index number theory.50 Two questions arise as a consequence of these results:
-
Does it matter which of these formulas is chosen?
-
If it does matter, which formula should be chosen?
18.89 With respect to the first question, Diewert (1978, p. 888) showed that all of the superlative index number formulas listed in Sections E.3 and E.4 approximate each other to the second order around any point where the two price vectors, P0 and p1, are equal and where the two quantity vectors, q0 and q1, are equal. In particular, this means that the following equalities exist for all r and s not equal to 0 provided that p0 = p1 and q0 = q1.51
where the Törnqvist Theil price index PT is defined by equation (18.11), the implicit quadratic mean of order r price indices Ps* is defined by equation (18.34) and the quadratic mean of order r price indices Pr is defined by equation (18.57). Using the above results, Diewert (1978, p. 884) concluded that “all superlative indices closely approximate each other.”
18.90 However, the above conclusion is not true even though the equations (18.61) through (18.66) are true. The problem is that the quadratic mean of order r price indices Pr and the implicit quadratic mean of order s price indices Ps* are (continuous) functions of the parameters r and s respectively. Hence, as r and s become very large in magnitude, the indices Pr and Ps* can differ substantially from, say, P2 = PF, the Fisher ideal index. In fact, using definition (18.57) and the limiting properties of means of order r,52 Robert Hill (2006) showed that Pr has the following limit as r approaches plus or minus infinity:
Using Hill’s method of analysis, we can show that the implicit quadratic mean of order r price index has the following limit as r approaches plus or minus infinity:
Thus for r large in magnitude, Pr and Pr* can differ substantially from PT, p1, p1* = PW (the Walsh price index) and P2 = P2* = PF (the Fisher ideal index).53
18.91 Although Robert Hill’s theoretical and empirical results demonstrate conclusively that all superlative indices will not necessarily closely approximate each other, there is still the question of how well the more commonly used superlative indices will approximate each other. All of the commonly used superlative indices, Pr and Pr*, fall into the interval 0 ≤ r ≤ 2.54 Robert Hill (2006) summarized how far apart the Törnqvist and Fisher indices were, making all possible bilateral comparisons between any two data points for his time-series data set as follows:
-
The superlative spread S(0,2) is also of interest since, in practice, Törnqvist (r = 0) and Fisher (r = 2) are by far the two most widely used superlative indices. In all 153 bilateral comparisons, S(0,2) is less than the Paasche-Laspeyres spread and on average, the superlative spread is only 0.1 percent. It is because attention, until now, has focused almost exclusively on superlative indices in the range 0 ≤ r ≤ 2 that a general misperception has persisted in the index number literature that all superlative indices approximate each other closely.
Thus for Hill’s time-series data set covering 64 components of U.S. GDP from 1977 to 1994 and making all possible bilateral comparisons between any two years, the Fisher and Törnqvist price indices differed by only 0.1 percent on average. This close correspondence is consistent with the results of other empirical studies using annual time-series data.55 Additional evidence on this topic may be found in Chapter 20.
18.92 A reasonably strong justification has been provided by the economic approach for a small group of index numbers: the Fisher ideal index PF = P2 = P2* defined by equation (18.10), the Törnqvist Theil index PT defined by equation (18.11), and the Walsh index PW defined by equation (16.19) (which is equal to the implicit quadratic mean of order r price indices Pr* defined by equation (18.54) when r = 1). They share the property of being superlative and approximate each other to the second order around any point. This indicates that for “normal” time-series data, these three indices will give virtually the same answer. The economic approach gave particular support to the Fisher and Törnqvist Theil indices, albeit on different grounds. The Fisher index was advocated as the only symmetrically weighted average of Laspeyres and Paasche bounds that satisfied the time reversal test. Economic theory argued for the existence of Laspeyres and Paasche bounds on a suitable “true” theoretical index. The support for the Törnqvist Theil index arose from it requiring less restrictive assumptions to show it was superlative than did the Fisher and Walsh indices. The Törnqvist Theil index seemed to be best from the stochastic viewpoint, and the Fisher ideal index was supported from the axiomatic viewpoint, in that it best satisfied the quite reasonable tests presented. The Walsh index seemed to be best from the viewpoint of the “pure” price index. To determine precisely which one of these three alternative indices to use as a theoretical target or actual index, the statistical agency will have to decide which approach to bilateral index number theory is most consistent with its goals. It is reassuring that, as illustrated in Chapter 20, for “normal” time series data, these three indices gave virtually the same answer.
E.6 Superlative indices and two-stage aggregation
18.93 Most statistical agencies use the Laspeyres formula to aggregate prices in two stages. At the first stage of aggregation, the Laspeyres formula is used to aggregate components of the overall index (e.g., agricultural output prices, other primary industry output prices, manufacturing prices, service output prices) and then at the second stage of aggregation, these component subindices are further combined into the overall index. The following question then naturally arises: Does the index computed in two stages coincide with the index computed in a single stage? This question is initially addressed in the context of the Laspeyres formula.56
18.94 Now suppose that the price and quantity data for period t, pt, and qt, can be written in terms of J subvectors as follows:
where the dimensionality of the subvectors ptj and qtj is Nj for j = 1,2,…, J with the sum of the dimensions Nj equal to N. These subvectors correspond to the price and quantity data for subcomponents of the export output price index for period t. Construct subindices for each of these components going from period 0 to 1. For the base period, the price for each of these subcomponents, say, Pj0 for j = 1,2,…, J, is set equal to 1 and each corresponding base-period subcomponent quantities, say, Qj0 for j = 1,2,…,J, is set equal to the base-period value of production for that subcomponent. For j = 1,2,…, J, that is,
Now use the Laspeyres formula in order to construct a period 1 price for each subcomponent, say, P for j = 1, 2,…, J, of the export price index. Because the dimensionality of the subcomponent vectors, ptj and qtj, differs from the dimensionality of the complete period t vectors of prices and quantities, pt and qt, different symbols for these subcomponent Laspeyres indices will be used, say, PLj for j = 1, 2,…, J. Thus the period 1 subcomponent Laspeyres price indices are defined as follows:
Once the period 1 J price subindices have been defined by equation (18.71), then corresponding J subcomponent period 1 quantity indices
Subcomponent price and quantity vectors for each J in each period t = 0,1 can now be defined using equations (18.70) to (18.72). Define the period 0 and 1 subcomponent price vectors P0 and p1 as follows:
where 1J denotes a vector of ones of dimension J and the components of p1 are defined by equation (18.71). The period 0 and 1 subcomponent quantity vectors q0 and q1 are defined as follows:
where the components of q0 are defined in equation (18.70) and the components of Q1 are defined by equation (18.72). The price and quantity vectors in equations (18.73) and (18.74) represent the results of the first stage aggregation. These vectors can now be used as inputs into the second stage aggregation problem; that is, the Laspeyres price index formula can be applied using the information in equations (18.73) and (18.74) as inputs into the index number formula. Because the price and quantity vectors that are inputs into this second stage aggregation problem have dimension J instead of the first stage formula, each of which utilized vectors of dimension Nj, a different symbol is needed for our new Laspeyres price index which is chosen to be PL*. Thus the Laspeyres price index computed in two stages can be denoted as PL*(p0, p1, Q0, Q1). It is now appropriate to ask whether this two-stage Laspeyres price index equals the corresponding single-stage price index PL that was studied in the previous sections of this chapter; that is, whether
If the Laspeyres formula is used at each stage of each aggregation, the answer to the above question is yes: Straightforward calculations show that the Laspeyres index calculated in two stages equals the Laspeyres index calculated in one stage. However, the answer is yes if the Paasche formula is used at each stage of aggregation; that is, the Paasche formula is consistent in aggregation just like the Laspeyres formula.
18.95 Now suppose the Fisher or Törnqvist formula is used at each stage of the aggregation; that is, in equation (18.71), suppose the Laspeyres formula PLj(p0j, p1j, q0j, q1j) is replaced by the Fisher formula PFj (p0j, p1j, q0j, q1j) or by the Törnqvist formula PTj(p0j, p1j, q0j, q1j), and in equation (18.75), PL*(P0, p1, Q0, Q1) is replaced by PF* (or by PT*) and PL(p0, p1, q0, q1) replaced by PF (or by PT). Then do counterparts to the two-stage aggregation result for the Laspeyres formula, (18.75), hold? The answer is no; it can be shown that, in general,
Similarly, it can be shown that the quadratic mean of order r index number formula Pr defined by equation (18.57) and the implicit quadratic mean of order r index number formula Pr* defined by equation (18.54) are also not consistent in aggregation.
18.96 However, even though the Fisher and Törnqvist formulas are not exactly consistent in aggregation, it can be shown that these formulas are approximately consistent in aggregation. More specifically, it can be shown that the two-stage Fisher formula PF* and the single-stage Fisher formula PF in equation (18.76), both regarded as functions of the 4N variables in the vectors p0, p1, q0, q1, approximate each other to the second order around a point where the two price vectors are equal (so that P0 = p1) and where the two quantity vectors are equal (so that q0 = q1) and a similar result holds for the two-stage and single-stage Törnqvist indices in equation (18.76).57 As was shown in the previous section, the single-stage Fisher and Törnqvist indices have a similar approximation property so all four indices in equation (18.76) approximate each other to the second order around an equal (or proportional) price and quantity point. Thus for normal time series data, single-stage and two-stage Fisher and Törnqvist indices will usually be numerically very close.58 This result is illustrated in Chapter 20 for an artificial data set.
18.97 A similar approximate consistency in aggregation results (to the results for the Fisher and Törnqvist formulas explained in the previous paragraph) can be derived for the quadratic mean of order r indices, Pr, and for the implicit quadratic mean of order r indices, Pr*; see Diewert (1978, p. 889). However, the results of Robert Hill (2006) again imply that the second order approximation property of the single-stage quadratic mean of order r index Pr to its two-stage counterpart will break down as r approaches either plus or minus infinity. To see this, consider a simple example where there are only four commodities in total. Let the first price relative pi1/pi0 be equal to the positive number a, let the second two price relatives pi1/pi0 equal b, and let the last price relative p41/p41 equal c where it is assumed that a = c and a ≤ b ≤ c. Using a result from Robert Hill (2006), we determine that the limiting value of the single-stage index is
Now if commodities 1 and 2 are aggregated into a subaggregate and commodities 3 and 4 into another subaggregate, using Hill’s result again, we find that the limiting price index for the first subaggregate is [ab]1/2 and the limiting price index for the second subaggregate is [bc]1/2. Now apply the second stage of aggregation and use Hill’s result once again to conclude that the limiting value of the two-stage aggregation using Pr as the index number formula is [ab2c]1/4. Thus the limiting value as r tends to plus or minus infinity of the single-stage aggregate over the two-stage aggregate is [ac]1/2/[ab2c]1/4 = [ac/b2]1/4. Now b can take on any value between a and c and so the ratio of the single stage limiting Pr to its two-stage counterpart can take on any value between [c/a]1/4 and [a/c]1/4. Because c/a is less than 1 and a/c is greater than 1, it can be seen that the ratio of the single-stage to the two-stage index can be arbitrarily far from 1 as r becomes large in magnitude with an appropriate choice of the numbers a, b, and c.
18.98 The results in the previous paragraph show that caution is required in assuming that all superlative indices will be approximately consistent in aggregation. However, for the three most commonly used superlative indices (the Fisher ideal PF, the Törnqvist Theil PT, and the Walsh PW), the available empirical evidence indicates that these indices satisfy the consistency in aggregation property to a sufficiently high enough degree of approximation that users will not be unduly troubled by any inconsistencies.59
F. Import Price Indices
F.1 The economic import price index for an establishment
18.99 Attention is now turned to the economic theory of the import input price index for an establishment. Note the nomenclature: It is an import price index that treats imports as inputs to a resident producing unit. This theory is analogous to the economic theory of the export output price index explained in Sections D and E above but now uses the joint cost function or the conditional cost function C in place of the revenue function R that was used in Section D and the behavioral assumption of minimizing costs as opposed to maximizing revenue. Our approach in this section turns out to be analogous to the Konüs (1924) theory for the true cost-of-living index in consumer theory.
18.100 Recall that in Section D above, the set St described the technology of the establishment. Thus if (y, x, z, m, v) belongs to St, then the nonnegative output vectors y of domestic outputs and x of exports can be produced by the establishment in period t if it can utilize the nonnegative vectors of z of domestic intermediate inputs, m of imported intermediate inputs, and v of primary inputs.
18.101 Let pm ≡ (pm1,…,pmN) denote a positive vector of import prices that the establishment might face in period t,60 and let y be a nonnegative vector of domestic output targets, x be a vector of export targets, and z and v be nonnegative vectors of domestic intermediate inputs and primary inputs respectively that the establishment might have available for use during period t. Then the establishment’s conditional import cost function using period t technology is defined as the solution to the following import cost minimization problem:
Thus Ct(px, y, x, z, v) is the minimum import cost, Σnpxnmm that the establishment must pay in order to produce the vectors of outputs y and x, given that it faces the vector of intermediate input prices px and given that it has the input vectors z and v available for use, using the period t technology.61
18.102 In order to make the notation for the import price index comparable to the notation used in previous chapters for price and quantity indices, in the remainder of this subsection, the import price vector pm is replaced by the vector p and the vector of import quantities m is replaced by the vector q. Thus Ct (pm, y, x, z, v) is rewritten as Ct (p, y, x, z, v). In order to further simplify the notation, the entire vector of reference quantities, [y, x, z, v], will be written as the composite quantity reference vector u. Thus Ct(p, y, x, z, v) is rewritten as Ct(p, u).
18.103 The period t conditional import input cost function Ct can be used to define the economy’s period t technology import price index Pt between any two periods, say, period 0 and period 1, as follows:
where P0 and p1 are the vectors of import prices that the establishment faces in periods 0 and 1 respectively and u is the reference vector of establishment quantities defined in the previous paragraph.62 If N = 1 so that there is only one imported commodity that the establishment uses, then it can be shown that the import price index collapses down to the single import price relative between periods 0 and 1, p11/p10. In the general case, note that the import price index defined by equation (18.79) is a ratio of hypothetical import costs that the establishment must pay in order to produce the vector of domestic outputs y and the vector of exports x, given that it has the period t technology, the vector of domestic intermediate inputs z, and the vector of primary inputs v to work with. The numerator in equation (18.79) is the minimum import cost that the establishment could attain if it faced the import prices of period 1, p1, whereas the denominator in equation (18.79) is the minimum import cost that the establishment could attain if it faced the import prices of period 0, P0. Note that all variables in the numerator and denominator of equation (18.79) except the vectors of intermediate import input prices are held constant.
18.104 As was the case with the theory of the export price index, there are a wide variety of price indices of the form of equation (18.79) depending on which (t, y, x, z, v) reference quantity vector is chosen (the reference technology is indexed by t, the reference domestic output vector is indexed by y, the reference export vector is indexed by x, the reference domestic intermediate input vector is indexed by z, and the reference primary input vector is indexed by v). As in the theory of the export price index, two special cases of the general definition of the import price index (equation 18.79) are of interest: (1) P0(p0, p1, u0), which uses the period 0 technology set, the output vector y0 that was actually produced in period 0, the export vector x0 that was produced in period 0 by the establishment, the domestic intermediate vector z0 that was used in period 0, and the primary input vector v0 that was used in period 0 and (2) p1(p0, p1, u1), which uses the period 1 technology set and reference quantities u1. Let q0 and q1 be the observed import quantity vectors for the establishment in periods 0 and 1 respectively. If there is import cost-minimizing behavior on the part of the producer in periods 0 and 1, then the observed import cost in periods 0 and 1 should be equal to C°(p°, u0) and C1(p1, u1) respectively; that is, the following equalities should hold:
18.105 Under these cost-minimizing assumptions, the arguments of Fisher and Shell (1972, pp. 57–58) and Archibald (1977, p. 66) can again be adapted to show that the two theoretical indices, P0(p0, p1, u0) and p1(p0, p1, u1), described in (1) and (2) above, satisfy the following inequalities (18.81) and (18.82):
where PL is the Laspeyres import input price index. Similarly,
where PP is the Paasche import price index. Thus the inequality (18.81) says that the observable Laspeyres index of import prices PL is an upper bound to the theoretical import index P0(p0, p1, u0) and the inequality (18.82) says that the observable Paasche index of import prices PP is a lower bound to the theoretical import price index p1(p0, p1, u1). Note that these inequalities are the reverse of the earlier inequalities (18.5) and (18.6) that were found for the export price index but the new inequalities are analogous to their counterparts in the theory of the true cost-of-living index.
18.106 As was the case in Section D.2, it is possible to define a theoretical import price index that falls between the observable Paasche and Laspeyres intermediate input price indices. To do this, first define a hypothetical import cost function, C(p,α), that corresponds to the use of an α weighted average of the technology sets S0 and S1 for periods 0 and 1 as the reference technology and that uses an α weighted average of the period 0 and period 1 reference quantity vectors, u0 and u1:
Thus the intermediate import input cost minimization problem in equation (18.83) corresponds to the α and (1 – α) weighted average of the reference quantity target vectors, (1 – α)u0 + αu1, where the period 0 reference quantity vector u0 gets the weight 1 – α and the period 1 reference quantity vector u1 gets the weight α, where a is α number between 0 and 1. The new import cost function defined by equation (18.83) can now be used to define the following family of theoretical intermediate import input price indices:
18.107 Adapting the proof of Diewert (1983a, pp. 1060–61) shows that there exists an α between 0 and 1 such that the theoretical import price index defined by equation (18.84) lies between the observable (in principle) Paasche and Laspeyres import price indices, PP and PL; that is, there exists an α such that
18.108 If the Paasche and Laspeyres indices are numerically close to each other, then equation (18.85) tells us that a “true” economic import price index is fairly well determined and a reasonably close approximation to the “true” index can be found by taking a symmetric average of PL and PP such as the geometric average which again leads to Irving Fisher’s (1922) ideal price index, PF, defined earlier by equation (18.10).
18.109 It is worth noting that the above theory of an economic import price index was very general; in particular, no restrictive functional form or separability assumptions were made about the technology.
18.110 The arguments used in Section D.3 to justify the use of the Törnqvist Theil export price index as an approximation to a theoretical export price index can be adapted to yield a justification for the use of the Törnqvist Theil import price index as an approximation to a theoretical import price index. Recall the definition of the period t conditional import cost function, Ct(px, y, x, z, v) = Ct(p, u), defined by equation (18.78) above. Now assume that the period t conditional import cost function has the following translog functional form for t = 0, 1:
where the coefficients satisfy the following restrictions:
The restrictions (18.89), (18.90), and (18.91) are necessary to ensure that Ct(p, u) is linearly homogeneous in the components of the import price vector p (which is a property that a conditional cost function must satisfy). Note that at this stage of the argument the coefficients that characterize the technology in each period (the α’s, β’s, and γ’s) are allowed to be completely different in each period.
18.111 If we adapt again the result in Caves, Christensen, and Diewert (1982b, p. 1410) to the present context:63 If the quadratic price coefficients in equation (18.86) are equal across the two periods where an index number comparison (i.e., αnj0 = αnj1 for all n, j) is being made, then the geometric mean of the economic import price index that uses period 0 technology and period 0 reference quantities, P0(p0, p1, u0), and the economic import price index that uses period 1 technology and period 1 reference quantities, p1(p0, p1, u1), is exactly equal to the Törnqvist import price index PT defined by equation (18.11);64 that is,
18.112 As was the case with the previous result (equation 18.85), the assumptions required for the result (equation 18.92) seem rather weak; in particular, there is no requirement that the technologies exhibit constant returns to scale in either period and the assumptions are consistent with technological progress occurring between the two periods being compared. Because the index number formula PT is exactly equal to the geometric mean of two theoretical economic import price indices and this corresponds to a flexible functional form, the Törnqvist import index number formula is said to be superlative.
18.113 It is possible to adapt the analysis of the output price index that was developed in Sections E.3 and E.4 above to the import price index and show that the two families of superlative output price indices, Pr* defined by equation (18.54) and Pr defined by equation (18.57), are also superlative import price indices. However, the details are omitted here because in order to derive these results, rather restrictive separability restrictions are required on the technology of the establishment.65
18.114 For the reader who has read Chapter 17 in the Producer Price Index Manual (ILO and others, 2004b), the above economic theories for the import price index for an establishment will seem very similar to the economic approaches to the intermediate input price index that appeared in that manual. In fact, the theories are exactly the same; only some of the terminology has changed. Also, another way of viewing the establishment import price index is as a subindex of a comprehensive intermediate input price index that encompasses both domestically and foreign-sourced intermediate inputs that are used by the establishment.
18.115 In the following section, the analysis presented in this section is modified to provide an economic approach to determining a household import price index.
F.2 The economic import price index for a household
18.116 The theory of the cost-of-living index for a single consumer (or household) was first developed by the Russian economist A.A. Konüs (1924). This theory relies on the assumption of optimizing behavior on the part of households. Thus given a vector of commodity prices pt that the household faces in a given time period t, this approach assumes that the corresponding observed quantity vector qt is the solution to a cost minimization problem that involves the consumer’s preference or utility function F.66 Thus in contrast to the axiomatic approach to index number theory, the economic approach does not assume that the two quantity vectors q0 and q1 are independent of the two price vectors P0 and p1. In the economic approach, the period 0 quantity vector q0 is determined by the consumer’s preference function F and the period 0 vector of prices P0 that the consumer faces and the period 1 quantity vector q1 is determined by the consumer’s preference function f and the period 1 vector of prices p1.
18.117 This household cost-of-living approach to an import price index is necessary in the present context because a small proportion of household consumption does not pass through the domestic production sector of the economy. The main expenditures of this type are tourist expenditures made abroad by domestic residents. In some countries expenditure on cross-border shopping may be a significant proportion of aggregate household consumption expenditure.
18.118 It is assumed that a household has preferences over combinations of imported goods and services, m = (m1,…,mN), and domestically supplied goods and services, y = (y1,…,yN), and these preferences can be represented by the utility function, u = F(m, y), where u is the utility the household receives if it consumes the services of the import vector m and the domestically supplied commodities y.
18.119 Given a target utility level u and a vector of domestic commodity availabilities, y, and given that the household faces the import price vector pm, the consumer’s conditional import cost function is defined as follows:
18.120 As usual, in order to make the notation in this chapter more comparable to the notation used in previous chapters, the import vector m will be replaced by the quantity vector q and the import price vector pm will be replaced by the vector p.
18.121 Suppose the household faces the import price vector P0 in period 0 and p1 in period 1. Suppose also that the household has available the domestic quantity vector y for use in both periods. Finally, suppose that the household wants to achieve the same standard of living in each period; that is, the household wants to achieve the utility level u in each period at minimum import cost. Under these conditions, the household’s conditional import cost function defined above can be used in order to define the following family of household import price indices:
18.122 There is a family of household import price indices; that is, as the standard of living indexed by the utility level u changes and as the reference vector of domestic quantity availabilities y changes, the import price index defined by equation (18.94) will change.
18.123 It is natural to choose two specific reference quantity vectors y and reference utility levels in definition (18.94): the observed base period domestic quantity vector y0 that the household had available in period 0 along with the period 0 level of utility that was achieved by the household, u0, and the period 1 counterparts, y1 and u1. It is also reasonable to assume that the household period 0 observed import vector m0 = q0 solves the following period 0 conditional cost minimization problem:
18.124 Similarly, it is reasonable to assume that the household period 1 observed import vector m1 = q1 solves the following period 1 conditional cost minimization problem:
Using assumptions (18.95) and (18.96), it is easy to establish the following bounds on two special cases of the family of import price indices defined by equation (18.94).
18.125 Consider the import price index that results when u is set equal to u0 and y is set equal to y0:
where PL is the Laspeyres price index defined in earlier chapters.67
18.126 The second of the two natural choices for a reference domestic quantity vector y and utility level u in definition (18.94) is y1 and u1. In this case the household import price index becomes
where PP is the Paasche price index defined earlier.68
18.127 At this stage, the reader will realize that the household theory of the import price index is more or less isomorphic to the establishment theory of the import price index that was developed in the previous section: The household conditional cost function replaces the establishment conditional cost function and the household price index concept defined by equation (18.94) replaces the establishment price index concept defined by equation (18.79). The same type of results that were established in the previous section can be established in the household context. Again, the Fisher and Törnqvist import price indices can be given strong justifications. The quadratic mean of order r price indices can also be justified in the present context with an appropriate separability assumption.69
However, see Chapters 4 and 15 on supply and use tables in volume terms and the corresponding valuation requirements for price indices.
The establishments, of course, may be owned or controlled by units in any institutional sector: nonfinancial and financial corporations, general government, households, and nonprofit institutions serving households (NPISHs). By definition, establishments, including those owned by general government, households, and NPISHs, combine nonfinancial assets and intermediate consumption to produce output, and they can engage in capital formation, but do not make final consumption expenditures. The “use of income accounts” of these noncorporation institutional units thus includes not only the capital formation expenditure these noncorporations have made, but also final consumption expenditure. This chapter distinguishes between the international trade noncorporation institutional units undertake for their own intermediate consumption and capital formation, and the international trade they undertake for final consumption.
It should be noted that 2008 SNA does have a recommended optional Table 15.1, which is suited to our present needs; that is, this table provides the detail for imports by industry by way of a use table in basic prices that separates imports from domestic production. However, 2008 SNA does not provide a recommendation for a corresponding commodity by industry table for exports.
In this modified definition of an establishment, it is generally a smaller collection of production units than a firm because a firm may be multinational. Thus, another way of defining an establishment for our practical purposes is as follows: An establishment is the smallest aggregate of national production units able to provide accounting information on its inputs and outputs for the time period under consideration.
For many highly specialized intermediate inputs in a multistage production process using proprietary technologies, market prices may simply not exist. Furthermore, several alternative concepts could be used to define transfer prices; see Diewert (1985) and Eden (1998) and Chapter 18 of this Manual. The 2008 SNA(Paragraph 3.128) noted that: “In some cases actual exchange values may not represent market prices. Examples are transactions involving transfer prices between affiliated enterprises, manipulative agreements with third parties, and certain non-commercial transactions, including concessional interest (that is, interest payable at a reduced rate as a matter of policy). Prices may be under- or over-invoiced, in which case an assessment of a market-equivalent price needs to be made. Although adjustment should be made when actual exchange values do not represent market prices, this may not be practical in many cases.” It continued (Paragraph 3.129): “Such transactions should be made explicit if their value is considerable and would hinder a proper interpretation of the accounts. In some cases, transfer pricing may be motivated by income distribution or equity build-ups or withdrawals. Replacing book values (transfer prices) with market-value equivalents is desirable in principle, when the distortions are large and when availability of data (such as adjustments by customs or tax officials or from partner economies) makes it feasible to do so. Selection of the best market-value equivalents to replace book values is an exercise calling for cautious and informed judgment.”
These pricing problems are pursued in Chapter 6, where the concept of a market price for each product produced by an establishment during the accounting period under consideration is the value of production for that product divided by the quantity produced during that period; that is, the price is the average price for that product. There are also practical difficulties in separating domestic transport costs out of the prices of imported goods and services.
Rowe was one of the first economists to appreciate the difficulties statisticians faced when attempting to construct price or quantity indices of production: “In the construction of an index of production there are three inherent difficulties which, inasmuch as they are almost insurmountable, impose on the accuracy of the index, limitations, which under certain circumstances may be somewhat serious. The first is that many of the products of industry are not capable of quantitative measurement. This difficulty appears in its most serious form in the case of the engineering industry. … The second inherent difficulty is that the output of an industry, even when quantitatively measurable, may over a series of years change qualitatively as well as quantitatively. Thus during the last twenty years there has almost certainly been a tendency towards an improvement in the average quality of the yarn and cloth produced by the cotton industry.… The third inherent difficulty lies in the inclusion of new industries which develop importance as the years go on” (1927, pp. 174–75). These three difficulties still exist today: Think of the difficulties involved in measuring the outputs of the insurance and gambling industries; an increasing number of industries produce outputs that are one of a kind, and, hence, price and quantity comparisons are necessarily difficult if not impossible; and, finally, the huge increases in research and development expenditures by firms and governments have led to ever increasing numbers of new products and industries. Chapter 8 considers the issues for index compilation arising from new and disappearing goods and services, as well as establishments.
An early study that computed Fisher ideal indices for a distribution firm in western Canada for seven quarters aggregating over 76,000 inventory items is found in Diewert and Smith (1994).
The theory may be found in Chapter 17 of the Consumer Price Index Manual (ILO and others, 2004a).
Depending on the context, these export prices may be either the per unit amounts that foreign demanders pay to the establishment or these prices may be adjusted for commodity tax or subsidy payments as in Section B.
The function Rt is closely related to the GDP function or the national product function in the international trade literature; see Kohli (1978, 1991) or Woodland (1982). It was introduced into the economics literature by Samuelson (1953). Alternative terms for this function include (1) the gross profit function; see Gorman (1968); (2) the restricted profit function; see Lau (1976) and McFadden (1978); and (3) the variable profit function; see Diewert (1973, 1974a). The mathematical properties of the conditional revenue function are laid out in these references.
This concept of the export price index was defined in Alterman, Diewert, and Feenstra (1999, pp.10–13) and it is closely related to output price indices defined by Fisher and Shell (1972, pp. 56–58), Samuelson and Swamy (1974, pp. 588–92), Archibald (1977, pp. 60–61), Diewert (1980, pp. 460–61; 1983a, p. 1055), and Balk (1998a, pp. 83–89). Readers who are familiar with the theory of the true cost-of-living index will note that the output price index defined by (18.2) is analogous to the true cost-of-living index which is a ratio of cost functions, say C(p1, u)/C(p0, u), where u is a reference utility level: R replaces C and the reference utility level u is replaced by the vector of reference variables (t, y, z, m, v). The optimizing behavior for the cost-of-living index is one of minimization while that for the export output price index is revenue maximization. For references to the theory of the true cost-of-living index, see Konüs (1924), Pollak (1983), or the consumer price index counterpart to this manual (ILO and others, 2004a).
This is due to the fact that the optimization problem in the cost-of-living theory is a cost minimization problem as opposed to our present revenue maximization problem. The method of proof used to derive equations (18.5) and (18.6) dates back to Konüs (1924), Hicks (1940), and Samuelson (1950).
However, validity of the inequality (18.6) does not depend on the relative position of the two output production possibilities sets. To obtain the strict inequality version of equation (18.6), it is necessary that two conditions be satisfied: (1) the frontier of the period 1 output production possibilities set needs to be “curved” and (2) relative output prices must change going from period 0 to 1 so that the two price lines through G and H in Figure 18.1 are tangent to different points on the frontier of the period 1 output production possibilities set.
The Laspeyres export price index is a lower bound to the theoretical index P0(p0, p1, u0) while the Paasche output price index is an upper bound to the theoretical index P1(p0, p1, u1).
When α = 0, R(p, 0) = R0(p, u0) and when α = 1, R(p,1) = R1(p, u1).
This is a normal output substitution effect. However, empirically, it will often happen that observed period-to-period decreases in price are not accompanied by corresponding decreases in supply. However, these abnormal “substitution” effects can be rationalized as the effects of technological progress. For example, suppose the price of computer chips decreases substantially from period 0 to 1. If the technology were constant over these two periods, we would expect domestic producers to decrease their supply of chips going from period 0 to 1. In actual fact, the opposite happens. The fall in price is driven by technological progress arising from a reduction in the cost of producing chips which is passed on to demanders of chips. Thus the effects of technological progress should not be ignored in the theory of the output price index. The counterpart to technological change in the theory of the cost-of-living index is taste change, which is often ignored.
Diewert adapted a method of proof originally developed by Konüs (1924) in the consumer context. Sufficient conditions on the period 0 and 1 technology sets for the result to hold are given in Diewert (1983a, p. 1105). Our exposition of the material in Sections D. E, and F.1 also draws on Alterman, Diewert, and Feenstra (1999).
It should be noted that Fisher (1922) constructed Laspeyres, Paasche, and Fisher output price indices for his U.S. data set. Fisher also adopted the view that the product of the price and quantity index should equal the value ratio between the two periods under consideration, an idea that he already formulated in Fisher (1911, p. 403). He did not consider explicitly the problem of deflating value added but by 1930, his ideas on deflation and the measurement of quantity growth being essentially the same problem had spread to the problem of deflating nominal value added; see Burns (1930).
This functional form was introduced and named by Christensen, Jorgenson, and Lau (1971). It was adapted to the revenue function or profit function context by Diewert (1974a).
Recall that the vector of reference quantities u was defined by (18.3) and is equal to (y, z, m, v). If the same commodity classification is used for domestically produced goods y, for domestic intermediate inputs z, and for imports and if the number of primary inputs v is K, then the u vector will have dimension 3N + K, which we denote by M.
It is also assumed that the symmetry conditions αnjt = αjnt for all n, j and for t = 0, 1 and γmkt = γkmt for all m, k and for t = 0, 1 are satisfied.
See Diewert (1973 and 1974a) for the regularity conditions that a revenue or profit function must satisfy.
See Diewert (1993b, pp. 169–74) for a more detailed description of these techniques for modeling monopolistic behavior and for additional references to the literature.
This method for justifying aggregation over commodities was developed by Shephard (1953, pp. 61–71). It is assumed that f(q) is an increasing, positive, and convex function of q for positive q. Samuelson and Swamy (1974) and Diewert (1980, pp. 438–42) also developed this approach to index number theory.
This terminology follows that used by Geary and Morishima (1973). The concept of weak separability dates back to Sono (1945). A survey of separability concepts can be found in Blackorby, Primont, and Russell (1978).
Suppose that in period 0, the vector of inputs v0 produces the vector of outputs q0. Our separability assumptions imply that the same vector of inputs v0 could produce any vector of outputs q such that f(q) = f(q0). In real life, as q varied, we would expect that the corresponding input requirements would also vary instead of remaining fixed.
The assumptions about the technology of the establishment that are made in Section D of this chapter are considerably stronger than the assumptions that were made in Section C above, where we made no separability assumptions at all. However, in the previous section, the export aggregates were conditional on a reference vector of quantities u, whereas in the present section, unconditional export aggregates are obtained.
It can be shown that r(p) has the following mathematical properties: r(p) is a nonnegative, nondecreasing, convex, and positively linearly homogeneous function for strictly positive p vectors; see Diewert (1974b) or Samuelson and Swamy (1974). A function r(p) is convex if for every strictly positive p1 and p2 and number λ such that 0 ≤ λ ≤ 1, r(λp1 + (1 – λ)p2) ≤ λr(p1) + (1 – λ)r(p2). A function r(p) is positively linearly homogeneous if for every positive vector p and positive number λ, we have r(λp) = λr(p).
For additional material on revenue and factor requirements functions, see Diewert (1974b).
The separability assumptions (18.44) play the same role in the economic theory of output price indices as the assumption of homothetic preferences does in the economic theory of cost-of-living indices.
Note that under the separability assumptions (18.17), the family of export price indices defined by (18.2) simplifies to the unit export revenue function ratio r(p1)/r(p0), which depends only on export prices (and not the reference quantity vector u) and the corresponding export quantity index is f(x1)/f(x0), which depends only on quantities of exports produced during the two periods under consideration.
In the following section, in order to make the notation more comparable with the notation used in previous chapters, the export quantity vector x will be replaced by the quantity vector q.
Actually, Wold derived his result in the context of a consumer utility maximization problem but his result carries over to the present production context.
To prove this, consider the first order necessary conditions for the strictly positive vector qt to solve the period t export revenue maximization problem,
Differentiate both sides of the equation f(λq) = fλ(q) with respect to λ and then evaluate the resulting equation at λ = 1. The equation
Fisher (1922, p. 247) used the term superlative to describe the Fisher ideal price index. Thus Diewert adopted Fisher’s terminology but attempted to give some precision to Fisher’s definition of superlativeness. Fisher defined an index number formula to be superlative if it approximated the corresponding Fisher ideal results using his data set.
Given the producer’s unit export revenue function r(p), it is possible to modify a technique in Diewert (1974a, p. 112) and show that the corresponding export aggregator function f(q) can be defined as follows: for a strictly positive quantity vector
Note that we have shown that the Fisher index PF is exact for the output aggregator function defined by equation (18.38) as well as the output aggregator function that corresponds to the unit revenue function defined by equation (18.43). These two output aggregator functions do not coincide in general. However, if the N by N symmetric matrix A of the aik has an inverse, then it can readily be shown that the N by N matrix B of the bik will equal A–1.
This terminology was used by Diewert (1976, p. 130). This functional form was first defined by Denny (1974) as a unit cost function.
The justifications for the Fisher and Törnqvist indices presented in Sections D.2 and D.3 are stronger than the justifications for the other superlative indices presented in Sections E.3 and E.4 because the arguments in Sections D.2 and D.3 did not rely on restrictive separability assumptions.
To prove the equalities in equations (18.62) through (18.66), simply differentiate the various index number formulae and evaluate the derivatives at p0 = p1 and q0 = q1. Actually, equations (18.61) through (18.66) are still true provided that p1 = λp0 and q1 = μq0 for any numbers λ > 0 and μ > 0, that is, provided that the period 1 price vector is proportional to the period 0 price vector and that the period 1 quantity vector is proportional to the period 0 quantity vector.
See Hardy, Littlewood, and Pólya (1934). Actually, Allen and Diewert (1981, p. 434) obtained the result in equation (18.67), but they did not appreciate its significance.
Robert Hill (2006) documented this for two data sets. His time-series data consist of annual expenditure and quantity data for 64 components of U.S. gross domestic product from 1977 to 1994. For this data set, Hill (2006, p. 16) found that “superlative indices can differ by more than a factor of two (i.e., by more than 100 percent), even though Fisher and Törnqvist never differ by more than 0.6 percent.”
Diewert (1980, p. 451) showed that the Törnqvist index PT is a limiting case of Pr as r tends to 0.
See, for example, Diewert (1978, p. 894) or Fisher (1922), which is reproduced in Diewert (1976, p. 135).
Much of the initial material in this section is adapted from Diewert (1978) and Alterman, Diewert, and Feenstra (1999).
See also Vartia (1976a and 1976b) and Balk (1996b) for a discussion of alternative definitions for the two-stage aggregation concept and references to the literature on this topic.
See Diewert (1978, p. 889), who utilized some of Vartia’s (1976a, 1976b) results. In other words, a string of equalities similar to (18.61) through (18.66) holds between the two-stage indices and their single-stage counterparts. In fact, these equalities are still true provided that p1 = λp0 and q1 = μq0 for any numbers λ > 0 and μ > 0.
For an empirical comparison of the four indices, see Diewert (1978, pp. 894–95). For the Canadian consumer data considered there, the chained two-stage Fisher in 1971 was 2.3228 and the corresponding chained two-stage Törnqvist was 2.3230, the same values as for the corresponding single-stage indices.
See Chapter 19 for some additional evidence on this topic.
From the viewpoint of economic theory, these prices should include all taxes and transportation margins, because when the establishment chooses its cost minimizing import quantities, what is relevant is the total cost of delivering these inputs to the establishment door. However, as was seen in Section B above, it often does no harm if these total import cost prices are decomposed into two or more separate terms, with the foreign price shown as one term and the tax and transportation terms shown as additional terms. However, these tax and transportation margin terms will affect establishment behavior according to the economic approach to price indices and so these terms cannot be ignored.
See McFadden (1978) for the mathematical properties of a conditional cost function. Alternatively, we note that—Ct(pm, y, x, z, v) has the same mathematical properties as the revenue function Rt defined earlier in this chapter.
This concept of the import price index is the same as the concept defined in Alterman, Diewert, and Feenstra (1999). This concept is related to the physical production cost index defined by Court and Lewis (1942–43, p. 30).
The Caves, Christensen, and Diewert translog exactness result is slightly more general than a similar translog exactness result that was obtained earlier by Diewert and Morrison (1986, p. 668); Diewert and Morrison assumed that all of the quadratic terms in equation (18.86) were equal to each other during the two periods under consideration whereas Caves, Christensen, and Diewert assumed only that αnj0 = αnj1 for all n, j. See Kohli (1990) for closely related results.
Of course, in the present context, export prices are replaced by import prices.
The counterpart to our earlier separability assumption (18.17) is now v1 = Ft(y, x, z, m, v2,…, vK) = Gt(y, x, z, f(m), v2, …, vK) for t = 0, 1 where the import aggregator function f is linearly homogeneous and independent of t.
For a description of the economic theory of the input and output price indexes, see Balk (1998a). In the economic theory of the output price index, qt is assumed to be the solution to a revenue maximization problem involving the output price vector pt.
This type of inequality was first obtained by Konüs (1924, 1939, p. 17). See also Pollak (1983).
This type of inequality is also from Konus (1924, 1939, p. 19). See also Pollak (1983).